RESEARCH UPDATE Spring 2021 - FEATURES PUBLICATIONS NEWS & EVENTS PEOPLE ANNOUCEMENTS - Banco de España

Page created by Margaret Martinez
 
CONTINUE READING
RESEARCH UPDATE Spring 2021 - FEATURES PUBLICATIONS NEWS & EVENTS PEOPLE ANNOUCEMENTS - Banco de España
RESEARCH    Spring 2021

UPDATE
               FEATURES

            PUBLICATIONS

           NEWS & EVENTS

                 PEOPLE

           ANNOUCEMENTS
Welcome to the Banco
de España Research Update
The Banco de España is pleased to announce the release of the Spring 2021 issue of its
Research Update. The Update aims to inform both academic and policy-oriented
economists and financial specialists about publications, conferences, and other research
activities at the Banco de España, during the semester from October 2020 to April 2021.

As usual, this issue includes several feature articles summarizing policy-relevant findings
from recent Banco de España projects in diverse areas of research. First, J. Andrés, O.
Árce and P. Burriel analyse whow the dampening of the estimated co-movement between
the output gap and inflation noticed in recent decades can be rationalized through a model
that incorporates the increase in polarization observed in several industries. Second, D.
Serrano-Puente evaluates the optimal progressivity of the Spanish personal income tax
scheme through the lens of a general equilibrium model featuring rich household
heterogeneity. He finds that there is room for welfare improvement by means of modifying
the effective average tax rates, at the expense of efficiency losses. Third, A. Alonso and J.
M. Carbó study the economic impact for financial institutions of using machine learning
(ML) models for credit default predictions. They find that, although ML models outperform
traditional ones, more complex algorithms do not imply better predictions. Fourth, F. Holub,
L. Hospido and U. Wagner estimate the impact of air pollution on the incidence of sick
leaves on a representative panel of employees affiliated to the Spanish social security
system. Controlling for several possible confounding factors, their evidence points towards
an impact of air pollution on the incidence of sick leaves, especially for women with pre-
existing conditions. Finally, P. García-Perea, A. Lacuesta and P. Roldán-Blanco document
that the increase in mark-ups in Spain during the financial crisis can be explained by the
response of relatively small and unproductive firms to the drop in their sales and the increase
in average costs.

In addition, the Update reports on other research news such as conferences and recent
publications, including the Financial Stability Review, a half-year journal published by the
Banco de España. This issue also covers an interview with Enrique Moral-Benito, Head of
the Sectoral Analysis Division, covering his research agenda, the policy developments at
the Banco de España related to the ongoing Covid19 crisis, as well as recent efforts to
develop and leverage large and granular datasets in order to tackle research and policy
questions.

We highlight these and other research developments at the Banco de España in hopes that
they will interest the broader research community in Spain and internationally, and thereby
contribute to an improved understanding of economic policy

                                                                                 Óscar Arce
                                                                             Olympia Bover
                                                                              Ángel Estrada
                                                                                 Eva Ortega
                                                                             Carlos Thomas

                                                                     Research Committee,
                                                                        Banco de España
FEATURES

Market polarization                                             unprecedented set of non-conventional monetary policy
                                                                measures after the global financial crisis (GFC), inflation and
and the Phillips curve                                          inflation expectations in most advanced economies
JAVIER ANDRÉS, ÓSCAR ARCE AND PABLO BURRIEL                     remained chronically subdued even before the Covid-19
Summary of Banco de España Working Paper no. 2106               crisis. Some argue that this comes from afar and potentially
                                                                well before the GFC (Blanchard, 2016). Prominent among
The Phillips curve has flattened out over the last decades.     the potential explanations for the weak reaction of prices to
We develop a model that rationalizes this phenomenon as         cyclical conditions are the decline of labor power, the rise of
a result of the observed increase in polarization in many       globalization and international trade, and the impact of
industries, a process along which a few top firms gain an       positive supply shocks caused by new technologies.
increasing share of their industry market. In the model,
firms compete à la Bertrand and there is exit and               These factors do not exhaust the list of possible causes
endogenous market entry, as well as optimal up and              behind the diminishing effect of cyclical fluctuations on
downgrading of technology. Firms with larger market             prices. A related strand of literature is placing increasing
shares find optimal to dampen the response of their price       attention on some ongoing significant changes in the
changes, thus cushioning the shocks to their marginal           industrial structure in advanced economies. These changes
costs through endogenous countercyclical markups.               include, among others, the rise in market shares in many
Thus, regardless of its causes (technology, competition,        industries, industrial polarization along different dimensions
barriers to entry, etc.), the recent increase in polarization   (e.g. firm size, productivity, etc.), the rise in markups,
in many industries emerges in the model as the key factor       intensification of competition spurred by technology and the
in explaining the muted responses of inflation to               decline of the labor share. In particular, the case for market
movements in the output gap witnessed recently.                 concentration over the last decades has been forcefully
                                                                established on empirical grounds (Covarrubias, Gutiérrez
                                                                and Philippon, 2019). Yet, so far little consensus can be
SUMMARY FOR THE APRIL RESEARCH UPDATE                           found about the likely effect of these factors on the inflation
                                                                rate or, more precisely, on the link between inflation and the
In this paper we set up a model consistent with many of         economic slack (Van Reenen, 2018). The importance of the
the features highlighted by the empirical industrial            new technological giants in shaping the way economies
organization literature, to argue that these changes might      respond to shocks, the archetypal case being the
be behind the muted response of inflation to shocks to the      disinflationary impact of Amazon, is in stark contrast with
marginal costs that has been observed lately. The flattening    the long held view in mainstream macroeconomics,
of the Phillips curve that has taken place over the last        according to which market concentration has been
twenty years poses a challenge for monetary authorities.        considered a source of inflationary pressure.
On the other hand, the availability of large data sets
containing firm level information on a number of relevant       Our model sheds light on the connection between the rise
variables has uncovered a series of facts that speak of         in market polarization (increase in market shares and
profound changes in the distribution of firms in many           widening gap in size and productivity across firms in the
industries   with   repercussion    in   the   response    of   same industry) and the flattening of the Phillips curve.
macroeconomic variables to exogenous shocks.                    Contrary to the previous standard view, in our model the
                                                                rise in market shares is neither inflationary nor deflationary
The pattern of inflation rates across most advanced             per se, but it reduces the slope of the Phillips curve, which
economies in recent years defies the traditional explanations   is consistent with the recent empirical literature (Del Negro,
based on the Phillips curve relation between inflation and      Lenza, Primiceri, and Tambalotti, 2020). In particular, the
the output gap. In spite of the implementation of an            slope of the Phillips curve derived in conventional New

                                                                        BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 3
FEATURES

Keynesian DSGE models (regardless of whether price                                                s
                                                                                          where ξN =
                                                                                                                s
                                                                                                                    (
                                                                                                                 s ε −1 )               s
                                                                                                                                        ∂ξ
                                                                                                                                    > 0, Ns > 0.
inertia is of the Calvo or the Rotemberg type) gets                                                                              
                                                                                                        1 − s   ε  1 − s  − 1
                                                                                                              s             s           ∂s
                                                                                                                           
augmented in our model by a factor that decreases with                                                                     
the market share of the firm, as shown in equation (1).
                                                                                          Therefore, when a firm faces a positive shock to its
                                1 −    s
                                       θp     1 − βθ s                                 marginal cost it raises prices, which in turn undermines its
                                                   p    
                              +                          mc s
        s              s
       πt   =   βE t π t +1                   s                 t                         market share and hence its desired markup; this dampens
                                            θp
                                                                                          the inflationary effect of the shock. The strength of this
                              Standard NKPC                                               effect increases with the firm’s market share. Hence, in an
                                                                                          economy featuring highly polarized industrial structures,
                        s  1 − θp 
                            s        s

