Should I stay or should I go? residential
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Should I stay or should I go? Housing and residential mobility across OECD countries by Orsetta Causa and Jacob Pichelmann Promoting residential mobility is not an end in itself, still it is an important policy challenge, especially in countries with large spatial disparities and labour market skills mismatches. Policies that remove disincentives to move are likely to bring efficiency and equity gains by lifting productivity growth and social mobility. Residential mobility is one way to encourage labour market adjustment and reallocation to encourage a smooth recovery from the Covid-19 crisis. Recent work by Causa and Pichelmann (2020) presents new evidence on housing and residential mobility across OECD countries and on the role of individual factors and policies, in particular housing policies, in enhancing or hampering mobility. The evidence strongly supports the view that housing conditions and structural policies influence people’s decisions and possibilities to move. To set the scene, there is a strong negative association between countries’ homeownership rates and their mobility rates, confirming previous evidence in this area. Mobility is particularly low in Eastern European countries exhibiting very high homeownership rates for historical reasons and also in large Southern European countries (e.g. Italy and Spain). The negative cross-country association between homeownership and residential mobility arises because across all countries, homeowners, whether outright owners or owners paying back
mortgage debt, are much less mobile than renters, controlling for an extensive array of individual and household drivers of mobility. By influencing mobility, the housing market can give rise to externalities, in particular on the labour market. The implication is that housing conditions and policies that magnify the cost of moving are likely to affect economic efficiency and equality of opportunities. Analyzing the policy drivers of residential mobility yields the following findings: A more responsive housing supply is associated with higher residential mobility. Reducing policy-driven barriers in this area, for example reforming poorly designed land-use and planning policies, may facilitate moving by reducing house price differences across locations. Stricter rental regulations are associated with lower residential mobility, particularly for low-educated and low-income households. Rental regulations need to strike a balance between tenants’ and landlords’ interests, create security of tenure and encourage the supply of rental housing for all socio-economic groups.
Social cash and in-kind spending on housing are positively correlated with residential mobility. While housing allowances are in principle more favorable to mobility than direct provision of social housing, the latter can be designed to avoid lock-in effects, for example, by waiving residency or queuing requirements in the case of unemployed workers taking up a job in the region. Higher transaction costs in buying and selling a home, in particular from transfer taxes and notary fees, are associated with lower residential mobility, especially among younger households, which are more likely to be first time-buyers. Tax reforms shifting housing taxation from non-recurrent (e.g. transfer) to recurrent taxes would help reducing barriers to mobility, on top of making the tax system more efficient with positive aggregate growth effects. Beyond housing policies, more generous cash income support to low-wage jobseekers and minimum income schemes embedded in social transfers are positively associated with residential mobility. By contrast, excessive job protection on regular contracts is negatively associated with mobility, particularly for youth, low-income and low-educated individuals. This suggests that shifting protection from jobs to individuals coupled with job counselling and training may help removing barriers to mobility.
This study highlights the importance of removing policy-driven obstacles to mobility and offers insights enabling policy makers to balance between encouraging people to move from less to more productive areas and avoiding the emergence of left- behind areas. It poses the question whether tax-favoring of owner-occupied housing is in need of rethinking and makes a case for reducing tax-driven barriers to mobility, such as housing transfer takes, while taking resilience implications into consideration. The findings underline the importance of housing-related policies that support affordability, especially for households at the bottom of the distribution: well-designed housing allowances and social housing, balanced rental market regulations, and a responsive housing supply. Further reading: Causa, O. and J. Pichelmann (2020), “Should I stay or should I go? Housing and residential mobility across OECD countries”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1626, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/d91329c2-en
Tax challenges from digitalisation: A global two- pillar solution could increase tax revenues and support economic activity By David Bradbury, Tibor Hanappi, Pierce O’Reilly, Ana Cinta González Cabral (OECD Centre for Tax Policy and Administration), Åsa Johansson, Stéphane Sorbe, Valentine Millot, Sébastien Turban (OECD Economics Department) The international corporate tax system faces growing challenges. While the OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) project represented an unprecedented multilateral effort to tackle profit shifting, many questions over the allocation of taxing rights remain unresolved. Digitalisation and globalisation have highlighted certain vulnerabilities in the existing framework, which allocates taxing rights principally on the basis of physical presence. In addition to this, some BEPS issues remain. In this context, an increasing number of jurisdictions are taking uncoordinated and unilateral actions (e.g. digital services taxes), contributing to an increase in tax and trade disputes and growing tax uncertainty. The COVID-19 crisis is exacerbating these tensions by accelerating the digitalisation of the economy and increasing pressures on public finances. The fact that many firms have benefitted from direct or indirect government support during the crisis is also likely to intensify public dissatisfaction with tax avoidance by multinational enterprises (MNEs).
