Why consumers wear sports gear - Elgaronline

Page created by Jonathan French
 
CONTINUE READING
1.       Why consumers wear sports gear
               “Sport has the power to change the world. It has the power to inspire.”
               This quote is significant in that it is not from a noted athlete, sports owner,
               league commissioner, or city council person vying for the public to pay for
               a new sports stadium. It is from Nelson Mandela – the acclaimed South
               African advocate of human rights and statesman, who, seemingly, would
               have had a much bigger view of the world than sports. Nonetheless, he
               made this statement in the context of South Africa hosting the 1995 Rugby
               World Cup and its importance to his country. The same idea is expressed
               more succinctly by the tag line, “sports matters,” for ESPN’s E:60 program,
               which highlights inspirational and moving sports stories.
                  Yet, there is a deep irony embedded in these references to the power of
               sports. Its influence does not readily stand out using common measures of
               economic performance. Yes, there are several billions of dollars in revenue
               generated by the National Football League (NFL), Major League Baseball
               (MLB), the National Basketball Association, and the National Hockey
               League (NHL) along with college sports and other pro sports. Yet, in
               comparing revenues generated by all sports leagues and college sports pro-
               grams in the US to other kinds of businesses, the sports industry appears
               to be of minor importance. Figure 1.1 presents an example of this kind of
               comparison, showing revenue for the top professional sports leagues in the
               US along with the top 125 schools from the National Collegiate Athletic
               Association (NCAA) and three of the four top retailers. The sports
               revenue ranges from $13 billion per year for the NFL down to $3.7 billion
               for the NHL with a sum of about $39 billion. In contrast, the revenue for
               CVS, Costco, and Kroger all exceed $100 billion per year and amount to
               nearly $400 billion, and this excludes the nation’s top retailer – WalMart.
               With it included, the top four retailers account for nearly $900 billion per
               year in sales.
                  Even with the revenue from every sporting league lumped together with
               these from the top five sports producers, it amounts to less than half of
               a single large retailer like Costco. Going beyond retailers, the sum of the
               revenues of the top five US-based companies exceeds $1.2 trillion dollars.
               The next five add up to nearly $700 billion. The revenue from these top five
               sports producers roughly equals that of individual companies like Merck

                                                      1
                                                               Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                    Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                             via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 1                                                                      12/07/2018 11:13
2                                   Sports economics uncut

                  160                                                          CVS

                  140
                                                                                         Costco
                  120                                                                              Kroger

                  100

                   80

                   60

                   40

                   20     NFL       MLB        NCAA       NBA       NHL
                      0
                              1       2           3          4        5          6          7         8

                  Note: The sports revenue data are from various sources. The retailer figures are most
                  recent reports from Yahoo Finance.

                  Figure 1.1      Comparing revenues of top US sports and selected retailers

                  or Best Buy. This is not trivial, but it is not a major industry. Adding in the
                  $13 billion per year generated by the world’s top five soccer leagues –
                  Premier League, German Bundesliga, Spanish La Liga, Italian Serie A,
                  and French Ligue 1 – does not change the story by much.
                     Going beyond direct revenues and considering indirect, tangible impacts
                  on communities offers a similar story. Most detailed and careful studies
                  of the impact of sporting events or sports stadiums on local economic
                  activity or tax revenues indicate that these impacts are relatively small and
                  rarely justify subsidies directed toward them. These results are not really
                  surprising given the modest size of the revenue figures.1
                     Yet, there is another side to the ironic twist about the importance of
                  sports. It attracts an enormous amount of attention among consumers – way
                  of out of line with the revenue that it produces. Longtime sports economist
                  Gerald Scully put it this way, “Sports, in general, and professional sports, in
                  particular, play a larger than life role in the United States.” When the rest
                  of the world is pulled in, the point is even clearer. Over one billion people
                  watched the 2014 FIFA World Cup final between Germany and Argentina
                  with an estimated 12 million Germans watching in public spaces.
                     Figure 1.2 demonstrates one of the more novel ways in which this
                  attention has been measured and illustrates how far the influence of
                  ­

                                                                     Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                          Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                                   via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 2                                                                                 12/07/2018 11:13
Why consumers wear sports gear	­3

                                      28,000
                                                                                            Halftime Match Ends
                                      24,000
              Cubic Meters per Hour

                                      20,000

                                      16,000

                                      12,000

                                       8000                                Match Begins

                                       4000
                                               16   17    18     19      20     21     22     23     24      25     26
                                                                               TIME

               Note: Data are from http://m.fifa.com/worldcup/news/y=2014/m=6/news=tv
               viewingbreaks-records-in-first-fifa-world-cup-matches-2378078.html and http://www
               iptvnews. com/2014/07/world-cup-final-breaks-records-worldwide-for-tv-broadcasters/.

