The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead

Page created by Mike Morris
 
CONTINUE READING
Journal of Economic Literature
Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000) pp. 595–613

                                                                   Williamson: The New Institutional Economics

      The New Institutional Economics:
        Taking Stock, Looking Ahead
                                 OLIVER E . W ILLIAMSON 1

               1. Introduction                            velopment (1994, p. 75). In considera-
                                                          tion, however, of the “splendid plausi-

I   OPEN MY DISCUSSION      of the new in-
    stitutional economics with a confes-
sion, an assertion, and a recommenda-
                                                          bility of error” to which Lord Acton re-
                                                          fers, 2 we need to sort the sheep from
                                                          the goats. That is accomplished by ask-
tion. The confession is that we are still                 ing each would-be theory to advance re-
very ignorant about institutions. The as-                 futable implications to which the data
sertion is that the past quarter century                  are applied.
has witnessed enormous progress in the                       R. C. O. Matthews, in his presidential
study of institutions. The recommenda-                    address to the Royal Economic Society
tion is that, awaiting a unified theory, we               in 1986, pronounced that “the econom-
should be accepting of pluralism.                         ics of institutions has become one of the
   Chief among the causes of ignorance                    liveliest areas in our discipline” (Mat-
is that institutions are very complex.                    thews 1986, p. 903). Such a pronounce-
That neoclassical economics was dismis-                   ment was a surprise to most of the pro-
sive of institutions and that much of or-                 fession. Hadn’t institutional economics
ganization theory lacked scientific am-                   long since been relegated to the history
bitions have also been contributing                       of economic thought? Whence the vitality
factors. As to progress, that is what                     to which Matthews made reference?
most of this paper is about. There being                     Matthews’ response was that the new
many instructive lenses for studying                      institutional economics (NIE) turned on
complex institutions, pluralism is what                   two propositions. First, “institutions do
holds promise for overcoming our                          matter”; and second, “the determinants
ignorance.                                                of institutions are susceptible to analy-
   Speaking for myself, I subscribe to                    sis by the tools of economic theory”
Jon Elster’s view that we work predomi-                   (Matthews 1986, p. 903). The second of
nantly on partial mechanisms rather                       these is what distinguishes the NIE, it
than general theories at this stage of de-                being the case that institutional econo-
  1 University of California, Berkeley. owilliam@
                                                          mists of all kinds—old and new—are
haas.berkeley.edu. This paper was first presented         unanimous in the view that institutions
at the third annual meeting of the International          matter.
Society for New Institutional Economics in Wash-             Indeed, although both the older and
ington, DC in September 1999 in my capacity as
president-elect. Helpful comments received there          newer styles of institutional economics
and from Bengt Holmstrom and John McMillan
are gratefully acknowledged.                               2   As quoted in Daniel Boorstin (1998, p. 281).
                                                    595
596       Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000)

subscribe to many of the same good ideas,              2. Four Levels of Social Analysis
a progressive research program requires
more. Kenneth Arrow speaks to the                    It will be useful for purposes of per-
transformation as follows (1987, p. 734):         spective to consider the four levels of
                                                  social analysis that are distinguished in
 Why did the older institutionalist school fail   Figure 1. 3 The solid arrows that con-
 so miserably, though it contained such able      nect a higher with a lower level signify
 analysts as Thorstein Veblen, J. R. Commons,
 and W. C. Mitchell? I now think that . . .
                                                  that the higher level imposes con-
 [one of the answers is in the] important spe-    straints on the level immediately below.
 cific analyses . . . of the New Institutional    The reverse arrows that connect lower
 Economics movement. But it does not consist      with higher levels are dashed and signal
 of giving new answers to the traditional ques-   feedback. Although, in the fullness of
 tions of economics—resource allocation and
 the degree of utilization. Rather, it consists
                                                  time, the system is fully interconnected,
 of answering new questions, why economic         I mainly neglect these feedbacks. The
 institutions emerged the way they did and        NIE has been concerned principally
 not otherwise; it merges into economic his-      with levels 2 and 3.
 tory, but brings sharper [microanalytic] . . .      The top level is the social embedded-
 reasoning to bear than had been customary.
                                                  ness level. This is where the norms, cus-
   There is no question that the NIE              toms, mores, traditions, etc. are located.
has grown in stature and influence over           Religion plays a large role at this level.
the fourteen years since Matthews’ pro-           Although Level 1 analysis is undertaken
nouncement. Initial skepticism has                by some economic historians and other
gradually given way to respect—it being           social scientists (E. C. Banfield 1958;
the case that economists are very prag-           Robert Putnam, Robert Leonardi, and
matic people. Tell them something dif-            Raffaella Nanetti 1993; Samuel Hunt-
ferent and consequential about phe-               ington 1996; and Victor Nee 1998),
nomena that are of interest to them and           Level 1 is taken as given by most insti-
demonstrate that the data are corrobo-            tutional economists. Institutions at this
rative: that will get their attention. The        level change very slowly—on the order
NIE has progressed not by advancing an            of centuries or millennia—whereupon
overarching theory but by uncovering              Douglass North poses the query, “What
and explicating the microanalytic features        is it about informal constraints that gives
to which Arrow refers and by piling               them such a pervasive influence upon
block upon block until the cumulative             the long-run character of economies?”
value added cannot be denied.                     (1991, p. 111).
   The NIE, moreover, will not stand                 North does not have an answer to
still. Even as institutional economics is         that perplexing question, nor do I. The
being incorporated within orthodoxy,              concept of “embeddedness,” both at the
new opportunities and challenges await.           level of society and in the context of on-
Both unfinished business and new proj-            going network relations, has been ad-
ects yet to be undertaken await the new           vanced to help explicate these issues
millennium.                                       (Granovetter 1985). The vast literature
   I begin with a sketch of four levels of        on culture (Paul DiMaggio 1994) is also
social analysis, next turn to some of the         pertinent. Neil Smelser and Richard
good ideas out of which the NIE works,            Swedberg discuss these and related issues
and then examine some of the applica-             in their introduction to the Handbook
tions to which the NIE has been put.                3 This framework was first set out in Williamson
Concluding remarks follow.                        (1998).
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics                    597

of Economic Sociology, where they ob-       mainly spontaneous origins—which is to
serve that different kinds of embedded-     say that deliberative choice of a calcula-
ness—cognitive, cultural, structural,       tive kind is minimally implicated. Given
and political—should be distinguished,      these evolutionary origins, they are
and conclude that “the concept of em-       “adopted” and thereafter display a great
beddedness remains in need of greater       deal of inertia—some because they are
theoretical specification” (1994, p. 18).   functional (as with conventions); others
   An identification and explication of     take on symbolic value with a coterie of
the mechanisms through which informal       true believers; many are pervasively
institutions arise and are maintained       linked with complementary institutions
would especially help to understand the     (formal and informal), etc. Be that as it
slow change in Level 1 institutions. I      may, the resulting institutions have a
conjecture in this connection that many     lasting grip on the way a society con-
of these informal institutions have         ducts itself. Insular societies often take
598      Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000)