            +                                      s s − βθ s E s s             (1)   with a few large and many small competitors in each
                                                     t       p t t +1 
               1 − s s   ε  1 − s s  − 1 θs                   
                                                                                          industry, much in line with the aforementioned recent
                                       p
                                      
                                                                                          evidence, the response of inflation to shocks becomes
                                 heterogeneity effect                                     more muted than it would be in a similar economy with a
                                                                                          more balanced distribution of firms. In our simulations,
            s                                                                 s
where π t , represents inflation of firms of size s, mc t , their                         small variations in the drivers of market concentration
                                      s
real marginal costs and              st ,   their market share.        1
                                                                                          deliver significant changes in the slope of the Phillips
                                                                                          curve. While strategic price interactions barely affect the
Key to this result is the fact that markups depend positively                             markup of smallish firms, they do condition the desired
on the firm’s market share. The endogeneity of markups                                    markup of large firms in a material manner (Amiti, Itskhoki,
hinges critically on the joint effect of two core features of the                         and Konings, 2019). This moderates the response of
industrial structure of the economy. We assume that firms                                 prices set by the latter to shocks, which in turn (upon
have access to different TFP levels and choose among them                                 aggregation) exerts a significant dampening effect on the
optimally taking into account the costs of moving up or down                              volatility of aggregate inflation. In fact, in the chart below
in the technology ladder. Furthermore, as in Etro and Rossi                               we show how a 20% increase in the productivity of larger
(2015), Andrés and Burriel (2018), and, more recently, Wang                               firms, which increases their market share, reduces the
and Werning (2020), we assume that firms compete à la                                     response of their inflation to a negative TFP shock
Bertrand taking into account the expected reaction of other                               significantly (by 28%), while the response of smaller firms
competitors when setting their prices. Thus, substituting for                             to the same TFP shock remains unaltered. As a
the endogenous market shares in equation (1) and solving,                                 consequence, the response of aggregate inflation is also
we get a Phillips Curve with the usual drivers of inflation,                              more moderate (by 26%). A similar result is obtained after
expected inflation and marginal costs, pre-multiplied by a                                an increase in the degree of competition as measured by
factor smaller than 1, which depends on the firms’ steady                                 the elasticity of demand. Moreover, these findings are also
                                 s
state market shares (s ), as shown in equation (2).                                       found for other standard shocks, like an increase in policy
                                                                                          rates, or negative preference or labour supply shocks.

      1 + θs ξ s                                          1 − θs   1 − βθ s 
                                        1                      p         p
 s         p N               s                                             mc s
πt =                  βE t π t +1 +                                                   To further assess the relevance of the mechanism analyzed
      1 + ξNs                                s                       s              t
                                      1 + ξN                     θp
                                                                                          in the paper, we investigate the medium term response of
                                                                                    (2)   the industrial structure to increases in technological
                                                                                          divergences, the elasticity of substitution among goods
                                                                                          and barriers to entry, three factors that Covarrubias,
1 In the model size and productivity level are interchangeable. The
                   s
                                                                                          Gutiérrez and Philippon (2019) identify as the main drivers
   parameter 1 − θp represents the share of firms that are allowed to
   change their prices every period according to the Calvo price-setting                  of market concentration in recent decades. The model
   mechanism, β is the discount factor and ε the elasticity of substitution
   between intermediate goods.                                                            predictions are consistent with the main facts reported by

BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 4
FEATURES

Chart 1
IMPULSE RESPONSE OF INFLATION AFTER AN INCREASE IN TFP UNDER DIFFERENT PRODUCTIVITY SCENARIOS

  1 AGGREGATE INFLATION                                   2 INFLATION OF HIGH -TFP FIRMS                                3 INFLATION OF LOW -TFP FIRMS

          %                                                        %                                                            %
   0.00                                                    0.00                                                          0.04

  -0.01                                                   -0.01                                                          0.00

  -0.02                                                   -0.01                                                         -0.04

  -0.03                                                   -0.02                                                         -0.08

  -0.04                                                   -0.02                                                         -0.12

  -0.05                                                   -0.03                                                         -0.16
          1   2   3    4   5   6    7     8    9    10              1     2   3     4   5   6   7    8    9   10                  1   2   3   4   5   6   7   8   9   10
                                              Quarters                                                    Quarters                                                Quarters

                                                               BASELINE                 20% INCREASE IN HIGH-TFP FIRMS PRODUCTIVITY

a The variables are presented as percentage differences with respect to the steady state.

the   empirical       literature:       (1)    Sustained       increase       in            Andrés, J. and P. Burriel, 2018): “Inflation and optimal monetary
                                                                                              policy in a model with firm heterogeneity and Bertrand
concentration in most industries (Bajgar, Berlingieri,
                                                                                              competition”. European Economic Review, 103, 2018, Pages
Calligaris, Criscuolo, and Timmis, 2019); (2) concentration                                   18-38
in employment but less intense than in sales (Autor, Dorn,
                                                                                            Autor, D., D. Dorn, L. Katz, C. Patterson, and J. Van Reenen
Katz, Patterson, and Van Reenen, 2019); (3) increase in                                       (2019): “The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar
polarization along other dimensions like productivity                                         Firms”, Quarterly Journal of Economics (forthcoming)

(Berlingueri,     Blanchenay            and        Criscuolo    (2017);       (4)           Bajgar, M., G. Berlingieri, S.Calligaris, C. Criscuolo, and J.
sustained increase of markups, mostly at the top of the                                       Timmis (2019): “Industry Concentration in Europe and North
                                                                                              America,” CEP Discussion Papers dp1654, Centre for
markup distribution (De Loecker, Eeckhout, and Unger
                                                                                              Economic Performance, LSE.
(2020); (5) steady decline in firm entry in most industries
(Akcigit and Ates, 2019); (6) generalized fall in investment                                Barkai, S. 2019: “Declining labor and capital shares”, Journal of
                                                                                              Finance (forthcoming)
rates in many advanced economies (Eggertsson, Robbins,
and Wold (2018); and (7) decline in the labor share                                         Blanchard, O. (2016): “The US Phillips Curve: Back to the 60s?”,
                                                                                              American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 106(5):
accompanied by a fall in capital share in most industries
                                                                                              31--34.
too (Barkai, 2019).
                                                                                            Covarrubias, M., G. Gutiérrez and T. Philippon (2019): “From
                                                                                              Good to Bad Concentration? U.S. Industries Over the Past 30
REFERENCES                                                                                    Years”, NBER, Working Paper 25983.

Akcigit, U, and S T Ates (2019), “Ten Facts on Declining Business                           De Loecker, J., J. Eeckhout, G. Unger, 2020. “The Rise of
  Dynamism and Lessons from Endogenous Growth Theory,”                                        Market Power and the Macroeconomic Implications”,
  NBER Working Paper 25755.                                                                   Quarterly Journal of Economics 135(2), 2020, 561-644.