               Figure 1.2 Berlin water usage during 2014 World Cup Final, Germany v
                           Brazil

               major sport events like the World Cup final can extend into everyday life.
               It displays Berlin water usage data in the hours during and surrounding
               Germany’s 2014 World Cup match with Brazil. Usage dropped by 60
               percent during the first half, jumped above the pre-game baseline during
               halftime, fell again by 60 percent during the second half, and then recov-
               ered briefly after the match before falling after midnight. Short of war, it
               is hard to imagine other events that could bring about this kind of impact.
                  Similarly, the Olympic Games generate worldwide attention. Figure 1.3
               illustrates this by showing the number of countries to which the summer
               Olympic games have been telecast since 1956. As television was emerging
               in the 1950s, coverage was sparse. Now the games beam to over 200 coun-
               tries. For the Beijing and London Olympics, there were about 3.5 billion
               viewers. At modest viewing amounts such as 100 minutes, these figures
               translate into roughly 40 billion viewer hours devoted to the games. If the
               value of time for these viewers were valued at $10 per hour, then this leisure
               time spent watching the game amounts to $400 billion.
                  The degree of media attention and time devoted to sports by consumers
               swamps that of industries and companies with much higher revenues.
               WalMart may generate $500 billion per year in revenue, but few people

                                                                                    Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                                         Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                                                  via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 3                                                                                              12/07/2018 11:13
4                                 Sports economics uncut

                  240

                  200

                  160

                  120

                   80

                   40

                      0
                          56   60   64    68   72   76   80   84   88   92   96   00   04   08   12   16

                  Note: Data are from Olympic Marketing Fact File, 2015.

                  Figure 1.3    Countries televising Summer Olympic Games

                  walk around wearing hats or shirts emblazoned with the companies name
                  or logo. Stanford University scientists have won over 20 Nobel Prizes and
                  Northwestern University scientists have many notable achievements, yet
                  trips to the Rose Bowl by their football teams create much more public
                  awareness. There are no trading cards for executives at ExxonMobil or
                  Google as there are for high profile athletes. Consumers do not continue
                  talking about their enjoyment of a gallon of gasoline for days or weeks
                  after purchase like they will “Music City Miracle.” There are no fantasy
                  leagues for cough syrup sales.
                     These are all visible indications of the large, intangible value of sports,
                  and they appear in other ways that are even more obvious. Every major
                  newspaper in the country has a sports section – even the Wall Street
                  Journal now has a page devoted to sports. Neither Costco nor the entire
                  discount superstore industry or very large industries claim stand-alone
                  sections devoted to them. Sports have spawned dedicated television chan-
                  nels. ESPN started in 1979 as the first 24-hour, seven-day-a-week television
                  coverage of sporting events and news. Now, there are multiple ESPN
                  channels along with one or more sports-dedicated channels for NBC, CBS,
                  and Fox along with stand-alone single sport channels such as the NFL
                  Network, MLB network, NHL, the Golf Channel, the Tennis Channel,
                  and others. Fans still converse about Michael Jordan’s shot against

                                                                    Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                         Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                                  via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 4                                                                                12/07/2018 11:13
Why consumers wear sports gear	­5

               Phoenix in the NBA finals 20 years later, the “immaculate reception” from
               the 1972 Pittsburgh-Oakland game or the Dodgers move from Brooklyn to
               Los Angeles 60 years after the fact.
                  Few sports, if any, illustrate the depth of feelings of fans as international
               football (soccer). The level of commitment and affection extends well
               beyond attending or viewing matches and into more visceral and demon-
               strative displays.
                  For instance, in the days leading up to the match between Russia and
               England in the 2016 European Championships, their fans clashed in
               Marseille, France. These incidents included verbal and physical combat
               with several arrests. In this case, the Russian fans were reported to
               be the instigators, but in many infamous incidents in the past in both
               international and domestic contests, English fans played the role of soccer
               hooligans. Because of past incidents, home and visiting fans in Premier
               League matches are often separated by physical barriers during games and
               police form human barriers to separate fans as they exit stadiums.
                  Placing monetary figures on these intangible values is not easy. Typically,
               economists have related housing values to characteristics and amenities
               in a community to associate a dollar value for these characteristics and
               amenities of a location such as proximity to the ocean or the amount of
               pollutants in the air.2 These housing price-based methods are problematic
               for sports teams because of sample issues and other obstacles. While there
               are cities with and without NFL teams, for example, the ones without
               are almost all on the lower end of metropolitan area population and do
               not give close comparisons for metro areas of five or 10 million people.
               Los Angeles went two decades without an NFL team; there has always
               been a lingering expectation of the return of a team, which confounds the
               interpretation of its housing values as reflecting a city with no NFL team.
                  In spite of the lack of hard estimates, it is not a stretch to say that the
               value of time spent reading, discussing, and reliving sports is large. The
               existence and size of fantasy sports provides an emphatic illustration as
               well as allowing for back-of-the envelope calculations of time and its value
               in this niche. Taking estimates of the amount of time spent on fantasy
               sports and multiplying it by a frequently used measure of the value of
               time – the average wage rate – yields a figure around $70 billion dollars.
               These values are derivative from the athletic contests. Yet, the time spent
               on fantasy sports captures only a small part of the overall time spent by
               fans reading about, discussing, or thinking about sports. Again, using the
               average wage rate as a gauge of the value of time, for every one million
               NFL fans of each team who average one hour per week for the entire year
               thinking about or discussing the team beyond time spent watching actual
               telecasts, the value is near $40 billion.

