The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000) pp. 595–613 Williamson: The New Institutional Economics The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead OLIVER E . W ILLIAMSON 1 1. Introduction velopment (1994, p. 75). In considera- tion, however, of the “splendid plausi- I OPEN MY DISCUSSION of the new in- stitutional economics with a confes- sion, an assertion, and a recommenda- bility of error” to which Lord Acton re- fers, 2 we need to sort the sheep from the goats. That is accomplished by ask- tion. The confession is that we are still ing each would-be theory to advance re- very ignorant about institutions. The as- futable implications to which the data sertion is that the past quarter century are applied. has witnessed enormous progress in the R. C. O. Matthews, in his presidential study of institutions. The recommenda- address to the Royal Economic Society tion is that, awaiting a unified theory, we in 1986, pronounced that “the econom- should be accepting of pluralism. ics of institutions has become one of the Chief among the causes of ignorance liveliest areas in our discipline” (Mat- is that institutions are very complex. thews 1986, p. 903). Such a pronounce- That neoclassical economics was dismis- ment was a surprise to most of the pro- sive of institutions and that much of or- fession. Hadn’t institutional economics ganization theory lacked scientific am- long since been relegated to the history bitions have also been contributing of economic thought? Whence the vitality factors. As to progress, that is what to which Matthews made reference? most of this paper is about. There being Matthews’ response was that the new many instructive lenses for studying institutional economics (NIE) turned on complex institutions, pluralism is what two propositions. First, “institutions do holds promise for overcoming our matter”; and second, “the determinants ignorance. of institutions are susceptible to analy- Speaking for myself, I subscribe to sis by the tools of economic theory” Jon Elster’s view that we work predomi- (Matthews 1986, p. 903). The second of nantly on partial mechanisms rather these is what distinguishes the NIE, it than general theories at this stage of de- being the case that institutional econo- 1 University of California, Berkeley. owilliam@ mists of all kinds—old and new—are haas.berkeley.edu. This paper was first presented unanimous in the view that institutions at the third annual meeting of the International matter. Society for New Institutional Economics in Wash- Indeed, although both the older and ington, DC in September 1999 in my capacity as president-elect. Helpful comments received there newer styles of institutional economics and from Bengt Holmstrom and John McMillan are gratefully acknowledged. 2 As quoted in Daniel Boorstin (1998, p. 281). 595
596 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000) subscribe to many of the same good ideas, 2. Four Levels of Social Analysis a progressive research program requires more. Kenneth Arrow speaks to the It will be useful for purposes of per- transformation as follows (1987, p. 734): spective to consider the four levels of social analysis that are distinguished in Why did the older institutionalist school fail Figure 1. 3 The solid arrows that con- so miserably, though it contained such able nect a higher with a lower level signify analysts as Thorstein Veblen, J. R. Commons, and W. C. Mitchell? I now think that . . . that the higher level imposes con- [one of the answers is in the] important spe- straints on the level immediately below. cific analyses . . . of the New Institutional The reverse arrows that connect lower Economics movement. But it does not consist with higher levels are dashed and signal of giving new answers to the traditional ques- feedback. Although, in the fullness of tions of economics—resource allocation and the degree of utilization. Rather, it consists time, the system is fully interconnected, of answering new questions, why economic I mainly neglect these feedbacks. The institutions emerged the way they did and NIE has been concerned principally not otherwise; it merges into economic his- with levels 2 and 3. tory, but brings sharper [microanalytic] . . . The top level is the social embedded- reasoning to bear than had been customary. ness level. This is where the norms, cus- There is no question that the NIE toms, mores, traditions, etc. are located. has grown in stature and influence over Religion plays a large role at this level. the fourteen years since Matthews’ pro- Although Level 1 analysis is undertaken nouncement. Initial skepticism has by some economic historians and other gradually given way to respect—it being social scientists (E. C. Banfield 1958; the case that economists are very prag- Robert Putnam, Robert Leonardi, and matic people. Tell them something dif- Raffaella Nanetti 1993; Samuel Hunt- ferent and consequential about phe- ington 1996; and Victor Nee 1998), nomena that are of interest to them and Level 1 is taken as given by most insti- demonstrate that the data are corrobo- tutional economists. Institutions at this rative: that will get their attention. The level change very slowly—on the order NIE has progressed not by advancing an of centuries or millennia—whereupon overarching theory but by uncovering Douglass North poses the query, “What and explicating the microanalytic features is it about informal constraints that gives to which Arrow refers and by piling them such a pervasive influence upon block upon block until the cumulative the long-run character of economies?” value added cannot be denied. (1991, p. 111). The NIE, moreover, will not stand North does not have an answer to still. Even as institutional economics is that perplexing question, nor do I. The being incorporated within orthodoxy, concept of “embeddedness,” both at the new opportunities and challenges await. level of society and in the context of on- Both unfinished business and new proj- going network relations, has been ad- ects yet to be undertaken await the new vanced to help explicate these issues millennium. (Granovetter 1985). The vast literature I begin with a sketch of four levels of on culture (Paul DiMaggio 1994) is also social analysis, next turn to some of the pertinent. Neil Smelser and Richard good ideas out of which the NIE works, Swedberg discuss these and related issues and then examine some of the applica- in their introduction to the Handbook tions to which the NIE has been put. 3 This framework was first set out in Williamson Concluding remarks follow. (1998).
