The Wall Street Consensus - Daniela Gabor (UWE Bristol) - OSF
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
The Wall Street Consensus Daniela Gabor (UWE Bristol) Abstract: The Wall Street Consensus (WSC) is an elaborate effort to reorganize development interventions around selling development finance to the market. The Billions to Trillions agenda, the World Bank’s Maximizing Finance for Development or the G20’s Infrastructure as an Asset Class all call on international development institutions and governments of poor countries to ‘escort capital’ – the trillions of institutional investors – into ‘investable development bonds’, preferably in local currency. For this, the 10 WSC commandments aim to simultaneously reorganize local financial systems around bond market-based finance and forge the de-risking state. The state derisks bond finance for institutional investors by extending guarantees and subsidies to cover (i) demand risks attached to user-fees for (PPP) infrastructure, (ii) political risk attached to policies such as nationalization, higher minimum wages and climate regulation, (iii) climate risks that may become part of regulatory frameworks as material credit risks and (iv) bond market (liquidity) risks that complicate foreign investors’ exit from development assets. The WSC narrows the scope for a green developmental state that could design a just transition to low- carbon economies. 1
INTRODUCTION ‘….we have to start by asking routinely whether private capital, rather than government funding or donor aid, can finance a project. If the conditions are not right for private investment, we need to work with our partners to de-risk projects, sectors, and entire countries’. Jim Yong Kim, World Bank Group President (2017) The international development literature made two notable predictions over the past twenty years. It announced the (overdue) death of the Washington Consensus paradigm (Gore, 2000; Rodrik 2006). The Washington Consensus, anchored in the work of John Williamson (1990, 1993), outlined ten policy areas that would set poor countries’ economies on firm market foundations, under a ‘holly Trinity’ of macroeconomic stabilization through lower inflation and fiscal discipline; liberalization of trade and capital flows, of domestic product and factor markets; and privatization of state companies. After the East Asian crisis, the poor performance of countries closely wedded to the Washington Consensus prescriptions (Rodrik, 2006; Fischer, 2019) and the revolt of notable insiders such as Joseph Stiglitz, Gore (2000) predicted that the holy Trinity would make room for an Asian developmental model, updated to the ‘age of global money’ (Yanagihara and Sambommatsu, 1996). The collapse of Lehman Brothers brought the second notable prediction: the end of the age of global money and its ‘foreign finance fetish’ (Birsdall and Fukuyama, 2011). Both predictions turned out wrong. Financial globalization is alive and well, and sets the particular context in which ‘international development’ is pursued in the 21st century. As Lord Stern, of the influential G20 Eminent Persons Group, put it: ‘the challenge of achieving the SDG is in large measure that challenge, of fostering the right kind of sustainable infrastructure’, for which, ‘you have to have good finance, 2
the right kind of finance, at the right scale, at the right time’1. The ambition is spelled out in the Billions to Trillions agenda, the World Bank’s new Maximising Finance for Development (MFD) agenda, or the G20 Infrastructure as an Asset Class agenda, which aim to create investable opportunities in poor countries that can attract the trillions of global institutional investors and orient them to the SDG ambitions. For instance, the MFD promises global institutional investors $12 trillion in market opportunities that include “transportation, infrastructure, health, welfare, education’, to be minted into investable securities via Public-Private Partnerships2. This shift in the development agenda is here conceptualized as the Wall Street Consensus, an emerging policy paradigm that reframes the (Post) Washington Consensus (Öniş and Senses, 2005) in the language of the Sustainable Development Goals, and identifies global finance as the actor critical to achieving the SDG. To explore its contours, the article draws on previous scholarly accounts of the financialisation of development, understood as strategies to ‘escort’ (speculative) capital to poor countries into derisked asset classes (Carroll and Jarvis, 2014; Baker 2015; Mawdlsey, 2018). While these micro-level accounts emphasize the role that MDBs or donor agencies play in derisking, the role of the state and its macro- financial policies is largely ignored. To fill in this gap, the article draws on a critical macrofinance (CMF) approach concerned with the co-evolution of global finance and the macro-institutions of the state (Gabor, 2020). This co-evolution reflects deeply political processes through which private finance seeks protection from systemic risks and accommodation for new asset classes (Dafermos et al, 2020). CMF takes as analytical starting point the transformation of global finance, and fleshes out its consequences for our understanding of credit creation, macroeconomic policies, and of development strategies in the age of financial capitalism. Through this lens, the WSC is an attempt to re-orient the institutional mechanisms of the state towards protecting the political order of financial capitalism against climate justice movements and Green New Deal initiatives (Wainwright and Mann, 2018). It 1 http://live.worldbank.org/implenting-SDGs-changing- world?CID=ECR_TT_worldbank_EN_EXT_AM2018-sdgs 2 The World Bank’s first Head for Maximising Finance for Development was previously Practice Manager for PPPs at the World Bank https://www.worldbank.org/en/about/people/c/clive-harris. 3
is an organized attempt to forge what conceptually can be conceived as the de-risking state that ‘escorts’ global finance to investible assets in the Global South. The creation of investable assets requires a two-pronged strategy: (a) enlist the ‘de- risking’ state into de-risking new ‘SDG’ bond classes created via Public-Private Partnerships in infrastructure projects, and (b) re-engineer local financial systems in the image of US market-based finance to allow global investors’ easy entry into, and exit from, new SDG bonds (see also Mawdlsey, 2018). This is what lies behind the World Bank’s ambitions to crowd in private investors and create new markets, coded into what institutional investors describe as ‘a cultural shift to a broader de-risking philosophy’ (Deau, 2019: 259). Thus, Wall Street Consensus marks a new moment in capitalist accumulation, from what David Harvey (2003) termed ‘accumulation by dispossession’ to accumulation by de-risking. The de-risking state does not break with the (Post-)Washington Consensus state, a state complicit in pushing the holy trinity since Margaret Thatcher (Bruff, 2014). Rather, it builds on the