                                                                Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                     Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                              via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 5                                                                       12/07/2018 11:13
6                            Sports economics uncut

                     Most of this value goes uncaptured by teams. Traces of it show up in
                  here and there as teams or advertisers attempt to turn fan value into a
                  monetized revenue stream. One such example is in the merchandising rev-
                  enues for teams, which range from $12 to $14 billion per year since 2009 for
                  North American sports teams.3 Of course, sports teams receive only a por-
                  tion of these billions paid out to them as royalties from licenses granted.
                  The point is not that teams are capturing all of the intangible value from
                  consumers through this mechanism, but that the very existence of these
                  kinds of sales highlights the existence of these underlying intangible values.
                  There are fans out there who are willing to express some of the value that
                  they get from watching the New England Patriots by wearing a Tom Brady
                  jersey. In addition to team merchandise, individual players in collaboration
                  with sellers of various products are also able to cash in. Michael Jordan
                  receives $60 million per year from his longstanding Nike shoe deal. LeBron
                  James and Kevin Durant both have deals in the region of $30 million per
                  year. At his performance and earning peak, Tiger Wood’s income from his
                  Nike endorsement hovered around $90 million per year.

                  DURABILITY OF SPORTS CONSUMPTION

                  What gives sports this unusual power to grab attention in spite of relatively
                  modest revenues? A suggestion for a starting point into an answer lies in
                  the fact that along with athletes, celebrities from film and television also
                  share in lucrative endorsements. George Clooney appears in Nespresso ads,
                  Charlize Theron for Dior, and Beyonce for Pepsi with each receiving about
                  $5 million per year. It is easy to forget that sports are part of the larger
                  entertainment industry. Like sports, other forms of entertainment create
                  unusual connections to the public. Seemingly, when Meryl Streep referred
                  contemptuously to people who would rather watch a football game than a
                  film during her speech at the 2017 Golden Globe Awards, she overlooked
                  the parallels between sports and its cousins in other areas of entertainment.
                     Not only is sport like film or theater in creating drama and imitating
                  aspects of life, but like these other forms of entertainment, consumers
                  recall and discuss great movies long after the initial viewing. Highly suc-
                  cessful adventure or fantasy films like the Star Wars or Harry Potter series
                  spawn a variety of merchandise sales, a method of monetizing some of the
                  intangible value created among consumers. Outside of entertainment, such
                  merchandising revenues are rare.
                     With entertainment, what are considered consumption items ­actually
                  possess a durable value similar to physical assets such as houses or
                  automobiles. The value of a gallon of gas disappears as soon as the engine

                                                               Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                    Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                             via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 6                                                                        12/07/2018 11:13
Why consumers wear sports gear	­7

               uses the last drop, but the value of the game or movie lives on past the
               narrow time span of the event itself. Beyond commercial entertainment,
               other forms of enjoyment and recreation like romantic evenings, family
               vacations, or hiking and fishing trips also have this quality. Yet, the degree
               of this kind of post-performance enjoyment and conversation in sports
               entertainment far outstrips most of these others, particularly other forms
               of entertainment. People relive games and seasons 50 years on. Green Bay
               Packer fans alive during the famous 1967 “Ice Bowl” NFL Championship
               game against Dallas can envision Bart Starr crossing the goal line as if it
               happened recently. The phrase “Miracle on Ice” – team USA’s unlikely
               defeat of the Soviet Union in the 1980 Olympics hockey tournament –
               immediately conjures up the memory to millions of individuals.
                  Observing this long-lasting consumption quality of sports raises a ques-
               tion on the next level. Why does entertainment, and sports entertainment
               in particular, possess this durable quality? This question digs into the
               psychology of consumers. At its root, sports is life, or, at least, life lived out
               on a stage. It mirrors life with its celebrations, disappointments, tensions,
               tradeoffs, furious activity, tedium, and subtleties. In this way, it taps into
               and appeals to emotions and deep-seated psychological underpinnings
               across a wide array of individuals, who emotionally invest in sports in the
               same way that they do in great movies or plays and, possibly, more so. The
               cooking pot from Costco or the gasoline from the convenience store does
               not create a similar emotional or deep-seated psychological attachment.
                  Recognizing sports as life is not a novel insight. Many times, commenta-
               tors have noted that “baseball is life.” This close association between base-
               ball and everyday life has spawned over 100 baseball-related films. Because
               baseball first secured the position of “America’s pastime,” it has been cited
               most often in regard to mirroring life, but the point can be expanded to all
               of sports. Soccer has been called the “theater of dreams.”
                  In this role, sports becomes more than mere entertainment. Because of
               sports’ deeply embedded and durable connection with society, it serves
               as an important institutional and cultural mechanism for social change.
               Jackie Robinson did far more than simply reflect societal changes – he
               shaped them. Similarly, the players of Texas Western forged new roads in
               winning the 1966 NCAA championship with an all-black starting lineup,
               as documented in the film Glory Road.

