Demographic and social changes: issues for the sixth central pay commission
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
special article Demographic and Social Changes: Issues for the Sixth Central Pay Commission Mukesh Anand, Saswata Chaudhury A Inadequate synchronisation of central government nalysis of expenditure on wages and salaries and pen- service and superannuation rules with a favourable sions and retirement benefits of central government (CG) employees, reveals that the proportion of the former has demographic structure and social developments gradually declined from above 90 per cent in 1950-51 to less may adversely affect labour and effort of government than 70 per cent in 2004-05 [Anand and Chaudhury 2007]. Thus employees. A slowdown in fresh recruitment has had a the quantum of deferred compensation has grown substan- negative impact on the system-dependency ratio and tially and current compensation accounts for a diminishing proportion of total remuneration. Further, this does not include the improvement in age-dependency has not resulted the medical benefits that would likely raise the proportion of in economic benefits. Some recent decisions may deferred compensation substantially [Nyce and Schieber 2005].1 exacerbate both inter- and intra-generational equity 1 Outline concerns in employees’ compensation. These may have The demographic change of specific concern, in this paper, relates implications for the cost and quality of public services. to age-distribution of population. Similarly, a relevant social change relates to increase in womens’ labour force participation. In several subtle ways, these changes impact the passivity ratio, dependency ratio and replacement ratio.2 Passivity ratio is the ratio of number of post-retirement years (until death) to number of working years; dependency ratio is the ratio of number of old (non-workers) to number of young (workers); replacement ratio is the ratio of compensation or payment in old age (non-working years) to the payment in youth (working years). These three para- metric ratios profoundly influence the sustainability of a pensions programme [Anand 2007; Whitehouse 2007]. These also carry signals that set incentives for individuals in exercising their choice of employment in government service. In Section 2, we highlight the relatively slow paced adjustment of normal age of superannu- ation to improvement in expectation of life. This has steadily raised passivity ratio in CG services. Improvement in longevity along with change in fertility impacts population age-distribution that, in turn, determines the dependency ratio. An analogy for (system) dependency in central government employees (CGE) is detailed in Section 3. Section 4 discusses liberalisation of superan- nuation benefits that has raised the proportion of deferred com- pensation (replacement ratio), in CG service, higher than ostensi- bly desired.3 Technological change induced skill requirement and change in womens’ labour force participation influence group and gender composition of CGE. These are discussed in Section 5. Sec- tion 6 concludes by highlighting additional issues concerning inter- and intra-generational equity. Mukesh Anand (manand@nipfp.org.in) is at the National Institute 2 Life Expectancy and Age of Superannuation of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi and Saswata Chaudhury Change in the normal age of superannuation in central govern- (som0303@gmail.com) is at the Indian Council for Research on ment service shows (Table 1, p 55) an increase of five years over a International Economic Relations, New Delhi. period of six decades. 54 february 16, 2008 EPW Economic & Political Weekly
special article The last increase in normal age of superannuation, by two probably raised the proportion of the elderly (60+ years) in the years, was introduced after almost four decades in 1998. In the population and gradually worsened old-age dependency ratio. In interim, significant improvements were achieved in expectation contrast, fertility decline in the last two decades has lowered the of life. Data from the Sample Registration System (SRS) [Regis- proportion of young dependents. Figure 3 depicts the population Table 1: Normal Age of trar General of India 2006] shows that, dependency ratio for two differing combinations of age groups. It Superannuation (years) expectation of life at birth was 49.7 years in portrays an improvement in (lowering of) dependency ratio, that Period Age 1975. This increased by 12.8 years to 62.5 is expected to bode well 1938 to 1962 55 years in 2002, an increase of almost 26 per for growth in output (and Table 2: Economic (or Worker) Dependency Ratio 1962 to May 13, 1998 58 Census NSSO cent in as many years (Panel A, Figure 1). hence income). Year Dependants Year Dependants May 13, 1998 onwards 60 Source: GoI (1997), Muthuswamy Over the same period expectation of life A more relevant measure Per 1000 Per 1000 Workers Workers PS + SS PS and Brinda (2002). at 60 increased by 3.4 years (from 13.8 to however, is the ratio of (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) 17.2, Panel B, Figure 1) and, that at 70 increased by 2.5 years number of non-workers 1961-62 1328 1977-78 1364 1695 (from 8.9 to 11.4), an increase of 25 and 28 per cent respectively.4 (non-earners) to number 1971-72 2037 1983-84 1381 1674 Slow adjustment of normal age of superannuation, in relation of workers (earners), that 1981-82 1725 1987-88 1427 1740 to improvement in life expectancy, is manifest in an increase in is, a measure of economic 1991-92 1667 1993-94 1381 1667 the number of pensioners drawing benefits (this is discussed dependency (Table 2). 