Post-Washington Consensus acceptance that the state is necessary to correct market failures, through regulation and poverty alleviation (Öniş and Senses, 2005). The WSC asks the state to compensate global finance confronted with complex risk landscapes in SDG assets: (i) demand risks attached to user-fees for PPP infrastructure, (ii) political risk attached to policies that would threaten profits such as nationalization, higher minimum wages and climate regulation, (iii) climate risks that may become part of regulatory frameworks as material credit risks and (iv) bond market and currency risks that complicate foreign investors’ exit. The practice of de-risking goes back to the developmental state, but its politics changed. The developmental state de-risked for domestic manufacturing companies in priority, mainly export, sectors (Wade, 2018). It was successful where it had the capacity to discipline local capital (Öniş, 1991), to govern market failures through evolving institutional structures (Haggard 1990, 2018) and to generate elite support for the developmental state as a political project (Mkandawire, 2001). In contrast, the WSC state de-risks for global institutional investors without the embedded autonomy of the developmental state (Evans, 1991). It lacks an autonomous strategic vision, 4
unless ‘more infrastructure’ can be described as such, and has fewer tools to discipline the global captains of finance industry. The content of structural transformation also changes through subtle norm substitution processes à la Washington Consensus (Kentikelenis and Babb, 2019). WSC proponents, from MDBs to states in the Global North and South, seek to normalize the appropriateness of a market-based financial structure in technocratic forums away from public scrutiny. Structural policies shift from the manufacturing sector, as in the traditional developmental states (Wade, 2018), to the local financial system. The WSC consolidates several global initiatives to restructure financial systems in developing and emerging economies (DEE) towards securities market- based finance or shadow banking (IMF and World Bank, 2020; also Gabor, 2018), where global and domestic institutional investors can easily purchase local bonds (securities), including infrastructure-backed securities, and finance as well as hedge their securities positions via repos and derivative markets. In pushing for financial structure change, institutional investors seek to preserve their ability to divest from local (SDG) securities, an implicit recognition of the limits of the de-risking state. De- risking capacity can be quickly eroded by shocks such as climatic or pandemic events. For this, the WSC aims to re-orient the central bank into tackling bond market risks and currency markets. The emerging WSC is a template, but not a straightjacket. It requires local political coalitions to consolidate around the de-risking state, to deliver on its demands or to diffuse political contestation. Indeed, the WSC downplays the costs and risks of the macro-financial order it seeks to impose. It engineers financial globalization that comes with increasing vulnerability to volatile capital flows (Rey, 2015) and also threatens developmental policy space, by narrowing the scope for a green developmental state that could design a just transition to low-carbon economies, where the burden of structural change does not disproportionately fall on the poor. To trace these reconfigurations, the paper explores the policy documents produced by WSC institutions (World Bank, other MDBs, the IMF) and private finance. The WB intends to mainstream the MFD/Cascade approach across its operations, using as pilot the infrastructure sector, broadly understood. By 2020, it had introduced a new tool 5
for the MFD approach, entitled Infrastructure Sector Assessment Programs (InfraSAP) and produced InfraSAPs for several MFD pilot countries: Egypt, Nepal Sri Lanka and Vietnam (for the energy sector in the last two)3. The paper finally provides a short reflection on the possible trajectories of the Wall Street Consensus during and after the COVID19 pandemic. THE WALL STREET CONSENSUS: A BRIEF TIMELINE The Wall Street Consensus has its origins in the 1980s, when donor governments turned to ‘de-risking’ seeking to realign policies with the Washington Consensus. One such pioneer, the German development bank Kreditanstalt für Wiederaufbau (KfW), persuaded German politicians that traditional lending to recipient governments should be repurposed to finance high-risk tranches of new financial instruments. This would circumvent local institutions vulnerable to capture, increase KfW’s ability to closely control development interventions and eventually involve private finance more systematically (Volberding, 2018). This logic remains dominant, as for instance in Germany’s Compact with Africa (see Banse, 2019). In parallel, Germany pushed the local bond markets agenda within the G8 (Gabor, 2018), recommending the elimination of capital controls that hamstrung portfolio inflows into local bond markets, and promoting local resource mobilization. The latter measure called for privatizing segments of the welfare state to create a domestic institutional investor base, including private pension funds, mutual funds and insurance companies, later conceptualized as shadow banking or market-based finance (Pozsar, 2013; Storm, 2018). At first, the global financial crisis stopped the Wall Street Consensus it its tracks. Rich and poor countries alike abandoned the celebratory narrative of free capital flows for a new vocabulary of shadow banking, global financial cycles, carry-trade speculation, interconnectedness on the balance sheet of global banks (Rey, 2014; 3 The publication of InfraSAP for Indonesia, one of the keenest supporters of the MFD approach, initially expected in January 2019, was delayed after public outcry over a leaked draft. 6
Gallagher 2015; Bortz and Kaltenbrunner, 2018). As the IMF dropped its notorious opposition, scholars celebrated the normalization of capital controls as the ‘the single most important way in which policy space for development has widened in several decades’ (Grabel, 2011:806). One after another, DEEs imposed controls on portfolio flows into local securities markets, upending an international development discourse focused on selling development finance to institutional investors via portfolio inflows. However by 2015, the WSC was back on track. The crisis narrative became gradually sensationalized along ‘greedy bankers’ lines, downplaying the structural roots that would have required significant reform, particularly of shadow banking (Gabor, 2019). Indeed, shadow banks – global asset managers, hedge funds and other institutional investors – are crucial actors in the political alliances backing the WSC, alongside MDBs, global regulators, elite technocrats (see the Eminent Persons Group 2018) and governments of high-income countries. The world largest financial institution, Blackrock, relied on ‘ferocious lobbying’ to successfully fight the Financial Stablity Board’s (FSB) attempts to regulate asset managers as systemic shadow banks in 2014-2015. As a result, the FSB announced that it would shift its approach to transforming shadow banking into resilient market-based finance. The resilience of market-based finance reflects the limited institutional incentives that either central banks or politicians have to pursue deep structural reforms. Post 2008, central banks protected their powerful position in the macrofinancial architecture by unconventional monetary policies such that stabilized market-based finance without reforming it (Hannoun, 2012; Gabor, 2016). Equally important is that central banks buried one important political aspect in technocratic discussions: market-based finance entangles monetary, fiscal, and financial stability policies. Sovereign debt is “vital to the functioning of the financial system, analogous to the function of money in the real economy,” stressed the ECB’s Benoît Cœuré (2016:3). But if sovereign debt is core to market-based finance, then central banks’ financial stability mandates structurally require them to protect governments from volatility in sovereign bond markets (Gelpern and Gerding, 2016). Paradoxically, it hardwires austerity into policy frameworks: caught between ‘independent’ central banks reluctant to intervene and ‘bond vigilantes’ threatening higher financing costs should structural reforms of finance be enacted, elected politicians embrace ‘fiscal discipline’. Austerity reinforces 7
market-based finance: hesitant taxation of big capital, asset-based welfare and passive index investment all feed into institutional investment in the age of asset management (Haldane, 2014). The Wall Street, rather than the Frankfurt or London, Consensus reflects the structural importance of US-based institutional investors and their asset managers, the ‘new powerbrokers of modern capital markets (Fisch et al, 2018). The ‘hidden power’ of the new ‘captains of finance industry’ extends from their influence over corporations as majority shareholders (Fichtner et al. 2017), to partnerships in global development initiatives such as the G20 Infrastructure as an Asset Class initiative 4 , and their growing involvement in national infrastructure, such as Blackrock in Mexico, for some a case of corporate colonialism5. THE TEN COMMANDMENTS OF THE WALL STREET CONSENSUS The Washington Consensus proposed 10 policy lines guided by the holy trinity of stabilization, privatization, and liberalization. These reimagined development for the international liberal order, attributing policy failures to domestic factors rather than global structures, and shifting the overarching ambition from long-run structural transformations to a more efficient distribution of resources (Gore, 2000). A similar set of policies can be traced into the emerging WSC (see Table 1). 4 See Blackrock (2015). 5 Between 2012 and 2018, Blackrock was a prime beneficiary of president Pena Nieto’s PPP- driven infrastructural projects, acquiring infrastructure assets through revolving door relationships. In his campaign, the left-wing Lopez Obrador denounced Blackrock as white- collar financial mafia, but gave up the campaign promise to review Blackrock PPP contracts once he won the presidency in 2019 (Blackrock Transparency Project, 2019). 8
Table 1: The 10 commandments of the Wall Street Consensus Washington Consensus Wall Street Consensus 1. Fiscal discipline, Central bank 1. Fiscal discipline, central bank independence independence 2. Public spending: primary education, 2. Public spending: de-risk new asset classes in primary health, public infrastructure education, health, transport, energy ‘Infrastructure as an asset class’ 3. Tax reform: lower marginal rate, broader 3. Sustainability reform: ESG criteria base 4. Macro-finance policy: replace 4. Sustainable local currency bond finance: engineer developmental banking with market-based market-based finance, prioritize securitization, support interest rates securities prices (market-maker of last resort) 5. Exchange rate: either market-determined 5. Hedger/swapper of last resort to de-risk currencies for or ‘competitive’ according to equilibrium (institutional) investors theories, capital account liberalization 6. Trade liberalization 6. Financial globalization (no capital controls) 7. FDI promotion 7. Portfolio flows promotion 8. Privatization 8. Privatization of pension funds for domestic resource mobilization (Privatization) PPPs for ‘infrastructure as an asset class’ 9. Competitiveness-enhancing deregulation 9. Removal of regulatory barriers to foreign-financed PPPs 10. Property rights 10. Surveillance capitalism/Screen New Deal The WSC revives the old developmental concerns with long-run structural transformation, now framed through questions of ‘how to grow in an age of global money’ that cannot move large pools of capital into small projects. This is no longer the world of vulgar ‘efficiency gains will deliver growth’ neoliberalism (Rodrik, 2006), but neither is it a return to developmental states (Haggard, 2018). Rather, structural transformation means policy-engineering SDG assets and a new market- based local financial system that can attract global money, i.e. the money of global 9
institutional investors, with specific mandates and practices of investment that need to be accommodated. The fiscal-monetary architecture The WSC preserves the basic institutional macro-architecture of the Washington Consensus: an independent central bank targeting inflation and a fiscally disciplined Ministry of Finance. The separation matters in two ways. First, this macro- architecture confers ‘infrastructural power’ to finance, since central banks rely on the financial system to implement inflation targeting (Braun and Gabor, 2019). The transmission mechanism of monetary policy becomes a stick to discipline advocates of ‘shrinking to size’ financial regulation. Reforming (shadow) banks, it is argued, will disrupt inflation targeting regimes. Second, the ‘game of chicken’ between an independent central bank and the treasury keeps at bay a developmentalist model that requires the central bank to work closely with the developmentalist technocracy in charge of strategic industrial policy (Öniş, 1991). Such a developmentalist model further requires the central bank to impose extensive capital controls in order to insulate the strategic industries, and the banking sector financing them, from financial instability (Wade, 2018). The focus on fiscal rectitude dictates the mechanisms for creating SDG asset classes: user-pay/concession Public-Private Partnerships are framed as a strategic necessity (Bull and Milkian 2019, also Foster 2017, World Bank 2018a, p13). PPPs are functional to the de-risking state because their coding into law and public finances allows a clandestine reorienting of public resources to private investors while maintaining the ideological commitment to ‘fiscal responsibility’. PPPs are more expensive than traditional public investment, but the illusion of fiscal effectiveness is useful for governments and MDBs because it allows them to circumvent budgetary restrictions and spend off-balance (Bayliss and van Waeyenberge, 2018), often in the guise of progressive infrastructure policies, as ‘affordable housing’ PPP projects in Brazil and Colombia suggest (Santoro, 2019). The state’s PPP commitments are recorded as contingent liabilities, and do not count as public debt. PPPs become a ‘get 10