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics 597 of Economic Sociology, where they ob- mainly spontaneous origins—which is to serve that different kinds of embedded- say that deliberative choice of a calcula- ness—cognitive, cultural, structural, tive kind is minimally implicated. Given and political—should be distinguished, these evolutionary origins, they are and conclude that “the concept of em- “adopted” and thereafter display a great beddedness remains in need of greater deal of inertia—some because they are theoretical specification” (1994, p. 18). functional (as with conventions); others An identification and explication of take on symbolic value with a coterie of the mechanisms through which informal true believers; many are pervasively institutions arise and are maintained linked with complementary institutions would especially help to understand the (formal and informal), etc. Be that as it slow change in Level 1 institutions. I may, the resulting institutions have a conjecture in this connection that many lasting grip on the way a society con- of these informal institutions have ducts itself. Insular societies often take
598 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000) measures to protect themselves against the response to such opportunities is “alien values.” often one of “failure.” Absent such a The second level is referred to as the window, major changes in the rules of institutional environment. The struc- the game occur on the order of decades tures observed here are partly the prod- or centuries. The European Union, uct of evolutionary processes, but de- for example, has been “in progress” for sign opportunities are also posed. Going fifty years and is still in early stages of beyond the “informal constraints (sanc- development. tions, taboos, customs, traditions, and What is often referred to as Positive codes of conduct)” of a Level 1 kind, we Political Theory (PPT) is concerned now introduce “formal rules (constitu- with working out the economic and po- tions, laws, property rights)” (North litical ramifications of Level 2 features. 1991, p. 97). This opens up the oppor- To be sure, such research also has les- tunity for first-order economizing: get sons for the normative design of better the formal rules of the game right. polities. Like the NIE of which it is a Constrained by the shadow of the part, however, PPT is predominantly an past, the design instruments at Level 2 exercise in positive analysis. The object include the executive, legislative, judi- is to better understand how things cial, and bureaucratic functions of gov- work—warts and all. The research prod- ernment as well as the distribution of uct of PPT scholarship has been noth- powers across different levels of gov- ing less than auspicious, which has been ernment (federalism). The definition good for both political science and the and enforcement of property rights and NIE. of contract laws are important features. Much of the economics of property Although such first-order choices are rights is of a Level 2 kind. Such re- unarguably important to the economic search flourished in the 1960s. A strong productivity of an economy (Nathan version of the argument is that “a pri- Rosenberg and L. E. Birdzell 1986; vate-enterprise system cannot function Ronald Coase 1992; North 1994; Brian properly unless property rights are cre- Levy and Pablo Spiller 1994; Mancur ated in resources, and, when this is Olson 1996; Witold Henisz 1998) cumu- done, someone wishing to use a re- lative change of a progressive kind is source has to pay the owner to obtain it. very difficult to orchestrate. Massive Chaos disappears; and so does the gov- discontent—civil wars (the Glorious ernment except that a legal system to Revolution; see North and Barry Wein- define property rights and to arbitrate gast 1989), or occupations (following disputes is, of course, necessary” (Coase World War II), perceived threats (the 1959, p. 12; emphasis added). Once Meiji Revolution), breakdowns (Eastern property rights have been defined and Europe and the former Soviet Union), a their enforcement assured, the govern- military coup (Chile), or a financial cri- ment steps aside. Resources are allo- sis (New Zealand)—will, however, occa- cated to their highest value as the marvel sionally produce a sharp break from es- of the market works its wonders. tablished procedures. Rare windows of This compact statement illustrates opportunity to effect broad reform are both the strength and the weakness of thereby opened. Such “defining mo- the property rights literature. The great ments” are nevertheless the exception strength of this literature is that it rather than the rule. At least partly be- brings property rights to the forefront, cause of our primitive understanding, where they belong, whereupon novel
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics 599 property rights reasoning could be however, is a truncated way to study or- brought to bear in informative ways ganization—especially if all complex (Armen Alchian 1961, 1965; Coase contracts are unavoidably incomplete 1959, 1960; Harold Demsetz 1967). The and if adaptation is the central problem weakness is that it overplayed its hand. of economic organization (Chester Bar- The claim, for example, that the legal nard 1938; Friedrich Hayek 1945). Mov- system will eliminate chaos upon defin- ing beyond the agency theory tradition of ing and enforcing property rights as- ex ante incentive alignment, transaction sumes that the definition and enforce- cost economics turns its attention—ad- ment of such rights is easy (costless). ditionally and predominantly—to the ex Plainly, many transactions do not qual- post stage of contract. ify (Coase 1960). Going beyond the This entails four moves: (1) to name rules of the game (property) to include and explicate the principal dimensions the play of the game (contract) was with respect to which transactions differ needed. That is the opening through (thereby to uncover differential adap- which the governance of contractual tive needs); (2) to name and explicate relations walked in during the 1970s. the principal attributes for describing This brings me to the third level, governance structures (where each is which is where the institutions of gover- defined by a distinctive syndrome of re- nance are located. Although property lated attributes, whence markets, hy- remains important, a perfectly function- brids, firms, regulation, bureaus, non- ing legal system for defining contract profits, etc. differ in discrete structural laws and enforcing contracts is not con- ways); (3) to effect a discriminating match, templated. Costless court ordering be- according to which transactions are ing a fiction, much of the contract man- aligned with governance structures so agement and dispute settlement action as to promote adaptation of autonomous is dealt with directly by the parties— and cooperative kinds; and (4) to ascer- through private ordering. The need to tain whether the predicted alignments come to terms with contract laws (plu- are corroborated by the data. ral), rather than an all-purpose law of The canonical problem for dealing contract (singular), is posed (Clyde with these issues is that of vertical inte- Summers 1969; Ian Macneil 1974). The gration, which is the issue posed by governance of contractual relations Coase in his classic 1937 article on “The becomes the focus of analysis. Nature of the Firm.” As it turns out, John R. Commons prefigured this any issue that arises as or can be refor- work with his observation that “the ulti- mulated as a contracting issue can be mate unit of activity . . . must contain examined to advantage in transaction in itself the three principles of conflict, cost economizing terms. A huge num- mutuality, and order. This unit is a ber of phenomena turn out to be con- transaction” (1932, p. 4). Not only does tractual variations on a common theme. transaction cost economics subscribe to What I refer to as second-order econo- the idea that the transaction is the basic mizing—get the governance structures unit of analysis, but governance is an ef- right—is realized at Level 3. The possi- fort to craft order, thereby to mitigate ble reorganization of transactions among conflict and realize mutual gains. governance structures is re-examined So conceived, a governance structure periodically, on the order of a year to a obviously reshapes incentives. To focus decade, often at contract renewal or entirely on ex ante incentive alignment, equipment renewal intervals.