Towards a global two-pillar solution Against this backdrop, the OECD/G20 Inclusive Framework on BEPS (Inclusive Framework), which brings together 137 member jurisdictions, is discussing proposals for a consensus-based reform of the international tax rules to address the tax challenges arising from the digitalisation of the economy. The proposals fall under two pillars, which are described in the Pillar One and Pillar Two Blueprint reports released last week (OECD, 2020a; OECD, 2020b). In their latest communiqué, G20 Finance Ministers confirmed that they remain committed to further progress on both pillars and urged the Inclusive Framework to address the remaining issues with a view to reaching a global and consensus-based solution by mid-2021 (G20, 2020). Pillar One seeks to adapt the international corporate tax system to the digital age through significant changes to the rules applicable to business profits to ensure that the allocation of taxing rights on business profits is no longer exclusively determined by reference to physical presence. Pillar Two aims to address remaining BEPS challenges and is designed to ensure that large internationally operating businesses pay a minimum level of tax regardless of where they are headquartered or the jurisdictions they operate in. This blog post summarises the main findings of the Economic Impact Assessment of the proposals carried out by the OECD Secretariat (OECD, 2020c). This is an ‘ex ante’ assessment, which relies on a number of illustrative assumptions on proposal design and parameters, without prejudice to the final decisions of the Inclusive Framework. The proposals would increase global tax
revenues Pillar One and Pillar Two could increase global corporate income tax (CIT) revenues by about USD 50-80 billion per year. Taking into account the combined effect of these reforms and the US GILTI regime, the total effect could represent USD 60-100 billion per year or up to around 4% of global CIT revenues. Pillar One would involve a significant change to the way taxing rights are allocated among jurisdictions, as taxing rights on about USD 100 billion of profit could be reallocated to market jurisdictions. This would lead to a modest increase in global tax revenues. On average, low, middle and high income economies would all benefit from revenue gains, while ‘investment hubs’ would tend to lose tax revenues. Pillar Two would yield a significant increase in CIT revenues and significantly reduce the incentives for MNEs to shift profits to low-tax jurisdictions, which would generate revenue gains in addition to the direct gains resulting from the implementation of the new rules. The combined revenue gains from the two pillars are estimated to be broadly similar – as a share of current CIT revenues – across low, middle and high income jurisdictions (Figure 1).
A consensus-based solution would support investment and economic growth A consensus-based multilateral solution involving Pillar One and Pillar Two would lead to a more favourable environment for investment and growth than would likely be the case in absence of an agreement by the Inclusive Framework: The two pillars would lead to a relatively small increase in the average (post-tax) investment costs of MNEs (Hanappi and González Cabral, 2020). The ensuing negative effect on global investment is estimated to be very small, as the proposals would mostly affect highly profitable MNEs whose investment is less sensitive to taxes (Millot et al., 2020). Overall, the negative effect on global GDP stemming from the expected increase in tax revenues associated with the proposals is estimated to be less than 0.1% in the long term. In contrast, the absence of a consensus-based solution would likely lead to a proliferation of uncoordinated
and unilateral tax measures (e.g. digital services taxes) and an increase in damaging tax and trade disputes. This would undermine tax certainty and investment and also result in additional compliance and administration costs. The magnitude of the negative consequences would depend on the extent, design and scope of these unilateral measures, and the scale of any ensuing trade retaliation. In the “worst-case” scenario, these disputes could reduce global GDP by more than 1% (Figure 2). The COVID-19 crisis has increased the need for reform The full impact of the COVID-19 crisis remains highly uncertain at this stage, but a few likely implications for the impact assessment of Pillar One and Pillar Two already stand out: The COVID-19 crisis is likely to reduce the expected
revenue gains from the proposals at least in the short run as the crisis weighs on the profitability of many MNEs, even though some digital-intensive MNEs have managed to sustain or enhance their profitability since the beginning of the crisis. The crisis has accelerated the digitalisation of the economy, increasing the need to address the tax challenges arising from digitalisation. References G20 (2020), “Communiqué – G20 Finance Ministers & Central Bank Governors Meeting”, https://g20.org/en/media/Documents/FMCBG%20Communiqu%C3%A9_Eng lish_14October2020_700pm.pdf. Hanappi, T. and A. González Cabral (2020), “The impact of the pillar one and pillar two proposals on MNE’s investment costs : An analysis using forward-looking effective tax rates”, OECD Taxation Working Papers, No. 50, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/b0876dcf-en. Millot, V. et al. (2020), “Corporate Taxation and Investment of Multinational Firms: Evidence from Firm-Level Data”, OECD Taxation Working Papers, No. 51, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9c6f9f2e-en. OECD (2020a), Tax Challenges Arising from Digitalisation – Report on Pillar One Blueprint: Inclusive Framework on BEPS, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/beba0634-en. OECD (2020b), Tax Challenges Arising from Digitalisation – Report on Pillar Two Blueprint: Inclusive Framework on BEPS, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/abb4c3d1-en. OECD (2020c), Tax Challenges Arising from Digitalisation – Economic Impact Assessment: Inclusive Framework on BEPS,
OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/0e3cc2d4-en. Navigating the United Kingdom towards fairer weather By Annabelle Mourougane, Trade and Agriculture Directorate The United Kingdom is sailing through troubled waters. Like other economies, the country is experiencing one of the most severe downturns in decades since the outbreak of the COVID-19 crisis. In addition, it has to manage its exit from the European Union, following almost 50 years of deep integration, and address its long-standing productivity gap. The country is at a critical juncture. Decisions made now about management of the COVID-19 crisis and future trade relationships will have a lasting impact on the country’s economic trajectory for the years to come. The latest OECD Economic Survey of the United Kindgom investigates these three inter-related issues in depth and puts forward recommendations to steer towards fairer weather.