out of jail’ card for politicians who can promise large infrastructure projects financed by foreign institutional investors without increasing debt/GDP levels – at least in the beginning. Infrastructure is the hook for orienting institutional investors towards SDGs. While institutional investors have long treated infrastructure as an asset class, they often argue that large-scale infrastructure investments face significant hurdles. Around 60% of infrastructure projects in emerging countries are not investible because their risk architecture does not create the cash flow characteristics that institutional investors prefer or are inscribed in their mandates6. Governments and MDBs are urged to plug in those risk gaps through global policy initiatives such as the G20 Infrastructure as an asset class (G20, 2018). Behind the rhetoric of independent central banks and fiscal discipline, the Wall Street Consensus imagines a new kind of state. The de-risking state puts its fiscal and monetary arm in the service of de-risking bond finance for global institutional investors. Public spending: de-risking for institutional investors The Washington Consensus codified what Williamson (1993) described as ‘belief in fiscal discipline’, in direct opposition to ‘left-wing believers in Keynesian stimulation via large budget deficits’, a perspective that became ‘almost an extinct species’ in the 1990s. Fiscal discipline meant cuts to subsidies for state-owned companies and for basic consumption goods (e.g. gasoline, food). It prescribed spending on primary education, primary health rather than high-tech hospitals in the capital, and on public infrastructure investment. 6 For instance, a common rule of thumb is that pension funds need a minimum 4% return plus inflation. See https://realassets.ipe.com/reports/infrastructure-as-asset-class-a-brief- history/realassets.ipe.com/reports/infrastructure-as-asset-class-a-brief- history/10026752.fullarticle 11
The Wall Street Consensus similarly celebrates fiscal restraint. The MFD’s operational tool, the Cascade Approach7, stresses that scarce fiscal resources cannot deliver the SDGs 8 (World Bank, 2017). Instead it sets out a series of steps for producing investible projects (see Figure 1), a theoretical armour for state interventions in the guise of de-risking. The Cascade Approach systematizes earlier efforts to promote renewable energy markets in Africa through de-risking political technologies (Sweerts et al 2019; Müller, 2020). Emerging out of a partnership between Deutsche Bank (DB, 2011) and the UNDP, suggestively entitled ‘De-risking clean energy business models in a developing country context’, the Global Energy Transfer Feed-in Tariffs (Get FiT) Program proposed an innovative public-private de-risking partnership that absorbed some of the risks faced by private renewable companies in developing countries. It built on the UNDP’s work on regulatory barriers, including vertically integrated, state-owned energy monopoly utilities, subsidised energy tariffs, to political risks or lack of local financing. A better distribution of risks, DB argued, would see host governments introduces tariffs and prioritise renewable energy in regulatory framework, whereas the public sector in high-income countries and MDBs would absorb counterparty credit risk (affecting agreements between state-owned wholesale electricity purchaser and the private renewable energy suppliers) and other political risks. Somewhat paradoxically, the DB report did not discuss renewable energy markets through the ‘infrastructure as an asset class’ lens, nor did it make reference to the trillions of institutional investors. Instead, it identified the limited lending capacity of local banking systems as a constraint, and green bonds as a mechanism for financing MDBs. However, the UNDP (2013) report frames de-risking as the instrument for escorting the trillions of global institutional investors to the Global South, distinguishing between policy de-risking instruments (energy market regulations, 7 MFD complements the IFC’s strategy to “Create Markets” and MIGA’s 2020 strategy by strengthening regulatory or policy frameworks, promoting competition, and achieving demonstration effects, as well as a cross-WBG program to develop local capital markets (“J- CAP”). (World Bank, 2017). 8 The World Bank’s (2018a) InfraSAP for Vietnam claims that the existing model for financing energy infrastructure – state lending to state companies – is no longer viable because of statutory public debt limits. 12
institutional capacity etc.) and financial de-risking instruments (loan guarantees, political risk insurance or public equity co-investments that would transfer the risks that investors face to public actors, such as development banks). The Cascade Approach simplifies the UNDP recommendations into a three-step blueprint for de-risking SDG assets created via PPPs. It recommends lifting regulatory or policy barriers to improve the risk-return profile, by for instance, allowing user fees on highways. If reforms are insufficient to attract investors, then subsidies and guarantees to de-risk the project might do so. Only when these measures fail, it is suggested to opt for a fully public solution. Furthermore it has to be ensured that SDG assets become investible, by identifying MFD-enabling projects, i.e. those projects that support financial or capital market reform to unlock additional sources of private financing (see IMF and World Bank, 2020). Figure 1 The Cascade Approach in the WB’s Maximising Finance for Development Source: Own representation of data from World Bank (2017) 13