600 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000) Such discrete structural analysis of who believed that institutions were governance is to be distinguished from both important and susceptible to the fourth level, which is the level at analysis. Feeling expansive, I would in- which neoclassical analysis works. Opti- clude six Nobel Laureates among the mality apparatus, often marginal analy- key figures: Kenneth Arrow, Friedrich sis, is employed, and the firm, for these Hayek, Gunnar Myrdal, Herbert Simon, purposes, is typically described as a pro- Ronald Coase, and Douglass North— duction function. Adjustments to prices the last two being the first two presi- and output occur more or less continu- dents of ISNIE. But there are others. ously. Agency theory, which emphasizes Armen Alchian has been an influential ex ante incentive alignment and effi- figure. So too has been research on or- cient risk bearing, rather than ex post ganization theory, especially at Carnegie governance, nonetheless makes provi- (some of it prefigured by earlier work sion for nonneoclassical complications, by Chester Barnard)—where the names of which multi-tasking is one (Bengt of Richard Cyert and James March join Holmstrom and Paul Milgrom 1991). that of Simon. Alfred Chandler’s pio- Indeed, a still earlier (zero level) of neering work in business history was analysis warrants remark: an evolution- also pathbreaking. Thoughtful contribu- ary level in which the mechanisms of tors from the law, especially contract the mind take shape (Steven Pinker law, include Karl Llewellyn, Stewart 1997). The application of these ideas to Macaulay, Lon Fuller, and Ian Macneil. economics even now is beginning to John R. Commons also brought original reshape our understanding of human and important ideas to the study of in- actors. Our evolutionary psychologist stitutional economics. The German His- and cognitive science colleagues are torical School was also concerned with vital to the exercise. related ideas (Erik Furubotn and Finally, I should call attention to Rudolf Richter 1997, pp. 34–35). technology. As compared with techno- Among the key good ideas that I logical innovation, the study of orga- associate with the NIE are these: nizational innovation has been compara- Human Actors. If “nothing is more tively neglected. The NIE has attempted fundamental in setting our research to rectify that—the idea being that agenda and informing our research “truly among man’s innovations, the use methods than our view of the nature of of organization to accomplish his ends the human beings whose behavior we is among both his greatest and his earli- are studying” (Simon 1985, p. 303), est” (Arrow 1971, p. 224). We cannot then social scientists should be pre- fail, however, to be awed by the pro- pared to name the key attributes of hu- found importance of technological inno- man actors. Both the condition of cog- vation (Robert Fogel 1999). Inasmuch nition and self-interestedness need to as these two work in tandem, we need be addressed. to find ways to treat technical and or- There is close to unanimity within ganizational innovation in a combined the NIE on the idea of limited cognitive manner. competence—often referred to as bounded rationality. Mind being a 3. Good Ideas scarce resource, cognitive specialization has economizing consequences. Also, The new institutional economics had given cognitive limits, the complex con- its origins in good critics of orthodoxy tracts to which I referred earlier are
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics 601 unavoidably incomplete. But while there flict, mutuality, and order to which I is near-unanimity that complete contin- referred earlier—is centrally implicated. gent claims contracting is impossible, Feasibility. Students of the NIE es- the appropriate way to model incom- chew hypothetical ideals—which work plete contracts remains controversial. off of omniscience, benevolence, zero Lack of agreement on the definition transaction costs, full credibility, and and operational import of bounded the like—and deal instead with feasible rationality is a major obstacle (Ariel organizational alternatives, all of which Rubinstein 1998; David Kreps 1999). are flawed. Coase (1964) and Demsetz Contractual incompleteness poses (1969) were among the first to take ex- added problems when paired with the ception with the asymmetric standards condition of opportunism—which mani- that were once used in the “market fail- fests itself as adverse selection, moral ure” literature—according to which hazard, shirking, subgoal pursuit, and markets are beset with failures whereas other forms of strategic behavior. Be- “omniscient, omnipotent, benevolent” cause human actors will not reliably dis- governments (Avinash Dixit 1996, p. 8) close true conditions upon request or would reliably administer efficacious self-fulfill all promises, contract as remedies. As we all should have recog- mere promise, unsupported by credible nized (but needed to be told), all feasi- commitments, will not be self-enforcing. ble forms of organization—government But for opportunism, the courts included—are flawed. 4 would simply ask witnesses to “tell us What I have referred to as the reme- what you know that is germane to our diableness criterion is intended to rec- decision.” That is not, however, the way tify this asymmetric state of affairs. This that testimony is taken. Witnesses are criterion holds that an extant mode of required to take an oath to “tell the organization for which no superior fea- truth, the whole truth, and nothing but the sible alternative can be described and truth”: don’t lie; don’t conceal; don’t implemented with expected net gains is mislead. Inasmuch, moreover, as oaths presumed to be efficient. are not self-enforcing, penalties for per- To be sure, public policy analysis be- jury remind witnesses that prevarication comes more complicated when analysts has consequences. can no longer condemn extant modes Still a third attribute of human actors because they deviate from a hypotheti- warrants remark, and that is the capac- cal ideal, full stop. The remediableness ity for conscious foresight. Indeed, as criterion presses the public policy ana- Richard Dawkins observes, it is the “ca- lyst to display a superior feasible alter- pacity to simulate the future in imagina- native. If, moreover, a proposed feasi- tion . . . [that saves] us from the worst ble alternative cannot be costlessly consequences of the blind replicators” implemented, then the costs of imple- (1976, p. 200). Parties to a contract mentation are appropriately included in who look ahead, recognize potential the net benefit calculus—which has ma- hazards, work out the contractual rami- jor ramifications for the path depen- fications, and fold these into the ex ante dency literature. Finally, grounds for contractual agreement obviously enjoy rebutting the efficiency presumption advantages over those who are myopic need to be addressed—which brings in or take their chances and knock on 4 Dixit (1996) counsels the older public finance wood. The governance of contractual tradition to come to terms with government fail- relations—the Commons triple of con- ures.