measures to protect themselves against       the response to such opportunities is
“alien values.”                              often one of “failure.” Absent such a
   The second level is referred to as the    window, major changes in the rules of
institutional environment. The struc-        the game occur on the order of decades
tures observed here are partly the prod-     or centuries. The European Union,
uct of evolutionary processes, but de-       for example, has been “in progress” for
sign opportunities are also posed. Going     fifty years and is still in early stages of
beyond the “informal constraints (sanc-      development.
tions, taboos, customs, traditions, and         What is often referred to as Positive
codes of conduct)” of a Level 1 kind, we     Political Theory (PPT) is concerned
now introduce “formal rules (constitu-       with working out the economic and po-
tions, laws, property rights)” (North        litical ramifications of Level 2 features.
1991, p. 97). This opens up the oppor-       To be sure, such research also has les-
tunity for first-order economizing: get      sons for the normative design of better
the formal rules of the game right.          polities. Like the NIE of which it is a
   Constrained by the shadow of the          part, however, PPT is predominantly an
past, the design instruments at Level 2      exercise in positive analysis. The object
include the executive, legislative, judi-    is to better understand how things
cial, and bureaucratic functions of gov-     work—warts and all. The research prod-
ernment as well as the distribution of       uct of PPT scholarship has been noth-
powers across different levels of gov-       ing less than auspicious, which has been
ernment (federalism). The definition         good for both political science and the
and enforcement of property rights and       NIE.
of contract laws are important features.        Much of the economics of property
   Although such first-order choices are     rights is of a Level 2 kind. Such re-
unarguably important to the economic         search flourished in the 1960s. A strong
productivity of an economy (Nathan           version of the argument is that “a pri-
Rosenberg and L. E. Birdzell 1986;           vate-enterprise system cannot function
Ronald Coase 1992; North 1994; Brian         properly unless property rights are cre-
Levy and Pablo Spiller 1994; Mancur          ated in resources, and, when this is
Olson 1996; Witold Henisz 1998) cumu-        done, someone wishing to use a re-
lative change of a progressive kind is       source has to pay the owner to obtain it.
very difficult to orchestrate. Massive       Chaos disappears; and so does the gov-
discontent—civil wars (the Glorious          ernment except that a legal system to
Revolution; see North and Barry Wein-        define property rights and to arbitrate
gast 1989), or occupations (following        disputes is, of course, necessary” (Coase
World War II), perceived threats (the        1959, p. 12; emphasis added). Once
Meiji Revolution), breakdowns (Eastern       property rights have been defined and
Europe and the former Soviet Union), a       their enforcement assured, the govern-
military coup (Chile), or a financial cri-   ment steps aside. Resources are allo-
sis (New Zealand)—will, however, occa-       cated to their highest value as the marvel
sionally produce a sharp break from es-      of the market works its wonders.
tablished procedures. Rare windows of           This compact statement illustrates
opportunity to effect broad reform are       both the strength and the weakness of
thereby opened. Such “defining mo-           the property rights literature. The great
ments” are nevertheless the exception        strength of this literature is that it
rather than the rule. At least partly be-    brings property rights to the forefront,
cause of our primitive understanding,        where they belong, whereupon novel
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics                      599

property rights reasoning could be            however, is a truncated way to study or-
brought to bear in informative ways           ganization—especially if all complex
(Armen Alchian 1961, 1965; Coase              contracts are unavoidably incomplete
1959, 1960; Harold Demsetz 1967). The         and if adaptation is the central problem
weakness is that it overplayed its hand.      of economic organization (Chester Bar-
The claim, for example, that the legal        nard 1938; Friedrich Hayek 1945). Mov-
system will eliminate chaos upon defin-       ing beyond the agency theory tradition of
ing and enforcing property rights as-         ex ante incentive alignment, transaction
sumes that the definition and enforce-        cost economics turns its attention—ad-
ment of such rights is easy (costless).       ditionally and predominantly—to the ex
Plainly, many transactions do not qual-       post stage of contract.
ify (Coase 1960). Going beyond the               This entails four moves: (1) to name
rules of the game (property) to include       and explicate the principal dimensions
the play of the game (contract) was           with respect to which transactions differ
needed. That is the opening through           (thereby to uncover differential adap-
which the governance of contractual           tive needs); (2) to name and explicate
relations walked in during the 1970s.         the principal attributes for describing
   This brings me to the third level,         governance structures (where each is
which is where the institutions of gover-     defined by a distinctive syndrome of re-
nance are located. Although property          lated attributes, whence markets, hy-
remains important, a perfectly function-      brids, firms, regulation, bureaus, non-
ing legal system for defining contract        profits, etc. differ in discrete structural
laws and enforcing contracts is not con-      ways); (3) to effect a discriminating match,
templated. Costless court ordering be-        according to which transactions are
ing a fiction, much of the contract man-      aligned with governance structures so
agement and dispute settlement action         as to promote adaptation of autonomous
is dealt with directly by the parties—        and cooperative kinds; and (4) to ascer-
through private ordering. The need to         tain whether the predicted alignments
come to terms with contract laws (plu-        are corroborated by the data.
ral), rather than an all-purpose law of          The canonical problem for dealing
contract (singular), is posed (Clyde          with these issues is that of vertical inte-
Summers 1969; Ian Macneil 1974). The          gration, which is the issue posed by
governance of contractual relations           Coase in his classic 1937 article on “The
becomes the focus of analysis.                Nature of the Firm.” As it turns out,
   John R. Commons prefigured this            any issue that arises as or can be refor-
work with his observation that “the ulti-     mulated as a contracting issue can be
mate unit of activity . . . must contain      examined to advantage in transaction
in itself the three principles of conflict,   cost economizing terms. A huge num-
mutuality, and order. This unit is a          ber of phenomena turn out to be con-
transaction” (1932, p. 4). Not only does      tractual variations on a common theme.
transaction cost economics subscribe to       What I refer to as second-order econo-
the idea that the transaction is the basic    mizing—get the governance structures
unit of analysis, but governance is an ef-    right—is realized at Level 3. The possi-
fort to craft order, thereby to mitigate      ble reorganization of transactions among
conflict and realize mutual gains.            governance structures is re-examined
   So conceived, a governance structure       periodically, on the order of a year to a
obviously reshapes incentives. To focus       decade, often at contract renewal or
entirely on ex ante incentive alignment,      equipment renewal intervals.
600      Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000)