Amiti, M., O. Itskhoki, and J. Konings, 2019: “International                                Del Negro, M., M. Lenza, G. E. Primiceri, and A. Tambalotti
 Shocks, Variable Markups, and Domestic Prices,” The Review                                   (2020): “What’s up with the Phillips Curve?,” NBER Working
 of Economic Studies, 02.                                                                     Papers 27003

                                                                                                         BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 5
FEATURES

Eggertsson, G., J. Robbins, and E. Wold, 2018: “Kaldor and
  Piketty’s Facts: The Rise of Monopoly Power in the United
  States”, NBER Working Paper No. 24287

Etro, F. and L. Rossi, 2015. “New-Keynesian Phillips curve with
  Bertrand competition and endogenous entry”, Journal of
  Economic Dynamics & Control, vol. 51(3), pp. 318--340.

Van Reenen, J., 2018. “Increasing Differences Between Firms:
  Market Power and the Macro-Economy,” CEP Discussion
  Papers DP1576, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE.

Wang, O. and I. Werning, 2020. “Dynamic Oligopoly and Price
 Stickiness,” NBER Working Papers 27536, National Bureau of
 Economic Research, Inc.

BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 6
FEATURES

Optimal Progressivity of Personal                                 economies. For that reason, the optimal design of a
                                                                  redistributive tax system is subject to many constraints, as
Income Tax: A General Equilibrium                                 argued by Bakis et al. (2015). This is why having a

Evaluation for Spain                                              quantitative theory that accounts accurately for the observed
                                                                  income and wealth inequality is crucial when assessing the
DARÍO SERRANO-PUENTE
                                                                  aggregate, distributional, and welfare implications of certain
Summary of Banco de España Working Paper no. 2101
                                                                  policies. For that purpose, a heterogeneous households
Published in SERIEs - Journal of the Spanish Economic
Association, vol. 11(4), pp. 407-455, November 2020               general equilibrium model is here calibrated to replicate
                                                                  some characteristics of the Spanish economy and used to
Is the Spanish economy positioned at its optimal                  compare the steady-state consequences of setting an
progressivity level in personal income tax? This article          optimal progressivity level in the Spanish personal income
quantifies the aggregate, distributional, and welfare             tax. This frames the setup here presented in literature of
consequences of moving toward such an optimal level. A            general equilibrium models with heterogeneous agents to
heterogeneous households general equilibrium model                explore the relationship between fiscal policy variables and
featuring both life cycle and dynastic elements is calibrated     the endogenous cross-sectional distribution of income
to replicate some characteristics of the Spanish economy          and wealth in Spain. Examples of this body of literature are
and used to evaluate potential reforms of the tax system.         Pijoan-Mas    and       González-Torrabadella   (2006),   Díaz-
The findings suggest that increasing progressivity would          Giménez and Pijoan-Mas (2019), and Guner et al. (2020),
be optimal, even though it would involve an efficiency loss.      among others.
The optimal reform of the tax schedule would reduce
wealth and income inequality at the cost of negative effects      The theoretical framework of this paper is built for Spain
on capital, labor, and output. Finally, these theoretical         following Castañeda et al. (2003). The model is devoted to
results are evaluated using tax microdata and describe a          (i) account for income and wealth inequality and (ii) study
current scenario where the income-top households                  decisions of households that face labor income processes
typically face suboptimal effective average tax rates.            that are random, household-specific, and uninsurable. In
                                                                  these model-based economies, households accumulate
                                                                  wealth in part to smooth their consumption. Heterogeneity
Many modern governments implement a redistributive fiscal         is introduced in this setup via distinct labor market
policy, where personal income is taxed at an increasingly         opportunities using an uninsurable process on the
higher rate, while transfers tend to target the poorest           endowment of efficiency labor units that features non-linear
households. The taxation of personal income is not a minor        dynamics. Given the labor market opportunity, the
issue, since most of the OECD economies obtain a large            households choose their work effort. In other words,
proportion of their tax collection through it. Raising taxes on
                                            1
                                                                  the labor choice is set here to be endogenous. Life cycle
higher incomes may be potentially justified by the increase in    characteristics are modeled using aging and retirement and
income and wealth inequality in recent years in Spain,            dynastic links are modeled in a way that households are
especially after the 2007 crisis, as documented by Angel et       altruistic toward their descendants (hybrid model with
al. (2018). Beforehand, one is likely to consider that raising    retirement and bequests). Household face a progressive tax
taxes on the income-rich households could reverse the             schedule modeled through the Heathcote et al. (2017)
growing concentration at the top. However, this type of policy    specification, a function that allows for assessing average
could be very costly in terms of efficiency in advanced market    level of taxes and progressivity separately. The model is
                                                                  properly calibrated to match some empirical statistics of the
                                                                  Spanish economy and replicates the distributions of income
  The OECD average of the share of personal income tax
1                                                                and wealth in very much detail (also at the very top tails of
   revenues over total tax revenues (excluding social security
   contributions) has been around 30-35% in recent years.         those distributions).

                                                                          BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 7
FEATURES

Once the theoretical framework is defined, a bunch of potential               decomposed by household type, where it is observed that the
progressivity reforms are assessed through the calculation of                 poorest working and non-working households are the ones
many different general equilibria (one equilibrium for each                   who benefit the most from the reform. Contrarily, the most
degree of progressivity evaluated). Then a Benthamite social                  efficient working households and the wealthiest ones (either
planner, who takes into account all households in the economy                 working or non-working) are those who experience the largest
by putting the same weight on each of them, discerns the                      trade-off between (i) positive welfare effects derived from higher
optimal progressivity reform that leaves the aggregate tax                    income (due to an increased interest rate that pushes up
burden and transfers-to-output levels unchanged. The findings                 capital returns) and (ii) adverse effects emerging from higher
suggest that aggregate social welfare is maximized when the                   tax payments (due to the increase in progressivity of the
level of progressivity of the Spanish personal income tax is                  income tax that discourages labor and savings). The losses
increased to some extent. More precisely, in the optimally                    from this trade-off are particularly high in top parts of the
reformed scenario (setting the optimal level of progressivity),               income and wealth distributions and clearly offset the potential
welfare gains are equivalent to an average increase of 3.08%                  welfare gains of the households populating such areas.
of consumption.                                                               Therefore, knowing that these agents would be the losers
                                                                              of the reform, despite positive aggregate welfare effects,
By decomposing the aggregate welfare change, it is shown                      the consequences on aggregate capital, labor, and
that most of the welfare gains are obtained from a majority of                output would be negative, which means that the economy
households facing a lower tax rate, i.e. the poorest households               would experience an efficiency loss. Moreover, looking at
facing lower effective income tax rates and richest households                the distributional implications, this reform would reduce
affronting higher effective income tax rates. On the contrary,                income and wealth inequality.
the general equilibrium effects of the optimal reformed
economy (higher interest rate and lower wage) and the effects                 Finally, the theoretical results are evaluated with Spanish tax
resulting from changes in the equilibrium distribution of                     micro data. From the point of view of a Benthamite social
households across income levels (larger mass of households                    planner, households between the 20th and the 80th
at lower income levels) show a welfare loss, but these losses                 percentiles would experience a decrease in their average tax
are so small that together cannot overpass the welfare gains                  rates under the optimal progressivity reform. For example,
directly coming from the reformed tax system, jointly resulting               the effective average tax rate encountered by a household
in positive aggregate welfare changes. These welfare gains are                situated within the 40th and the 60th percentiles of the

Figure 1
AGGREGATE WELFARE CHANGE

       % change in consumption
   4

   2

   0

  -2

  -4

  -6

  -8
                                          A ct u a l                Optimal
 -10

