Brexit - potential economic consequences if the UK exits the EU - Global Economic Dynamics (GED)
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Brexit – potential economic Policy Brief # 2015/05 consequences if the UK exits the EU If the United Kingdom (UK) exits the EU in 2018, it would reduce that country’s exports and make imports more ex- pensive. Depending on the extent of trade policy isolation, the UK’s real gross domestic product (GDP) per capita would be between 0.6 and 3.0 percent lower in the year 2030 Dr. Ulrich Schoof Program than if the country remained in the EU. If we take into ac- Shaping Sustainable Economies count the dynamic effects that economic integration has on Phone: investment and innovation behavior, the GDP losses could +49 5241 81-81384 Email: rise to 14 percent. In addition, it will bring unforeseeable po- ulrich.schoof@ bertelsmann- litical disadvantages for the EU – so from our perspective, stiftung.de we must avoid a Brexit. Dr. Thieß Petersen Program Shaping Sustainable Economies Phone: Focus +49 5241 81-81218 Depending on the extent of trade isolation Email: thiess.petersen@ resulting from a Brexit, the deadweight bertelsmann- welfare losses would differ for the remain- stiftung.de ing EU member states. For example, Ger- Dr. Rahel Aichele many’s real GDP per capita would be be- ifo Institut München tween 0.1 and 0.3 percent lower in 2030 Phone: than without a Brexit due to the decline in +49 89 9442-1275 trade activities. These static deadweight Email: welfare effects are compounded by dy- aichele@ifo.de namic effects that could cause a drop in Prof. Gabriel the GDP in Germany by up to 2 percent. Felbermayr, Ph.D. ifo Institut München Phone: +49 89 9442-1428 Email: felbermayr@ifo.de
Future Social Market Economy Policy Brief # 2015/05 Since the UK joined the European Com- being overwhelmed are also fueling anxi- munity in 1973, its relationship to the rest ety in the population. In addition, people of Europe and the European Union (EU) are questioning whether EU membership has been tense, ranging from critical to offers any benefits at all for their own aloof. It already held a referendum in 1975 country (see Beichelt 2010 and Peters on whether to remain in the European 2014). Community. In 1984, Prime Minister Mar- garet Thatcher spoke the now legendary Harboring doubts about the advantages of words, “I want my money back!” – and ob- a common Europe is not just unique to the tained a rebate on British contributions to British. However, the EU is facing the the EU budget that is honored to this day greatest skepticism in the UK. At the end (see Freund/Schwarzer 2011). The UK still of 2014, the market research network has not signed off on the Schengen Agree- WIN/Gallup International conducted a rep- ment, which took effect 1995 and abol- resentative population survey in 11 EU ished border checks between the participat- countries. Among other things, it asked ing EU countries. how the citizens would vote if a referen- dum were held in »Brexit«, the term coined by the media from the words “Brit- their country on re- ain” and “exit”, is misleading in that Britain would not be exit- maining in the EU. ing the EU, but rather the United Kingdom, which includes 64 percent of those England, Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland. The geograph- surveyed in the 11 ical term “British Isles” also encompasses Ireland, which is not member countries debating whether to leave the EU. The terms “UK” and “Brit- supported staying in ish” are used synonymously in this text. For example, when we the EU. The desire to talk about the British GDP, we mean the GDP of the United continue EU mem- Kingdom (UK). bership prevailed in 10 countries. In Ger- The UK is by no means the only country many, approval was at 73 percent. In the with voices critical of the EU. Parties in UK, a scant majority of 51 percent sup- other member states such as “Die (wahren) ported exiting the EU (see Euractiv.de Finnen,” the “Alternative für Deutsch- 2015). land,” Italy’s “Lega Nord” and the “Partij voor de Vrijheid” headed by Dutch right- In light of this fundamentally critical atti- wing populist Geert Wilders are EU-skep- tude, it is not surprising that the UK has yet tic movements that are gaining traction (see again been discussing an EU referendum Peters 2014, pg. 10 as well as Hoffmann for some time. British Prime Minister Da- 2014, pp. 2-10). There are a variety of rea- vid Cameron announced in January 2013 sons for rejecting the EU. The most im- that he would allow such a referendum if portant of these include the fear of losing he is reelected (see The Conservative Party national identity and sovereignty, concerns Manifesto 2015, pg. 72). The Labour Party about overregulation by the EU through as well as the Liberal Democrats reject this transferring too much power to Brussels, referendum. and high net payments to the Community. High immigration levels from other EU member states accompanied by the loss of the country’s own culture, rising unem- ployment and the social security systems 02