               MORE THAN CONSUMERS

               Most of this book is devoted to examining the overlap between sporting
               issues and other areas of life. In many ways sports consumers are like any

                                                                Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                     Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                              via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 7                                                                         12/07/2018 11:13
8                            Sports economics uncut

                  other consumers. They express their preferences with their expenditures,
                  and these expenditures are limited by their incomes. When examined in
                  more detail, however, the preferences and behavior of sports consumers
                  exhibit features that are not seen in most other settings. They have a pas-
                  sion for the product that rarely, if ever, emerges in relation to other goods
                  or services. Few fights or shouting matches break out between the buyers
                  of Grape Nuts and the buyers of Cheerios. Sports fans will travel far and
                  wide to follow their favorite team. They will endure rain and snow to sit
                  through games or queue for tickets. They will celebrate championships in
                  the streets and lament losses for years. Sixty years after the Dodgers left
                  Brooklyn, there are people who talk about it with sadness and conviction.
                  Over 30 years after his death, some Alabama fans still wear hounds tooth
                  hats in either homage to Bear Bryant or as a symbol of his enduring legacy
                  in the program.
                     In England and other places in Europe, soccer is like a tribal identity
                  even beyond what is seen among American sports fans. The teams have
                  been around for a long time and fans have close geographic attachment
                  to a team – in many cases, the proximity is, literally, on a neighborhood
                  level. Among Premier League teams, Tottenham Hotspur and Arsenal
                  divide up consumers in north London with stadiums only about four
                  miles apart. Chelsea draws from west London and West Ham from the
                  east side. Alongside these clubs, even smaller neighborhood affiliations
                  around London exist for clubs that have hopped in and out of the Premier
                  League including Charlton, Crystal Palace, Fulham, Queens Park Rangers,
                  Watford, and others. Manchester hosts two of the most financially success-
                  ful clubs in the world in Manchester United and Manchester City, but a
                  bevy of other clubs and their fans are scattered in and near the metro area.
                  Birmingham splits supporters among Birmingham City, Aston Villa, and
                  West Bromwich Albion. Liverpool is divided between Liverpool FC and
                  Everton with their stadiums separated by less than a mile. These clubs are
                  among the more recognizable, but England is dotted with teams that divide
                  cities and neighborhoods. Nottingham holds Nottingham Forest as well as
                  Notts County. Bristol contains Bristol City and Bristol Rovers.
                     In the framework and terminology of economics, the identification of
                  local residents with these teams and the tribalism means that the consum-
                  ers are not merely consumers. These fans become members of a club. As
                  club members, they are part consumers of team services but are also part
                  producers. The club membership has evolved into formal and explicit
                  relationships such as when fans purchase “memberships” into Premier
                  League teams or college fans purchase membership in some level of a
                  booster club or organization by making donations. The language of fans
                  also gives explicit expression to these ties that bind them to the club. They

                                                               Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                    Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                             via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 8                                                                       12/07/2018 11:13
Why consumers wear sports gear	­9

               refer to “we” rather than “them” when discussing team performance and
               outcomes.
                  The club-like features between sporting teams and fans run much
               deeper than these explicit mechanisms and indications. There is a branch
               of economics about clubs.4 At its root, the economics of clubs focuses on
               shared aspects of a good or service, whether the shared elements arise in the
               production or consumption of the good. Concepts drawn from club eco-
               nomics have been applied to a diverse set of settings, ranging from activities
               of religious groups to the workings of the European Union. In the case of
               sports, the fans share both in consumption and production. As consumers
               they attend games in person or watch the game as a shared experience.
               However, while attending or watching, fans yell and scream not merely to
               get something out of the game, but to put something in. Their efforts impact
               both the team as well as the experience of other fans. Even the mere pres-
               ence of other fans at the game produces a more enjoyable experience than
               watching at home or sitting in a stadium that is nearly empty. The shared
               experiences revolving around the team go beyond the time spent watching
               games. Conversations among fans about past or future performances of the
               team become part of the consumer-producer experience.
                  The club aspect to sport spawns fan affiliation and loyalty that extends
               far beyond what is typically seen for goods and services. Not all English
               citizens care about soccer and not all residents of Alabama follow Crimson
               Tide football. For many who do care, their interest far surpasses a recrea-
               tional diversion. It becomes a deep-seated, common cultural experience,
               more akin to highly committed religious or political association and fervor
               than the purchase of an item from the grocery store or even other forms of
               entertainment such as a night out at the movies. Moods for the day or week
               can be determined by the latest performance of the favored team.
                  At its extreme among diehard fans, team loyalty becomes a defining
               characteristic of people’s lives and connections. Phrases like “Red Sox
               Nation,” “Big Blue Nation,” “Leeds Forever,” and similar are indicative
               of the strength of these bonds. The reasons that fan affiliation and club
               loyalty develop to a stronger extent in some places than others seems tied
               to geographic connectedness. Where a large percentage of fans live near
               the team their entire lives, a stable, long-run connection between teams and
               fans develops. After all, for the tribalism to develop, fans need to be in close
               contact with each other and near enough the team to receive regular media
               coverage. Another factor has been the competition from other sporting
               and recreational outlets.
                  Advances in technology and changes in television programming are
               reducing the need for geographic proximity among fans for them to build
               strong connections to the team and between each other. College and

                                                                Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                     Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                              via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 9                                                                       12/07/2018 11:13
10                            Sports economics uncut

                  professional football games are now accessible to fans spread across the
                  country. The internet allows fans to access media coverage of their favorite
                  team regardless of location and to interact with other fans through blogs
                  and discussion boards. While this may never replace daily, face-to-face
                  interactions, it does diminish the reliance on it to a degree.