 -12
       0            0.05            0.1                0.15   0.2     0.25              0.3         0.35          0.4         0.45               0.5
                                                                                                                                Progressivity level
              AGGREGATE WELFARE CHANGE

BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 8
FEATURES

Figure 2
AVERAGE EFFECTIVE TAX RATES AND SHARE OF TAX REVENUES

 1 AVERAGE EFFECTIVE TAX RATES

          Average effective tax rates (%)
 40

                                                                                                                                                                 33.00

                                                                                                                                                        28.40
 30
                                                                                                                                            25.20
                                                                                                                                   22.40

                                                                                                18.00   18.80      18.20   18.80
 20

                                                                             11.70     11.00
 10                                                        6.70
                                                                      5.60
                                     2.00       1.40
              0.10          0.01
  0
                     0-20                   20-40             40-60              60-80             80-100              90-95           95-99               99-100
                                                                                                                                     Percentiles of household gross income

 2 SHARE OF TOTAL INCOME TAX REVENUE

           Share of total income tax revenues (%)
 100
  90
                                                                                                        78.13
  80                                                                                            74.88

  70
  60
  50
  40
                                                                                                                                                                 26.47
  30                                                                                                                               20.89    22.48      23.73
                                                                             17.25       15.7
  20                                                                                                               13.78   13.71
                                                           6.48       5.29
  10                                  1.34          0.88
               0.06         0.0001
      0
                      0-20                  20-40                 40-60          60-80             80-100              90-95           95-99               99-100
                                                                                                                                     Percentiles of household gross income

                                                                                     ACTUAL              OPTIMAL

income distribution would drop from 0.067 to 0.056, which                                       addition, the reform would reduce income and wealth
involves a change of 1.1 p.p.. On the other hand, households                                    inequality. However, this would lead to an efficiency loss
above the 80th percentile would experience a drastic increment                                  of the economy, since it discourages work and savings
in their effective average tax rate. For instance, the top 1%                                   mainly by penalizing the top-working and wealthiest
households of the gross income distribution would go from                                       households.
confronting an average tax rate of 0.284 in the actual scenario
to dealing with an average tax rate of 0.330 in the optimal one.                                REFERENCES

                                                                                                Anghel, B., H. Basso, O. Bover, J. M. Casado, L. Hospido, M.
In conclusion, as policy implications arising from this                                           Izquierdo, I. A. Kataryniuk, A. Lacuesta, J. M. Montero, and E.
study, what the model (jointly with the data) indicates is                                        Vozmediano (2018): “Income, Consumption and Wealth
                                                                                                  Inequality in Spain,” SERIEs - Journal of the Spanish Economic
that, in terms of aggregate welfare, it would be optimal to
                                                                                                  Association - Journal of the Spanish Economic Association, 9,
increase the progressivity of the personal income tax. In                                         351–378.

                                                                                                         BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 9
FEATURES

Bakis, O., B. Kaymak, and M. Poschke (2015): “Transitional
  dynamics and the optimal progressivity of income
  redistribution,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 18, 679–693.

Castaneda, A., J. Díaz-Giménez, and J. V. Ríos-Rull (2003):
  “Accounting for the U.S. Earnings and Wealth Inequality,”
  Journal of Political Economy, 111, 818–857.

Díaz-Giménez, J. and J. Pijoan-Mas (2019): “Investment
  expensing and progressivity in flat-tax reforms,” SERIEs -
  Journal of the Spanish Economic Association, 10, 365–399.

Guner, N., J. Lopez-Segovia, and R. Ramos (2020): “Reforming
  the Individual Income Tax in Spain,” SERIEs - Journal of the
  Spanish Economic Association, 11, 369-406.

Heathcote J, Storesletten K, Violante G (2017) “Optimal tax
  progressivity: an analytical framework,” Quarterly Journal of
  Economics, 132, 1693–1754.

Pijoan-Mas, J. and M. González-Torrabadella (2006): “Flat Tax
   Reforms: A General Equilibrium Evaluation for Spain,”
   Investigaciones Económicas, 30, 317–351.

BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 10
FEATURES

Understanding the performance                                   institutions could realize by using different ML algorithms.
                                                                While there exists an extensive and growing literature on
of machine learning models to                                   the predictive gains of ML in credit default prediction,

predict credit default: a novel                                 usually the findings are based on different sample sizes
                                                                and different types of underlying assets, making any
approach for supervisory                                        conclusion not robust enough. Furthermore, the economic
evaluation                                                      impact of the use of ML in credit default prediction remains
                                                                understudied.
ANDRÉS ALONSO AND JOSÉ MANUEL CARBÓ
Summary of Banco de España Working Paper no. 2105
                                                                To tackle this research gap we use a unique and
We study the economic impact for financial institutions         anonymized database provided by one of the most
of using machine learning (ML) models in credit default         important Spanish banks. We first measure the relative
prediction. We do so by using a unique and anonymized           performance of the following ML models, comparing it
database from a major Spanish bank. We first measure            with a logistic regression (Logit): Lasso penalized logistic
the statistical performance in terms of predictive power,       regression, Classification And Regression Tree (CART),
both in classification and calibration, comparing models        Random Forest, XGBoost and Deep Neural Networks. To
like Logit and Lasso, with more advanced ones like              this purpose we calculate the benefits in terms of statistical
Trees (CART), Random Forest, XGBoost and Deep                   performance assessing the predictive performance under
Learning. We find that ML models outperforms traditional        different circumstances such as different sample sizes and
ones, although more complex ML algorithms do not                different amount of explanatory variables. This allows us to
necessarily predict better. We then translate this into         test whether the better statistical behavior of ML models
economic impact by estimating the savings in regulatory         comes from an information advantage (associated to the
capital that an institution could achieve when using a          access to big amounts of data) or model advantage
ML model instead of a simpler one to compute the risk-          (associated to ML as high-end technology). We find that
weighted assets following the Internal Ratings Based            ML models outperform Logit both in classification and in
(IRB) approach. Our benchmark results show that                 calibration,   particularly   XGBoost,   existing   a   model
implementing XGBoost instead of Lasso could yield               advantage that can be statistically isolated from an
savings from 12.4% to 17% in capital requirements,              information advantage. Nevertheless, most complex
depending on the type of underlying assets.                     models like Deep Learning (Neural Networks), do not
                                                                necessarily predict better.
Recent surveys show that financial institutions are
increasingly adopting Machine Learning (ML) tools in            Second, we propose a novel approach to translate this
several areas of credit risk management, like regulatory        statistical performance into actual economic impact of
capital calculation, optimizing provisions, credit-scoring or   using ML models in credit default prediction. Taking as a
monitoring outstanding loans (BoE, 2019; Fernández,             basis the Basel formulas for risk-weighted assets (RWA)
2019). While ML models usually yield better predictive          and the regulatory capital requirements in the Internal
performance, from a supervisory standpoint they also            Ratings-Based (IRB) approach, we compute the savings in
bring new challenges, like interpretability of the results,     terms of minimum capital requirements which could be
stability of the predictions and governance of the models       achieved by using more advanced algorithms, in particular
(EBA, 2020; BdF, 2020). Given the novelty and complexity        XGBoost, compared to traditional techniques like Lasso.
of some ML models, defining an adequate supervisory             We perform a step-by-step computation of the capital
model evaluation approach is not an easy task. Therefore,       requirements for both methods. Out of nearly 75,000 loans
before conducting any model risk analysis, it is essential to   in our dataset, we use around 60,000 to train the models
understand the real economic gains that financial               and make predictions of the probability of default (PD) over