Moving from emergency to a new phase of targeted support is essential to chart a course to a sustainable recovery. The United Kingdom has been hit hard by the COVID-19 crisis. Policy reaction to limit long-term scarring of the economy has been massive. A large majority of firms applied to the Coronavirus Job Retention Scheme. Since July, the Government has moved to a new phase of support by phasing out some emergency measures, and extending and introducing others, including programmes to help people get back to work. A key challenge will be ensuring that people in activities that are lastingly impacted by the COVID-19 crisis are able to move to new activities and do not become detached from the labour market. It will be important to ensure support remains available as needed given epidemiological and economic developments, and to consider introducing more targeted measures. Further increasing active labour market spending to support displaced and low-skilled workers will also help to get people back to work in good-quality jobs and to support low-income households. The crisis also provides an opportunity to move toward a greener economy and to meet the UK’s ambitious target of zero net emissions by 2050 by investments that will help to lower emissions in the transport sectors. A smooth exit from the EU Single Market and Customs Union and maintaining close trade relationships with the UK’s largest trading partners will be essential to maintain on course toward a sustainable recovery. Estimates from the OECD METRO model suggest that the trade impact of entering a Free Trade Agreement with the European Union with zero tariffs and without quotas would be much less costly than an exit without a deal (Arriola et al., 2020). Firms will nevertheless have to adapt to new trading relations and the overall output loss could amount to 3.5% in the medium term compared to the present situation. About two-thirds of the cost would come from rising trade costs on goods and the remaining third stems from rising regulations on services. Keeping low barriers to
trade and investment vis-à-vis EU and non EU countries and seeking high market access for services, including financial services, would help key sectors to continue to flourish. Fostering productivity in the service sector is key to ensuring recovery and sustained growth. Productivity growth in the United Kingdom has consistently underperformed relative to expectations and has been disappointed more than in most other OECD economies since at least the global financial crisis (Figure 1). Sluggish productivity growth in the service sectors was the main factor behind this weak performance. Raising productivity will help to sustain employment and wages, but there is no silver-bullet: it will require a broad range of policies. Data: https://stat.link/3vd4tl Keeping low barriers to trade and competition will create a supportive environment for strong productivity performance for the UK service sectors. Prioritising digital infrastructure in the allocation of the planned increase in public investment would bring large productivity dividends. Further increasing public spending on training to develop the digital skills of low-qualified workers, who have been particularly affected by the COVID-19 crisis, will be a double-dividend policy,
boosting productivity and lowering inequality. Navigating through the current waves will be challenging, but there, policy can steer a course to a fairer, greener and more resilient economy. References OECD (2020), OECD Economic Surveys: United Kingdom 2020, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/2f684241-en. Arriola, C., S. Benz, A. Mourougane and F. Van Tongeren (forthcoming), “The Trade Impact of the UK’s Leaving the EU Single Market”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, OECD Publishing, Paris. Five priorities to help rejuvenate Greece’s labour market after the COVID-19 crisis by Tim Bulman, Greece Desk, OECD Economics Department Across the globe, the COVID-19 crisis has hit workers with temporary contracts and those working in tourism and consumer- related services particularly hard. These groups make up large shares of Greece’s workforce, and tourism’s strong growth in recent years. Greece’s government is currently planning how the European Recovery and Resilience Facility will help overcome the COVID-19 shock and move the economy to a path of sustained and
stronger growth. To support Greece’s workers through the COVID-19 crisis and to set the labour force for a stronger recovery, the OECD’s new Working Paper on ‘Rejuvenating Greece’s labour market to generate more and higher-quality jobs’ highlights five policy priorities: 1. Strengthen the social safety net’s protection for low- income households (Figure 1). Reforms to Greece’s social protection in recent years helped reduce poverty prior to the COVID-19 crisis but important coverage gaps remain. Further raising the value of Guaranteed Minimum Income transfers while tapering transfers to ensure that work pays would help protect households from income losses. Responsive and efficient administrative processes are vital for vulnerable households to access this support when they need it. 2. Better support caregivers. Around the world, the COVID-19 crisis has disrupted schools and workplaces, and added to the pressures on family caregivers. In Greece, comparatively few young children are enrolled in early childhood education and care, while support to care for elderly relatives is limited. This can make the barriers to working or to engaging in adult education and training insurmountable (Figure 2), contributing
to low employment rates among women in Greece. 3. Improve access to active labour market policies for job search, training and work experience. This will improve employment prospects and help employers find the skills they need (Figure 3). Greece has been boosting the capacity of its public employment services, but they play a smaller role in Greece’s labour market than in other OECD countries and suffer a legacy of under investment. Leveraging private sector providers to complement the public employment services would allow Greece to swiftly boost its capacity to support jobseekers to find lasting jobs.