The revival of the PPPs in the age of institutional investors does little to address the old criticisms of PPP models: extra demands on fiscal resources, concentration of PPP activity in areas already benefiting from public investment, dubious effects on poverty, access and inequality (Bayliss and van Waeyenberge, 2018), regulatory and technical capacities hardly available to poor countries (Romero, 2018 9 ). But the renewed PPP push in the Wall Street Consensus incorporates lessons drawn from the early 2000s on how to systemically enlist the state in de-risking infrastructure assets. In the early 2000s, infrastructure as asset class projects typically involved the privatization of urban infrastructure in high-income countries, de-risking via complex financial instruments, and global interlinking in the portfolio of global institutional investors (Pryke and Allen, 2017). Yet local political contestation of contract terms often threatened cash flows (Morag Torrance, 2008). Where new asset classes involve uncertain flows of value, as Carruthers and Stinchcombe (1999) show for the US mortgage market, the state can step in to generate predictability by first rendering assets knowable and then ‘deriskable’. State agencies Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac assembled mortgage loans for delivery to shadow banks, which in turn resorted to securitization in order to create tranches with different risk profiles. Legal processes code into law the new asset classes a la Pistor (2018). The WSC takes these lessons to construct a broad range of techniques and institutional mechanisms for de-risking. Indeed, the four InfraSAPs – for Egypt, Nepal, Vietnam and Sri Lanka - identify PPPs as the key priority for the infrastructure strategy and map a set of derisking avenues (World Bank 2018a,b; 2019a,b). The WSC targets demand risk in PPP, user-fee based (social) infrastructure and political risk that future governments might (re-)nationalize commodified infrastructure or introduce tighter regulations, of for instance climate exposures or labour markets. Demand risks are a critical feature of PPP infrastructure because the WSC advises transitioning from taxpayer funding to user fees, set above cost recovery. While this 9 https://www.devex.com/news/opinion-public-private-partnerships-don-t-work-it-s-time-for- the-world-bank-to-take-action-92585 14
remains the price liberalization agenda of the Washington Consensus, user fees do not ensure predicable cash flows. Where the poor cannot afford the social infrastructure, the de-risking state is expected to guarantee the cash flows that service the interest payments on securities sold to institutional investors. Such guarantees are written into PPP laws under the heading ‘risk distribution’. The WB Egypt InfraSAP advises the Egyptian Electricity Holding Company (EEHC), the national electricity utility, that PPP contracts should include Payment Security Mechanisms that effectively guarantee payment flows against low demand. Similarly, the Vietnam InfraSAP applauds the PPP law that commits public resources to cover Vietnam risks, including offtake 10 and supply risks, currency convertibility and inflation adjustment, and termination payment obligations, across social infrastructure in ‘transportation; street lighting; water supply; waste treatment; power plants and transmission; commercial infrastructure; social infrastructure facilities for health care, culture, sports, industry, and agriculture’ (World Bank, 2018b: 23). Figure 2 InfraSAPs recommendations: the Cascade Approach in practice Source: Own representation of data from WB InfraSAPs. 10 In poor countries, the standard institutional arrangement in power infrastructure relies on a state-owned utility as the main project counterparty responsible for purchasing the power output produced by PPP companies, at a pre-agreed price. The offtake risks are those risks of not getting paid for output. 15
The mechanics of demand de-risking can be gleaned from Nigeria. At the World Bank’s Maximizing finance for the development of infrastructure in Nigeria workshop in September 2019, the Minister of Finance noted that ‘Nigeria no doubt lacks the fiscal space to self-finance’ the estimated USD 100 billion a year infrastructure gap. Instead, she promised to continue its collaboration with the World Bank to leverage private investment, building on previous success stories in ‘transport, energy and power sectors using PPP models’ 11 . Among those, the World Bank representative identified the Azura power plant ‘as an example of how we have attracted private sector investment in the power sector’, the first privately-financed power project in Nigeria. While Azura was set up as the de-risking PPP template for ‘lighting up Africa’12, it is hardly a success story. Similar to other private operators, Azura sells power to state-owned Nigeria Bulk Electricity Trading (NBET), who would pass it to distributors to recover costs and pay Azura. Once Azura started operating in 2018, demand risks materialized as its installed capacity could not be absorbed by the dilapidated Nigerian grid energy infrastructure. The PPP contract shifted demand risks to either NBET or failing, that, to the World Bank, whose partial risk guarantee promised to pay Azura if the Nigerian state failed to do so. Thus, MDB guarantees trap the de-risking state into a lose-lose situation, since a triggered risk guarantee becomes a WB loan to Nigeria (the de-risking state always pays!). Under pressure from the World Bank, the Nigerian federal government mandated its central bank to pay Azura from an existing USD 2.3 billion fund destined to cover NBET payment shortfalls. In doing so, the Nigerian central bank reallocated funds destined to other private providers, who responded with a legal case against the Nigerian government and Azura13. 11 See https://nairametrics.com/2019/09/24/nigeria-needs-100-billion-annually-to-fix- infrastructural-deficit-finance-minister/ 12 https://www.institutionalinvestor.com/article/b14z9q8pv7zzdb/is-new-nigerian-power- plant-a-template-for-lighting-up-africa 13 https://uk.reuters.com/article/uk-nigeria-power-exclusive/exclusive-nigerian-energy- sectors-crippling-debts-delay-next-power-plant-idUKKCN1OK1J4. While the ensuing scandal prompted the government to suspend other PPP initiatives, the September event suggests continued political commitment to the Wall Street Consensus. 16
While the Nigerian case is indicative of how the WSC works in practice, the range of demand risks that the state is expected to assume varies across countries. The Sri Lankan InfraSAP (WB and IFC, 2019) recommends a government-sponsored currency hedging facility that protects foreign investors from currency volatility. It also advises the state to pass the costs of de-risking to end-users via periodic adjustments of tariffs, and in case of severe disruptive events, to absorb those costs (p. 63). The InfraSAPs for Egypt (World, Bank 2018a), Vietnam (World Bank, 2018b) and Nepal (2019b) similarly call for the state to facilitate the development of hedging facilities. Furthermore, the Egyptian InfraSAP targets the relics of the traditional developmental state. Its National Investment Bank, it argues, should stop direct lending for public projects and instead embrace a more catalytic role for commercial financing of infrastructure, following the KfW business model (World Bank, 2018a). Equally important, the climate crisis gives rise to a series of political and demand risks that institutional investors need de-risking for. Sustainability reform: the turn to ESG ratings The 2011 DB/UNDP report on renewable energy was written at a time when green bonds were still a niche area for impact investors. By 2020, green finance moved into mainstream investment practice through the framework of Environmental, Social and Governance (ESG), a private sector approach that, it is increasingly argued, could be guided by the SDGs14. The ESG ratings system started as a corporation-focused, equity-tailored, sustainable impact investor system of aggregating into a rating a set of environmental, social and governance practices, as identified by the ESG provider. Once central banks in the Network for Greening the Financial System identified climate risks as material risks for financial stability, global finance embraced ESG as a private taxonomy for green finance. 14 https://www.pimco.co.uk/en-gb/insights/viewpoints/esg-investing-and-fixed-income-the- next-new-normal/ 17