   Such discrete structural analysis of      who believed that institutions were
governance is to be distinguished from       both important and susceptible to
the fourth level, which is the level at      analysis. Feeling expansive, I would in-
which neoclassical analysis works. Opti-     clude six Nobel Laureates among the
mality apparatus, often marginal analy-      key figures: Kenneth Arrow, Friedrich
sis, is employed, and the firm, for these    Hayek, Gunnar Myrdal, Herbert Simon,
purposes, is typically described as a pro-   Ronald Coase, and Douglass North—
duction function. Adjustments to prices      the last two being the first two presi-
and output occur more or less continu-       dents of ISNIE. But there are others.
ously. Agency theory, which emphasizes       Armen Alchian has been an influential
ex ante incentive alignment and effi-        figure. So too has been research on or-
cient risk bearing, rather than ex post      ganization theory, especially at Carnegie
governance, nonetheless makes provi-         (some of it prefigured by earlier work
sion for nonneoclassical complications,      by Chester Barnard)—where the names
of which multi-tasking is one (Bengt         of Richard Cyert and James March join
Holmstrom and Paul Milgrom 1991).            that of Simon. Alfred Chandler’s pio-
   Indeed, a still earlier (zero level) of   neering work in business history was
analysis warrants remark: an evolution-      also pathbreaking. Thoughtful contribu-
ary level in which the mechanisms of         tors from the law, especially contract
the mind take shape (Steven Pinker           law, include Karl Llewellyn, Stewart
1997). The application of these ideas to     Macaulay, Lon Fuller, and Ian Macneil.
economics even now is beginning to           John R. Commons also brought original
reshape our understanding of human           and important ideas to the study of in-
actors. Our evolutionary psychologist        stitutional economics. The German His-
and cognitive science colleagues are         torical School was also concerned with
vital to the exercise.                       related ideas (Erik Furubotn and
   Finally, I should call attention to       Rudolf Richter 1997, pp. 34–35).
technology. As compared with techno-            Among the key good ideas that I
logical innovation, the study of orga-       associate with the NIE are these:
nizational innovation has been compara-         Human Actors. If “nothing is more
tively neglected. The NIE has attempted      fundamental in setting our research
to rectify that—the idea being that          agenda and informing our research
“truly among man’s innovations, the use      methods than our view of the nature of
of organization to accomplish his ends       the human beings whose behavior we
is among both his greatest and his earli-    are studying” (Simon 1985, p. 303),
est” (Arrow 1971, p. 224). We cannot         then social scientists should be pre-
fail, however, to be awed by the pro-        pared to name the key attributes of hu-
found importance of technological inno-      man actors. Both the condition of cog-
vation (Robert Fogel 1999). Inasmuch         nition and self-interestedness need to
as these two work in tandem, we need         be addressed.
to find ways to treat technical and or-         There is close to unanimity within
ganizational innovation in a combined        the NIE on the idea of limited cognitive
manner.                                      competence—often referred to as
                                             bounded rationality. Mind being a
             3. Good Ideas                   scarce resource, cognitive specialization
                                             has economizing consequences. Also,
   The new institutional economics had       given cognitive limits, the complex con-
its origins in good critics of orthodoxy     tracts to which I referred earlier are
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics                             601

unavoidably incomplete. But while there       flict, mutuality, and order to which I
is near-unanimity that complete contin-       referred earlier—is centrally implicated.
gent claims contracting is impossible,           Feasibility. Students of the NIE es-
the appropriate way to model incom-           chew hypothetical ideals—which work
plete contracts remains controversial.        off of omniscience, benevolence, zero
Lack of agreement on the definition           transaction costs, full credibility, and
and operational import of bounded             the like—and deal instead with feasible
rationality is a major obstacle (Ariel        organizational alternatives, all of which
Rubinstein 1998; David Kreps 1999).           are flawed. Coase (1964) and Demsetz
   Contractual incompleteness poses           (1969) were among the first to take ex-
added problems when paired with the           ception with the asymmetric standards
condition of opportunism—which mani-          that were once used in the “market fail-
fests itself as adverse selection, moral      ure” literature—according to which
hazard, shirking, subgoal pursuit, and        markets are beset with failures whereas
other forms of strategic behavior. Be-        “omniscient, omnipotent, benevolent”
cause human actors will not reliably dis-     governments (Avinash Dixit 1996, p. 8)
close true conditions upon request or         would reliably administer efficacious
self-fulfill all promises, contract as        remedies. As we all should have recog-
mere promise, unsupported by credible         nized (but needed to be told), all feasi-
commitments, will not be self-enforcing.      ble forms of organization—government
   But for opportunism, the courts            included—are flawed. 4
would simply ask witnesses to “tell us           What I have referred to as the reme-
what you know that is germane to our          diableness criterion is intended to rec-
decision.” That is not, however, the way      tify this asymmetric state of affairs. This
that testimony is taken. Witnesses are        criterion holds that an extant mode of
required to take an oath to “tell the         organization for which no superior fea-
truth, the whole truth, and nothing but the   sible alternative can be described and
truth”: don’t lie; don’t conceal; don’t       implemented with expected net gains is
mislead. Inasmuch, moreover, as oaths         presumed to be efficient.
are not self-enforcing, penalties for per-       To be sure, public policy analysis be-
jury remind witnesses that prevarication      comes more complicated when analysts
has consequences.                             can no longer condemn extant modes
   Still a third attribute of human actors    because they deviate from a hypotheti-
warrants remark, and that is the capac-       cal ideal, full stop. The remediableness
ity for conscious foresight. Indeed, as       criterion presses the public policy ana-
Richard Dawkins observes, it is the “ca-      lyst to display a superior feasible alter-
pacity to simulate the future in imagina-     native. If, moreover, a proposed feasi-
tion . . . [that saves] us from the worst     ble alternative cannot be costlessly
consequences of the blind replicators”        implemented, then the costs of imple-
(1976, p. 200). Parties to a contract         mentation are appropriately included in
who look ahead, recognize potential           the net benefit calculus—which has ma-
hazards, work out the contractual rami-       jor ramifications for the path depen-
fications, and fold these into the ex ante    dency literature. Finally, grounds for
contractual agreement obviously enjoy         rebutting the efficiency presumption
advantages over those who are myopic          need to be addressed—which brings in
or take their chances and knock on               4 Dixit (1996) counsels the older public finance
wood. The governance of contractual           tradition to come to terms with government fail-
relations—the Commons triple of con-          ures.
602      Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000)