4. Dramatically expand access to adult education and reskilling programmes. This would help prepare Greece’s workers for new career opportunities, and ensure workers are ready for the coming opportunities and disruption from digitalisation. Historically, participation in lifelong learning has been low in Greece, and much of the workforce’s skills need upgrading to employers’ modern needs. Deep downturns such as the COVID-19 crisis are the best time to invest in adult education. Greece can do this by financing access to courses, encouraging universities to provide courses for adults that develop professional skills, and by certifying the quality and contents of private providers’ courses. 5. Reducing social contribution rates while aligning effective income tax rates across different employment types would reduce both the cost of employing workers and the incentives to work semi-formally. Greece’s high labour income tax and social contribution wedge create high employment costs and reduce the return from working. The government is cutting some tax and social contribution rates. Large differences in tax rates depending on the legal form of employment can encourage
self-employment. The self-employed are generally less productive and more at risk from income shocks, such as the shock from the COVID-19 crisis. Aligning tax rates across employment types would reduce the incentive to be self- employed. It would boost the tax base, and so support revenues. The Working Paper discusses how Greece can pursue these priorities. The Paper accompanies the 2020 Economic Survey of Greece , launched in July 2020. The Survey estimated that pursuing these priorities would boost incomes by 5% by 2030 and by more over the following years. Along with other reforms outlined in the Survey, these five priorities can contribute to Greece reversing the COVID-19 shock and moving to stronger and sustained recovery. For more details see: Bulman, T. (2020), “Rejuvenating Greece’s labour market to generate more and higher-quality jobs”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1622, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/8ea5033a-en. 2020 OECD Economic Survey of Greece Why are some U.S. cities successful, while others are not? Past lessons for the
post COVID-19 era By Fozan Fareed, Patrick Lenain and Douglas Sutherland1 The COVID-19 pandemic has triggered severe recessions around the world. Beyond this short-term impact, long-lasting changes are also likely to happen. After past shocks, such as the global financial crisis, some industries have remained depressed for a long time, while others got back on their feet and returned to growth quickly, as shown by the evidence from the United States. Similarly, past shocks have hit large cities: some have been quick to recover, but others have struggled for many years, with severe social consequences. Drawing lessons from past shocks is useful as cities plan their own recovery from the pandemic — see also OECD (2020a). Our research investigated why some cities have adapted to shocks, while others have struggled (Azzopardi et al., forthcoming). We built a dataset covering the 372 metropolitan areas and took advantage of the new Job-to-Job flow statistics compiled by the U.S. Census Bureau, which tracks all job 2 moves. We used a machine-learning algorithm to classify the metropolitan areas in statistically distinct clusters. Preliminary results were included in the 2020 OECD Economic Survey of the United States. Four categories of cities were identified: booming areas (67),
prosperous mega metropolitan areas (99), resilient areas (149), and distressed metropolitan areas (57). This classification was obtained by focusing on indicators such as the job-to-job mobility rate, unemployment rate, income growth, population increase and GDP growth rate. The results show that prosperous cities are predominantly located in the West and the South of the United States (Figure 1). The main features of their success have revolved around embracing digital technologies, adopting local regulations friendly to job mobility and business creation, avoiding strict rules on land-use and housing market, and improving the wellbeing of the city’s population 3 . These results highlight that cities adopting well-targeted policies can accelerate the return to growth after a shock. Booming metropolitan areas: These 67 metropolitan areas, home to about 7% of urban population, have enjoyed very fast growth of GDP per capita. They have often found success thanks to fast-growing industries, notably technology clusters – Midland, Austin, and Colorado
Springs are examples. Other cities have found prosperity by becoming retirement destinations – most obviously cities in Florida (The Villages, Pensacola area, Panama City). They have become magnets for people looking for good jobs, high quality of life and comparatively low cost of living. For example, in 2017, about 305,000 workers were attracted by cities in Texas, many having decided to leave California and Louisiana. About 260,000 workers left states such as Georgia and New York and moved to Florida. Prosperous mega metropolitan areas: This cluster is the largest one: it includes 99 metropolitan areas and about three quarters of the U.S. urban population resides here. These are very large cities, with an average population size of 2 million, which can take advantage of agglomeration externalities. This category includes some of the largest U.S. metropolitan areas such as New York, Los Angeles, Chicago, Dallas, Houston, Washington DC and Miami. They have stayed buoyant in the face of shocks and have benefited from low unemployment rates, average job mobility rate, and a high income per capita as compared to other clusters. However, rising inequality is a challenge here, and their future will depend on improving housing affordability and transportation. Resilient metropolitan areas: 149 metropolitan areas are part of this cluster and account for about 11% of the urban population. This cluster is mainly composed of relatively smaller areas such as Lewiston, ID-WA, Great Falls, MT, Columbus, IN and Kokomo, IN. Neither booming nor in distress, these areas are generally classified by relatively low job mobility. However, they have a comparatively higher income per capita growth rate, and a number of these areas seem to be on an upward trajectory. The average population size of this group is
the lowest among all clusters. Distressed metropolitan areas: Home to 6% of the total urban population, these 57 metropolitan areas are characterized by a low job mobility rate, high unemployment rate, and low GDP and income per capita growth rates. This group includes many trailing cities and old industrial areas. They can be found in North Dakota (Bismarck), Illinois (Bloomington, Champaign- Urbana) and Southern California (El Centro). Metropolitan areas in central California are also in this cluster. Many of these distressed cities are located in states that are characterized by strict rules on occupational licensing, which has been found in recent OECD work as hindering labour mobility (Hermansen, 2019) and productivity growth (Bambalaite, Nicoletti and Rueden, 2020). In 2017, more than one- quarter million job-to-job moves went out of California to other states. The highest number of these jobs went to Texas (about 33,000) followed by Arizona (about 25,000) and Washington (about 24,000). Another major reason behind these moves seems to be the high cost of living and the high housing prices in some of these metropolitan areas.
Diverging trends between cities create social challenges because new jobs are being created in places far away from the places where old jobs are lost. Moving from job to job is essential for workers to avoid spells of joblessness, remain productive and benefit from higher earnings (Haltiwanger et al., 2018; Hermansen, 2019). However, the U.S. population has become less mobile: the share of the population moving each year has fallen from around 20% in the 1970s to under 10% more recently, with moves across state and metropolitan boundaries or moves to look for work also having been reduced. Therefore, in order to address the economic and social challenges that the ongoing COVID-19 pandemic has brought to the fore, cities need to act now to avoid long periods of economic downturn. With drastic changes happening in the urban ecosystem, it has become more important than ever to focus on housing and land zoning rules, and other restrictions to mobility, notably occupational licensing. With a major reallocation coming up4, cities that address these regulatory barriers would be in a better position to benefit from new opportunities and attract businesses and talents looking for a new home.