602 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000) politics (Williamson 1996, 1999). Ab- lytically convenient (and sometimes sent rebuttal, the remediableness crite- adequate) conception of the firm-as- rion stands as a reminder of the obvi- production function (which is a techno- ous: it is impossible to do better than logical construction) to consider the one’s best. firm as a governance structure (which is Firms and Bureaus. In addition to the an organizational construction) in which nature of the human beings to which Si- internal structure has economic pur- mon referred, we need also to be self- pose and effect. More generally, the conscious about the “Nature of the Firm,” need was to identify and explicate the which was the title of Coase’s classic properties of alternative modes of gover- 1937 article from which the NIE draws nance—spot markets, incomplete long much of its inspiration. Arrow speaks to term contracts, firms, bureaus, etc.— the fundamental importance of the the- which differ in discrete structural ways. ory of the firm, and to long-standing Because each generic mode of gover- misconceptions thereof, as follows: “Any nance possesses distinctive strengths and standard economic theory, not just neo- weaknesses, there is a place for each yet classical, starts from the existence of each needs to be kept in its place. The firms. Usually, the firm is a point or at logic of discriminating alignment to any rate a black box. . . . But firms are which I referred earlier applies. palpably not points. They have internal In a heuristic way, the choice of structure. This internal structure must governance structure moves from mar- arise for some reason” (1999, p. vii). ket to hierarchy through the sequence The need was to get beyond the ana- of moves shown in Figure 2 (where h
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics 603 denotes contractual hazards and s de- introduced when transactions are re- notes safeguards). 5 This can be inter- moved from the market and placed un- preted as a move from simple to com- der unified ownership (the firm). Be- plex. We thus begin with autonomous cause added compliance and security contracting, which is the ideal transac- features always come at a cost, more tion in both law and economics: “sharp complex modes of governance are re- in by clear agreement; sharp out by served for those transactions for which clear performance” (Macneil 1974, p. contractual hazards are especially difficult. 738). This discrete transaction para- The public bureau, in this scheme of digm comes under strain as contractual things, can be thought of as the organi- hazards appear. The inability of courts, zation form of last resort: try spot mar- for example, to verify what is common kets, try incomplete long-term con- knowledge between the parties to an ex- tracts, try firms, try regulation, and change (Williamson 1975, p. 30) could reserve recourse to public bureaus for induce a move from interfirm to in- when all else fails (comparatively). Note trafirm organization. Other sources of that the common practice of condemn- contractual hazard include bilateral de- ing public bureaus because they have pendency (by reason of nonredeploy- lower-powered incentives, more rules able assets), weak property rights (es- and regulations, and greater job secu- pecially intellectual property rights), rity than a counterpart firm completely undisclosed quality, health, and safety misses the point. These features have hazards, failures of probity, and the like. been deliberately crafted into the pub- Such hazards compromise contractual lic bureau, thereby to make it better integrity and give rise to contractual im- suited to govern some (especially diffi- passes, maladaptations, and investment cult) transactions. 6 Vigilance is none- distortions. Here, as elsewhere, ineffi- theless needed—lest the public bureau ciency invites relief. Cost-effective haz- be “overused.” ard mitigation through added governance If transaction cost economics works ensues. out of variations on a few key themes, Moving from less to more complex then this schema, which was initially governance entails introducing added devised to help explicate the gover- security features, reducing incentive in- nance of contractual relations in inter- tensity, and incurring added bureau- mediate product market transactions, cratic costs. Moving from simple (dis- should also apply, with variation, to crete) contracts to complex (incomplete other classes of transactions. It does. long term) contracts is thus attended by The four nodes are interpreted with a whole series of features: the length of reference to intermediate product the contract increases, penalties to de- transactions above. Consider final goods ter breach are introduced, provision is markets and government procurement made for added information disclosure transactions. and processing, and specialized dispute Transactions in final goods markets, settlement mechanisms appear. where individual consumers are the Additional mechanisms, to include the use of hierarchy to effect coordi- 6 This is a recurrent theme not only of the trans- nation and decide disputes by fiat, are action cost economics literature but also of parts of the agency theory literature. See especially 5 A variant of Figure 2 originally appeared in my Holmstrom (1989) and Holmstrom and Milgrom paper on “Public and Private Bureaucracies” (1991, 1994), where the benefits of low-powered (1999). incentives in firms are featured.