Initially, ESG data were used to encourage corporations to engage more systematically in ESG disclosure. More recently, private providers have issued ESG ratings for countries. This is another step towards the extension of ESG ratings to securities (bonds, securitization tranches etc.), as institutional investors recognize that ESG is no longer simply about impact investment but about credit risks to portfolios with carbon equities and securities (Inderst and Stuart, 2018). Thus, the ESG framework is morphing into a private taxonomy for green/dirty15 finance: high ESG ratings are interpreted to signal a ‘green’ financial instrument, and vice-versa. For institutional investors, ESG ratings are a strategic necessity in the Wall Street Consensus. First, in mapping ESG ratings against the SDGs, institutional investors strive to become credible development partners to the de-risking state and MDBs, and more importantly, epistemic guardians of green taxonomies. Such new partnerships around ESG are emerging rapidly. The Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’s Asia ESG Enhanced Credit Managed Portfolio includes an ESG Markets Initiative in partnership with asset managers, to demonstrate ‘an AIIB ESG Framework that is consistent with the spirit and vision of the AIIB’s Environmental and Social Framework’ 16 (AIIB, 2019: 3). The AIIB ESG framework would allow the asset manager to design, monitor and enforce ESG criteria, delegating rule making and enforcement to private finance. The World Bank’s updated Environmental and Social Framework17 similarly embraces the ESG status-quo. Long seen as ‘gold standard in development finance’18, the mandatory safeguards have recently been replaced with a ‘risk-based, outcome focused, tailored and proportionate approach’. The World Bank accepts the use of borrowers’ E&S frameworks that are ‘materially’ close to the WB’s 15 the standard climate finance language distinguishes between green and ‘brown’ assets, disregarding the racist connotations embedded in conceptualizing dirty finance as ‘brown’ (see https://www.commondreams.org/views/2020/06/26/language-brown-finance-climate- finance-racist). In this paper, dirty finance replaces the standard ‘brown’ term. 16 https://www.aiib.org/en/projects/approved/2018/_download/regional/ESG-enhanced-credit- managed-portfolio.pdf 17 Other MDBs use a similar framework, with varying degrees of credible commitment to the E&S principles (see for example https://thediplomat.com/2017/08/is-the-aiib-really-lean- clean-and-green/ for AIIB) 18 http://archive.bankinformationcenter.org/world-banks-updated-safeguards-a-missed- opportunity-to-raise-the-bar-for-development-policy/ 18
own, without clearly defining either ‘materially close’ in terms of thresholds or mechanisms for monitoring changes in borrowers’ frameworks19. Second, the turn to ESG raises the distinct possibility of SDG/green washing. ESG providers use bespoke screening to eliminate issuers whose business lines are inconsistent with certain investment policies or social norms. For instance, the financial service firm MSCI provides bespoke screening for 'Catholic values' like anti-abortion legislation 20 . This would allow institutional investors to claim SDG outcomes when their investment decisions actively undermine women's rights agendas. Beyond SDG washing, the private ESG status-quo is functional to the Wall Street Consensus. A private ESG metric for SDG asset classes allows investors to shop around for high ESG ratings for their ‘sustainable’ portfolios, and for asset managers to boost their climate warrior credentials. In one instructive example, Blackrock pioneered ESG ETFs (passive investment vehicles), while wielding its shareholder 21 power to block climate measures against high-carbon companies. Even as institutional investors divest from coal assets, large asset managers insulate companies from sustainability pressures through index investment, potentially becoming holders of last resort of high-carbon, potentially stranded, assets (Jancke 2019). Such climate hypocrisy is accommodated by private providers – such as MSCI, FTSE or Sustainalytics - who quantify the ESG performance on a large number of criteria, chosen and assessed on discretionary basis. Hence, ratings often conflict: Tesla’s global auto ESG ratings vary from very good (MSCI) to very bad (FTSE) and mid- range (Sustainalytics)22. ESG providers face similar disincentives to those of credit rating agencies before 2008. These responded to ratings shopping by awarding high 19 https://consultations.worldbank.org/Data/hub/files/oxfam_comments_on_second_draft_wb_ environmental_and_social_framework.pdf 20 http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/913961524150628959/pdf/125442-REPL- PUBLIC-Incorporating-ESG-Factors-into-Fixed-Income-Investment-Final-April26- LowRes.pdf 21 https://bit.ly/2zzTZ5f 22 https://ftalphaville.ft.com/2018/12/06/1544076001000/Lies--damned-lies-and-ESG-rating- methodologies/ 19
ratings to issuers of complex financial products without due diligence into the credit quality of the underlying loans. In turn, weak ESG standards perpetuate the failure of financial markets to price climate risks adequately23. The WSC creates mechanisms to protect investors from climate-related losses. In promising to assume demand risks via PPP contracts, the state would absorb the physical risks of extreme climate events or global pandemics that would strand infrastructure assets. SDG-led development thus becomes a strategy of green financialisation through which private finance manages the environmental crisis, a step further in the financialization of nature that once focused on risk instruments such as catastrophe bonds (Keucheyan, 2018). The WSC also protects investors against political risks arising from the potential emergence of green developmental states. The green developmental state would prioritise the reorientation of finance towards low carbon activities. This requires a public taxonomy of ‘green’ and ‘dirty’ assets that overcomes the shortcomings of private ESG ratings, and policies to penalize dirty assets (through capital requirements or haircuts) 24 . Yet in the Wall Street Consensus framework, such policies would classify as political risks to SDG assets. In its strategy to mutate climate risks into political and demand risks, private finance may have found an important ally. Central banks in the Network on Greening the Financial System conceptualize the immediate impact of tighter climate rules as transition risks25. Realigning portfolios through ESG ratings, it is often argued, would improve their resilience to physical risks that climate events would strand high- carbon/dirty assets (Christophers, 2019), and to transition risks, those financial stability risks arising from climate regulation that accelerate the transition to low- carbon economies. These are risks that the transition to a low-carbon economy would 23 Blackrock calculated that several US asset classes that do not price in extreme climate events would experience significant losses over a long horizon. See https://www.ft.com/content/2350de58-7236-3593-ad79-16bfa6ecea8d 24 Such initiatives already exist. The European Commission announced a public taxonomy in June 2019 that it expects to become the benchmark for European finance. https://ec.europa.eu/info/business-economy-euro/banking-and-finance/sustainable-finance_en 25 See https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/knowledgebank/climate-change-what-are-the-risks- to-financial-stability 20