References: Azzopardi, D., F. Fareed, P. Lenain, D. Sutherland (forthcoming), “Why are some U.S. cities successful, while others are not – New evidence from machine learning”, OECD Economics Department Working Paper. Bambalaite, I., G. Nicoletti and C. von Rueden (2020), “Occupational entry regulations and their effects on productivity in services: Firm-level evidence”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1605, OECD Publishing, Paris. Barrero, J. M., Bloom, N., and Davis, S. J. (2020). “Covid-19 is also a reallocation shock”. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, No. w27137. Haltiwanger, J., Hyatt, H., and McEntarfer, E. (2018). “Who moves up the job ladder?”. Journal of Labor Economics, 36(S1), 301-336. Hermansen, M. (2019). “Occupational licensing and job mobility in the United States”. OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1585, OECD Publishing, Paris. OCDE (2020a), “Cities Policy Responses”, COVID-19 notes on policy responses. OECD (2020b). “OECD Economic Surveys: United States 2020 Ensuring a strong, inclusive and sustainable recovery from
the COVID-19 crisis in Israel by Gabriel Machlica and Oliver Röhn, Economics Department The coronavirus pandemic has interrupted Israel’s progress in boosting standards of living. Before the pandemic, Israel enjoyed strong employment growth and living standards had risen close to the OECD average. To contain the spread of the pandemic, the government reacted swiftly and introduced stringent confinement measures in March and April. The government and financial authorities deployed emergency measures quickly to support households’ and firms’ incomes and liquidity. After the economy had largely reopened, a second outbreak has given way to a renewed lockdown in September (Figure 1, Panel A). As in other countries, high uncertainty and the containment measures necessary to limit the spread of the virus have led to a sharp drop in economic activity. The economy is projected to decline by around 6% this year (Figure 1, Panel B). At the height of the crisis, over a million employees were temporarily laid off. Many have returned to work as the economy reopened. However, the unemployment rate, broadly defined to include workers on unpaid leave and workers who have left the labour force due to the pandemic, remains high at 11%. Moreover, the crisis threatens to aggravate Israel’s long-standing challenges of high poverty and wide productivity disparities between its vibrant high-tech sector and lagging sheltered sectors.
The new OECD Economic Survey of Israel (2020) identifies measures that can help Israel navigate this crisis. In the short term, the government and financial authorities should continue to provide fiscal, monetary and financial market support to buttress the recovery, boost confidence and avoid widespread bankruptcies. The government has expanded the eligibility to unemployment benefits to workers on unpaid leave and extended benefits until next year. This should be complemented by stepping up active labour market policies, such as retraining and job search support, to help workers transition to new jobs with better prospects. The Survey identifies priorities to put Israel on a stronger, sustained and inclusive recovery. Introducing ambitious reforms can improve the standard of living of the average Israeli citizen by some 15% by 2050 and help to reduce the gap in living standards vis-à-vis the upper half of the OECD countries (Figure 2). These measures and reform areas include: Upgrading infrastructure. Israel’s core infrastructure stock is almost a third smaller than in other OECD countries. The availability and quality of public transport is also limited. Boosting public
infrastructure investment can lift productivity and connect people to job opportunities. Improving educational outcomes. The gaps in students’ outcomes between Arab-Israeli students and the rest of the population are significant, amounting to 4 years of schooling on average. Reducing gaps will require improving pre-school education, recruiting high-quality teachers, especially in the poor municipalities, and reducing disparities in students’ outcomes between different school streams. Strengthening the fiscal framework for local governments. Poorer municipalities lack resources to finance adequate public services for their residents. This calls for supporting poorer municipalities through higher compensation from wealthier municipalities. Merging municipalities and promoting regional clusters can improve efficiency. Supporting the poor. Employment among groups with traditionally low labour market attachment has significantly improved. However, the income received from work was not enough to make a substantial dent in poverty, which remains comparatively high. Further expanding Israel’s earned income tax credit would support the poor while maintaining strong incentives to work. Simplifying the tax system and reducing economic distortions. The tax mix is reasonably growth- and employment-friendly with a relatively low tax burden on labour. Nevertheless, ample room exists to simplify the tax system by abolishing inefficient tax expenditures and broadening tax bases, which would support revenues. The business and property tax system should be reviewed to reduce distortions. Improving environmental outcomes and reducing health risks. Poor air quality remains a concern for the well- being of Israelis. Introducing congestion charges would reduce traffic flows and air pollution, and can provide
additional resources to boost the public transport infrastructure. Pricing fossil fuels according to their carbon content and other pollutants, while protecting the most vulnerable, would further lower carbon emissions, and make renewable energy generation more competitive. References: OECD (2020), OECD Economic Surveys: Israel 2020, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_surveys-isr-2018-en. Coronavirus: Living with Uncertainty by Laurence Boone, OECD Chief Economist The global economy is facing unprecedented uncertainty as the evolution of the Covid-19 pandemic weighs heavily on the
economic outlook. Nine months after the initial outbreak in Wuhan, it is still difficult to predict the path of the virus. Each country has been hit in a different way, and response strategies have varied. There is much we still do not know. Research for a vaccine is ongoing across the globe, but more needs to be done to prepare for mass-scale testing, manufacturing and distribution that will be required. It seems clear today that we will have to live with the virus for some time, with our principal defence being tigher hygiene standards and physical distancing measures. Amid this unprecedented uncertainty, what we know is that the world will be much poorer than it would have been without the virus. If our central projection of a gradual recovery, after the rebound, materialises, global income will be USD 7 trillion lower by the end of 2021 than what we projected less than a year ago in November 2019. This is roughly equivalent to losing a year’s production from France and Germany combined. The initial economic shock in the first part of 2020 was deep and profound. In the wake of national confinements, the global economy plunged 7.8% in the second quarter of this year, an unprecedented drop in peace time. The decline would have been harder had governments not put in place a wide safety net for firms and individuals. As economies began to reopen, activities that could operate with physical distancing rebounded strongly. But it would be imprudent to infer from this that the recovery is V-shaped and global income can rapidly return to pre-crisis levels. In some industries a rapid recovery will occur; those linked to digital activity for example, but others will not be able to fully recover for some time. Scheduled flights are still down around 50% on a year ago in September. Entertainment and tourism have been deeply affected. Overall, 13-20% of OECD employment is threatened.
