Lowering Generic Drug Prices Less Regulation Equals More Competition
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
MEDICAL CARE Volume 41, Number 1, pp 135–141 ©2003 Lippincott Williams & Wilkins, Inc. Lowering Generic Drug Prices Less Regulation Equals More Competition ASLAM H. ANIS, PHD, DAPHNE P. GUH, MSC, AND JOHN WOOLCOTT, MA BACKGROUND. In Ontario, Canada, the 70/90 as the number of generic firms increased regulations were instituted in May 1993 to within these periods. However, this decrease establish provincial government procurement in P was significantly less in the AP (median: prices for generic drugs. Accordingly, the first 0.75 f 0.68 f 0.67) than in BP (0.71 f 0.61 f generic entrant’s price could not exceed 70% of 0.53) as the number of generics increased from the incumbent’s branded price. Subsequent 1 to 2 to 3, respectively. The regression analysis entrants’ prices could not exceed 90% of the showed that the price ratio in the AP was first entrant’s price. higher than that in the BP by 0.05, 0.09, and 0.13 OBJECTIVE. These regulations’ impact on ge- for first, second, and third generic entrant neric market competitiveness are evaluated. respectively. DESIGN and METHODS. Data on 518 drugs CONCLUSIONS. Our findings show that the spanning nine therapeutic classifications were 70/90 regulations not only failed to achieve collected for the period of 04/01/1987 to 12/31/ their goal of lowering the procurement price 1998 from Ontario Drug Benefit formulary and but instead the opposite occurred. The man- IMS Canada. The period 04/01/1987 to 04/30/ dated procurement price became a focal point 1993 was defined as the before period (BP) and and resulted in a clustering of prices around 05/01/1993 to 12/31/1998 was the after period the maximum allowable levels with little price (AP). We compared the price ratio (P ⴝ PG/PB) dispersion. between BP and AP and performed regression Key words: Drug policy; drug price regula- analysis to assess the determinants of P. tion; generic market competitiveness. (Med RESULTS. P in both the BP and AP decreased Care 2003;41:135–141) When available, the use of generic as opposed to natives. This may be because of the lower costs of brand prescription drugs can significantly reduce production associated with generics who do not costs for drug insurance plans. Additionally, price have to incur R&D costs and the increased compe- regulation is often used to further reduce costs. tition which results after the expiry of the branded Often drug price regulation is tied to drug substitu- products’ patent. This process is facilitated by regu- tion laws to redirect dispensing toward cheaper lations that attempt to lower generic prices while generics from more expensive branded drugs. His- increasing generic competition. torically the prices of generic drugs are significantly Although well intentioned, price regulations are lower than the prices of the relevant branded alter- often poorly conceived. Several studies have doc- From the Department of Health Care and Epidemi- Address correspondence and reprint requests to: ology, University of British Columbia, Centre for Health Aslam H. Anis, PhD, CHEOS, 620-1081 Burrard St., Evaluation & Outcome Sciences, St. Paul’s Hospital, Vancouver, B.C., Canada, V6Z 1Y6. E-mail: Vancouver, British Columbia. anis@cheos.ubc.ca An earlier version of this paper was presented at the 3rd World Conference of International Health Econom- Received October 12, 2001; initial review December ics Association, July 22 to 25, 2001, York, UK. 14, 2001; accepted July 12, 2002. 135
ANIS ET AL MEDICAL CARE umented the association between price regula- may be charged by manufacturers. Under the tions and a rise in the average price of generic regulations, a generic drug manufacturer wanting drugs and a reduced dispersion of prices that their product to be eligible for reimbursement normally existed between generics.1–3 under the ODB plan must first have their product In a typical marketplace, free and unfettered listed as interchangeable under the Drug Inter- exchange between suppliers and demanders of changeability and Dispensing Fee Act (DIDFA) goods and services occurs on a regular basis. No and listed on the ODB Formulary. To be listed, the rules or regulation are necessary for the smooth price of the generic drug cannot exceed a specified functioning of such markets. The equilibrium price (maximum) level with respect to the branded of the competitive market ensures that there is manufacturer’s price. The 70/90 regulations