2001-02 1558 1999-2000 1519 1740 further in the next section). Alternatively, this is an adverse In any case, economic 2003-04 1375 1625 Figure 1: Expectation of Life at Birth and at Age 60, Male and Female (in Years) dependency is much higher (1) PS, Principal Activity Status; SS, Subsidiary Activity Status. Panel B:B:At Age6060 (2) Census figures portray a decline in economic dependency 80 Panel A: At Birth 20 Panel At Age 2002 (worse) than age-depend- over the past four decades. However, such a trend is not seen 60 1991 2002 1991 2002 15 1991 2002 1991 1971 ency. Segregating the in National Sample Survey Organisation data, especially upon 1971 excluding workers with subsidiary status (col 5). 1971 1971 1951 1951 population into the age Source: Authors’ own computations. Basic Data: Census of India; 40 1951 1951 10 groups 0-19, 20-64 and GoI (2001, 2005). 20 5 65-plus (instead of 0-14, 0 0 Male Female Male 1 Female 2 15-59 and 60-plus) years raises (that is, worsens) the age-depend- 1 2 Figure pertains to five year moving average ending with year shown. ency ratio, but it is still far below the estimate for economic Source: GoI 2005; Census of India 2001 (Population Projections). dependency (compare Table 2 and unshaded bars in Figure 3). outcome of a rapid increase in the passivity ratio5 that profoundly However, any realistic assessment of dependency should account impacts the proportion of expenditure on present and ex-employ- for a gradual shifting out of average age of entry into the labour ees. An increase in the passivity ratio, ceteris paribus under a force, as well as the likelihood of a longer spell in the labour defined benefit (DB) system of pensions, would continually raise force, commensurate with improvements in average educa- the proportion of deferred compensation. On the contrary, under tional achievement, health and longevity. a defined contribution (DC) system, it re-exposes individuals to longevity risk.6 Public policy, therefore, should devise acceptable 4 Retirement Benefits and Replacement Ratio norms to circumscribe passivity (see Table A1, p 57). In addition, The rules governing retirement benefits for CG employees have the passivity ratio based on superannuating pensioners only, may been continually liberalised and the social security net has be an underestimate as it is unadjusted for survivor pensioners. expanded (Table B1, p 57). Not only the quantum of benefits, These and other issues relating to liberalisation of retirement but also the domain of beneficiaries has been expanded. benefits are discussed in Section 4. Figure 2: Growth of Total Population and of Elderly While improved estimates are desirable, 2.4 7 crude projections suggest that, for an 3 Elderly Population and 1.9 Annual average growth individual, deferred component con preceding decade 6.5 Dependency Ratio (%, left scale) stitutes more than one-third of total life- 1.4 Over the last century, the population has 6 time compensation. If one includes 0.9 Annual average growth grown at an average annual rate of 1.47 since 1901 (%, left scale) 5.5 medical benefits, then perhaps the 0.4 per cent per annum. However, the 60 + population (%, of total, right scale) deferred component may be upward of -0.1 5 compounded annual average growth rate 1901 1921 1941 1961 1981 2001 two-fifths. Coupled with secure service (CAGR) of 0.83 per cent between 1901 Source: Authors’ own computations, Basic Data: Singh et al 1989; Census of India. conditions, such a structure of com and 1951, was significantly lower than Figure 3: Age Dependency Ratio (per thousand persons) pensation leads to perverse incentives 2.11 per cent between 1951 and 2001. The 1991 and perhaps induces conservatism in growth in population was at its peak 2001 work effort. acceleration in the 1950s. The rate 2011 Inadequate appreciation of the fiscal plateaued in 1960s and, has declined 2021 impact of the change in rules governing since then (left-hand scale in Figure 2). 2026 retirement benefits appears as a major High fertility rates around the middle lacuna. The Fifth Pay Commission (FPC) 0 200 400 600 800 1000 1200 of the last century combined with 0-14 and 60 + 0-19 and 65 + had recommended raising the proportion improvement in expectation of life at Dependency per thousand persons between 15-59 (20-64) years. of commutation to 40 per cent of pension Source: Authors’ own computations. Basic Data: Census of India 2001 (Population older ages, (Panel B, Figure 1) has Projections). and to reduce length of restoration Economic & Political Weekly EPW february 16, 2008 55