politics (Williamson 1996, 1999). Ab-       lytically convenient (and sometimes
sent rebuttal, the remediableness crite-    adequate) conception of the firm-as-
rion stands as a reminder of the obvi-      production function (which is a techno-
ous: it is impossible to do better than     logical construction) to consider the
one’s best.                                 firm as a governance structure (which is
   Firms and Bureaus. In addition to the    an organizational construction) in which
nature of the human beings to which Si-     internal structure has economic pur-
mon referred, we need also to be self-      pose and effect. More generally, the
conscious about the “Nature of the Firm,”   need was to identify and explicate the
which was the title of Coase’s classic      properties of alternative modes of gover-
1937 article from which the NIE draws       nance—spot markets, incomplete long
much of its inspiration. Arrow speaks to    term contracts, firms, bureaus, etc.—
the fundamental importance of the the-      which differ in discrete structural ways.
ory of the firm, and to long-standing       Because each generic mode of gover-
misconceptions thereof, as follows: “Any    nance possesses distinctive strengths and
standard economic theory, not just neo-     weaknesses, there is a place for each yet
classical, starts from the existence of     each needs to be kept in its place. The
firms. Usually, the firm is a point or at   logic of discriminating alignment to
any rate a black box. . . . But firms are   which I referred earlier applies.
palpably not points. They have internal        In a heuristic way, the choice of
structure. This internal structure must     governance structure moves from mar-
arise for some reason” (1999, p. vii).      ket to hierarchy through the sequence
   The need was to get beyond the ana-      of moves shown in Figure 2 (where h
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics                                   603

denotes contractual hazards and s de-                 introduced when transactions are re-
notes safeguards). 5 This can be inter-               moved from the market and placed un-
preted as a move from simple to com-                  der unified ownership (the firm). Be-
plex. We thus begin with autonomous                   cause added compliance and security
contracting, which is the ideal transac-              features always come at a cost, more
tion in both law and economics: “sharp                complex modes of governance are re-
in by clear agreement; sharp out by                   served for those transactions for which
clear performance” (Macneil 1974, p.                  contractual hazards are especially difficult.
738). This discrete transaction para-                    The public bureau, in this scheme of
digm comes under strain as contractual                things, can be thought of as the organi-
hazards appear. The inability of courts,              zation form of last resort: try spot mar-
for example, to verify what is common                 kets, try incomplete long-term con-
knowledge between the parties to an ex-               tracts, try firms, try regulation, and
change (Williamson 1975, p. 30) could                 reserve recourse to public bureaus for
induce a move from interfirm to in-                   when all else fails (comparatively). Note
trafirm organization. Other sources of                that the common practice of condemn-
contractual hazard include bilateral de-              ing public bureaus because they have
pendency (by reason of nonredeploy-                   lower-powered incentives, more rules
able assets), weak property rights (es-               and regulations, and greater job secu-
pecially intellectual property rights),               rity than a counterpart firm completely
undisclosed quality, health, and safety               misses the point. These features have
hazards, failures of probity, and the like.           been deliberately crafted into the pub-
Such hazards compromise contractual                   lic bureau, thereby to make it better
integrity and give rise to contractual im-            suited to govern some (especially diffi-
passes, maladaptations, and investment                cult) transactions. 6 Vigilance is none-
distortions. Here, as elsewhere, ineffi-              theless needed—lest the public bureau
ciency invites relief. Cost-effective haz-            be “overused.”
ard mitigation through added governance                  If transaction cost economics works
ensues.                                               out of variations on a few key themes,
   Moving from less to more complex                   then this schema, which was initially
governance entails introducing added                  devised to help explicate the gover-
security features, reducing incentive in-             nance of contractual relations in inter-
tensity, and incurring added bureau-                  mediate product market transactions,
cratic costs. Moving from simple (dis-                should also apply, with variation, to
crete) contracts to complex (incomplete               other classes of transactions. It does.
long term) contracts is thus attended by                 The four nodes are interpreted with
a whole series of features: the length of             reference to intermediate product
the contract increases, penalties to de-              transactions above. Consider final goods
ter breach are introduced, provision is               markets and government procurement
made for added information disclosure                 transactions.
and processing, and specialized dispute                  Transactions in final goods markets,
settlement mechanisms appear.                         where individual consumers are the
   Additional mechanisms, to include
the use of hierarchy to effect coordi-                  6 This is a recurrent theme not only of the trans-
nation and decide disputes by fiat, are               action cost economics literature but also of parts
                                                      of the agency theory literature. See especially
  5 A variant of Figure 2 originally appeared in my   Holmstrom (1989) and Holmstrom and Milgrom
paper on “Public and Private Bureaucracies”           (1991, 1994), where the benefits of low-powered
(1999).                                               incentives in firms are featured.
604      Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000)

buyers, are similar but different. Node     are initially expressed as tautologies,
A transactions are generic and competi-     which Coase has wryly defined as “a
tively organized. Node B transactions       proposition that is clearly right” (1988,
are rare. These correspond to “P. T.        p. 19). Because good tautologies expand
Barnum”—there’s a sucker born every         the mind and are hard to come by, they
minute—and other fly-by-night transac-      deserve respect. Lest, however, we slip
tions. Node C is the credible commit-       into the speculations to which Wesley
ment node. Branding in combination          Mitchell once referred 7—which is a fate
with reputation effects and product         that beset the older style institutional
warranties appear. Also, for some natu-     economics as well as the American Le-
ral monopoly transactions, public utility   gal Realism movement—we need to ask
regulation serves credibility purposes.     what are the mechanisms through
Node D is a nearly empty set. Econo-        which a proposed theory operates and
mies of scale and of specialization are     what are the refutable implications.
impediments to own-supply by consum-           The effort to operationalize promis-
ers, although collective organization       ing ideas has both theoretical and em-
(consumer cooperatives) can be used         pirical parts. The theoretical often takes
to manage some transactions. (Many          the form of a progression from informal
household services can be thought of as     to preformal, semi-formal, and fully for-
own-supply, but few fit comfortably         mal modes of analysis—ideally acquir-
within the schema.)                         ing value added in the process. Such an
   Government procurement transac-          effort helps to sort the sheep from the
tions are also similar but different.       goats. Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen had
Node A describes generic transactions       a felicitous way of putting it: although
to which, often, tedious technical speci-   the “purpose of science is not predic-
fications apply. Very few government        tion, but knowledge for its own sake,”
transactions are of a Node B kind.          prediction is nevertheless “the touch-
Credibility mechanisms at Node C in-        stone of scientific knowledge” (1971, p.
clude the elaborate machinery of “ad-       37). Would-be theories for which pre-
ministered contracting,” as with defense    dictive content is lacking must eventu-
procurement (which transactions, how-       ally step aside (be set aside) for those
ever, are sometimes compromised by          for which the hard work of formalization
the shared interests of the government      and empirical testing are undertaken.
agency and the private supplier). And          Theory Development. Formalization
Node D is the public bureau, where for      is vital to a progressive research agenda,
probity or political reasons the govern-    but it sometimes comes at a cost. Thus
ment chooses to manage the transaction      although Simon once argued that
itself.                                     “mathematical translation is itself a sub-
   Other applications of the schema in-     stantive contribution to theory . . . be-
clude the employment relation (James        cause it permits clear and rigorous rea-
Baron and Kreps 1999, ch. 4) and cor-       soning about phenomena too complex
porate finance (the choice between          to be handled in words” (1957, p. 89)
debt and equity). Some transactions,           7 “Speculative systems can be quickly excogi-
such as alliances and joint ventures,       tated precisely because they do not require the
pose complications of a disequilibrium      economist to collect and analyze masses of data, to
contracting kind (Williamson 1991) that     test hypotheses for conformity to fact, to discard
                                            those which do not fit, to invent new ones and test
are beyond the reach of the schema.         them until, at long last, he has established a factu-
   Operationalization. Many good ideas      ally valid theory” (Mitchell 1945, p. 2).
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics                                 605