604 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000) buyers, are similar but different. Node are initially expressed as tautologies, A transactions are generic and competi- which Coase has wryly defined as “a tively organized. Node B transactions proposition that is clearly right” (1988, are rare. These correspond to “P. T. p. 19). Because good tautologies expand Barnum”—there’s a sucker born every the mind and are hard to come by, they minute—and other fly-by-night transac- deserve respect. Lest, however, we slip tions. Node C is the credible commit- into the speculations to which Wesley ment node. Branding in combination Mitchell once referred 7—which is a fate with reputation effects and product that beset the older style institutional warranties appear. Also, for some natu- economics as well as the American Le- ral monopoly transactions, public utility gal Realism movement—we need to ask regulation serves credibility purposes. what are the mechanisms through Node D is a nearly empty set. Econo- which a proposed theory operates and mies of scale and of specialization are what are the refutable implications. impediments to own-supply by consum- The effort to operationalize promis- ers, although collective organization ing ideas has both theoretical and em- (consumer cooperatives) can be used pirical parts. The theoretical often takes to manage some transactions. (Many the form of a progression from informal household services can be thought of as to preformal, semi-formal, and fully for- own-supply, but few fit comfortably mal modes of analysis—ideally acquir- within the schema.) ing value added in the process. Such an Government procurement transac- effort helps to sort the sheep from the tions are also similar but different. goats. Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen had Node A describes generic transactions a felicitous way of putting it: although to which, often, tedious technical speci- the “purpose of science is not predic- fications apply. Very few government tion, but knowledge for its own sake,” transactions are of a Node B kind. prediction is nevertheless “the touch- Credibility mechanisms at Node C in- stone of scientific knowledge” (1971, p. clude the elaborate machinery of “ad- 37). Would-be theories for which pre- ministered contracting,” as with defense dictive content is lacking must eventu- procurement (which transactions, how- ally step aside (be set aside) for those ever, are sometimes compromised by for which the hard work of formalization the shared interests of the government and empirical testing are undertaken. agency and the private supplier). And Theory Development. Formalization Node D is the public bureau, where for is vital to a progressive research agenda, probity or political reasons the govern- but it sometimes comes at a cost. Thus ment chooses to manage the transaction although Simon once argued that itself. “mathematical translation is itself a sub- Other applications of the schema in- stantive contribution to theory . . . be- clude the employment relation (James cause it permits clear and rigorous rea- Baron and Kreps 1999, ch. 4) and cor- soning about phenomena too complex porate finance (the choice between to be handled in words” (1957, p. 89) debt and equity). Some transactions, 7 “Speculative systems can be quickly excogi- such as alliances and joint ventures, tated precisely because they do not require the pose complications of a disequilibrium economist to collect and analyze masses of data, to contracting kind (Williamson 1991) that test hypotheses for conformity to fact, to discard those which do not fit, to invent new ones and test are beyond the reach of the schema. them until, at long last, he has established a factu- Operationalization. Many good ideas ally valid theory” (Mitchell 1945, p. 2).
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics 605 and subsequently asserted that the for the property rights theory of the “poverty of mathematics is an honest firm, which is a major intellectual poverty that does not parade imaginary achievement that has spawned a grow- riches before the world” (1957, p. 90), ing literature on the formal modelling provision also needs to be made for the of incomplete contracts. 8 As Kreps sug- possibility that core features of the the- gests, however, valuable chunks are ory are left out or obscured by the missing. In the spirit of full disclosure translation. There is, after all, such a (honest poverty), I focus on these. thing as prematurely formal theory. The most consequential difference Kreps speaks to the issues as follows between the TCE and GHM setups is (1999, p. 122): that the former holds that maladapta- tion in the contract execution interval is If Markets and Hierarchies has been transla- the principal source of inefficiency, ted into game theory using notions of infor- mation economics, it is a very poor transla- whereas GHM vaporize ex post tion . . . In particular, mathematics-based maladaptation by their assumptions of theory still lacks the language needed to cap- common knowledge and costless ex post ture essential ideas of bounded rationality, bargaining. The upshot is that all of the which are central to . . . transaction costs inefficiency in GHM is concentrated in and contractual form. Anyone who relies on the translations alone misses large and valuable the ex ante investments in human assets chunks of the original. (which are conditional on the ownership of physical assets). 9 What is referred to as the “property This shift from ex post maladaptation rights theory of the firm,” which had its (the hazards from which vary with the origins with Sanford Grossman and condition of asset specificity and the Oliver Hart (1986) and has subsequently disturbances to which a transaction is been developed by Hart and John Moore subject) to ex ante investment distor- (hence the reference to the GHM model), tions matters. For one thing, GHM relates to but differs significantly from makes very limited contact with the the transaction cost economics setup (as data 10 whereas (as discussed below) presented, for example, in Williamson TCE is an empirical success story. Re- 1985, 1991). It is similar in that it deals lated (ex post) governance and (ex ante) with the make-or-buy decision through investment differences are the following: a setup where contracts are incomplete 8 The January 1999 issue of the Review of Eco- (by reason of bounded rationality), nomic Studies is entirely devoted to recent contri- mere promise cannot be used to over- butions, critiques, responses, and extensions upon come noncontractibility (by reason of the GHM model. 9 Bounded rationality enters this setup in a very opportunism), and parties to the con- peculiar way: parties who are unable to write com- tract are bilaterally dependent (by rea- plete contracts ex ante are nevertheless able to an- son of asset specificity). These com- ticipate ex ante what decisions will be taken ex monalities notwithstanding, there are post, contingent on state realizations (Kreps 1999, pp. 123–25). In effect, the GHM setup is one of also major differences. selective unbounded rationality: “not everything Some of these differences are attrib- that is logically consistent is credulous” (Kreps utable to simplifications that invariably 1999, p. 125). 10 That the data relevant to GHM are so limited attend formal modelling. Ideally, core and inaccessible explains why there has been “no features of the verbal argument and the formal testing of the property rights approach” mechanisms through which they work (Hart 1995, p. 49)—although the “inside contract- ing system” (John Buttrick 1952) is an approxima- are made more precise in the process of tion to (and its failures could be interpreted as a formalization. Such a case can be made partial contradiction of) GHM.