stipu- neither “excess”demand nor supply in the market. lated that the first generic entrants’ price could not With numerous buyers and sellers these markets exceed 70% of the incumbent branded product are assumed to be competitive, and any attempts price. Subsequent entrants could not price their to raise prices above the competitive equilibrium product at greater than 90% of the first entrants’ level would be unsustainable because the compe- price, which essentially limits the subsequent en- tition would attract all the business. The market trants’ price to be at most 63% of the relevant for prescription pharmaceuticals does not, how- branded product price. ever, resemble the competitive market scenario. The 70/90 regulations were first introduced as First, for the most part, there are few, rather than the 75/90 regulations in May 1993 and were numerous sellers. Second, the demanders (physi- subsequently amended and became the 70/90 cians) are not consumers, and furthermore often regulations in November 1998 (see Appendix A. the demanders and consumers are not the pur- Table 1). The only difference between the 75/90 chasers. This creates a market imperfection where regulations and the 70/90 regulations is that under the ramifications of price changes are not directly the former, the first entrant had to offer a 25% felt by the consumers and therefore have negligi- discount on the incumbents’ branded product, ble effects on demand. Thus, a rationale for im- which under the latter was increased to 30%. The plementing price regulation exists. objective of this study was to evaluate the impact In the province of Ontario, Canada, for the past of these regulations, and given that the current three decades, Drug Product Selection/Substitu- regulation is known as the 70/90 regulation, we tion (DPS) laws, have been enforced regarding refer to these regulations as the 70/90 regulations price, interchangeability, legal liability, etc. for all on generic market competitiveness throughout the eligible prescription drugs.4 The Ontario Drug remainder of the text. Benefit (ODB) publishes a formulary listing of all Parenthetically it should be noted that in 1991 eligible drug products and the price for each pharmacoeconomic guidelines were introduced in dosage form that will be paid directly to pharma- Ontario.6 However, these guidelines applied spe- cists when the drug is dispensed to anyone cov- cifically to new drugs seeking ODB formulary ered by the provincial plan. The drug cost for inclusion. Branded products already on the ODB multiple-source drugs was determined as the low- formulary and generic products (existing or new est price submitted to the formulary by any eligible entrants) were exempt. manufacturer and was designated as the Best Available Price (BAP). For single-source drugs, the BAP referred to the only price submitted to the Materials and Methods formulary. The philosophy of the BAP-type system was to force suppliers of multiple-source drugs to To assess the impact of the 70/90 regulations, compete among each other by submitting low- we compared the price ratio between the relevant price bids. By designating the lowest-price bid as generic and branded drug products launched be- the BAP and additionally requiring pharmacists fore and after the regulations. A sample of drug via substitution legislation to substitute all pre- products listed under the ODB Formulary between scriptions for the cheaper BAP products, it was April 1, 1987 to December 31, 1998 was selected hoped that a substantial cost savings could be from the following therapeutic classifications: car- achieved.5 diovascular drugs, antiarthritics, psychotherapeu- The 70/90 regulations specifically govern the tics, antiinfectives, analgesics, neurologic disor- pricing of generic drugs and limit the prices that ders, cholesterol reducing/lipotropic drugs, 136