and subsequently asserted that the                  for the property rights theory of the
“poverty of mathematics is an honest                firm, which is a major intellectual
poverty that does not parade imaginary              achievement that has spawned a grow-
riches before the world” (1957, p. 90),             ing literature on the formal modelling
provision also needs to be made for the             of incomplete contracts. 8 As Kreps sug-
possibility that core features of the the-          gests, however, valuable chunks are
ory are left out or obscured by the                 missing. In the spirit of full disclosure
translation. There is, after all, such a            (honest poverty), I focus on these.
thing as prematurely formal theory.                    The most consequential difference
Kreps speaks to the issues as follows               between the TCE and GHM setups is
(1999, p. 122):                                     that the former holds that maladapta-
                                                    tion in the contract execution interval is
 If Markets and Hierarchies has been transla-
                                                    the principal source of inefficiency,
 ted into game theory using notions of infor-
 mation economics, it is a very poor transla-       whereas GHM vaporize ex post
 tion . . . In particular, mathematics-based        maladaptation by their assumptions of
 theory still lacks the language needed to cap-     common knowledge and costless ex post
 ture essential ideas of bounded rationality,       bargaining. The upshot is that all of the
 which are central to . . . transaction costs
                                                    inefficiency in GHM is concentrated in
 and contractual form. Anyone who relies on
 the translations alone misses large and valuable   the ex ante investments in human assets
 chunks of the original.                            (which are conditional on the ownership
                                                    of physical assets). 9
   What is referred to as the “property                This shift from ex post maladaptation
rights theory of the firm,” which had its           (the hazards from which vary with the
origins with Sanford Grossman and                   condition of asset specificity and the
Oliver Hart (1986) and has subsequently             disturbances to which a transaction is
been developed by Hart and John Moore               subject) to ex ante investment distor-
(hence the reference to the GHM model),             tions matters. For one thing, GHM
relates to but differs significantly from           makes very limited contact with the
the transaction cost economics setup (as            data 10 whereas (as discussed below)
presented, for example, in Williamson               TCE is an empirical success story. Re-
1985, 1991). It is similar in that it deals         lated (ex post) governance and (ex ante)
with the make-or-buy decision through               investment differences are the following:
a setup where contracts are incomplete
                                                       8 The January 1999 issue of the Review of Eco-
(by reason of bounded rationality),
                                                    nomic Studies is entirely devoted to recent contri-
mere promise cannot be used to over-                butions, critiques, responses, and extensions upon
come noncontractibility (by reason of               the GHM model.
                                                       9 Bounded rationality enters this setup in a very
opportunism), and parties to the con-
                                                    peculiar way: parties who are unable to write com-
tract are bilaterally dependent (by rea-            plete contracts ex ante are nevertheless able to an-
son of asset specificity). These com-               ticipate ex ante what decisions will be taken ex
monalities notwithstanding, there are               post, contingent on state realizations (Kreps 1999,
                                                    pp. 123–25). In effect, the GHM setup is one of
also major differences.                             selective unbounded rationality: “not everything
   Some of these differences are attrib-            that is logically consistent is credulous” (Kreps
utable to simplifications that invariably           1999, p. 125).
                                                       10 That the data relevant to GHM are so limited
attend formal modelling. Ideally, core              and inaccessible explains why there has been “no
features of the verbal argument and the             formal testing of the property rights approach”
mechanisms through which they work                  (Hart 1995, p. 49)—although the “inside contract-
                                                    ing system” (John Buttrick 1952) is an approxima-
are made more precise in the process of             tion to (and its failures could be interpreted as a
formalization. Such a case can be made              partial contradiction of) GHM.
606        Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000)