Future Social Market Economy Policy Brief # 2015/05 EU members would no longer apply. The 1. Economic effects of a EU’s trade agreements – currently 38 ac- Brexit on the UK tive agreements and 12 agreements still in negotiation – would be invalid. Many areas of government, some of which fall under The question of whether a British exit from the EU’s jurisdiction, would need to be ad- the EU would increase or decrease the justed or re-established. For those reasons, country’s economic growth and its real in- there is a great deal of uncertainty regard- come as measured by the gross domestic ing the specific consequences under inter- product is controversial. There is a whole national law of a country exiting the EU. series of studies that examine the economic Therefore, quantifying the economic ef- advantages and disadvantages of EU mem- fects of this exit can only be approximate bership – and yield a variety of different re- and heavily driven by assumptions. To il- sults. A study by the Open Europe Think lustrate these uncertainties, we present the Tank, a group critical of Brussels, reaches following three scenarios in which the ifo the following conclusion: If the UK exits Institute has calculated the effects on GDP the EU on January 1, 2018, the GDP in using a variety of empirical simulation 2030 would be 2.2 percent lower than if it techniques. Unlike the above-mentioned remained in the EU (in its least favorable studies, it determines not only effects on scenario). In the most favorable case, a the UK, but the consequences for the rest higher GDP of around 1.6 percent is possi- of the world and Germany as well. In all ble. The politically realistic range of three scenarios, the UK loses its trade priv- growth effects from exiting the EU would ileges with the EU: come in between 0.6 percent higher and 0.8 1. In the most favorable case from the percent lower GDP (see Persson et al 2015, British perspective (“soft exit”), the UK pg. 2). The Center for Financial Studies receives a status similar to that of Swit- calculates a loss of prosperity for the UK zerland or Norway and thereby has a even under optimistic assumptions. Ac- trade agreement with the EU. While cording to it, the real GDP losses – taking there would be non-tariff barriers to into account the savings from payments not trade, there would be no tariffs. made to the EU budget – would lie between 2. In the second most favorable scenario 1.1 and 3.1 percent. If dynamic effects are (“deep cut”), this trade agreement does also taken into consideration, meaning low not exist. As a result, there are higher productivity growth resulting from exiting non-tariff barriers to trade as well as to the EU, income drops of 6.3 to 9.5 percent tariffs in trade between the UK and EU. are conceivable (see Ottaviano et al 2014, These tariffs reach the level found in pp. 8-11). foreign trade relations between the EU and USA. The problem lies in the fact that the results 3. In the least favorable scenario (“isola- of simulation calculations depend substan- tion of the UK”), the country also loses tially on the underlying assumptions of all privileges arising from the EU’s 38 how the UK would organize its relations existing trade agreements with other with the remaining EU states and other countries. Although the UK can reach trade partners after a Brexit. Exiting the EU new trade agreements through inde- can have far-reaching consequences: The pendent negotiations, experience has four basic freedoms of the European do- shown that this is a lengthy process. mestic market (free movement of goods, Moreover, the UK’s negotiating power services, capital and people) with the other would be less than that of the EU. 03
Future Social Market Economy Policy Brief # 2015/05 All of these scenarios show an increase in gree of assumed trade isolation, real in- the cost of British exports as well as for im- come losses for the British economy range ported consumer goods and advance pay- between 0.6 and 3 percent. The severity of ments. Declining exports and rising prices the impact will differ for individual indus- result in a downturn in economic activities tries. In particular, the chemicals, mechan- and a lower real GDP. ical engineering and automotive industries will see steep losses in value added because Aside from the economic disadvantages of they are heavily incorporated in European exiting the EU, we must also take into ac- value chains. The chemicals industry will count the canceled annual payments to the face the greatest drop – nearly 11 percent. EU budget. In 2013, the net contribution For the more important area of financial that the UK paid to the EU was approxi- services, anticipated losses in value added mately €8.64 billion, or around 0.5 percent reach around 5 percent in the unfavorable of British economic strength as measured scenario. by the GDP. Savings from canceling these payments represent the UK’s greatest eco- The losses in income shown above result nomic benefit from a Brexit. exclusively from lower trade levels due to a Brexit. However, the dynamic effects must also be taken into account in addition 2. EU exit would damage to these static effects. The following two aspects are among the most important: British economic growth 1. Declining cross-border trade activities also have a negative impact on a coun- The UK is closely intertwined economi- try’s productivity growth: If the pres- cally with the EU. Currently, more than 50 sure from international competition percent of British exports go to EU mem- weakens, domestic companies have less ber states. Over 50 percent of the country’s need to improve their competitiveness imports also come from the EU. In the mid- through investments and innovation. 