speciAl article period to 12 years. The latter though was left unchanged at superannuation. Thus, w idening the domain of the social 15 years. It is likely that in the last few years a significant security net is likely to have a multiplicative effect on the effec- proportion of pensioners have become eligible for restoration tive replacement ratio.8 of the commuted amount. While no confirmed data is availa- ble, this is arguable given that life expectancy at age 60 5 Gender and Group Composition exceeds 15 years (Figure 1, Panel B). The discussion in the preceding sections focused on age Table 3: Replacement Ratio: Moreover India, perhaps, is the only (demographic) dimension. However several social changes have CG Employees Joining Service in 1961-62 (in %) (or, one of few) country(ies) that also occurred in the interim. Two such changes are likely to Age of allows for such restoration of contribute significantly towards correcting intra-generational Superannuation 60 62 65 Age of Joining commuted amounts. inequity. The first relates to increase in women’s participation, Service While not a precise representation, and second to changes in structural composition of CG 23 53 43 30 Tables 3 and 4 present replacement workforce. 25 55 44 31 ratios for two differing hypothetical 27 55 46 32 cases of individuals in CG services. 5.1 Women’s Participation Source: Authors’ own computation. The average (annual) salary is The proportion of women workers in CG civilian services in Table 4: Replacement Ratio: CG projected, based on trend rate of 1979-80, 1980-81 and 1981-82 was (roughly) 3.53, 3.64 and 3.80 Employees Retiring in 2002-03 (in %) growth (3.54 per cent per annum per cent respectively [GoI 1991]. As per the report of the FPC, Age of at constant 1999-2000 prices) of there were 2.83 lakh women workers constituting 7.51 per cent of Superannuation 60 62 65 average salary compensation between CG civilian workers. It is likely that, in the intervening period Age of Joining 1961-62 and 2002-03 [Anand and since 1993-94, the number of women workers in CG services has Service 23 57 47 34 Chaudhury 2007]. The annual increased. But, the occupational exigencies of its largest two 25 59 48 35 average pension payment is estimated employers, namely, railways and defence may be inhibiting, even 27 61 50 36 as 50 per cent of current wage if newer vistas are also opening up there for women. Source: Authors’ own computation. compensation.7 Replacement ratios As per the latest data (for the year 2002) from the SRS [Regis- are estimated as cumulated deferred trar General of India 2006], life expectancy at birth for females compensation during years in retirement as a ratio of cumulated exceeds that for males by about Table 5: Difference in Life Expectancy salary compensation. 1.7 years (Table 5). (Years) at Various Ages, 2002 Table 3 pertains to individuals of differing ages joining service In India, the normal age of Age At Birth 20 30 60 70 (Female minus Male) on the same date in 1961-62 and Table 4 pertains to individuals superannuation is identical for Expectation of Life 1.7 3.1 3.3 2.0 1.3 retiring on the same date in 2002-03. Along the columns of each males and females (gender Source: Authors’ own computations; Basic Data: Same table, one may read-off the replacement ratio for individuals neutrality).9 Ceteris paribus, as Figure 1. joining service at differing ages, given some mandatory age of an increase in proportion of females, in CG employment, is likely superannuation (60, 62 or 65 years). Conversely, figures along to raise replacement ratio, largely due to some increase in average the rows are replacement ratios for individuals joining service at passivity ratio. a particular age but retiring at differing mandatory age of super- Wider participation of women is likely to improve (lower) the annuation. The replacement ratio along a column increases economic dependency ratio. Further, there is significant evidence largely due to an increase in passivity ratio. On the contrary, that an increase in female labour force participation boosts movement along a row mimics a decline in passivity, inducing a economic growth and development [Nyce and Schieber 2005]. decline in the replacement ratio. However, if not complemented adequately with enabling provi- For ease of exposition, assume that expectation of life, at sions, there is the likelihood of an adverse impact on fertility. age 60, is 15 years for those joining service in 1961-62. The This in turn may have an adverse impact on future economic corresponding expectation of life for those retiring in 2002-03 dependency ratio. is 16 years. Between Tables 3 and 4, one observes an increase in t he replacement