                  THE WIDE WORLD OF SPORTS ECONOMICS
                  With the expansive interest in sports, the “economics of sports” attracts
                  a number of followers among professional economists and beyond. In a
                  narrow sense the “economics of sports” centers on revenues, costs, indus-
                  try structure, compensation practices, and related topics. It is the study of
                  sports in and of itself.
                     Yet, sports intimates connection to life and the importance that consum-
                  ers vest in sports allow for a bridge beyond sports economics for the sake
                  of sports alone and to broader socio-economic topics that overlap with
                  sports. That is the focus in this volume. What are lessons learned on play-
                  ing fields and in sports institutions that provide insights into other areas?
                  Such inquiries are not without critics inside and outside of academic
                  economists. To them, sports amounts to only a small industry of little
                  importance involving mere games. The outcomes do not really “matter.”
                  To these critics, there tends to be far too much focus on sports already.
                     These criticisms overlook the points that we have just discussed and
                  related ones considered below. In spite of modest revenues and impacts in
                  terms of typical economic metrics like revenue, the outcomes matter deeply
                  both to participants and consumers. The enormous attention devoted
                  to sports, even inordinate to those critical of sports, is itself prima facie
                  evidence that sports outcomes really do “matter” – not because life and
                  death hinge on them but because people invest importance in them. There
                  is more to the study of sports than merely the comparison of batting aver-
                  ages, passing efficiencies, or player salaries. There are connections to much
                  more general questions in life.
                     Whether looking narrowly at sports economics topics or more broadly,
                  sports offer rich environments for data analytic studies of all sorts. The
                  observability of these environments has sometimes led to comparisons to
                  laboratory settings.5 It is not exactly a laboratory setting in that researchers
                  cannot manipulate outcomes and hold certain factors constant, although
                  it frequently provides “natural experiments” where a rule or institutional
                  change occurs while most other influences are constant. For example, the
                  elimination of the 2-line offsides pass in the NHL creates a switch in incen-
                  tives and optimal strategy.

                                                                Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                     Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                              via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 10                                                                         12/07/2018 11:13
Why consumers wear sports gear	­11

                  Beyond these natural experiments, sports affords countless opportun­
               ities for “field research.” The variety of settings, observability of outcomes,
               and tradition of detailed statistical measurement allows for empirical
               investigation of a wide array of topics that can hardly be rivaled by any
               other setting. The behavior of labor, management, ownership, leagues,
               officials, and consumers can all be observed and monitored in measurable
               ways so much so that economics journals of all sorts regularly publish
               sports economists’ articles; and an entire journal, the Journal of Sports
               Economics, is now devoted to the subject along with economics-oriented
               articles in related journals such as the Journal of Sport Management and
               the Journal of Quantitative Analysis in Sports. The tentacles of economics-
               based sports research have grown wider with the explosion of the analytics
               and “big data” era. In fact, sports research has led the way into the sports
               analytics era as evidenced by books like Moneyball and the MIT Sloan
               Sports Analytics annual conference.
                  Of course, sports do not incorporate every aspect of everyday life,
               particularly at the extremes. There are no murders, assaults, child abuse,
               or similar extremes on sporting fields. Short of these extremes, however,
               most aspects of life are reflected in sports to some extent. There may be
               no divorces, per se, but there are break-ups with strong emotional content.
               There may be no births, but fans and players celebrate victories and cham-
               pionships with as much vigor. After Team Canada secured the gold medal
               in the 2010 Winter Olympics in Vancouver, Canadians poured out into the
               streets in celebration by the hundreds of thousands.
                  Simon Rottenberg (1956) kicked off the use of economic research using
               sports markets with his study of baseball labor markets and the alloca-
               tion of players among teams.6 He explained a simple but powerful and
               somewhat controversial thesis at the time: the allocation of players among
               teams would not be very different in a free agency setting versus a world
               where a single club reserved exclusive rights over a player. The essence of
               his reasoning was that the Yankees could obtain higher quality players
               either in a free-agent world by paying them directly or in a restricted labor
               world by paying lower revenue teams.
                  His insight expresses the fundamental logic behind the famous Coase
               Theorem in economics – the idea that with low costs of reaching an agree-
               ment (low transactions costs), the assignment of rights will not impact the
               allocation of resources. Yet, Rottenberg’s article predates Coase’s by five
               years and vividly illustrates important connections between the world of
               sports and broader economic and social issues in the world beyond. Ronald
               Coase won the Nobel Prize for economics in 1991, in large part, for this idea.
                  In another seminal contribution with regard to sports labor markets,
               Gerald Scully (1973) showed that MLB’s Reserve Clause, which allocated