Because developments are so varied across countries and uncertainty is so high, we have produced two scenarios around our central projection. On the upside, if businesses and households were to become more confident because a vaccine or treatment is in sight or only mild containment measures were required to contain virus outbreaks, world growth would be stronger (figure). The loss of global output would be around USD4 trillion by the end of 2021. On the downside, if confidence remains weak because outbreaks were to intensify or stricter containment measures were required, household spending and business investment would weaken and the recovery would slow, and the loss in output would be USD11 trillion. Even if this crisis is strikingly different from others we have experienced and uncertainty is extremely high, we have seen that policy matters. In the confinement phase of the Covid-19 crisis, policymakers worldwide used a rich policy toolbox. These measures included short-term working schemes, furloughed employment, credit or grants to firms and tax holidays. This is pushing debt up by around 15 percentage points of GDP across the OECD, but was necessary, and will remain so for 2021. Central banks provided liquidity support,
and low rates kept debt interest payments at lower levels. Policy will continue to play an important role in the next phase of the crisis. We learnt from the aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis that tightening fiscal policy prematurely could impart a serious blow to an already weakened economy. Fiscal support will have to continue. We also learnt that policy can only temporarily prevent a rise in bankruptcies and unemployment. Support to firms must evolve to let non-viable firms go and encourage viable ones to grow. Equity instruments could be deployed for large firms, with state support, provided competition is preserved and a clear strategy for exit designed. However, it will require more creativity for SMEs, for example in the form of tax credits, with repayments occuring when firms sustainably return to profit. Individuals in vulnerable sectors also need policy support. For sectors where the shock is seen as temporary, short-term working schemes may continue, with more flexibility to allow people to take on new activity. For other sectors, existing schemes to support individuals and firms need to be tailored to avoid maintaining support to unviable jobs and firms that blocks reallocation necessary for a strong and persistent recovery. Training and job placement should be supported by digital infrastructure and be tailor-made to individuals as a norm. Policymakers need to make an extra-effort to be sure support reaches those who need it most. Furthermore, the first phase of the crisis has shown that barriers to trade can be hugely disruptive for an efficient supply of goods and services. International cooperation must resume to ensure health goods and services can be delivered to all, but also that trade barriers do not rise further putting some firms and activities, and the associated jobs, at risk. Looking further ahead, there is no way today to predict how people will behave after 18 months of a pandemic, how they will work and undertake leisure activities. We can sketch out
how some trends will accelerate though. First, there will be a wider use of teleworking, although the limits of out-of-office work must be taken into consideration. Second, we will see more services move online and increased online retail sales. Third, there will be greater demand, and need, for crisis management preparation, including health, cybersecurity, energy security and protection against natural disasters. Fourth, as the crisis impacts more precarious workers, the essential workers who cannot telework, those living in crowded accomodation, those in poor health, public demand for greater access to essential goods and services including public health and education provision should prevail. Amid a background of public disapproval with the evolution of inequality, policies will need to improve on transparency, increasing competition and reducing collusion, and finding the means for a more efficient delivery of public services. Policymakers have to aim higher than trying to restore our pre-pandemic living standards: they need to deal with pre- crisis trends that threaten our future and seize the opportunity for change. It is an opportunity to implement green recovery and a significant shift in the sustainability of our economies. Governments are spending a lot of money in the policy response to the pandemic, but not enough of this is focused on sustainable solutions. Some countries are taking measures, but the effort needs to be bolder. Still, over 50% of policy support for energy in recovery packages is going to ‘brown’ fossil fuels. As recovery plans will be at the heart of governments budget preparation for 2021, the opportunity to reboot the economy on a stronger, fairer and more sustainable footing should not be wasted.