ratio for the corresponding cells. Note 5.2 Group Composition that an improvement in expectation of life by one year, without The size of CGE expanded in 1960s and early 1970s (Figure 4). any change in the mandatory age of superannuation, raises This bulge, in employee intake then, has likely resulted in a the passivity ratio and consequently ballooning number of superannuating the replacement ratio. Note also that Figure 4: Number of Public Sector Workers (in lakhs) pensioners in the 1990s. While a more 80 these are conservative estimates of detailed study is desirable, past employ- expectation of life and thus provide a 60 State government ment trends hint that growth in number Quasi government lower bound for the true replace Central government of pensioners from CG services maybe ment ratio. Given our assumptions, 40 plateauing soon. This is also borne out ceteris paribus, a one-year improve 20 by relatively slow growth in pension ment in expectation of life raises the Local bodies expenditure in recent years, even if replacement ratio by approximately 4 0 1960-61 1966-67 1972-73 1978-79 1984-85 1990-91 1996-97 2002-03 improvement in expectation of life has per cent, for a given mandatory age of Source: GoI 2005. led to cumulation of pensioners. 56 february 16, 2008 EPW Economic & Political Weekly
special article Importantly, the structure of CGE has undergone perceptible Annexure A: Hypothetical Scenarios to Estimate Passivity Ratio change over the decades. Technological advancement has We assume that an average worker in the year 1921 joined civilian induced a decline in number and proportion of group D service at age 20. Corresponding age on joining service is 22 and 25 employees, especially in civilian services from 56.30 per cent years respectively in 1963 and 2006. The fourth example is of a de- in 1957 to 27.27 per cent in 1994 [GoI 1997: 230). It is likely fence personnel joining service at a relatively lower age. Table A1 then tracks these individuals, assuming that each worker provides full that this proportion would continue to decline. On the other service up to normal age of retirement (reduced for defence person- hand, there has been a rapid expansion in number of group C nel) [Unnithan 2007] and lives full average expected life. employees, with sanctioned posts almost quadrupling between Note that full-service period is rendered ineffective in all cases, as 1957 and 1994. expected working life upon joining service is longer than full service In the medium term, it is likely that need for group B period. To encourage merit, increase in full service period stipulation may need to exceed increase in the age of retirement. workers may rise. The (observed) average age on joining Table A1: Hypothetical Central Government Employee service is likely to be higher in upper hierarchical groups. But Attribute Civil Defence employees, especially in group A, also move along a steeper I II III IV compensation profile. Ceteris paribus, therefore an increase in Date of birth July 1, 1901 July 1, 1941 July 1, 1981 July 1, 1981 the proportion of employees in upper hierarchical groups Age at joining service (years) 20 22 25 18 would gradually push up the per worker (average) cost of govern- Date of joining service July 1, 1921 July 1, 1963 July 1, 2006 July 1, 1999 ment employment. While our estimates of the replacement ratio Normal age of superannuation upon are based on average current compensation, most pensioners joining service (years) 55 58 60 40 Expected date of retirement July 1956 July 1999 July 2041 July 2021 derive benefits based on compensation that are likely closer to Expected working life 35 36 35 22 maximum of the range (for a group). This is likely to raise replace- Expectation of life at birth (years) ~ 24 ~ 32 ~ 54 ~54 ment ratio further. Expectation of life on joining service (years) ~ 25 ~ 36 ~ 42 ~49 Change in normal age of superannuation No Change 60 (in No Change No Change 6 Conclusions May 1998) The FPC alluded to right-sizing of CGE and had also indicated Actual working life No Change 38 No Change No Change existing slack, leading to over employment and therefore ineffi- Date of retirement July 1956 July 2001 July 2041 July 2021 ciency (in terms of costs) of government operations. Figure 4 Full service period (years) 30 33 33 suggests that decline in the number of employees had started Expectation of life upon retirement ~ 14 ~ 16 ~ 20 ~ 33 Passivity ratio-narrow (PR-N = years in earlier, but gained acceleration in the post-FPC era. retirement/years of work) 0.40 0.42 0.57 ~ 1.5 Most public services directly impacting daily life are in the Passivity ratio-broad (PR-B = non-earning domain of the states, but a whittled down size of CG may not be years/earning years) 0.97 1.00 1.29 ~ 2.3 able to provide the requisite level or quality of service for Expectation of life figures relates to males. However, there are marked differences in life expectancy between males and females, and between rural and urban