1960s, these were both significantly less Therefore, productivity growth falls. than 40%. According to studies that estimate the influence of de- The terms “loss of income” or “GDP losses” describe the differ- creasing trade ence expressed in percentages between the observed real GDP in openness on the the base year (2014) and the simulated (counterfactual) value for long-term real a situation in which the UK is not an EU member. Based on expe- GDP (Freyer 2009 rience, trade policy measures take 10 to 12 years after they are and Felber- introduced to reach full effect. If a Brexit occurs in 2018, the high- mayr/Gröschl lighted effects would be fully felt by 2030. No prognosis is made 2013), a Brexit for global GDP numbers with and without a Brexit for the year could lead to a 2030 due to the associated additional uncertainties. long-term drop in the UK’s real Exiting the EU would increase the costs of GDP per capita ranging from 2 percent trade between the UK and EU and reduce (“soft exit”) to 14 percent (“deep cut”) bilateral trade activities. The specific ex- compared to remaining in the EU. tent of associated changes in real income is 2. The EU is currently in negotiation with shown for the selected countries in the fo- a number of countries on bilateral free cus graphic (pg. 1). Depending on the de- trade agreements that are close to ratifi- 04
between 0.8 and 2.7 percent. Other coun- Future Social Market Economy Policy Brief # 2015/05 cation (Canada, USA, Japan, Singa- pore, India, Malaysia, Vietnam, etc.). tries that would see above average GDP The EU is expecting positive growth drops include Luxembourg, Belgium and momentum from the accompanying Sweden as well as Malta and Cyprus, heavier trade integration. By exiting the which are not shown in the focus graphic. EU, the UK would forgo this impetus Germany’s static deadweight welfare for growth. The long-term GDP losses losses described above would lie slightly associated with this would range from below the EU-27 average. 1.4 percent in case of a soft exit to 7.5 percent with a deep cut scenario. If the dynamic effects of a Brexit are taken into account, the impact is greater: De- pending on the Brexit scenario and under- 3. The Brexit’s economic lying econometric estimates, the long-term real GDP per capita in Germany would effects on Germany and range between 0.3 and 2 percent below the Europe value projected if the UK were to remain in the EU. If the UK’s economic growth slows down In addition, we must also take into consid- due to exiting the EU, this also has eco- eration that the remaining EU member nomic consequences for its trade partners. states would need to compensate for the A lower real income leads to declining de- lost British contributions to the EU budget mand for goods and services – and also for in case of a Brexit. For Germany that imports. For trade partners, this means would add approximately €2.5 billion lower exports and therefore lower produc- (gross) to its annual expenditures. France tion as well. Nevertheless, the GDP losses would have to pay an additional €1.9 bil- for the rest of the world are relatively mod- lion, Italy almost €1.4 billion and Spain erate compared to the economic disad- around €0.9 billion (see Fig. 1). vantages for the UK. For example, the ef- fects of decreasing trade activities in Ger- many (static effects, see focus graphic, pg. 4. Assessment and outlook 1) would be relatively minor with a real GDP per capita drop of 0.1 to 0.3 percent The assessments presented here regarding in the year 2030. Individual industries the costs of the UK exiting the EU are as- would be impacted differently by lower ex- sociated with significant uncertainties. No ports to the UK. The automotive industry one knows what the international economic would see the greatest drop in value added relationships between the UK and the rest by sector with a decline of up to 2 percent. would look like should the UK leave the EU. However, it is certain that the UK’s in- For the entire remaining EU-27 (without tegration in the global economy would de- the UK), the expected reduction in real cline and that this de-integration would GDP per capita due to lower trade activity shrink British economic growth. with the UK would fall between 0.1 percent with a soft Brexit and around 0.4 percent in Although these deadweight welfare losses case of UK isolation, although significant are countered by savings in the form of regional differences would emerge (see fo- canceled contributions to the EU budget, cus graphic, pg. 1). Ireland would be hit according to the calculations presented particularly hard with real income losses of here even the most favorable scenario from 05