Further reading: OECD Interim Economic Outlook, 16 September, 2020 Coronavirus : Vivre avec l’incertitude par Laurence Boone, Cheffe économiste de l’OCDE L’économie mondiale fait face à des incertitudes sans précédent. L’évolution de la pandémie pèse lourdement sur les perspectives économiques. Neuf mois après son apparition à Wuhan, la trajectoire de propagation du virus reste toujours délicate à prévoir. Les pays ont été touchés de différentes façons, et leur stratégie, en réaction, a varié. De nombreuses inconnues demeurent. La recherche d’un vaccin est en cours dans le monde entier, mais beaucoup reste à faire pour préparer les opérations de dépistage de grande échelle, et la large production et distribution du vaccin qui seront nécessaires. Il semble clair aujourd’hui que nous devrons vivre avec le virus pendant un certain temps, avec comme principale défense des normes d’hygiène renforcées et de
mesures de distanciation physique à respecter. Dans ce climat d’incertitude inédit, la seule chose que nous sachions est que le monde se retrouvera beaucoup plus pauvre qu’il ne l’aurait été en l’absence de virus. Si notre scénario central d’une reprise graduelle, après la phase de rebond, se réalise, le revenu mondial sera inférieur, à la fin de 2021, de 7 000 milliards USD au niveau que nous avions estimé il y a moins d’un an, en novembre 2019. Ce chiffre équivaut globalement à une année de production de la France et de l’Allemagne réunies. Le choc initial sur l’économie au premier semestre de 2020 a été rude. Dans le sillage des mesures de confinement nationales, l’économie mondiale a plongé de 7.8 % au second trimestre de cette année, une chute jamais vue en temps de paix. La déclin aurait été plus prononcé encore si les pouvoirs publics n’avaient pas déployé de larges filets de sécurité pour protéger les entreprises et les personnes. Lorsque les mesures de strict confinement ont pris fin, les secteurs qui pouvaient fonctionner en appliquant des mesures de distanciation physique ont rebondi énergiquement. Toutefois, il serait imprudent d’en déduire que l’économie se redressera en suivant une courbe en V et que le revenu mondial pourra renouer bientôt avec ses niveaux d’avant la crise. Certains secteurs se redresseront rapidement, notamment ceux liés aux activités du numérique, mais d’autres auront besoin de temps pour se rétablir totalement. Ainsi, le nombre de vols prévus en septembre était encore inférieur de près de la moitié à celui d’il y a un an. Les secteurs du divertissement et du tourisme ont été profondément touchés. Au total, 13 % à 20 % des emplois sont menacés dans l’OCDE.
Face à des évolutions si diverses d’un pays à l’autre et à un degré d’incertitude aussi élevé, nous avons choisi de produire deux scénarios articulés autour de notre scénario de référence. Selon le scénario favorable d’une révision à la hausse par rapport aux prévisions, la croissance mondiale serait plus forte (graphique) si la confiance des entreprises et des ménages s’améliorait parce qu’un vaccin ou un traitement serait en vue, ou si des mesures d’endiguement plutôt légères suffisaient à circonscrire la propagation du virus. La contraction de la production mondiale se situerait alors autour de 4 000 milliards USD d’ici la fin de 2021. Dans le scénario plus défavorable, les dépenses des ménages et l’investissement des entreprises fléchiraient, la reprise ralentirait et la perte de production s’établirait à 11 000 milliards USD si la confiance devait rester faible en raison d’une intensification de l’épidémie, ou parce que des mesures d’endiguement plus strictes s’imposeraient. Même s’il est évident que cette crise est très différente d’autres crises que nous avons connues et si les incertitudes sont particulièrement fortes, nous avons pu observer que l’action publique est importante. Pendant la phase de
confinement de la crise liée au COVID-19, les responsables de l’action publique ont, partout dans le monde, mobilisé un vaste arsenal de mesures. Parmi ces mesures, on peut citer les dispositifs de chômage partiel, le chômage technique, les prêts ou subventions aux entreprises ou encore les exonérations fiscales temporaires. Ces mesures devraient augmenter la dette de quelque 15 points de PIB dans la zone OCDE, mais elles étaient nécessaires et le resteront en 2021. Les banques centrales ont procédé à des apports de liquidités et le faible niveau des taux d’intérêts a permis aux charges d’intérêt de la dette de ne pas trop augmenter. L’action publique continuera de jouer un rôle important au cours de la prochaine phase de la crise. Nous avons appris des suites de la crise financière mondiale qu’un resserrement prématuré de la politique budgétaire pouvait mettre sérieusement à mal une économie déjà affaiblie. Le soutien budgétaire devra donc être poursuivi. Nous avons aussi appris que l’action publique ne parvient que temporairement à prévenir l’augmentation des faillites et du chômage. Le soutien aux entreprises doit évoluer pour laisser disparaître les entreprises non viables et encourager celles qui le sont à se développer. Des instruments de fonds propres pourraient être déployés pour les grandes entreprises, avec le soutien de l’État, à condition que la concurrence soit préservée et qu’une stratégie de sortie claire soit définie. Une plus grande créativité sera toutefois nécessaire s’agissant des PME, le soutien prenant par exemple la forme de crédits d’impôt remboursables une fois que les entreprises auront renoué durablement avec les bénéfices. Les personnes se trouvant dans des secteurs vulnérables ont aussi besoin du soutien de l’action publique. Dans les secteurs où le choc est considéré comme temporaire, les dispositifs de chômage partiel peuvent être maintenus, avec une souplesse plus grande pour permettre à chacun de s’engager dans une activité nouvelle. Dans les autres secteurs, les