increase the cost of funding or dramatically change asset values, affecting profitability. The faster the low-carbon transition, the higher the potential that transition risks affect financial stability, thus binding central banks in political trade- offs that privilege incremental green regulatory regimes, however urgent the climate crisis. In seeking to enlist central banks in the political coalitions against biting climate regulation, the Wall Street Consensus would tie the hands of green developmental states directly, by making it liable for transition risks that can be framed as political and demand risks, and indirectly, by reducing the public resources and central bank support for Green New Deal programs that can effectively manage transition risks. The de-risking state and the green developmental state can hardly co-exist, particularly within market-based financial structures. Structural reforms: the turn to sustainable bond finance (formerly known as shadow banking) The turn to private finance as vehicle for sustainable development requires a change in financial structures. Bank-dominated financial systems would transform into market-based financial systems. This project of transforming shadow banking into resilient market based finance accommodates the entry of global and domestic institutional investors into local (SDG) securities and allows them to finance and hedge their securities positions via repos and derivative markets. In this push for structural transformation, the Wall Street Consensus assigns a de-risking role to the central bank as market-maker of last resort that reduces liquidity and currency risks for global investors. The MFD agenda converges with several other global initiatives to restructure financial systems towards market-based finance (see Figure 3). The Local Currency Bond Market Initiative seeks to Americanise the local currency securities markets of DEE countries by creating the ‘plumbing’ – derivatives and repo markets – necessary for their increased liquidity (Gabor, 2018). It was originally introduced under the leadership of the German Central Bank, the Bundesbank, in cooperation with the 21
World Bank and the IMF, at the G8 meeting in Germany in 2007, as part of a broader push for selling development finance to the market. The 2011 G20 Action Plan noted that well-developed local securities markets would reduce dependency on external financing and improve DEE countries’ ability to withstand volatile capital inflows. While acknowledging capital flow volatility, the Action Plan called for carefully phasing out capital controls, eliminating first those capital controls that hamstrung local securities markets (such as withholding taxes on foreign investors’ bond earnings). Domestic institutional investors were also to be encouraged, by privatizing pension funds and ‘enabling mutual funds and insurance companies’. Similarly, the Financial Stability Board announced in 2015 its new priority, to transform shadow banking into resilient market-based finance, understood as the development of securities, derivatives and repo markets that would allow the real economy to tap credit from institutional investors. Figure 3 The turn to securities markets/market-based finance in international development Source: own representation. In another illustration of the implicit WSC promotion of shadow banking, the push for market-based finance brings back securitization as an important de-risking instrument to crowd in private (institutional) investors and scale up sustainable assets. Securitization features prominently in the OECD’s low-carbon infrastructure push, 22
the MDBs plans to optimize balance sheets, or the G20 plans26 for Infrastructure as an Asset Class. Securitization – shadow banking instrument par excellence - is promoted as a de- risking instrument that transforms non-tradable loans, extended by MDBs or private banks, into a range of tradable securities with distinctive risk/return profiles that can be sold to institutional investors (Gabor, 2019). The securitisation of infrastructure loans would create both highly-rated, low-return tranches suitable for conservative pension funds/asset managers and lower-rated, higher return tranches suitable for investors with higher risk appetite. It would also accelerate lending to infrastructure projects, constrained by Basel III rules for banks. As the Vietnam InfraSAP suggests, bank energy loans could be securitized to make room for additional lending. Banks could also sell infrastructure loans to platforms such as the AIIB’s Infrastructure Private Capital Mobilization Platform, which in turn would package and securitize them for distribution through capital markets to ‘build infrastructure as an asset class’ (AIIB, 2019:1). The promotion of securitization and domestic capital markets that are deep and liquid downplays the systemic risks characteristic to market-based finance. While reducing dependency on foreign currency debt (Berensmann et al, 2015), the shift to market- based finance comes with systemic, shadow banking type instabilities that turned Lehman into a global systemic event. The WSC template for liquid securities markets calls for importing the fragile liquidity structures of US financial markets (Brunnermeier and Pedersen, 2009). It asks countries to redesign repo (securities financing) markets and derivative markets according to the US template so that foreign (institutional) investors can easily finance and short securities. This ‘Americanization’ of local financial systems involves liberalising repo markets to enable legal transfer of title to collateral securities, to allow mark to market and shorting, and the development of onshore derivative markets. Yet it was precisely this type of collateral-based financing 26 See the Eminent Persons Group proposals to the G20 https://g20.org/sites/default/files/media/epg_chairs_update_for_the_g20_fmcbgs_meeting_in _buenos_aires_march_2018.pdf 23