  (1) The TCE rendition of the make-                       ing). GHM assume that incentive
      or-buy decision between succes-                      intensity, administrative controls,
      sive stages (A and B) asks whether                   and informal organization are un-
      A and B should be separately                         changed by ownership and that
      owned and operated or if the own-                    courts are irrelevant (because of
      ership and operation of these two                    costless renegotiation). None of
      stages should be unified. If in-                     the physical asset utilization and
      dependent, then each stage appro-                    transfer pricing distortions that I
      priates its net receipts (high-pow-                  associate with the “impossibility of
      ered     incentives   obtain)     but                selective intervention” (Williamson
      maladaptation problems can arise                     1985, pp. 135–40) thus occur
      during contract execution. If uni-                   under the GHM setup.
      fied, then the two stages are man-               (3) TCE examines a wide range of ex
      aged coordinately through hierar-                    post devices for infusing credible
      chy. (Maladaptation problems are                     commitments into contracts and
      thereby relieved; incentives are                     applies this reasoning to a wide set
      lower-powered; and added bureau-                     of transactions. Variations on this
      cratic costs arise.) By contrast,                    theme include hybrid modes of or-
      GHM view vertical integration in a                   ganization (Scott Masten 1996,
      directional way: either A buys B or                  Part III), exchange agreements
      B buys A, and it matters which way                   and other uses of hostages to sup-
      this is done. That is because com-                   port exchange, the organization of
      mon ownership under GHM does                         work, the organization of labor and
      not imply unified management. In-                    human resources more generally,
      stead, each stage (in all configura-                 corporate governance, regulation
      tions—A and B are independent; A                     (and deregulation), public bu-
      buys B; B buys A) appropriates its                   reaus, and project financing. Be-
      net receipts. This last is a very un-                cause GHM is a property rights
      usual condition, in that unified                     and property rights only construc-
      ownership is normally thought of                     tion (Holmstrom 1999), it relates
      as a means by which to effect                        to some of these issues not at all
      cooperation.11                                       and others very selectively (Hart
  (2) TCE maintains that each generic                      1995; Hart, Andrei Shleifer, and
      mode of governance—spot market,                      Robert Vishny 1997).
      incomplete long-term contract,
      firm, bureau, etc.—is defined by a               GHM is nonetheless a pathbreaking
      syndrome of attributes to which                contribution and has set the formal
      distinctive strengths and weak-                modelling of incomplete contracting in
      nesses accrue. Specifically, TCE               motion. New formal models of incom-
      holds that alternative modes differ            plete contracts which are closer in spirit
      in incentive intensity, administra-            to TCE include the treatment of pro-
      tive controls (to include auditing,            curement by Patrick Bajari and Steven
      accounting, and transfer pricing),             Tadelis (1999), which focuses on the in-
      access to the courts, and informal             centive and ex post adaptation differ-
      organization (to include politick-             ences between fixed price and cost plus
                                                     contracting. Also, the recent paper by
  11 The inside contracting system referred to in    Susheng Wang and Tian Zhu (2000)
note 7 supra is in the spirit of GHM organization.   employs the idea that alternative modes
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics                                607

of governance work out of different                  graduate students) are progressively
contract law regimes (Williamson 1991).              built up—moving from less formal to
And Gene Grossman and Elhanan Help-                  more formal stages of development. Fi-
man (1999) appeal to the added bureau-               nally, as with promising graduate stu-
cratic costs of unified as compared with             dents, we do not hold on to cherished
market governance in their assessment                theories indefinitely: some do flunk out.
of alternative modes for producing dif-              Specifically, theories that remain tauto-
ferentiated consumer products. More                  logical or yield predictions that are con-
veridical treatments of incomplete con-              tradicted by the data must make way for
tracting are thus in progress and still              theories that yield predictions for which
more are in prospect. 12                             the data are corroborative.
   Empirical. Some scoff at prediction,                 Empirical applications of transaction
evidently in the belief that prediction is           cost economics got under way in the
easy. Also, since everyone knows that                U.S. in the 1980s and have grown expo-
“it is easy to lie with statistics,” what            nentially since: the number of pub-
useful purpose is served by empirical                lished studies exceeds 500 and involves
testing? My experience is different: pre-            social scientists in Europe, Japan, India,
diction is a demanding standard, which               China, Mexico, South America, Austra-
is why so many would-be theories re-                 lia, New Zealand, and the list goes on.
main excogitated speculations; and cor-              It could have been otherwise, but the
roboration is difficult, which explains              theory and evidence display a remark-
why few predictions are tested.                      able congruity (Scott Masten 1995, p.
   Because, however, good theories are               xi). Recent empirical surveys include
rarely fully developed at the outset, the            Howard Shelanski and Peter Klein
theory and the evidence are often inter-             (1995), Bruce Lyons (1996), Keith
active. As Alan Newell observes (1990,               Crocker and Masten (1996), and Aric
p. 14):                                              Rindfleisch and Jan Heide (1997).
  Theories cumulate. They are refined and re-
                                                        Not only has this research been
  formulated, corrected and expanded. Thus,          broadly corroborative of the predictions
  we are not living in the world of Popper. . . .    of transaction cost economics, but the
  [Theories are not] shot down with a falsifica-     importance of risk aversion to commer-
  tion bullet. . . . Theories are more like gradu-   cial contracting has been placed in
  ate students—once admitted you try hard to
  avoid flunking them out. . . . Theories are
                                                     doubt (Douglas Allen and Dean Lueck
  things to be nurtured and changed and built        1999). To be sure, transaction cost eco-
  up.                                                nomics, like everything else, will bene-
                                                     fit from more and better empirical
  Good but underdeveloped ideas are                  work. I have no hesitation, however, in
evidently like good but underdeveloped               declaring that the NIE is an empirical
minds: both are precious things. Be-                 success story. Paul Joskow concurs:
cause development is costly, promising               “this empirical work is in much better
theories, like promising graduate stu-               shape than much of the empirical work
dents, are admitted only if they cross a             in industrial organization generally”
threshold. Once admitted, theories (and              (1991, p. 81). Those who have done this
  12 For an earlier formal treatment (of a reduced   modest, slow, molecular, definitive
form kind) akin to Bajari and Tadelis, see Michael   work deserve enormous credit. 13
Riordan and Williamson (1985). The recent paper
by Hart and Moore, “On the Design of Hierar-           13 The recurring regularity is this: more complex
chies” (1999a), also makes express provision for     modes of governance appear as contractual haz-
organization.                                        ards build up—where bilateral dependency, due
608        Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000)