Vol. 41, No. 1 DRUG PRICE REGULATIONS proprietary analgesics, and diuretics. These thera- first generic product over the branded product, the peutic classifications together accounted for more ratio of the second generic entrant over the than 50.5% of the prescriptions written in Canada branded product and the ratio of the third generic for 1999.7 The ODB Formulary, updated and pub- entrant over the branded product. lished periodically, contained information regard- Occasionally, the market in the before and after ing the interchangeable drug categories and pric- periods changed from a situation of one branded ing data for all drug products. Additional data firm to a situation of one branded and two generic regarding launch dates of individual generic prod- firms without the intermediate case of one ucts was obtained from the Drugstore and Hospi- branded and one generic firm. Similarly, there also tal Database constructed by IMS Canada. were instances where the market changed from The study sample was primarily selected based the situation of one branded and one generic firm, on the availability of the data. A pharmacist re- to one branded and three or more generic firms viewed the database and some inconsistencies directly. When this occurred, the price ratios of first with respect to launch dates were found. These generic product, second generic product and/or inconsistencies related primarily to situations second generic product over branded product where: (1) for the same drug product, multiple would not be available. Furthermore, because we drug manufacturers were named because of li- did not have pricing data before April 1987, no censing arrangements between parties; or (2) a price ratios could be calculated when more than new drug information number was subsequently three generic products within the same inter- issued for an existing drug product as the new changeable drug category were already present in drug information number may have been issued the market before April 1987. because of a change in the manufacturing site or a The precise expiry date of each patent during change in the source of raw materials for the drug the study period was not available to us. Patent product. In these circumstances, these observa- expiry was inferred from generic entry. The num- tions were excluded from the study. Also excluded ber of first, second, or third generic entrants is were generic products owned by branded firms governed entirely by patent expires, market size known as “fighting generics” or “pseudo- and entry conditions. To observe that there were generics.” They were excluded from the analysis more first entrants in either period is a function of because they do not typically compete with the both the number of patent expires, and the profit incumbent branded firm. On the contrary, these potential of generic entrants, which, among other “pseudo-generics” allow the owner of the patent factors would be a function of market size in the (branded firm) to segment the market in a manner relevant therapeutic category. that maximizes their revenues from both the brand Univariate analysis using nonparametric version and generic version. (distribution-free) Wilcoxon rank sum test was As the regulations were first introduced in May performed to compare PG/PB in the before period 1993, the period between April 1, 1987 and April versus the after period.4 We chose the Wilcoxon 30, 1993 was defined as the before period while rank sum test, which tests the hypothesis that the the period between May 1, 1993 and December 31, distributions of the two populations are the same 1998 was defined as the after period. Each generic because our data are skewed. drug product was classified as being launched in Multiple regression analysis was additionally the before period or in the after period. The order performed to identify the determinants of the ratio at which each generic drug product launched of price. In the final regression model, the vari- within each interchangeable drug category was ables included were the period at which the also determined from its launched date. generic product was launched (before period or For each generic product, the price ratio, which after period), the number of generic product exist- was defined as the price of generic product over ing in the market the generic product (0, 1, 2), their the price of branded product (PG/PB) in the same interaction term, and the therapeutic classification. interchangeable drug category, was calculated. We The regression model was estimated using Gen- used the first available pricing data for both the eralized Estimating Equations approach because generic and branded products in the same edition when generic products were from the same inter- of the Formulary after the launch date of the changeable drug category, the price of these generic product to calculate PG/PB. Three types of branded products would contribute to more than price ratio were examined in our study: the ratio of one price ratio and these ratios may not be con- 137