areas. presently expanding population. Anecdotal evidence indicates the growing incidence of ad hoc appointments encouraging infor- Annexure B: Liberalisation of Retirement Benefits malisation and largely directed at denial of social security and Table 1 enlists some attributes reflecting liberalisation of rules governing retirement benefits. No rule signalling stringency could be deciphered. retirement benefits. This creates more classes of employees than Table B1 envisaged, and obscures expenditures relating to employee Attribute Pre-FPC Pensioner Post-FPC Pensioner compensation in government service. Pension ceiling 4,500 INR per month 50% of highest pay The slowdown in new recruitment raises the average age of Parity in respect of old pensioners No 50% of the revised scale for all current workers. In addition, an improvement in life expectancy, pensioners beyond the age of retirement, adversely impacts the system Gratuity ceiling 2.5 lakh INR 3.5 lakh INR dependency ratio. For any given age of superannuation, maintain- Gratuity calculation includes dearness allowance No Yes ing the number of employees, by hiring fresh recruits at the rate Commutation proportion one-third 40% of new retirees, may have an adverse impact on expenditure Dearness relief 50%, partial relief for 100% neutralisation for all towards employees’ compensation. Given the cornucopia of family pensioners penioners retirement benefits (gratuity, leave encashment, commutation of Family pension rate(s) Slabs of 30, 20 and 15% Uniform 30% pension, etc) rough estimates suggest that (deferred) compensa- Family pension ceiling 1,250 INR per month 30% of pay for all categories tion received in the first year of retirement exceeds thrice the Dependant parents, widowed/ Not eligible for family “included in the definition of final year salary compensation. Further, given the extant pay divorced daughters pension family” for purpose of family pension structure, it is likely that total wage compensation to a young Dearness relief for re-employed entrant in a given group, may be less than compensation of a new pensioners and employed family retiree from that group. pensioners Not permitted Allowed The rules governing deferred compensation should be Medical allowance Nil 100 INR for eligible pensioners not covered under urgently amended incorporating favourable demographic CGHS developments. In particular, extant full service stipulation of Leave encashment up to 240 days up to 300 days 33 years appears to be redundant, when it is easily exceeded by INR, Indian Rupees Source: GoI 2002. the average (expected) working life. However, more debate Economic & Political Weekly EPW february 16, 2008 57
speciAl article should precede an upward revision of this stipulation, to vulnerability in ensuring adequate provisioning for old age incentivise service period contribution as also productivity and expenditure needs. Whether this holds incentive, to attract and efficiency. retain merit, appears questionable. The issue of inter-genera- tional equity calls for some balance between current and deferred Circumscribing Inequality compensation. The maxim of “one-post one-pay” (or one-rank In sharp contrast to the former defined benefit (DB) pension plan, one-pay) appears to be grossly violated not only between workers new recruits in (non-military) government service from January and retirees, but also among current workers. 1, 2004, are members of a defined contribution (DC) pension plan. Responsible governments should ensure that those employed Under the DC plan of the new pension system (NPS), individuals by them are empowered with sufficient financial capacity for a mandatorily contribute 10 per cent of their pay, matched by an decent living. While there is little likelihood of a consensus on equal contribution by government into an individual retirement a desirable ratio between the maximum and minimum pay account. While employer’s contribution adds to government’s (disparity ratio), circumscribing inequality is desirable for present expenditure, individual contribution lowers the net pragmatic reasons. The disparity ratio varied between 54.5 and present remuneration of new recruits as compared to those in 37.5 during the spell of the First Pay Commission, and was service before January 1, 2004. This drives a wedge in current brought down to 10.7 by the Fourth Pay Commission [GoI 1973 compensation of present workers. and 1997]. The FPC retained this ratio, but care should be In the extant form deferred remuneration of new recruits is exercised that there ought to be sufficient disincentives to prevent inadequately assured. Pre-funding strategy of the NPS, pending dilution in the hierarchical relationships for smooth functioning the passage of the Pension Fund Regulatory and Development of government machinery (both, across public and private Authority bill by Parliament, fails to ameliorate individual sectors, as well as within public sector). Notes 9 In several countries [Castel and Fox 2001] on the Unit, Department of Expenditure, Ministry of contrary, it is lower, for females, for example, Finance, New Delhi. 