                4. Phenomena                          the oligopoly problem, 14 and the multi-
                                                      national corporation being examples
   The NIE is predominantly concerned
                                                      (Peter Buckley and Mark Casson 1976;
with Levels 2 and 3 of the four levels of
                                                      Hubert Gatignon and Erin Anderson
social analysis shown in Figure 1. These
                                                      1988).
are the levels of the institutional envi-
                                                         Many public policy issues, moreover,
ronment and the institutions of gover-
                                                      turn jointly on the combined use of
nance, respectively. Between them,
                                                      Level 2 and Level 3 reasoning. In the
they cover a lot of ground.
                                                      area of privatizing telecommunications,
   The formal features of the institu-
                                                      for example, Levy and Spiller examine
tional environment—the laws, polity,
                                                      the institutional environments in five
judiciary, bureaucracy—are crucial in
                                                      countries through a comparative con-
examining the development of nation
                                                      tractual lens in which issues of credible
states (North and Weingast 1989) and
                                                      contracting are featured (1994, 1996).
for making intertemporal comparisons
                                                      The recent study of reforming urban
within and cross-national comparisons
                                                      water systems by Claude Menard and
between nation states. Indeed, this last
                                                      Mary Shirley (1999) likewise makes
has come to be a growth industry to
                                                      clear that ownership is not determina-
which many economists who are only
                                                      tive but needs to be examined in con-
slightly associated with the NIE have
                                                      junction with the support, or the lack
made contributions. It is nonetheless
                                                      thereof, of the mechanisms of gover-
noteworthy that the NIE has done
                                                      nance. Again, issues of credible contract-
much of the pioneering work in this
                                                      ing are salient. The same is true of com-
area.
                                                      mercial contracting in Vietnam (John
   To repeat, any issue that arises as or
                                                      McMillan and Christopher Woodruff
can be posed as a contractual issue can
                                                      1999).
be examined to advantage in transaction
                                                         Broad reach notwithstanding, the
cost economizing terms. Examples for
                                                      NIE is not and does not pretend to be
which contractual issues are evident at
                                                      an all-purpose construction, as the re-
the outset include contracts for inter-
                                                      form of economies of Eastern Europe
mediate products, for labor, for final
                                                      and the former Soviet Union illustrate.
goods and services, for the rental or
                                                      Thus Coase in his Nobel Prize lecture
lease or purchase of land, equipment,
                                                      observed that (1992, p. 714):
and buildings, for professional services,
for marriage, and the list goes on. Even,               The value of including . . . institutional fac-
moreover, if contractual features are                   tors in the corpus of mainstream economics is
                                                        made clear by recent events in Eastern
not immediately evident from the out-                   Europe. These ex-communist countries are
set, many issues can be reformulated so                 advised to move to a market economy, and
as to disclose their contractual qualities,             their leaders wish to do so, but without the
the choice between debt and equity,                     appropriate institutions no market economy
                                                        of any significance is possible. If we knew
                                                        more about our own economy, we would be
to asset specificity in any of its forms (physical,     in a better position to advise them.
human, site-specific, dedicated assets, brand, and
temporal), in combination with disturbances that      Two years later, North, in his Nobel Prize
beset contracts during the contract execution in-     lecture, expressed similar precautions.
terval are responsible for many of these hazards.
Working, as it does, out of noncontractible human        14 Of the various ways in which it can be posed,
asset investment distortions, GHM cannot lay          its contractual nature becomes more evident when
claim to these same empirical successes (Michael      it is posed as a problem of reaching and enforcing
Whinston 1997; Holmstrom 1999).                       a cartel agreement (Williamson 1975, Chap. 12).
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics                         609

Thus even if we are confident that “poli-               This political prescription for massive
ties significantly shape economic perfor-            and rapid privatization was reinforced
mance because they define and enforce                by the economic theory of the firm on
the economic rules,” whereupon “an es-               which the Boycko et al. team relied.
sential part of development policy is the            Specifically, they appealed to the afore-
creation of polities that will create and            mentioned work by Grossman and Hart
enforce efficient property rights,” there is         (1986), which views ownership as a sys-
the further problem that “we know very               tem of control rights and treats the ap-
little about how to create such polities”            propriate assignment of property rights
(North 1994, p. 366).                                as determinative (Boycko, Shleifer, and
   Real-time events, however, cannot be              Vishny 1995, p. 13). Upon privatizing
put on hold. Hard choices have to be                 state-owned enterprises, therefore, ef-
made. Economic reform in Russia is an                fective restructuring by the new stake-
example.                                             holders would presumably follow (op
   The team of Maxim Boycko, Andrei                  cit, p. 150). In the confidence that the
Shleifer, and Robert Vishny responded                future would take care of itself, the
to the perceived need to give shape to               mass privatization program that was be-
the reform with the recommendation                   gun in the spring of 1992 had purport-
that the Russian economy should be                   edly reached a “triumphant completion”
privatized quickly and massively. Con-               in June 1994 (op cit, p. 8), by which
siderations of both Realpolitik and eco-             date two-thirds of Russian industry was
nomic theory were invoked in support                 privately owned.
of this recommendation.                                 Had the Boycko et al. team consulted
   There being widespread agreement that             the new institutional economics, a more
“political influence over economic life              cautious and selective program of priva-
was the fundamental cause of economic                tization with greater attention to imple-
inefficiency” [in Russia], Boycko, Shleifer,         mentation would have resulted. Consider
and Vishny (1995, p. 11) declared that:              first the literature on franchise bidding
                                                     for natural monopoly, where the prop-
 . . . the principal objective of reform was . . .
 to depoliticize economic life. . . . Privatiza-
                                                     erty rights approach and the gover-
 tion fosters depoliticization because it de-        nance approach reach very different
 prives politicians of the opportunity to allo-      conclusions.
 cate goods. . . . The goal of privatization was        The property rights approach to the
 to sever the links between enterprise manag-        problem of natural monopoly is to con-
 ers and politicians. . . . There was no other
 way to achieve restructuring and efficient
                                                     duct an ex ante bidding competition
 operation of firms.                                 and award the right to serve the market
                                                     to the group that tenders the best bid
   The two strategic actors in this re-              (Demsetz 1968; George Stigler 1968;
form program were the official bureauc-              Richard Posner 1972). Very much in the
racy, which was viewed as “the enemy                 spirit of Boycko et al., the future will
to be fought at all costs” and the stake-            take care of itself once the assets have
holders—managers, employees, and lo-                 been privatized in this way.
cal governments. The Boycko et al.                      That sanguine view does not with-
team “consistently and generously rec-               stand scrutiny if serious ex post imple-
ognized stakeholders’ claims, and thus               mentation problems are in prospect.
ensured their eventual support of priva-             Under the governance approach, the
tization” (Boycko, Shleifer, and Vishny              award of a monopoly franchise needs to
1995, pp. 13–14).                                    be assessed comparatively. This entails
610       Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII (September 2000)