the British perspective (soft exit with ex- The economic weakening of the British Future Social Market Economy Policy Brief # 2015/05 clusively static effects) yields expected economy would also have consequences GDP losses of around 0.6 percent, which is for the remaining EU countries. Even if higher than the savings from the net pay- real income losses there fall below the UK ments to the EU budget of around 0.5 per- values, costs would arise from a lower cent of the GDP. Even in this case, a Brexit GDP growth and the need to compensate clearly poses an economic loss for the UK. for lost British contributions to the EU With more severe economic isolation and budget. taking into account the dynamic effects (shrinking productivity growth resulting Beyond the purely economic considera- from lower competitive pressure, departure tions, the political disadvantages must be of EU migrants, declining investment due taken into account. A Brexit would be a to less freedom of movement for capital significant setback for European integra- transactions), the GDP losses are signifi- tion and would inevitably weaken the EU. cantly higher. In the worst case scenario, the UK’s real GDP per capita in 2030 could Therefore, we are firmly convinced that the be 14 percent lower than if it remained in combination of economic and political dis- the EU. Even if such extreme isolation is advantages of the UK exiting the EU would politically rather unlikely from our per- be detrimental for everyone involved and spective, this theoretically conceivable must be avoided. value shows how heavily the UK’s eco- nomic growth would depend on trade policy goodwill after a Brexit. The lost growth effects from future EU free-trade agreements are not even taken into consid- eration here. 06
Literature Future Social Market Economy Policy Brief # 2015/05 • Persson, M. et al: What if …? The Con- sequences, challenges & opportunities • Auswärtiges Amt (Dept. of Foreign Af- facing Britain outside EU, Open Europe fairs): Schengen Agreement Report 03/2015, London/Brussels/Berlin (http://www.auswaertiges- 2015. amt.de/DE/EinreiseUndAufen- thalt/Schengen_node.html, download on • Peters, M.: Demokratie durch Kritik: 04.13.2015). Wider die EU-Skepsis, in: Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte, year 64, 12/2014 from • Beichelt, T.: EU-Skepsis als Aneignung 03.17.2014, pp. 37 - 41. europäischer Politik, in: Berliner Debatte Initial, year 21, issue 2, 2010, pp. 3 - 16. • The Conservative Party Manifesto 2015 (http://www.conservativehome.com/wp- • Euractiv.de: Survey: Nur Briten sind content/uploads/2015/04/Conservative- mehrheitlich für EU-Austritt, published on Manifesto2015.pdf, download on 01.18.2015 (http://www.euractiv.de/sec- 04.21.2015). tions/europawahlen-2014/umfrage-nur- briten-sind-mehrheitlich-fuer-eu-austritt- 311136, download on 04.10.2015). • Felbermayr, G./Gröschl, J.: Natural Dis- asters and the Effect of Trade on Income: A New Panel IV Approach, in: European Economic Review, year 58, 2013, pp. 18 – 30. • Freund, M./Schwarzer, J.: Die britische Diva, Handelsblatt online dated 12.12.2011 (http://www.handels- blatt.com/politik/international/sonderwu- ensche-aus-london-die-britische- diva/5949160.html, download on 04.13.2015). • Freyer, J.: Trade and Income – Exploit- ing Time Series in Geography, NBER Working Paper 14910, Cambridge, MA 2009. • Hoffmann, I.: Im Netz der Populisten, spotlight europe 2014/02, Gütersloh 2014. • Ottaviano, G. et al: The Costs and Bene- fits of Leaving the EU, CFS Working Pa- per Series No. 472, Frankfurt am Main 2014. 07
Policy Brief 2015/03: Wage inequality in Germany – Future Social Market Economy Policy Brief # 2015/05 What role does global trade play? Wage inequality in Germany has increased significantly since the mid-1990s. The intensification of international trade relations is a frequently cited cause for this issue. However, an empirical study revealed that global trade can only directly explain around 15 percent of the increase in wage inequality in Germany. Primarily, the growing heterogeneity among companies in Germany plays a greater role. The decline in collective bargaining is the primary company-specific driver of wage inequality. Nevertheless, protec- tionist measures would not be effective for achieving greater wage equality. Policy Brief 2015/04: Labour Mobility in Europe – An untapped resource? Despite the public perception in many member states, intra-EU migration remains low. The limits to the potential of labour mo- bility became evident during the economic crisis as high unem- ployment rates in the periphery have only caused limited mobility from crisis countries. Hence, the bulk of labour mobility still flows from east to west. The Commission and member states should improve existing tools for cross-border job matching and adopt a longer-term view on labour mobility. V.i.S.d.P Upcoming releases: Bertelsmann Stiftung Carl-Bertelsmann-Straße 256 • ??? D-33311 Gütersloh www.bertelsmann-stiftung.de Dr. Thieß Petersen Phone: +49 5241 81-81218 thiess.petersen@bertelsmann-stiftung.de Eric Thode Phone: +49 5241 81-81581 eric.thode@bertelsmann-stiftung.de 08 ISSN-Nummer: 2191-2467
You can also read