                                                               Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                    Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                             via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 11                                                                     12/07/2018 11:13
12                           Sports economics uncut

                  negotiating rights to a single team, lowered the pay of major league
                  baseball players below what they could have earned in an open market
                  setting. The problem Scully addressed was how the open market value of
                  an MLB player could be determined when MLB markets were not open.
                  He developed a simple but ingenious solution by using statistics to link
                  player performance statistics like slugging percentages for hitters and
                  strikeout to walk ratios for pitcher to team performance, and then linking
                  these player performances to their contribution to revenues by way of the
                  impact of team performance on revenue. His approach became a template
                  for estimating market values in restricted markets. Methods derived from
                  this have been employed to generate market values for college athletes
                  and used as a template to examine whether workers in broader contexts
                  receive payments in line with their contribution to firm revenues outside
                  of sports settings.7 It also served as a precursor to the “Bosman ruling”
                  in soccer that switched exclusive rights from players to teams. The ruling
                  has not only impacted player compensation but has had a major impact
                  on migration of players and growth of revenues of leagues like the English
                  Premier League.8
                     An area of longstanding connections between sports economics and
                  broader research in economics is the structure of industries and how firms
                  compete and cooperate within them. The earliest premise presented by
                  Neale (1964) in the Quarterly Journal of Economics were that sports leagues
                  emerged as collusive arrangements between producers that restrict output
                  or price with the ultimate aim of increasing profits above a competitive
                  level – cartels.9 This cartel view of sporting leagues and associations was
                  long dominant among economists and captured many essential elements
                  of league structure and decision making. Extension and expansion of the
                  view focused on game-theoretic dilemmas faced by such arrangements in
                  terms of potential gains from restrictive agreements but, simultaneously,
                  set up ongoing incentives for behavior that undermines the agreement.10
                  The suit brought against the NCAA cartel by the University of Georgia
                  and the University of Oklahoma that, ultimately, found its way to the
                  US Supreme Court and ended some of the cartel practices continues to
                  reverberate in conference shifting to the present time.
                     Over time, a more nuanced understanding of industry structure and
                  firm relationships emerged in economics, in general, with sports analysis
                  also evolving.11 Sports leagues are now seen as joint ventures that may
                  integrate some cartel functions but continue to compete as separate entities
                  and cooperate in some ways that are benign with regard to consumer or
                  labor interests.12 For example, schools in the NCAA may continue to act as
                  a cartel with respect to player restrictions at an association level; however,
                  teams in conferences behave more like participants in a joint venture. In

                                                               Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                    Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                             via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 12                                                                       12/07/2018 11:13
Why consumers wear sports gear	­13

               other cases, rather than joint ventures among independent firms, a sport
               like National Association for Stock Car Auto Racing (NASCAR) is organ-
               ized with a centralized structure operating as a single firm. The PGA Tour
               operates with this kind of structure with individual players rather than
               teams as the key operational unit and excels at extracting rewards from
               local tournament sponsors.13 Ross and Szymanski (2005) have considered
               whether this structure might also be more efficient for other sports.
                  This brief summary and sampling of references provides a guide to
               many of the starting points of the interface between economics and
               sports. For many years, sports economics focused primarily on labor
               markets and industry or firm structure. Over the past few decades, as
               economics widened its scope, many more topics related to sports came
               under examination by economists. These include race and discrimination,
               law enforcement and corruption, managerial decisions, strategic behavior,
               inequality, market efficiency, and many more. These topics comprise the
               subject matter for the remainder of this volume. Of course, not every topic
               related to sports and economics is covered in the following chapters. One
               example is the relative efficiency of market mechanisms and participants
               in their decisions. Economists have used the extensive data available in
               sports betting markets with a view toward evaluating the degree to which
               markets are efficient in eliminating systematic profit opportunities and
               whether these betting values reflect valuable information. By and large,
               participants, at least as a group, are highly skilled in utilizing existing
               information, but some interesting exceptions crop up. One exception found
               with regularity is the over-betting of longshots while under-betting of
               favorites in terms of expected returns. Recent evidence suggests that this
               error by market bettors grows out of misperceptions of the probabilities;
               however, the size of the error is small, not allowing for systematic profits
               above transactions costs.14

               PUSHING THE BOUNDARIES

               My intent in this volume is not to provide a comprehensive review of
               existing contributions to sports economics or take on every topic. There
               are a number of existing economics-oriented books that push into various
               corners of sports topics.15 I select a few topics deserving of additional
               attention such as the idea that sports really matters, topics on race, inequal-
               ity, the balance between traditional economic views of managers and
               behavioral views, and a few others. The “uncut” part of this book comes
               from my effort to push these topics, highlight dilemmas, probe for insights,
               and ask questions that are unanswered or avoided. I have not tried to be