ANIS ET AL MEDICAL CARE sidered as independent observations.8 A simple TABLE 1. Summary of Price Ratio by Generic exploratory analysis was also performed to check if Entrant Before and After Price Regulations there is an increasing trend of price ratios over Estimated Price Ratio time for first, second, and third entrants (PG/PB) respectively. 04/01/87- 05/01/93- Comparison 04/30/93 12/31/98 P st Results Branded vs. 1 generic N 52 19 A total of 125 branded drug products (ie, 125 Mean 0.70 0.73 interchangeable drug categories) and 510 generic SD 0.13 0.03 products were selected. Of those, 19 branded drug Median 0.71 0.75 0.42 products had only one generic product competing Q1–Q3 0.64–0.75 0.71–0.75 in the market during the study period, 23 with Range 0.32–1.00 0.67–0.75 Branded vs. 2nd generic two, 37 with three, 32 with four, and 14 with more N 56 22 than four competing generic products. Because of Mean 0.55 0.71 the availability of the pricing data as explained SD 0.21 0.13 earlier, the number of price ratios we were able to Median 0.61 0.68 0.01 obtain was 71, 78, and 69 for first, second, and Q1–Q3 0.47–0.71 0.67–0.75 third entrant, respectively. Out of a total of 125, we Range 0.05–0.90 0.46–1.11 only had 71 first entrant prices because 47 of the Branded vs. 3rd generic remaining 54 cases resulted in a market where two N 33 36 generics entered simultaneously and for the re- Mean 0.50 0.65 maining seven cases, the branded drug was un- SD 0.21 0.08 Median 0.53 0.67 0.0001 listed and its price was no longer available. In total, Q1–Q3 0.38–0.60 0.60–0.67 23 branded drugs were excluded for the reasons Range 0.04–0.95 0.46–0.90 listed in the previous section; 21 were launched in the before period whereas two were launched in the after period. Among the excluded branded products, 11 (all in the before period) were before period by 0.05, 0.09, and 0.13 for first, “pseudo-generics”. second, and third generic entrant, respectively. Table 1 and Figure 1 present the summary Moreover, as the number of generic product in- statistics and box plots of the price ratio between a creases from 1 to 2 and 3, the price ratio decreases new generic product and the respective branded in the before period by 0.08 and 0.16 whereas it product according to the before period and after only decreases in the after period by 0.04 and 0.08, period. It shows that the price ratio in both the respectively. The results of the multivariate analy- before period and the after period decreased as the sis resolve that a significant degree of change in number of existing generic products increases. the price ratio (PG/PB) can be attributed to the However, the data clearly show that this decrease period in which the generic drug was introduced. in price ratio is substantially less in the after period These findings, like those of the univariate analy- than in the before period. Additionally, the sub- sis, are consistent with the hypothesis that the stantially smaller spread of the price ratio in the pricing regulations have the intended effect of after period suggests that the generic products in raising generic prices. the after period were priced at the level close to what the regulation set. However, in the before period, many generic products were priced at a Discussion much lower level. Additionally, plots of price ratios over time by generic entry did not reveal signifi- Our findings suggest that Ontario’s 70/90 Reg- cant trends. ulations failed to achieve their goal of lowering the The results from the regression analysis are cost of generic drugs for the ODB plan. The presented in Table 2. The results suggested that generic marketplace appears to be an inherently after the therapeutic class being adjusted, the price competitive marketplace in which there is a natu- ratio in the after period was higher than that in the ral, market-imposed pressure on the first generic 138
Vol. 41, No. 1 DRUG PRICE REGULATIONS FIG. 1. Price ratio by order of generic entry. entrant to not set prices too high and as the such that all generics are treated as a homogenous number of competitors increases with entry of good. That is generic firm specific prices do not additional generic firms, prices are driven down- exist. All generics are paid the same reimburse- ward. The data also suggests that in the after ment amount, the BAP. Hence, cutting prices does period, the decrease in price ratio caused by in- not necessarily generate market to the firm cutting creased number of generic firms is much lower, the price but that all generics in the specific market which is supportive of the premise that price now receive a lower reimbursement. controls have interfered with natural competitive More generally speaking, the