                                                                       BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 11
FEATURES

Figure 1
RANKING PDS PER MODEL

 1 LASSO                                                                                 2 XGBoss

 0.30                                                                                    0.35

 0.25                                                                                    0.30

                                                                                         0.25
 0.20
                                                                                         0.20
 0.15
                                                                                         0.15
 0.10
                                                                                         0.10

 0.05                                                                                    0.05

 0.00                                                                                    0.00
        1         8         15        22         29        36         43        50              1       8          15   22   29     36      43      50

                                                                 OBSERVED DEFAULT RATE              PD ESTIMATED

the remaining 15,000 loans.1 We organise the predictions                                  17 % lower for XGBoost than for Lasso. These capital
proportionally into 50 buckets (about 300 loans in each                                   savings come from two sources. First, the difference in the
bucket), from lower to higher values of PD. The results are                               distribution of loans in buckets between models. Lasso’s
displayed in Figure 1. The discrepancy between the                                        PD distribution is particularly flat in areas with low PD
observed default rate (blue line) and the average PD (red                                 (Figure 1), accumulating a disproportionately large amount
line) is greater for Lasso than for XGBoost, as Lasso                                     of loans at around 1.5% of PD. According to the Basel
tends to both overestimate and underestimate the                                          formulas, the K function of a group of loans is mainly
fraction of default.                                                                      concave and increases with the PD of the loans, particularly
                                                                                          for low PDs. Second, the difference in the number of
In order to get the approval from a supervisor, the                                       buckets found within each model. Since XGBoost’s PD
classification into buckets must comply with two criteria: (i)                            distribution (Figure 1 right) fits the observed default better
risk    heterogeneity         between         buckets,       and      (ii)   risk         than Lasso’s, XGBoost ends up with more buckets in the
homogeneity within buckets. To meet both criteria, we                                     final rank (eight instead of six). This implies, due to the
sequentially reduce the number of buckets. Out of the 50                                  concavity of the RWA Basel function over the parameter
starting buckets, we end up with six for Lasso and eight                                  PD, a difference in capital requirements in its favour.
for XGBoost. Lasso finds fewer buckets because we are
constrained by its underlying PD distribution, which                                      Our results indicate that ML models, due to their better
presents important flat areas, undifferentiated, that do not                              statistical performance, could generate significant savings
allow further disaggregation (Figure 1 left).                                             for financial institutions in terms of regulatory capital
                                                                                          requirements compared to traditional statistical models.
Once we have our final bucket classification for Lasso and                                The magnitude of our results suggests that supervisors
XGBoost, we calculate the capital requirements (K) for                                    need to thoroughly investigate the risks associated with
each bucket, and find that the average K can be up to                                     the use of these models, both from a micro and macro-
                                                                                          prudential perspective, in order to ease the adoption of
1 Different train-test partitions do not affect the results of this section.             this innovation in the market.

BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 12
FEATURES

REFERENCES

BdF (2020). “Governance of Artificial Intelligence in Finance,”
  Fintech Innovation Hub ACPR. Banque de France. June 2020.

BoE (2019). “Machine learning in UK financial services.” Bank of
  England

Fernández, Ana (2019). ”Inteligencia artificial en los servicios
  financieros.” Boletín Económico 2/2019. Artículos Analíticos.
  Banco de España

EBA (2020). ”Report on Big Data and Advanced Analytics.”
  European Banking Authority.

                                                                   BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 13
FEATURES

Urban air pollution and sick                                                  observed in post-industrial economies. Our empirical analysis
                                                                              is based on a novel administrative dataset from the period
leaves: Evidence from social                                                  2005-2014 that links rich information on personal and

security data                                                                 occupational characteristics of Spanish workers to the
                                                                              frequency, length, and diagnosis, of sick leaves taken. We
FELIX HOLUB, LAURA HOSPIDO
AND ULRICH J. WAGNER                                                          estimate the impact of air pollution on workers’ propensity to

Summary of Banco de España Working Paper no. 2041
                                                                              call in sick, based on weekly variation in ambient
                                                                              concentrations of particulate matter (PM10) across 99 cities in
Air pollution poses a major threat to public health by                        Spain. Our baseline model is a linear regression of the share
shortening lives (Deryugina et al., 2019) and increasing acute                of sick-leave days on the share of high-pollution days and
morbidity (Schlenker and Walker, 2016). Air pollution causes                  weather variables. To control for non-random assignment of
additional damage by reducing productivity on the job (Graff                  pollution across workers, we include city-by-year, year-by-
Zivin and Neidell, 2012) and by hindering human capital                       quarter, and worker fixed-effects. Possible remaining
accumulation (Currie et al., 2009; Ebenstein et al., 2016).                   endogeneity is addressed in an instrumental-variables (IV)
Recent research has provided credible evidence that air                       regression that exploits exogenous variation in PM10 driven by
pollution damages the economy also via reductions in labor                    dust storms in Northern Africa. Under certain meteorological
supply in the context of emerging economies (Hanna and                        conditions, storms in the Sahara Desert stir up dust into high
Oliva, 2015; Aragón et al., 2017), but little is known so far                 altitudes. These dust clouds can travel very long distances
about this relationship in post-industrial societies where                    and reach European territory several times a year. The arrival
pollution levels are low and productivity is high.                            of Sahara dust occurs throughout all of Spain, and it is most
                                                                              frequently observed on the Canary Islands, due to their
Our paper provides the first causal estimates of how many                      geographical             proximity      to    the    Sahara,          where      the
work days are lost due to air pollution concentrations typically              phenomenon is popularly known as “Calima”. Because

Figure 1
TRENDS IN POLLUTION, EMPLOYMENT AND WAGES 2005-2014

1 SHARE OF HIGH-POLLUTION DAYS (a)                                            2 EMPLOYMENT AND PRODUCER WAGES (b)

                                                                                                                                                            100
                                                                                    7.5
.4
.3

                                                                                                                                                                          95
                                                                                            7
                                                                              Million workers

                                                                                                                                                             Euros of 2018
.2

                                                                                                                                                            90
                                                                             6.5
.1

                                                                                                                                                            85
0

                                                                                    6

         2006           2008             2010        2012           2014                        2006        2008          2010           2012           2014
                                     Year                                                                              Year

                               PM10 > 50 ?g/m³                                                          Affiliated workers (cities in the sample)
                               PM10 > 37.5 ?g/m³                                                        Real daily producer wage

NOTES: Figure 1.1 displays the share of worker days with PM10 concentration exceeding EU 24-hour limit of 50 mg/m3 (solid line) and the share of
worker days with concentration in excess of 75% of the limit value (dashed line). The figure is based on our sample of 99 Spanish cities with at least
40,000 inhabitants. PM10 concentrations are weighted by the number of social security affiliates in each city and year. Figure 1.2 displays the number
of workers affiliated with the General Social Security Regime on our sample of 99 Spanish cities with at least 40,000 inhabitants (solid line) and the
daily producer wage, expressed in constant 2018 Euros (dashed line).

BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 14
FEATURES

Calima events substantially increase non-anthropogenic             response of vulnerable workers (defined as those belonging
PM10    concentrations,     the   cities   affected   by    this   to the top-five percentile of the distribution of sick leaves
phenomenon are allowed to discount the measured                    taken during the pre-estimation period) is more than three
24-hour-mean concentration for this effect. Official PM10          times stronger than the response of healthy workers.
discounts constitute a valid instrument for pollution              Furthermore, our analysis reveals that job security matters, in
because they shift local PM10 concentrations in ways that          that workers with a high predicted risk of losing their job
are plausibly orthogonal to local conditions that drive sick       respond less strongly to a pollution shock than others. This
leaves, after conditioning on weather.                             finding suggests that exacerbated presenteeism could
                                                                   adversely affect future health outcomes and lower productivity
Our IV estimates imply that a 10%-reduction in high-pollution      in this tier of the labor market. These interactions of behavior
events reduces the weekly absence rate by 0.0213                   and labor market institutions have a large impact on estimates
percentage points, i.e. by 0.8% of the mean absence rate           of the external costs of air pollution that arise from changes in
(2.79%). The estimation results allow us to compute a lower        labor supply. If we adjust the above-mentioned benefits of air
bound on the benefits of improving urban air quality in Spain.      quality improvements to account for presenteeism, the
We proceed in two steps. First, we calculate the reduction in      impact estimates imply a corresponding increase in
sick days caused by a specific improvement in air quality. To       production worth €706 million. Irrespective of which number
translate this into a monetary benefit, we then multiply this       one prefers, this exercise shows that the productivity-related
number by the average daily producer wage. Under the               benefits of air quality improvements that occurred in Spain
assumption that workers are paid their marginal product, this      between 2005 and 2014 were both economically and
approximates the value of incremental production enabled by        statistically significant.
the reduction in sick days. While improving air quality yields
sizable additional benefits by reducing mortality, human            REFERENCES
suffering, and medical treatment costs, we focus on foregone
                                                                   Aragón, F., Miranda, J. J., and Oliva, P. (2017). Particulate matter
production because this component of the social costs of air         and labor supply: The role of caregiving and non-linearities.
pollution is directly linked to our outcome variable and has not     Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 86,
                                                                     295–309.
yet been quantified in previous research.
                                                                   Currie, J., Hanushek, E. A., Kahn, E. M., Neidell, M., and Rivkin,
                                                                     S. G. (2009). Does pollution increase school absences?
In particular, we evaluate the cumulative benefits of the
                                                                     Review of Economics and Statistics, 91 (4), 682–694.
actual air quality improvements that have taken place in
urban Spain over the period. The left-hand side graph of           Deryugina,T., Heutel, G., Miller, N. H., Molitor, D., and Reif, J.
                                                                     (2019). The mortality and medical costs of air pollution:
Figure 1 shows that worker exposure to PM10 concentrations           Evidence from changes in wind direction. American Economic
exceeding the EU 24-hour limit of 50 µg/m³ decreased from            Review, 109 (12), 4178–4219.
18.8% in 2005 to just under 2% in 2014. This improvement           Ebenstein, A., Lavy, V., and Roth, S. (2016). The long-run
in ambient air quality saved at least €503 million in foregone       economic consequences of high-stakes examinations:
                                                                     Evidence from transitory variation in pollution. American
production by reducing worker absence by more than 5.55
                                                                     Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 8 (4), 36–65.
million days. It is important to note that this calculation is
affected by major economic fluctuations that occurred               Graff Zivin, J. and Neidell, M. (2012). The impact of pollution on
                                                                     worker productivity. American Economic Review, 102 (7),
during the sample period, depicted in the right-hand side            3652–3673.
graph of Figure 1. We account for this by using annual
                                                                   Hanna, R. and Oliva, P. (2015). The effect of pollution on labor
values of employment and wages.                                      supply: Evidence from a natural experiment in Mexico City.
                                                                     Journal of Public Economics, 122, 68–79.
We uncover two important sources of treatment heterogeneity.       Schlenker, W. and Walker, W. R. (2016). Airports, air pollution,
One relates to preexisting medical conditions that we infer          and contemporaneous health. Review of Economic Studies,
from a worker’s sick leave record. We estimate that the health       83 (2), 768–809.

                                                                           BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 15
FEATURES

Raising Markups to Survive:                                    costs are a theoretical construct, so one needs a proxy for
                                                               them. Second, output price data at the firm level is scarce,
Small Spanish Firms during                                     if not inexistent. For this reason, we rely on recent

the Great Recession                                            methodological                        advances     in   production    function
                                                               estimation (e.g. De Loecker and Warzynski, 2012),
PILAR GARCÍA-PEREA, AITOR LACUESTA
AND PAU ROLDAN-BLANCO                                          measuring firm-level markups as the ratio of a variable

Summary of Banco de España Working Paper no. 2033
                                                               input’s elasticity to output on that input’s share of total
                                                               sales. The Banco de España data proves to be an excellent
Over the past few decades, profit rates and various other      resource because not only is it highly representative of the
measures of market concentration have been on the rise in      Spanish economy (containing a large amount of firms and
the United States (De Loecker et al, 2020). These patterns     a very high percentage of aggregate value added), but it
of the data have attracted much attention recently in both     also contains very disaggregated information on the
academic as well as policy circles for their impact on         structure of costs, allowing us to disentangle variable
productivity dynamics, the composition of industries and       inputs (e.g. materials and labor expenses from workers
ultimately consumer welfare. The evidence points to            with fixed-term contracts) from fixed inputs (e.g. other
rapidly growing and highly productive firms as the drivers     operating expenses and labor expenses from open-
of this phenomenon, with these firms leading the increase      ended contracts with large firing costs). It is this latter
in markups and the decline in the labor share (Autor et al.    aspect which allows us to make the main point of the
2017 and 2020). However, these trends seem to be less          paper: the evolution of firm-level markups in Spain can be
pronounced in Europe, and be driven by factors seemingly       explained by firms’ efforts to rebalance their cost structure
unrelated to the dynamics of superstar companies.              between variable and fixed inputs, a behavioral response
                                                               to the cycle, rather than by reasons of a more structural
In this article, we exploit rich balance-sheet data from the   nature. Therefore, in the case of Spain, the evolution of
Banco de España to document the behavior of markups            markups may not reflect aggregate changes in the
at the aggregate level in Spain, and perform various           competitive structure of markets, but rather an idiosyncratic
decompositions to help us identify the main drivers            response of firms to economic conditions.
behind their evolution over the period 2004-2017. Our
main finding is that, contrary to the United States, markup    The figure above shows the evolution of the sales-
dynamics were primarily led by small and unproductive          weighted average markup (measured relative to materials)
firms. Particularly in response to the Great Recession of      over the period 2004-2017. The average markup has been
2008, these firms were unable to increase their productive
efficiency when their average costs rose due to a sharp
                                                               Figure 1
increase in the fixed part of their production costs, and      SALES-WEIGHTED AVERAGE MARKUP (2004 = 1)
this translated into higher price markups. This behavioral
                                                                                   1.14
response, related to the composition of the structure of
                                                                                   1.12
costs, seems to indicate that these firms, when faced
                                                                                   1.10
with economic hardship, may have preferred to increase
                                                               Normalized Markup

                                                                                   1.08
their markups in an attempt to survive in their sector even
                                                                                   1.06
if this may have come at the expense of losing some
                                                                                   1.04
market share in the process.
                                                                                   1.02

                                                                                   1.00
Measuring price markups (defined as the ratio of a firm’s
                                                                                   0.98
                                                                                       2004   2006     2008     2010   2012   2014     2016
final output price to the marginal cost of producing it) is
                                                                                                                                          Year
challenging because of at least two reasons. First, marginal

BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 16
FEATURES

normalized to one in 2004. We observe that markups are                                                    in some specific sectors after 2009, most notably in
countercyclical, rising by about 13ppt between 2004 and                                                   Construction, Supplies and Real Estate.
2009, and declining slightly thereafter. The behavior in
the first part of the sample is roughly common across                                                     Most importantly, we find that the behavior of average
most sectors of activity, albeit markups continued to rise                                                markups is driven by small and unproductive firms. First,

Figure 2
SALES-WEIGHTED AND UNWEIGHTED AVERAGE INPUT COSTS SHARES, RELATIVE TO FIRM SALES, BY TYPE OF INPUT

1 MATERIALS/SALES                                                                                        2 GENERAL COSTS/SALES

0.65                                                                                                     0.28

                                                                                                         0.26
0.60
                                                                                                         0.24

0.55                                                                                                     0.22

                                                                                                         0.20
0.50
                                                                                                         0.18

                                                                                                         0.16
0.45
                                                                                                         0.14
0.40                                                                                                     0.12
       2004

              2005

                     2006

                            2007

                                   2008

                                          2009

                                                 2010

                                                        2011

                                                               2012

                                                                      2013

                                                                             2014

                                                                                    2015

                                                                                           2016

                                                                                                  2017

                                                                                                                 2004

                                                                                                                          2005

                                                                                                                                  2006

                                                                                                                                          2007

                                                                                                                                                  2008

                                                                                                                                                          2009

                                                                                                                                                                  2010

                                                                                                                                                                          2011

                                                                                                                                                                                  2012

                                                                                                                                                                                         2013

                                                                                                                                                                                                2014

                                                                                                                                                                                                       2015

                                                                                                                                                                                                              2016

                                                                                                                                                                                                                     2017
3 LABOUR COSTS/SALES                                                                                     4 TEMP LABOUR COSTS/SALES

0.40                                                                                                     0.09

                                                                                                         0.08
0.35
                                                                                                         0.07
0.30
                                                                                                         0.06

0.25                                                                                                     0.05

                                                                                                         0.04
0.20
                                                                                                         0.03

0.15                                                                                                     0.02
       2004

              2005

                     2006

                            2007

                                   2008

                                          2009

                                                 2010

                                                        2011

                                                               2012

                                                                      2013

                                                                             2014

                                                                                    2015

                                                                                           2016

                                                                                                  2017

                                                                                                                 2004

                                                                                                                          2005

                                                                                                                                  2006

                                                                                                                                          2007

                                                                                                                                                  2008

                                                                                                                                                          2009

                                                                                                                                                                  2010

                                                                                                                                                                          2011

                                                                                                                                                                                  2012

                                                                                                                                                                                         2013

                                                                                                                                                                                                2014

                                                                                                                                                                                                       2015

                                                                                                                                                                                                              2016

                                                                                                                                                                                                                     2017

5 PERM LABOUR COSTS/SALES                                                                                6 FINANCIAL EXPENSES/SALES

0.35                                                                                                     0.030

0.30                                                                                                     0.025

0.25                                                                                                     0,020

0.20                                                                                                     0.015

0.15                                                                                                     0.010

0.10                                                                                                     0.005
       2004

              2005

                     2006

                            2007

                                   2008

                                          2009

                                                 2010

                                                        2011

                                                               2012

                                                                      2013

                                                                             2014

                                                                                    2015

                                                                                           2016

                                                                                                  2017

                                                                                                                   2004

                                                                                                                           2005

                                                                                                                                   2006

                                                                                                                                           2007

                                                                                                                                                   2008

                                                                                                                                                           2009

                                                                                                                                                                   2010

                                                                                                                                                                           2011

                                                                                                                                                                                  2012

                                                                                                                                                                                         2013

                                                                                                                                                                                                2014

                                                                                                                                                                                                       2015

                                                                                                                                                                                                              2016

                                                                                                                                                                                                                     2017

                                                                                       SALES-WEIGHTED               UNWEIGHTED

                                                                                                                        BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 17
FEATURES

most of the increase during the Great Recession is due to          However, we find that most of the evolution of the sales-
the firms at the very top of the markup distribution, who          weighted markup is explained by changes in the composition
happen to be firms with relatively low levels of productivity      of industries among surviving firms, as well as by changes in
and low market shares. Second, the firms that increase their       the markups of these firms themselves, rather than by the
markup the most (in relative terms) during this period were        extensive margin of entry and exit of firms.
precisely this group of small and unproductive companies.
                                                                   All in all, our study demonstrates that understanding the
To understand what is behind this phenomenon, we next              structure of firm’s balance sheets is key to understand
turn to the behavior of different variable and fixed costs over    the behavior of markups in Spain. Rather than reflecting
this period. In the figure, the black line is the sales-weighted   change in market power per se, the rise in markups during
share of each input relative to firm turnover (sales), while the   the Great Recession seems to have been driven by a
red line is an unweighted average. By construction, when           reshuffling of cost expenditures away from variable and into
the sales-weighted average is above the unweighted                 fixed inputs. This was particularly the case among small and
average, smaller firms (in terms of sales) have a lower input      unproductive firms, who may have behaved in this manner
share of sales. As seen in the figure, there exist sizable         in order to soften the blow of the shock onto their profits,
differences in the terms of the cost structure of firms by firm    and thereby increase their chances of survival.
size, especially regarding the contribution of materials and
labor expenses. First, larger firms devote a larger share of       REFERENCES
their sales to paying for material inputs (the variable input
                                                                   Autor, D., D. Dorn, L. F. Katz, C. Patterson and J. V. Reenen
relative to which our markup estimates are computed). In             2017). Concentrating on the fall of the labor share. American
response to the Great Recession, all firms decreased the             Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 107 (5), 180 – 185.
share of their sales that pays for material expenses, but this     — (2020). The fall of the labor share and the rise of superstar
ratio decreased disproportionally more for smaller firms,           firms. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 135, 645 – 709.
explaining the stronger response in markups for these              De Loecker, J., J. Eeckhout and G. Unger (2020). The rise of
firms. This phenomenon is reversed for inputs with higher            market power and the macroeconomic implications. Quarterly
adjustment costs, such as general costs and labor                    Journal of Economics, 135 (2), 561 – 644.

expenses related to permanent workers on open-ended                — and F. Warzynski (2012). Markups and firm-level export
contracts with high firing costs. In both cases, the share of       status. American Economic Review, 102 (6), 2437 – 2471.

sales paying for these fixed inputs increased, indicating
that in response to the adverse economic shock,
continuing firms shifted their resources away from variable
costs into fixed ones, perhaps in an attempt to soften the
adverse effects of the shock on their economic profits and
their chances at survival.

To complement this analysis, we conclude on the evolution
of firm demographics and measures of market concentration
during this period. We show that, in spite of the
aforementioned behavioral responses at the firm level, we
do observe a decline in firm entry (from about 11% to about
7% only in the period 2007-2009) and a rise in firm exit (from
about 4% to 8% in the same period), as well as a mild
increase in the share of industry sales captured by the ten
largest firms (on average, from 47% in 2008 to 56% in 2017).

BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 18
PUBLICATIONS

Recent working papers                      WHO TRULY BEARS (BANK) TAXES?
                                           EVIDENCE FROM ONLY SHIFTING
Link to Working Papers page                STATUTORY INCIDENCE
                                           GABRIEL JIMÉNEZ, DAVID MARTÍNEZ-MIERA AND
SPILLOVER EFFECTS IN INTERNATIONAL         JOSÉ-LUIS PEYDRÓ
BUSINESS CYCLES                            Working paper no. 2040
MÁXIMO CAMACHO, MATÍAS PACCE AND GABRIEL
PÉREZ-QUIRÓS
Working Paper no. 2034                     URBAN AIR POLLUTION AND SICK LEAVES:
                                           EVIDENCE FROM SOCIAL SECURITY DATA
                                           FELIX HOLUB, LAURA HOSPIDO AND ULRICH J
APPLICATION OF TEXT MINING TO THE          WAGNER
ANALYSIS OF CLIMATE-RELATED                Working paper no. 2041
DISCLOSURES
ÁNGEL IVÁN MORENO AND TERESA CAMINERO
Working paper no. 2035
                                           THE NARRATIVE ABOUT THE ECONOMY AS
                                           A SHADOW FORECAST: AN ANALYSIS USING
                                           BANCO DE ESPAÑA QUARTERLY REPORT
WAGE DETERMINATION AND THE BITE OF         NÉLIDA DÍAZ SOBRINO, CORINNA GHIRELLI, SAMUEL
COLLECTIVE CONTRACTS IN ITALY AND          HURTADO, JAVIER J. PÉREZ AND ALBERTO URTASUN
SPAIN: EVIDENCE FROM THE METAL             Working paper no. 2042
WORKING INDUSTRY
EFFROSYNI ADAMOPOULOU AND ERNESTO
VILLANUEVA                                 REFORMING THE INDIVIDUAL INCOME TAX
Working paper no. 2036
                                           IN SPAIN
                                           NEZIH GUNER, JAVIER LÓPEZ-SEGOVIA AND
                                           ROBERTO RAMOS
SCREENING AND LOAN ORIGINATION TIME:       Working paper no. 2043
LENDING STANDARDS, LOAN DEFAULTS
AND BANK FAILURES
MIKEL BEDAYO, GABRIEL JIMÉNEZ, JOSÉ-LUIS   OPTIMAL PROGRESSIVITY OF PERSONAL
PEYDRÓ AND RAQUEL VEGAS                    INCOME TAX: A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM
Working paper no. 2037
                                           EVALUATION FOR SPAIN
                                           DARÍO SERRANO-PUENTE
                                           Working paper no. 2101
WHY COGNITIVE TEST SCORES OF SPANISH
ADULTS ARE SO LOW? THE ROLE OF
SCHOOLING AND SOCIOECONOMIC                ECONOMIC UNCERTAINTY AND DIVISIVE
BACKGROUND                                 POLITICS: EVIDENCE FROM THE
BRINDUSA ANGHEL, PILAR CUADRADO AND        DOS ESPAÑAS
FEDERICO TAGLIATI                          SANDRA GARCÍA-URIBE, HANNES MUELLER
Working paper no. 2038                     AND CARLOS SANZ
                                           Working paper no. 2102

THE SHORT- AND LONG-RUN EMPLOYMENT
IMPACT OF COVID-19 THROUGH THE             EMU DEEPENING AND SOVEREIGN DEBT
EFFECTS OF REAL AND FINANCIAL              SPREADS: USING POLITICAL SPACE TO
SHOCKS ON NEW FIRMS                        ACHIEVE POLICY SPACE
CHRISTOPH ALBERT, ANDREA CAGGESE AND       IVÁN KATARYNIUK, VÍCTOR MORA-BAJÉN AND
BEATRIZ GONZÁLEZ                           JAVIER J. PÉREZ
Working paper no. 2039                     Working paper no. 2103

                                                  BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 19
PUBLICATIONS

ARE WE MOVING TOWARDS AN ENERGY-                      TIME VARIATION IN LIFECYCLE CONSUMPTION
EFFICIENT LOW-CARBON ECONOMY?                         AND INCOME
AN INPUT-OUTPUT LMDI DECOMPOSITION                    YUNUS AKSOY, HENRIQUE S. BASSO AND CAROLYN
OF CO2 EMISSIONS FOR SPAIN AND THE EU28               ST AUBYN
DARÍO SERRANO-PUENTE                                  Working paper no. 2111
Working paper no. 2104

                                                      PRICE SETTING IN CHILE: MICRO EVIDENCE
UNDERSTANDING THE PERFORMANCE OF                      FROM CONSUMER ON-LINE PRICES DURING
MACHINE LEARNING MODELS TO PREDICT                    THE SOCIAL OUTBREAK AND COVID-19
CREDIT DEFAULT: A NOVEL APPROACH FOR                  JENNIFER PEÑA AND ELVIRA PRADES
SUPERVISORY EVALUATION                                Working paper no. 2112
ANDRÉS ALONSO AND JOSÉ MANUEL CARBÓ
Working paper no. 2105
                                                      DOES THE ADDED WORKER EFFECT MATTER?
                                                      NEZIH GUNER, YULIYA A. KULIKOVA AND ARNAU
MARKET POLARIZATION AND THE PHILLIPS                  VALLADARES-ESTEBAN
CURVE                                                 Working paper no. 2113
JAVIER ANDRÉS, ÓSCAR ARCE AND PABLO
BURRIEL
Working paper no. 2106
                                                      UNEQUAL TRADE, UNEQUAL GAINS: THE
                                                      HETEROGENEOUS IMPACT OF MERCOSUR
                                                      RODOLFO G. CAMPOS AND JACOPO TIMINI
NEW DIMENSIONS OF REGULATORY                          Working paper no. 2114
COMPLEXITY AND THEIR ECONOMIC COST.
AN ANALYSIS USING TEXT MINING
JUAN DE LUCIO AND JUAN S. MORA-SANGUINETTI
Working paper no. 2107
                                                      Recent occasional papers
                                                      Link to Occasional Papers page

ENDOGENOUS TIME VARIATION IN VECTOR                   TENDENCIAS RECIENTES DE LA POBLACIÓN EN
AUTOREGRESSIONS                                       LAS ÁERAS RURALES Y URBANAS DE ESPAÑA
DANILO LEIVA-LEON AND LUIS UZEDA                      EDUARDO GUTIÉRREZ, ENRIQUE MORAL-BENITO
Working paper no. 2108                                AND ROBERTO RAMOS
                                                      Occasional Paper no. 2027

WEATHER, MOBILITY AND THE EVOLUTION
OF THE COVID-19 PANDEMIC                              THE EFFECTS OF CHANGES IN THE
CORINNA GHIRELLI, ANDREA GONZÁLEZ, JOSÉ LUIS          COMPOSITION OF EMPLOYMENT ON EURO
HERRERA AND SAMUEL HURTADO                            AREA WAGE GROWTH: PANEL DATA ANALYSIS
Working paper no. 2109                                ÁNGEL LUIS GÓMEZ
                                                      Occasional Paper no. 2028

FED COMMUNICATION ON FINANCIAL
STABILITY CONCERNS AND MONETARY                       ANALYSIS OF INSOLVENCY PROCEEDINGS
POLICY DECISIONS: REVELATIONS                         IN SPAIN AGAINST THE BACKDROP OF THE
FROM SPEECHES                                         COVID-19 CRISIS: INSOLVENCY PROCEEDINGS,
KLODIANA ISTREFI, FLORENS ODENDAHL                    PRE-INSOLVENCY ARRANGEMENTS AND
AND GIULIA SESTIERI                                   THE INSOLVENCY MORATORIUM
Working paper no. 2110                                MIGUEL GARCÍA-POSADA GÓMEZ
                                                      Occasional Paper no. 2029

BANCO DE ESPAÑA | RESEARCH UPDATE, SPRING 2021 | 20
You can also read