                                                               Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                    Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                             via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 13                                                                     12/07/2018 11:13
14                            Sports economics uncut

                  bombastic or provocative for its own sake. While being sensitive to the
                  delicate nature of some of these issues, I have tried to push outside the box
                  of politically approved explanations.
                     Even though sports fans share some common attributes and behave
                  like club members, all sports fans are not created equal. In Chapter 2 the
                  discussion centers on how it took MLB more than a decade to realize that
                  its fans differed from NFL fans. In fact, the rethink occurred, largely, as a
                  result of the entrepreneurship of the Braves and Cubs against the wishes of
                  other teams. Also, college sports represents an anomaly in not only sports
                  but entertainment more broadly in that a lower-skill production, college
                  football and basketball, can rival the consumer interest at a higher-level
                  of production, professional football and basketball, at least among top
                  programs. I examine the factors behind this along with consumer interest
                  in women’s sports and the long-run threats to the fan bases of the most
                  popular sports like football and baseball.
                     In Chapter 3 I ask what the race-related studies in sports indicate about
                  trends in terms of bias and discrimination and current degree of such
                  biases. Studies in sports economics have long found substantive evidence
                  of discrimination. Over time, however, the nature of the evidence has been
                  changing in terms of the magnitude of bias and discrimination. It is one
                  thing to say that bias and discrimination still exists, but it is a different
                  thing to show that it matters in substantive ways. In fact, the evidence now
                  indicates that to the extent that discrimination lingers in sports, it is on a
                  scattered, random basis or in very microscopic quantities. The discussion
                  goes on to ask more provocative questions: is a zero-bias world the goal
                  or is bias all bad? At first glance, the answer seems obvious, but when bias
                  is considered as a different label for affinity, it seems both unrealistic and
                  undesirable to work toward an affinity-free world.
                     Bias and bigotry persist in the world, yet one of the ongoing stories in
                  sports economics is that markets penalize these attitudes. Beyond the bias
                  and discrimination, there is a story of racial integration and the factors
                  behind it. These are the subject matter of Chapter 4. The Jackie Robison
                  story has been widely told and dramatized in movies, along with the Texas
                  Western story. The wider story of how process of integration as a type of
                  innovation and competition worked out on a wider scale in MLB and col-
                  lege basketball is less well known but informative about the way and time
                  in which markets root out bias.
                     A related and also controversial question is addressed in Chapter 5,
                  coauthored with Dennis Wilson, as to whether segregation should always
                  be taken as a sign of discrimination. The study of “positional discrimina-
                  tion,” as the label implies, attributes observed differences in catchers versus
                  pitchers or quarterbacks versus wide receivers to discrimination and bias.

                                                                Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                     Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                              via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 14                                                                        12/07/2018 11:13
Why consumers wear sports gear	­15

               Likely, such discrimination in positions existed at one time, but continued
               differences in usage of blacks and whites at different positions may be
               due to alternative explanations that are innocuous and reflect economic
               motives.
                  Chapter 6 draws on the studies of sports, law enforcement, and corrup-
               tion to raise a question regarding the longstanding antagonism that seems
               to exist between the public and the police. Many people, who are not seri-
               ous criminals, go through life suspicious of police in spite of their “public
               servant” role. In sports, such antagonism arises, in part, because officials
               help one team when punishing their opponent. Beyond this element,
               however, there are interesting issues that arise with regard to incentives to
               and evaluation of officials. Different sports leagues employ different evalu-
               ation and incentive mechanisms. On a related twist, I consider the ongoing
               antagonism toward NFL Commissioner Roger Goodell and what is at the
               heart of the push for more independent arbitrators to decide punishments.
                  In business settings and in personal settings, decision makers often come
               relatively close to the optimizing behavior expressed in fundamental eco-
               nomic models. However, there are well documented departures from such
               models as studied in the sports betting literature as well as sports manage-
               ment literature, which lend themselves to more of a “behavioral” view of
               decision making. For example, NFL teams punt more frequently on 4th
               down than is implied by expected point difference maximization. While
               these decisions may be less than optimal from a team standpoint, there
               are underlying incentives on managers that may contribute to this kind
               of outcome. This is the focus of Chapter 7. Beyond small departures from
               simple models of optimal decision making, managers sometimes engage
               in egregiously bad behavior. New Orleans Saints head coach Sean Payton
               blatantly ignored explicit instructions from the NFL Commissioner and
               his owner to stop the payment of “bounties.” In a scandalous and sad case,
               the revered longtime coach at Penn State, Joe Paterno, enabled the contin-
               ued behavior of a child molester. We use these sports examples to explain
               how unconstrained, poorly monitored behavior leads to bad decisions in
               and out of sports settings.
                  In Chapter 8, I consider some of the complexities that arise regarding
               competitive balance and equality among sports teams. One of the ongoing
               themes of competitive balance in sports leagues that have limited revenue
               sharing or soft salary caps is the ability of well-endowed teams to establish
               longstanding dominance. College football fits this world where teams like
               Alabama, USC, and Texas have advantages that help establish winning
               records, albeit with some bumps. At the same time, smaller schools like
               Western Kentucky University can compete better in football against major
               programs in a way they could not 25 years ago. Why is this? Likewise,