lowest submitted forces. The question that must then be addressed price was designated as the BAP, yet the submit- by policy makers is, whether there is a role for ting bidder did not get any special rights as the regulation in the market of post patent pharma- sole supplier at this bid. All generics were allowed ceuticals? The answer which this paper along with to supply at this price. This led to a flawed process others show that to date the stated goals of for generating competitive bids and the addition of legislation are not being met and therefore differ- the 70/90 regulations did not alter this basic flaw, ent approaches should be explored.1–3,8,9 ie, lowest bidder did not get the sole supplier It is our contention that the 70/90 regulations contract.5 created a focal point for setting the initial price of As illustrated by Caves et al,11 in unregulated any generic product. A potential generic entrant markets, generics were found to be priced approx- has no incentive to submit a price lower than the imately 60% less than branded products facing mandated ceiling price because, given inelastic only one generic competitor. In addition, the paper demand and substitution legislation, it is the profit showed that the greater the number of generics in maximizing price except for instances where entry the market the lower the generic prices. Using is unprofitable. The preceding is similar to the Canadian data within the context of formulary effect of implementing price caps or cost ceilings.10 pricing similar to the ODB framework, Anis5 dem- Furthermore, the nature of the generic market is onstrated a similar result. Using six countries (US, 139
ANIS ET AL MEDICAL CARE TABLE 2. Estimated Coefficients of the this regulation led the price of branded products Regression Model* on Price Ratio (PG/PB) facing generic competition to increase and generic Estimated firms also raising their prices with fewer firms Variable Coefficient (SE) P entering the market. When faced with entry price regulation, Abbot3 noted that branded firms, given After May, 1993 0.05 (0.03) 0.11 their monopoly power, set launch prices 50% No. of existing generic product ⫺0.04 (0.01) 0.003 higher than they would in an unregulated market. Interaction 0.04 (0.02) 0.04 A limitation of our study is that because the Therapeutic classification ODB Formulary was normally updated and pub- Cardiovascular 0.52 (0.03) 0.0001 lished semi-annually, the drug prices listed could Antiarthritics 0.47 (0.03) 0.0001 be different from the launch price of those phar- Psychotherapeutic 0.37 (0.05) 0.0001 maceuticals. Also, we did not look at the usage Antiinfectives 0.50 (0.03) 0.0001 levels of the generic products to analyze whether Analgesics 0.54 (0.04) 0.0001 the 70/90 regulations had an effect on usage levels. Neurological disorders 0.47 (0.05) 0.0001 Another issue that was beyond the scope of this Cholesterol/lipotropic 0.65 (0.03) 0.0001 paper was the impact of the 70/90 regulations in Proprietary analgesics 0.44 (0.01) 0.0001 preventing generic entry. This would occur if branded firms were to price their products below N ⫽ 218. the normal levels or if the mandatory discount *Pearson Goodness-of-Fit statistic over its degrees of freedom is 1.06. prevented potential entrants from being able to feasibly making a profit. A lack of a control group was another limitation of this study and we real- UK, Denmark, Holland, Germany, and South Af- ized that there might be some confounding factor rica) with varying levels of pricing freedom with that caused the differences in the price ratios respect to new product pricing, Reekie2 compared between periods. Because Ontario is the largest pricing of the top five products. He showed that in market in Canada, Ontario generic prices were markets with greater pricing freedom, competition likely to be applicable to the rest of the country as created by rival products lowered the price of well. Therefore, even though the 70/90 regulations medicines. were specific to Ontario, other provinces in Can- The Gordon Commission report),13 which in- ada could not be used as controls. Because the vestigated drug pricing in Ontario was particularly regulation originally restricted the first generic at critical of the failure of the ODB formulary prices 75% of the branded product, we have observed to reflect the true acquisition cost of drugs and price ratios of first generic entrant to the branded referred to this practice as “spread pricing.” Ac- product over 0.70 and close to 0.75. However, we cording to this