606 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000) (1) The TCE rendition of the make- ing). GHM assume that incentive or-buy decision between succes- intensity, administrative controls, sive stages (A and B) asks whether and informal organization are un- A and B should be separately changed by ownership and that owned and operated or if the own- courts are irrelevant (because of ership and operation of these two costless renegotiation). None of stages should be unified. If in- the physical asset utilization and dependent, then each stage appro- transfer pricing distortions that I priates its net receipts (high-pow- associate with the “impossibility of ered incentives obtain) but selective intervention” (Williamson maladaptation problems can arise 1985, pp. 135–40) thus occur during contract execution. If uni- under the GHM setup. fied, then the two stages are man- (3) TCE examines a wide range of ex aged coordinately through hierar- post devices for infusing credible chy. (Maladaptation problems are commitments into contracts and thereby relieved; incentives are applies this reasoning to a wide set lower-powered; and added bureau- of transactions. Variations on this cratic costs arise.) By contrast, theme include hybrid modes of or- GHM view vertical integration in a ganization (Scott Masten 1996, directional way: either A buys B or Part III), exchange agreements B buys A, and it matters which way and other uses of hostages to sup- this is done. That is because com- port exchange, the organization of mon ownership under GHM does work, the organization of labor and not imply unified management. In- human resources more generally, stead, each stage (in all configura- corporate governance, regulation tions—A and B are independent; A (and deregulation), public bu- buys B; B buys A) appropriates its reaus, and project financing. Be- net receipts. This last is a very un- cause GHM is a property rights usual condition, in that unified and property rights only construc- ownership is normally thought of tion (Holmstrom 1999), it relates as a means by which to effect to some of these issues not at all cooperation.11 and others very selectively (Hart (2) TCE maintains that each generic 1995; Hart, Andrei Shleifer, and mode of governance—spot market, Robert Vishny 1997). incomplete long-term contract, firm, bureau, etc.—is defined by a GHM is nonetheless a pathbreaking syndrome of attributes to which contribution and has set the formal distinctive strengths and weak- modelling of incomplete contracting in nesses accrue. Specifically, TCE motion. New formal models of incom- holds that alternative modes differ plete contracts which are closer in spirit in incentive intensity, administra- to TCE include the treatment of pro- tive controls (to include auditing, curement by Patrick Bajari and Steven accounting, and transfer pricing), Tadelis (1999), which focuses on the in- access to the courts, and informal centive and ex post adaptation differ- organization (to include politick- ences between fixed price and cost plus contracting. Also, the recent paper by 11 The inside contracting system referred to in Susheng Wang and Tian Zhu (2000) note 7 supra is in the spirit of GHM organization. employs the idea that alternative modes
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics 607 of governance work out of different graduate students) are progressively contract law regimes (Williamson 1991). built up—moving from less formal to And Gene Grossman and Elhanan Help- more formal stages of development. Fi- man (1999) appeal to the added bureau- nally, as with promising graduate stu- cratic costs of unified as compared with dents, we do not hold on to cherished market governance in their assessment theories indefinitely: some do flunk out. of alternative modes for producing dif- Specifically, theories that remain tauto- ferentiated consumer products. More logical or yield predictions that are con- veridical treatments of incomplete con- tradicted by the data must make way for tracting are thus in progress and still theories that yield predictions for which more are in prospect. 12 the data are corroborative. Empirical. Some scoff at prediction, Empirical applications of transaction evidently in the belief that prediction is cost economics got under way in the easy. Also, since everyone knows that U.S. in the 1980s and have grown expo- “it is easy to lie with statistics,” what nentially since: the number of pub- useful purpose is served by empirical lished studies exceeds 500 and involves testing? My experience is different: pre- social scientists in Europe, Japan, India, diction is a demanding standard, which China, Mexico, South America, Austra- is why so many would-be theories re- lia, New Zealand, and the list goes on. main excogitated speculations; and cor- It could have been otherwise, but the roboration is difficult, which explains theory and evidence display a remark- why few predictions are tested. able congruity (Scott Masten 1995, p. Because, however, good theories are xi). Recent empirical surveys include rarely fully developed at the outset, the Howard Shelanski and Peter Klein theory and the evidence are often inter- (1995), Bruce Lyons (1996), Keith active. As Alan Newell observes (1990, Crocker and Masten (1996), and Aric p. 14): Rindfleisch and Jan Heide (1997). Theories cumulate. They are refined and re- Not only has this research been formulated, corrected and expanded. Thus, broadly corroborative of the predictions we are not living in the world of Popper. . . . of transaction cost economics, but the [Theories are not] shot down with a falsifica- importance of risk aversion to commer- tion bullet. . . . Theories are more like gradu- cial contracting has been placed in ate students—once admitted you try hard to avoid flunking them out. . . . Theories are doubt (Douglas Allen and Dean Lueck things to be nurtured and changed and built 1999). To be sure, transaction cost eco- up. nomics, like everything else, will bene- fit from more and better empirical Good but underdeveloped ideas are work. I have no hesitation, however, in evidently like good but underdeveloped declaring that the NIE is an empirical minds: both are precious things. Be- success story. Paul Joskow concurs: cause development is costly, promising “this empirical work is in much better theories, like promising graduate stu- shape than much of the empirical work dents, are admitted only if they cross a in industrial organization generally” threshold. Once admitted, theories (and (1991, p. 81). Those who have done this 12 For an earlier formal treatment (of a reduced modest, slow, molecular, definitive form kind) akin to Bajari and Tadelis, see Michael work deserve enormous credit. 13 Riordan and Williamson (1985). The recent paper by Hart and Moore, “On the Design of Hierar- 13 The recurring regularity is this: more complex chies” (1999a), also makes express provision for modes of governance appear as contractual haz- organization. ards build up—where bilateral dependency, due
608 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000) 4. Phenomena the oligopoly problem, 14 and the multi- national corporation being examples The NIE is predominantly concerned (Peter Buckley and Mark Casson 1976; with Levels 2 and 3 of the four levels of Hubert Gatignon and Erin Anderson social analysis shown in Figure 1. These 1988). are the levels of the institutional envi- Many public policy issues, moreover, ronment and the institutions of gover- turn jointly on the combined use of nance, respectively. Between them, Level 2 and Level 3 reasoning. In the they cover a lot of ground. area of privatizing telecommunications, The formal features of the institu- for example, Levy and Spiller examine tional environment—the laws, polity, the institutional environments in five judiciary, bureaucracy—are crucial in countries through a comparative con- examining the development of nation tractual lens in which issues of credible states (North and Weingast 1989) and contracting are featured (1994, 1996). for making intertemporal comparisons The recent study of reforming urban within and cross-national comparisons water systems by Claude Menard and between nation states. Indeed, this last Mary Shirley (1999) likewise makes has come to be a growth industry to clear that ownership is not determina- which many economists who are only tive but needs to be examined in con- slightly associated with the NIE have junction with the support, or the lack made contributions. It is nonetheless thereof, of the mechanisms of gover- noteworthy that the NIE has done nance. Again, issues of credible contract- much of the pioneering work in this ing are salient. The same is true of com- area. mercial contracting in Vietnam (John To repeat, any issue that arises as or McMillan and Christopher Woodruff can be posed as a contractual issue can 1999). be examined to advantage in transaction Broad reach notwithstanding, the cost economizing terms. Examples for NIE is not and does not pretend to be which contractual issues are evident at an all-purpose construction, as the re- the outset include contracts for inter- form of economies of Eastern Europe mediate products, for labor, for final and the former Soviet Union illustrate. goods and services, for the rental or Thus Coase in his Nobel Prize lecture lease or purchase of land, equipment, observed that (1992, p. 714): and buildings, for professional services, for marriage, and the list goes on. Even, The value of including . . . institutional fac- moreover, if contractual features are tors in the corpus of mainstream economics is made clear by recent events in Eastern not immediately evident from the out- Europe. These ex-communist countries are set, many issues can be reformulated so advised to move to a market economy, and as to disclose their contractual qualities, their leaders wish to do so, but without the the choice between debt and equity, appropriate institutions no market economy of any significance is possible. If we knew more about our own economy, we would be to asset specificity in any of its forms (physical, in a better position to advise them. human, site-specific, dedicated assets, brand, and temporal), in combination with disturbances that Two years later, North, in his Nobel Prize beset contracts during the contract execution in- lecture, expressed similar precautions. terval are responsible for many of these hazards. Working, as it does, out of noncontractible human 14 Of the various ways in which it can be posed, asset investment distortions, GHM cannot lay its contractual nature becomes more evident when claim to these same empirical successes (Michael it is posed as a problem of reaching and enforcing Whinston 1997; Holmstrom 1999). a cartel agreement (Williamson 1975, Chap. 12).