mécanismes actuels d’aide aux personnes et aux entreprises doivent être réajustés pour éviter de continuer à soutenir des emplois et des entreprises non viables, bloquant ainsi la réaffectation nécessaire à une reprise vigoureuse et durable. Les actions de formation et de placement professionnel devraient pouvoir s’appuyer sur une infrastructure numérique et être systématiquement personnalisées. Les responsables de l’action publique devraient renforcer leurs efforts pour s’assurer que les dispositifs de soutien bénéficient effectivement à ceux qui en ont le plus besoin. En outre, la première phase de la crise a montré que les obstacles aux échanges pouvaient très gravement perturber la fourniture des biens et des services en nuisant à son efficacité. La coopération internationale doit reprendre pour garantir que des produits et services de santé pourront être mis à la disposition de tous, mais aussi que les entraves au commerce ne vont pas continuer d’augmenter, avec les risques que cela fait peser sur certaines entreprises et activités, et sur les emplois associés. À un horizon plus lointain, il est impossible aujourd’hui de prévoir comment les individus se comporteront après 18 mois de pandémie, comment ils travailleront et quels seront leurs loisirs. Toutefois, nous pouvons esquisser la manière dont certaines tendances vont s’accélérer. Premièrement, le recours au télétravail va se développer, même si les limites du travail à distance doivent être prises en compte. Deuxièmement, de plus en plus de services vont être proposés en ligne et le commerce électronique va s’intensifier. Troisièmement, on va voir augmenter la demande, et la nécessité, d’une préparation à la gestion de crise, que cela concerne la santé, la cybersécurité, la sécurité énergétique ou la protection contre les catastrophes naturelles. Quatrièmement, la demande citoyenne d’une augmentation de l’offre de services publics de santé et d’éducation devrait prendre de l’ampleur car la crise a touché en premier lieu les travailleurs les plus précaires, les professions de première
ligne pour lesquelles le télétravail est impossible, ceux qui vivent dans des logements trop étroits et ceux qui ne sont pas en bonne santé. Dans un contexte de mécontentement du public face à l’évolution des inégalités, les responsables des politiques publiques devront progresser en matière de transparence, favoriser la concurrence et réduire les phénomènes de collusion, et trouver les moyens de rendre plus efficiente la fourniture des services publics. Les pouvoirs publics doivent viser plus haut qu’une simple tentative de rétablissement de nos niveaux de vie d’avant la pandémie : il est nécessaire qu’ils prennent plus largement en compte les menaces qui, avant la crise, pesaient déjà sur notre avenir et saisissent cette opportunité pour changer l’action publique dans ces domaines. Nous avons la possibilité d’engager une relance verte et d’opérer un basculement dans la durabilité de nos économies. Les pouvoirs publics consacrent énormément d’argent aux mesures destinées à faire face à la pandémie, mais la part de cet argent consacrée à des solutions durables n’est pas suffisante. Certains pays agissent, mais les efforts doivent être plus audacieux. Dans les trains de mesures en faveur de la reprise, plus de 50 % des aides publiques à l’énergie concernent encore les combustibles fossiles « bruns ». Alors que les plans de relance vont être au cœur de la préparation des budgets publics pour 2021, il ne faut pas laisser échapper l’occasion de remettre l’économie sur une trajectoire plus vigoureuse, plus juste et plus durable.
À lire: Perspectives économiques de l’OCDE, Rapport intermédiaire, Septembre 2020 Thomas Laubach – A world- class economist and a dear friend by Laurence Boone, Vincent Koen and Patrick Lenain, OECD Economics Department Across the OECD, Thomas’ family and friends are in our thoughts.
Photo source: “Der einflussreiche Deutsche im Hintergrund der Fed”, Handelsblatt, 9 April 2018 Rarely does an economist have the opportunity to exert a direct influence on policymaking and contribute to better outcomes. Thomas Laubach did just that during his 23-year tenure in the Federal Reserve system, where he rose to the key position of Director of Monetary Affairs and directly advised Chairwoman Janet Yellen and Chairman Jerome Powell. Known worldwide for his innovative work on the natural rate of interest – famously labelled “R-star” — he was also the author and co-author of over twenty articles published in key academic journals. His 2003 piece with John Williams, “Measuring the natural rate of interest”, was quoted no less than 1100 times (Google scholar) and his 1998 book with Ben Bernanke, Frederic Mishkin and Adam Posen on “Inflation targeting: lessons from international experience” received almost 3000 quotations. Thomas was also a close friend of the OECD. He spent two years in the OECD Economics Department, in 2003-05, as part of a long-standing programme where the Federal Reserve dispatches one their promising researchers to Paris, with mutual benefits for both institutions. There, he worked on two OECD countries – the largest economy (United States) and the smallest one
(Iceland). Thomas was passionate about both, and his intellectual contributions continued to resonate in Reykjavik for many years. His unfailing kindness, collegiality and equanimity, to borrow Jay Powell’s words, won him many good friends in Paris. Back at the Fed, he remained involved with the OECD, notably as a regular and key participant in working groups, including the small but influential network of “Monetary Experts”, which has been recognized as a key platform to exchange views on the latest in monetary economics. A loyal friend, he stayed in touch with many of his former OECD colleagues. Born in Germany in 1965, Thomas graduated from the University of Bonn before embarking on one of his countless transatlantic trips. At Princeton University, he started to work with then Professor Ben Bernanke, who supervised his PhD in Economics, which led to their investigation of the international experience with inflation targeting. Thomas stayed close to Ben Bernanke and their joint efforts eventually led to the Federal Reserve adopting in 2012 a long-run inflation objective of 2% as a new framework to anchor inflation expectations. After a brief stint at the Federal Reserve Branch of Kansas City, Thomas joined the Board of Governors in Washington DC, where he published his important work on the natural rate of interest. The idea of a neutral interest rate was already present in John Taylor’s monetary policy rule as the interest rate that should prevail when the economy is operating at potential with stable inflation. However, there was no consensus on how to estimate it. Together with John Williams, now President of the New York Fed, Thomas elaborated a methodology to estimate a time-varying natural rate of interest, depending on the trend growth rate of output. It used the Kalman filter to jointly estimate the natural rate of interest, potential output, and trend growth. The Laubach-Williams model (“LW R-star”) found the estimated natural rate of interest to have varied
You can also read