                                                               Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                    Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                             via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 15                                                                   12/07/2018 11:13
16                                  Sports economics uncut

                  it is natural to think that a team boosting its financial resources with a
                  generous owner will make life harder for lower teams. However, the entry
                  of Chelsea and Manchester City into the upper echelon of the English
                  Premier League seemed to make life more difficult for Manchester United
                  and Arsenal as much as or more than lower-placed teams.
                     College athletics is a world of cognitive dissonance. On the one hand,
                  it is easy to observe the large and growing revenues generated by major
                  football and basketball programs. On the other hand, many programs
                  show little or no surpluses, leading analysts and reporters to conclude
                  that schools subsidize college sports to a large extent. Chapter 9 explains
                  how the world of college sports provides instructive lessons on the world
                  of not-for-profit firms and how valuations of the contributions of college
                  athletes can be made in relatively simple ways.
                     Chapter 10 shows how the power of sports can make a difference on a
                  national scale in addressing problems or expressing common sentiments.
                  The quote from Nelson Mandela at the beginning of this chapter is part
                  of his use of the 1995 World Cup as a means to attempt to unite South
                  Africans and heal some of the longstanding wounds of apartheid. Besides
                  South Africa in 1995, many other sporting events illustrate the political
                  overtones embedded in sports. Some of the most famous incidents include
                  the 1956 “Blood in the Water” water polo match between Hungary and
                  the USSR or the 1980 “Miracle on Ice” victory of the US over the USSR
                  in Olympic ice hockey. While sports can have a positive impact on a large
                  scale, this kind of power and overlap with politics also creates dilemmas
                  on an international level by giving rise and power to super-national organi-
                  zations like FIFA as well as on a local level with debates about public
                  subsidies to sports stadiums.

                  NOTES

                   1.   Some examples across different stadium settings include Noll and Zimbalist (1997),
                        Coates and Humphreys (2003), Dehring et al (2007).
                   2.   Carlino and Coulson (2004) estimate the net benefits to a city of hosting an NFL team,
                        finding sizable effects in total. Coates et al (2006) express criticisms of their methods,
                        prompting a reply by Carlino and Coulson (2006). Atkinson et al (2008) consider the
                        intangible impacts of the London Olympics, while Humphreys et al (2011) estimate the
                        value of medals for Canadian athletes in the 2010 Winter Games in Vancouver.
                   3.   The merchandising revenue figures are from https://www.statista.com/statistics.
                   4.   The seminal contributions to the economics of clubs are Buchanan (1965) and Olson
                        (1965). An extensive discussion is available in Sandler and Tschirhart (1980). There are
                        more recent articles in both sports economics and sports marketing focusing on fan
                        affiliation and loyalty.
                   5.   Goff and Tollison (1990, Ch 1) first raise the comparisons between laboratory experi-
                        ments and sports settings. They are explored in greater detail by Kahn (2000).

                                                                    Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                         Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                                  via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 16                                                                                         12/07/2018 11:13
Why consumers wear sports gear	­17

                6.   An overview of connections between sports labor markets and broader issues in labor
                     economics are provided by Rosen and Sanderson (2001) and Kahn (2000).
                7.   Brown (1993, 1994) uses it as a basis to consider the value of college athletes, a topic we
                     take up in a later chapter.
                8.   See Simmons (1997) and Goddard et al (2012) for examinations of the impact of the
                     Bosman ruling.
                9.   Fort and Quirk (1995) offered a wide-ranging review of the economics of sports leagues
                     in the Journal of Economic Literature and then authored a comprehensive study of
                     professional sports (Quirk and Fort, 1997) and abuses in pro sports (Quirk and Fort,
                     1999). Noll and Zimbalist (1997) is another wide-ranging examination of sports leagues.
                     Zimbalist (1994) focuses on baseball.
               10.   Fleisher et al (1992) present a detailed study of the NCAA as a cartel. Fleisher et al
                     (1988) and DeSchriver and Stotlar (1996) are studies that explore the NCAA’s cartel-like
                     arrangements.
               11.   Abere et al (2012) provide detailed discussions of the economic structure of NASCAR.
               12.   The joint venture perspective on sports leagues appears in Tollison (1999) and Flynn
                     and Gilbert (2001).
               13.   Cottle (1981) is responsible for this insight into the PGA Tour’s activities.
               14.   Sauer (1998) provides a review of many of the early studies of the efficiency of sports
                     betting markets. He explains that the evidence generally supports market efficiency, but
                     with some interesting exceptions. Brown and Sauer (1993) show that betting markets
                     respond to team abilities and special factors rather than just fluctuating due to random
                     noise.
               15.   Bradbury (2007) looks at baseball with an economist’s eye.

                                                                    Brian Goff - 9781788118736
                                         Downloaded from Elgar Online at 07/13/2021 06:13:07AM
                                                                                  via free access

GOFF_9781788118729_t.indd 17                                                                                       12/07/2018 11:13
You can also read