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics 609 Thus even if we are confident that “poli- This political prescription for massive ties significantly shape economic perfor- and rapid privatization was reinforced mance because they define and enforce by the economic theory of the firm on the economic rules,” whereupon “an es- which the Boycko et al. team relied. sential part of development policy is the Specifically, they appealed to the afore- creation of polities that will create and mentioned work by Grossman and Hart enforce efficient property rights,” there is (1986), which views ownership as a sys- the further problem that “we know very tem of control rights and treats the ap- little about how to create such polities” propriate assignment of property rights (North 1994, p. 366). as determinative (Boycko, Shleifer, and Real-time events, however, cannot be Vishny 1995, p. 13). Upon privatizing put on hold. Hard choices have to be state-owned enterprises, therefore, ef- made. Economic reform in Russia is an fective restructuring by the new stake- example. holders would presumably follow (op The team of Maxim Boycko, Andrei cit, p. 150). In the confidence that the Shleifer, and Robert Vishny responded future would take care of itself, the to the perceived need to give shape to mass privatization program that was be- the reform with the recommendation gun in the spring of 1992 had purport- that the Russian economy should be edly reached a “triumphant completion” privatized quickly and massively. Con- in June 1994 (op cit, p. 8), by which siderations of both Realpolitik and eco- date two-thirds of Russian industry was nomic theory were invoked in support privately owned. of this recommendation. Had the Boycko et al. team consulted There being widespread agreement that the new institutional economics, a more “political influence over economic life cautious and selective program of priva- was the fundamental cause of economic tization with greater attention to imple- inefficiency” [in Russia], Boycko, Shleifer, mentation would have resulted. Consider and Vishny (1995, p. 11) declared that: first the literature on franchise bidding for natural monopoly, where the prop- . . . the principal objective of reform was . . . to depoliticize economic life. . . . Privatiza- erty rights approach and the gover- tion fosters depoliticization because it de- nance approach reach very different prives politicians of the opportunity to allo- conclusions. cate goods. . . . The goal of privatization was The property rights approach to the to sever the links between enterprise manag- problem of natural monopoly is to con- ers and politicians. . . . There was no other way to achieve restructuring and efficient duct an ex ante bidding competition operation of firms. and award the right to serve the market to the group that tenders the best bid The two strategic actors in this re- (Demsetz 1968; George Stigler 1968; form program were the official bureauc- Richard Posner 1972). Very much in the racy, which was viewed as “the enemy spirit of Boycko et al., the future will to be fought at all costs” and the stake- take care of itself once the assets have holders—managers, employees, and lo- been privatized in this way. cal governments. The Boycko et al. That sanguine view does not with- team “consistently and generously rec- stand scrutiny if serious ex post imple- ognized stakeholders’ claims, and thus mentation problems are in prospect. ensured their eventual support of priva- Under the governance approach, the tization” (Boycko, Shleifer, and Vishny award of a monopoly franchise needs to 1995, pp. 13–14). be assessed comparatively. This entails
610 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000) looking ahead and uncovering ex post verdict. Thus, although privatization was contractual hazards, thereafter working evidently a success for small firms, it out the ramifications for alternative was deeply problematic and attended by modes of governance (Williamson 1976, massive corruption in others. But for pp. 79–91). Because franchise bidding undue reliance on ex ante property rights works much better for some natural mo- reasoning, some of these problems nopoly industries than others (William- could have been anticipated by looking son 1976, pp. 102–103), the use of fran- ahead and examining the hazards of ex chise bidding will be reserved for those post implementation. Greater apprecia- industries where comparative net bene- tion for the shortfalls of the institutional fits can be projected—but not other- environment in Russia would have led to wise. Privatization, it turns out, is not an more cautious pronouncements (Anders all-purpose solution (Victor Goldberg Aslund 1995). Whether added respect 1976; George Priest 1993). for the rules of the game (to include an Although privatizing an entire econ- appreciation for the limited efficacy of omy is a much more ambitious undertak- Russian law enforcement) would have ing than privatizing a natural monopoly resulted in rule improvements in Russia industry, the key lessons nevertheless could be disputed. Arguably, however, carry over. Specifically, privatizing needs the effort to reform Russia would have to go beyond the ex ante award stage to proceeded in a more modest, slow, include an examination of possible ex molecular, deliberative way. post implementation problems and, in None of this is to suggest that the consideration of the differential hazards, NIE could have done it all. The Boycko to proceed selectively. et al. team made heroic efforts. My Recall, moreover, that the NIE oper- claim is much more modest: the NIE is ates at two levels. Upon moving from informative and should be included as the level of governance to that of the part of the reform calculus. institutional environment, the rules of the game come under review. The