1 Lifetime healthcare costs tend to cluster dispro- Kazakhstan, Kyrgyz Republic, Latvia, Moldova. – (1997): Report of the Fifth Central Pay Commis- portionately in a relatively brief period before death. sion, Ministry of Finance, New Delhi, January. 2 Several variants may be used while estimating References – (2001): An Assessment of Government of India’s these ratios. For example, passivity ratio may be Pensionary Liability, Ministry of Finance, p 8. Anand, Mukesh (2007): ‘Pensions’ in Kaushik Basu (ed), – (2002): Report of the High Level Expert Group on the ratio of the sum of years until joining the work The Oxford Companion to Economics in India, Pensions, Ministry of Finance, New Delhi. force and years in retirement, to number of work- Oxford University Press, New Delhi, India, pp 391-94. ing years, dependency ratio may be the ratio of – (2005): Statistical Abstract, India, 2004, Central non-earners to earners, replacement ratio may Anand, Mukesh and Saswata Chaudhury (2007): Statistical Organisation, Ministry of Statistics be the ratio of net (of taxes) compensation during ‘Government Employment and Employees’ Com- and Programme Implementation, New Delhi, non-working years to net compensation during pensation: Some Contours for the Sixth Central October. working years, etc. Pay Commission’, Economic & Political Weekly, Volume XLII, No 31, August 4-10, pp 3225-32. – (2001, 2005): Report Number 506 and 458, 3 The report of the High Level Expert Group [GoI National Sample Survey Organisation, Ministry 2002] also lamented that “This has resulted in en- Castel, Paulette and Louise Fox (2001): ‘Gender Dimen- of Statistics and Programme Implementation, hanced benefits than what a government servant is sions of Pension Reforms in the Former Soviet New Delhi. entitled to on retirement...”, especially in the con- Union’, Ch 12 in Holzmann Robert and Joseph E Stiglitz (eds), New Ideas About Old Age Security: Muthuswamy, P and V Brinda (2002): Swamy’s text of restoration of commuted value of pensions, Pension Compilation Incorporating CCS Pension Towards Sustainable Pension Systems in the para 2.11, page 16, draft report of January 2002. Rules, Swamy Publishers (P) Ltd. 21st Century, World Bank, Washington DC, 4 In the beginning of the 20th century, expectation pp 424-51. Nyce, Steven A and Sylester J Schieber (2005): The of life at birth, in India, was less than 25 years, al- Economic Implications of Aging Societies: The Costs Census of India (1961, 1971, 1981, 1991, 2001): Final most the same as at age 30. For nearly half a cen- of Living Happily Ever After, Cambridge University Population Totals, Registrar General and Census tury, expectation of life at age 20 was higher than Press. Commissioner, India. that at birth. Further, expectation of life, at all – (2001): Population Projections for India and Registrar General of India (2006): Statistical Report ages, registered a secular decline for nearly three States 2001-26, Office of the Registrar General 2006, Sample Registration System, India. decades in the beginning of last century. The per- ilous situation was reversed only in the census of and Census Commissioner, India. Unnithan, Sandeep (2007): ‘Defence: The Talent 1931. Since then expectation of life, at all ages, GoI (1973): Report of the Third Central Pay Commis- Marches Out’, India Today, April 23, pp 34-36. has improved continually and significantly. sion, Ministry of Finance, New Delhi, March. Whitehouse, Edward (2007): Pensions Panorama: 5 Broadly defined, passivity ratio constitutes sum of – (1991): Brochure on Pay and Allowances of Central Retirement-Income Systems in 53 Countries, World two phase components, one prior to entering la- Government Civilian Employees, Pay Research Bank, Washington DC. bour force and another upon exiting from it. The latter component pertains to (prevalent) narrow definition. 6 This connotes a situation where people outlive savings cumulated during their income-earning years. 7 The ostensible rule for pension payments ensures Unbound Back Volumes of Economic and Political Weekly from 1976 to 2007 are available. a monthly pension of 50 per cent of emoluments (calculated as average emoluments for last 10 Write to: months before retirement) upon completion of full service (currently stipulated at 33 years). However, this is likely an underestimate, as Circulation Department, Anand and Chaudhury (2007) show that support Economic and Political Weekly ratio (average pension/average salary) has risen rapidly from 38 per cent in 1990-91 to 56 per cent Hitkari House, 284 Shahid Bhagat Singh Road, by 1999-2000. Mumbai 400 001. 8 Replacement ratio estimated as a ratio of cumu- lated net (of tax) receipts, during and prior to Circulation@epw.org.in retirement, is likely to be higher. 58 february 16, 2008 EPW Economic & Political Weekly
You can also read