markets that fed, through shadow banking, cycles of liquidity and leverage before Lehman. When the crisis came, it manifested in fire sales of securities, evaporating market liquidity and wholesale funding runs. The FSB’s repo collateral rules and Basel III do not go far enough to contain such dynamics (Gabor, 2018), and may be rolled back in response to the global COVID pandemic. The structural transformation of financial systems does not protect institutional investors against liquidity risks in the bond markets that are used as collateral for financing. This is why the central bank becomes an important anchor of the de-risking state through bond market-maker of last resort (MMLR) that institutionalizes a commitment to preserve collateral liquidity through outright purchases when market- based finance comes under pressure (Mehrling, 2012). Such interventions, introduced through (often clandestine) extensions of formal mandates after Lehman’s collapse, derisk bond markets by creating an asymmetric regime where the central bank puts floors but not ceilings on securities prices (Gabor, 2016). Before the COVID19 pandemic, bond derisking only occurred in high-income countries. In some polities like the Eurozone, it gave rise to significant contestation because most interventions to stabilise the plumbing of market-based finance requires outright purchases of government bonds, for conservative voices a revival of the monetary financing of governments. Similarly, the notion of market maker of last resort was taboo in emerging and poor countries, denounced as a pathological capture of the central bank by populist governments. Instead, the WSC celebrated the growing presence of non-resident investors in local currency bond markets as a victory of its mantra ‘development aid is dead, long-live private finance!’. Portfolio inflows would improve the liquidity of government bond markets, and with it, DEEs dependence on external debt. The vulnerabilities associated with the global dollar financial cycle were set aside (see Gevorkyan and Kvangraven, 2016), as if borrowing from foreign investors automatically generates policy autonomy. But elsewhere, the IMF recognized that local securities and equity markets, capital flows and credit cycles increasingly move together, all in the shadow of the US dollar (Adrian, 2019). Increasingly popular Exchange Traded Funds (ETFs) - that package equities or bonds and issue ETF shares against them - sharpen this dependency: while emerging market ETFs are traded on the exchanges of high-income countries, their issuance and 24
redemption requires the purchase/sale of the underlying shares/bonds, thus generating capital flows. As Converse et al (2020) document, ETFs amplify the global financial cycle for DEEs. Thus, direct and indirect (via ETFs) inflows into local currency bond markets move with dollar financing conditions, while exchange rate volatility amplifiesof portfolio flow pro-cyclicality: currency depreciation accelerates capital flight (Hördahl and Shim, 2020). Indeed, currency risk has long been identified as a significant obstacle to attracting foreign institutional investors in large-scale infrastructure assets (see Baker, 2015 for renewable energy in South Africa). In response, the WSC outlines three currency derisking strategies (see Hördahl and Shim, 2020). As the World Bank’s InfraSAPs recommend, state development banks could provide hedging facilities through which institutional investors transfer currency risk to the state. Second, central banks can undertake regular derivative operations to derisk exchange rates for foreign holders of local currency bonds (Macalos, 2017). Finally, central banks can become swappers of last resort, supplying financial institutions with foreign liquidity during periods of instability, thus reducing exchange rate volatility (Gonzales et al, 2019). Note that these strategies are designed to minimize recourse on capital controls, further entrenching Rey’s (2015) dilemma: free portfolio flows into local (SDG) securities markets comes with loss of monetary policy independence and of influence over local credit conditions. The critical de-risking role assigned to central banks in part reflects that the journey to infrastructure as a bond asset class is long and fraught with institutional complexity. As Klagge and Nweke-Eze (2020) document, complex risk structures deter institutional investors from participating in Keyna’s renewable energy projects, leaving MDBs, governments and renewable industry investors to finance and derisk. In other words, the derisking of PPP infrastructure and its financing via securities sold to institutional investors may proceed at different pace, constrained by the pace of structural transformation of local financial systems. 25
Surveillance capitalism in the WSC Finally, WSC aims to leverage the model of surveillance capitalism (Zubhoff, 2019) already deployed via the trope of digital financial inclusion in overlapping networks of state institutions, international development organisations and ‘philanthropic investment’ fintech companies (Gabor and Brooks, 2017). The aim was to map, harvest and monetize digital footprints via behavioural analytics to render the poor ‘investible’ through an ‘all data is credit data’ approach. Surveillance capitalism increasingly overlaps with the Wall Street Consensus, as illustrated by the turn to private/PPP healthcare in African countries. In the wake of the Washington Consensus, African countries privatized health through different methods, from user fees on public health services to encouraging private healthcare and promoting insurance schemes (Baloyi, 2019). Across SubSaharan Africa, 50% of healthcare is provided by the private sector, with financing provided by investment platforms and fund managers promoting the development of healthcare asset classes (Hunter and Murray, 2019). Enter digital healthcare, with its promise of better diagnostics through advanced technologies, and a complex ecosystem ripe for ‘health as an asset class’ initiatives. PharmAccess Group, for instance, operates both on the supply side and the demand side of private healthcare. It provides financing to small-scale private health companies in Tanzania, Kenya, Ghana and Nigeria, from healthcare SMEs to specialist care providers and other businesses catering to health facilities, through the Medical Credit Fund. PharmAccess’ partners include AfDB, the World Bank and most official development aid agencies, alongside foundation involved in the financial inclusion project. On the demand side, it has received ODA funding for the Safaricom-backed healthcare app M-Tiba, where users save for medical care, pay and manage their insurance policies and support their dependants. Digital healthcare can morph into surveillance devices whereby insurance companies can adjust premiums via data delivered to doctors. For instance, MTiba launched a new hypertension and care app for low-income patients in 2018, that allows them to monitor blood pressure and blood glucose levels, digitally sending the results to 26
You can also read