looking ahead and uncovering ex post           verdict. Thus, although privatization was
contractual hazards, thereafter working        evidently a success for small firms, it
out the ramifications for alternative          was deeply problematic and attended by
modes of governance (Williamson 1976,          massive corruption in others. But for
pp. 79–91). Because franchise bidding          undue reliance on ex ante property rights
works much better for some natural mo-         reasoning, some of these problems
nopoly industries than others (William-        could have been anticipated by looking
son 1976, pp. 102–103), the use of fran-       ahead and examining the hazards of ex
chise bidding will be reserved for those       post implementation. Greater apprecia-
industries where comparative net bene-         tion for the shortfalls of the institutional
fits can be projected—but not other-           environment in Russia would have led to
wise. Privatization, it turns out, is not an   more cautious pronouncements (Anders
all-purpose solution (Victor Goldberg          Aslund 1995). Whether added respect
1976; George Priest 1993).                     for the rules of the game (to include an
   Although privatizing an entire econ-        appreciation for the limited efficacy of
omy is a much more ambitious undertak-         Russian law enforcement) would have
ing than privatizing a natural monopoly        resulted in rule improvements in Russia
industry, the key lessons nevertheless         could be disputed. Arguably, however,
carry over. Specifically, privatizing needs    the effort to reform Russia would have
to go beyond the ex ante award stage to        proceeded in a more modest, slow,
include an examination of possible ex          molecular, deliberative way.
post implementation problems and, in              None of this is to suggest that the
consideration of the differential hazards,     NIE could have done it all. The Boycko
to proceed selectively.                        et al. team made heroic efforts. My
   Recall, moreover, that the NIE oper-        claim is much more modest: the NIE is
ates at two levels. Upon moving from           informative and should be included as
the level of governance to that of the         part of the reform calculus.
institutional environment, the rules of
the game come under review. The Levy                    5. Concluding Remarks
and Spiller (1994, 1996) study of priva-
tizing telecommunications in five coun-           The new institutional economics is a
tries reveals that the decision to priva-      boiling cauldron of ideas. Not only are
tize and the nature of privatization turn      there many institutional research pro-
critically on the condition and quality of     grams in progress, but there are com-
judicial independence, the division of         peting ideas within most of them. With
powers between the executive and leg-          reference to history, for example, we see
islative branches, the competence of           North (1990) and Avner Greif (1999)
the regulatory bureaucracy, and con-           pursuing complementary but separate
tractual safeguards. Whether and how           agendas. The institutions of embedded-
to privatize telecommunications should         ness (Level 1) are an important but un-
therefore be made conditional on these         derdeveloped part of the story. Within
features.                                      transaction cost economics we distin-
   As Bernard Black, Reinier Kraakman,         guish between governance and measure-
and Anna Tarassova detail in their pa-         ment branches. The attributes of mixed
per on “Russian Privatization and Cor-         ownership modes (alliances, joint ven-
porate Governance: What Went Wrong”            tures, franchising, and the like) as well
(1999), the “triumphant completion” of         as the mechanisms for supporting cred-
privatization in Russia was a premature        ible contracting between autonomous
Williamson: The New Institutional Economics                            611

firms are incompletely worked out. In-                          REFERENCES
complete contracting of semi-formal          Alchian, Armen. 1961. “Some Economics of Prop-
and fully formal kinds differ in conse-         erty,” RAND Corporation D-2316.
                                             Allen, Douglas, and Dean Leuck. 1999. “The Role
quential ways, although the gap has             of Risk in Contract Choice,” J. Law Econ. Org.
been closing. Evolutionary economics            15:3, pp. 704–36.
of selectionist, population ecology, and     Arrow, Kenneth J. 1971. Essays in the Theory of
                                                Risk-Bearing. Chicago: Markham.
ontogenetic kinds are in progress. Path      ——— . 1987. “Reflections on the Essays,” in Ar-
dependency is a real and important con-         row and the Foundations of the Theory of Eco-
dition, but its interpretation is actively      nomic Policy. George Feiwel, ed. NY: NYU
                                                Press, pp. 727–34.
disputed. The merits of privatization        ———. 1999. “Foreword” in Firms, Markets and
are real but are not uniform and need           Hierarchies. Glenn Carroll and David Teece,
to be assessed with reference to both           eds. NY: Oxford U. Press, pp. vii–viii.
                                             Aslund, Anders. 1995. How Russia Became a Mar-
the rules of the game and the play of           ket Economy. Washington, DC: Brookings Insti-
the game. The firm is variously de-             tution.
scribed in technological, contractual,       Bajari, Patrick and Steven Tadelis. 1999. “Incen-
                                                tives versus Transaction Costs,” unpublished
and competence/ knowledge-based per-            paper, Stanford U.
spectives. How best to describe human        Banfield, E. C. 1958. The Moral Basis of a Back-
actors is still unsettled, although evolu-      ward Society. NY: Free Press.
                                             Barnard, Chester. 1938. The Functions of the Ex-
tionary psychology holds promise. Poli-         ecutive. Cambridge, MA: Harvard U. Press.
tics is judged with reference to a hypo-     Baron, James and David Kreps. 1999. Strategic
thetical ideal by some (North 1990) and         Human Resources. NY: John Wiley & Sons.
                                             Black, Bernard; Reinier Kraakman, and Anna
in comparative institutional terms by           Tarassova. 1999. “Russian Privatization and
others (Williamson 1999). Efficiency ar-        Corporate Governance: What Went Wrong?”
guments have mainly prevailed over              unpublished manuscript, Stanford Law School.
                                             Boorstin, Daniel. 1998. The Seekers. NY: Random
power interpretations because the latter        House.
are tautological, but power issues refuse    Boycko, Maxim; Andrei Shleifer, and Robert
to go away. Bureaucracy remains a               Vishny. 1995. Privatizing Russia. Cambridge,
                                                MA: MIT Press.
poorly understood condition no matter        Buckley, Peter and Mark Casson. 1976. The Fu-
what lens is brought to bear. Private or-       ture of the Multinational Enterprise. London:
dering approaches to contract have              Holmes and Meier.
                                             Buttrick, John. 1952. “The Inside Contracting Sys-
made progressive headway, but legal             tem,” J. Econ. Hist. 12:3, pp. 205–21.
rules remain important and their rela-       Coase, Ronald. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm,”
tion to private ordering is incompletely        Economica, 4:6, pp. 386–405.
worked out. Positive political theory has    ——— . 1959. “The Federal Communications
                                                Commission,” J. Law Econ. 2:2, pp. 1–40.
made major conceptual advances, but          ——— . 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost,” J.
an overarching understanding of poli-           Law Econ. 3, pp. 1–44.
ties does not appear imminent. And the       ——— . 1964. “The Regulated Industries: Discus-
                                                sion,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 54:3, pp. 194–97.
list goes on.                                ——— . 1988. The Firm, the Market, and the Law.
   The upshot is that, its many accom-          Chicago: U. Chicago Press.
plishments notwithstanding, there is a       ——— . 1992. “The Institutional Structure of Pro-
                                                duction,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 82:4, pp. 713–19.
vast amount of unfinished business—re-       Commons, John R. 1932–33. “The Problems of
finements, extensions, new applications,        Correlating Law, Economics and Ethics,” Wisc.
more good ideas, more empirical test-           Law Rev. 8:1, pp. 3–26.
                                             Crocker, Keith and Scott Masten. 1996. “Regula-
ing, more fully formal theory. I con-           tion and Administered Contracts Revisited:
clude that the new institutional eco-           Lessons from Transaction Cost Economics for
nomics is the little engine that could.         Public Utility Regulation,” J. Regulatory Econ.
                                                9:1, pp. 5–39.
Its best days lie ahead. Who could ask       Dawkins, Richard. 1976. The Selfish Gene. NY:
for more?                                       Oxford U. Press.
You can also read