Levy 5. Concluding Remarks and Spiller (1994, 1996) study of priva- tizing telecommunications in five coun- The new institutional economics is a tries reveals that the decision to priva- boiling cauldron of ideas. Not only are tize and the nature of privatization turn there many institutional research pro- critically on the condition and quality of grams in progress, but there are com- judicial independence, the division of peting ideas within most of them. With powers between the executive and leg- reference to history, for example, we see islative branches, the competence of North (1990) and Avner Greif (1999) the regulatory bureaucracy, and con- pursuing complementary but separate tractual safeguards. Whether and how agendas. The institutions of embedded- to privatize telecommunications should ness (Level 1) are an important but un- therefore be made conditional on these derdeveloped part of the story. Within features. transaction cost economics we distin- As Bernard Black, Reinier Kraakman, guish between governance and measure- and Anna Tarassova detail in their pa- ment branches. The attributes of mixed per on “Russian Privatization and Cor- ownership modes (alliances, joint ven- porate Governance: What Went Wrong” tures, franchising, and the like) as well (1999), the “triumphant completion” of as the mechanisms for supporting cred- privatization in Russia was a premature ible contracting between autonomous
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics 611 firms are incompletely worked out. In- REFERENCES complete contracting of semi-formal Alchian, Armen. 1961. “Some Economics of Prop- and fully formal kinds differ in conse- erty,” RAND Corporation D-2316. Allen, Douglas, and Dean Leuck. 1999. “The Role quential ways, although the gap has of Risk in Contract Choice,” J. Law Econ. Org. been closing. Evolutionary economics 15:3, pp. 704–36. of selectionist, population ecology, and Arrow, Kenneth J. 1971. Essays in the Theory of Risk-Bearing. Chicago: Markham. ontogenetic kinds are in progress. Path ——— . 1987. “Reflections on the Essays,” in Ar- dependency is a real and important con- row and the Foundations of the Theory of Eco- dition, but its interpretation is actively nomic Policy. George Feiwel, ed. NY: NYU Press, pp. 727–34. disputed. The merits of privatization ———. 1999. “Foreword” in Firms, Markets and are real but are not uniform and need Hierarchies. Glenn Carroll and David Teece, to be assessed with reference to both eds. NY: Oxford U. Press, pp. vii–viii. Aslund, Anders. 1995. How Russia Became a Mar- the rules of the game and the play of ket Economy. Washington, DC: Brookings Insti- the game. The firm is variously de- tution. scribed in technological, contractual, Bajari, Patrick and Steven Tadelis. 1999. “Incen- tives versus Transaction Costs,” unpublished and competence/ knowledge-based per- paper, Stanford U. spectives. How best to describe human Banfield, E. C. 1958. The Moral Basis of a Back- actors is still unsettled, although evolu- ward Society. NY: Free Press. Barnard, Chester. 1938. The Functions of the Ex- tionary psychology holds promise. Poli- ecutive. Cambridge, MA: Harvard U. Press. tics is judged with reference to a hypo- Baron, James and David Kreps. 1999. Strategic thetical ideal by some (North 1990) and Human Resources. NY: John Wiley & Sons. Black, Bernard; Reinier Kraakman, and Anna in comparative institutional terms by Tarassova. 1999. “Russian Privatization and others (Williamson 1999). Efficiency ar- Corporate Governance: What Went Wrong?” guments have mainly prevailed over unpublished manuscript, Stanford Law School. Boorstin, Daniel. 1998. The Seekers. NY: Random power interpretations because the latter House. are tautological, but power issues refuse Boycko, Maxim; Andrei Shleifer, and Robert to go away. Bureaucracy remains a Vishny. 1995. Privatizing Russia. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. poorly understood condition no matter Buckley, Peter and Mark Casson. 1976. The Fu- what lens is brought to bear. Private or- ture of the Multinational Enterprise. London: dering approaches to contract have Holmes and Meier. Buttrick, John. 1952. “The Inside Contracting Sys- made progressive headway, but legal tem,” J. Econ. Hist. 12:3, pp. 205–21. rules remain important and their rela- Coase, Ronald. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm,” tion to private ordering is incompletely Economica, 4:6, pp. 386–405. worked out. Positive political theory has ——— . 1959. “The Federal Communications Commission,” J. Law Econ. 2:2, pp. 1–40. made major conceptual advances, but ——— . 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost,” J. an overarching understanding of poli- Law Econ. 3, pp. 1–44. ties does not appear imminent. And the ——— . 1964. “The Regulated Industries: Discus- sion,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 54:3, pp. 194–97. list goes on. ——— . 1988. The Firm, the Market, and the Law. The upshot is that, its many accom- Chicago: U. Chicago Press. plishments notwithstanding, there is a ——— . 1992. “The Institutional Structure of Pro- duction,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 82:4, pp. 713–19. vast amount of unfinished business—re- Commons, John R. 1932–33. “The Problems of finements, extensions, new applications, Correlating Law, Economics and Ethics,” Wisc. more good ideas, more empirical test- Law Rev. 8:1, pp. 3–26. Crocker, Keith and Scott Masten. 1996. “Regula- ing, more fully formal theory. I con- tion and Administered Contracts Revisited: clude that the new institutional eco- Lessons from Transaction Cost Economics for nomics is the little engine that could. Public Utility Regulation,” J. Regulatory Econ. 9:1, pp. 5–39. Its best days lie ahead. Who could ask Dawkins, Richard. 1976. The Selfish Gene. NY: for more? Oxford U. Press.
You can also read