practice, manufacturers included a believed that subsequent amendments to the pric- margin over cost in their price submission to the ing restrictions that set the maximum price ceiling formulary in attempts to prompt pharmacists to for the first generic at 70% instead of 75% of the price select in their favor ie, choose to dispense incumbent’s price, were merely incidental to the their particular drug product.13 Lexchin9 found original change in paradigm in 1993. that indeed the greater the level of competition Finally, with previous studies showing that and consequently the greater the number of pro- ducers the smaller is the spread and consequently prices resulting from Ontario’s BAP-type of for- the lower the cost of drugs. mulary not being competitive5,8,13 and the anti- Similar to the 70/90 regulations, the Omnibus competitive effects of the 70/90 regulations dem- Budget Reconciliation Act of 1990 (OBRA 1990) onstrated in this study, the spill-over effects of allowed Medicaid (US federally funded health these regulations on other Canadian provinces insurance program) to adopt a most-favored- needs to be considered. Given that Ontario is the customer rule with respect to pharmaceutical pur- largest market in Canada, the impact of the 70/90 chases.12 The OBRA 1990 allowed Medicaid to regulations could result in increased generic drug purchase pharmaceuticals at a given percentage prices across the country. This is a concern that below average price if the best price was not low should not be ignored by policy makers both enough. It has been shown by Scott-Morton1 that within and outside of the Ontario market. 140
Vol. 41, No. 1 DRUG PRICE REGULATIONS Acknowledgments Ontario and Canada. Pharmacoeconomics 1993; 3:354 –361. The authors acknowledge the assistance of Dianne 7. IMS Health. Canadian Pharmaceutical Industry Calbick, and IMS Canada in researching and preparation Review. Pointe Claire, Quebec; 2000. of this manuscript. 8. Liang KY, and Zeger SL. Longitudinal data analysis using generalized linear models. Biometrika 1986;73:13–22. References 9. Lexchin J. Effect of generic drug competition on the price of prescription drugs in Ontario. CMAJ 1. Scott-Morton F. The strategic response by phar- 1993;148:35–39. maceutical firms to the Medicaid most-favored- customer rules. Rand J Econ 1997;28:269–290. 10. Laffont J, Tirole J. A theory of incentives in procurement and regulation. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press; 2. Reekie WD. How competition lowers the costs 1993:75–76. of medicines. Pharmacoeconomics 1998;14(Supp 1):107– 113. 11. Caves RE, Whinston MD, Hurwitz MA. Patent, expiration, entry, and competition in the US 3. Abbott TA. Price regulation in the pharmaceu- pharmaceutical industry. Brookings Papers on Economic tical industry: Prescription or placebo? J Health Econ Activity, Microeconomics 1991;1– 48. 1995;14:551–565. 12. US Congress, Office of Technology Assess- 4. Anis AH. Substitution law, insurance coverage, ment. Pharmaceutical R&D: Costs, risks and rewards. and generic drug use. Med Care 1994;32:240 –256. Washington DC: US Government Printing Office; 5. Anis AH. Pharmaceutical prices with insurance OTA-H- 1993:522. coverage and formularies. Can J Econ 1992;25:420 – 437. 13. Gordon JRM. Report of the Commission on the 6. Detsky A. Guidelines for economic analysis of pricing of multiple-source drug products in Ontario. pharmaceutical products: a draft document for Kingston, Ontario: Mimeo; 1984. Appendix APPENDIX A. TABLE 1. 70/90 Regulations: Legislative Framework Time Regulations May 1993 75/90 program was imposed under the Prescription Drug Cost Regulation Act (PDCRA) and the Ontario Drug Benefit Act (ODBA). According to the regulations, new first generic products were not designated and listed unless they were priced at or lower 75% of the equivalent brand name product. New second and subsequent generic products were not listed and designated unless priced at or below 90% of the lowest priced listed comparable product. Nov 1998 The new 70/90 Regulations were embraced under section 11 of Regulation 201/96 under the ODBA. And under Subsection 7(2) of Regulation 935 under the Drug Interchangeability and Dispensing Fee ACT (DIDFA) which, prior to May 27, 1996 was known as PDCRA. According to the amended regulations, the drug benefit price of new first generic products must be equal to or less than 70% of the price of the original products. Restrictions on the pricing of new second and subsequent generic products were maintained. 141
You can also read