Actual, Adjacent, and Potential Competition
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, Volume 35, Part 2, May 2001, pp.239± 256 Actual, Adjacent, and Potential Competition Estimating the Full EŒect of Southwest Airlines Steven A. Morrison Address for correspondence: Department of Economics, Northeastern University, Boston, MA 02115 (sam1@neu.edu). This paper is based on research undertaken on behalf of Southwest Airlines. The views expressed are the author’s own and are not necessarily those of Southwest Airlines. The author would like to thank Tae Oum, CliŒWinston, and an anonymous referee for helpful comments. Abstract Southwest Airlines is frequently credited with having an important influence on the success of airline deregulation in the United States. This paper uses an original set of competition variables to estimate the extent of that influence in 1998. The estimated savings Ð due to actual, adjacent, and potential competition from Southwest Ð were $12.9 billion. Southwest’s low fares were directly responsible for $3.4 billion of these savings to passengers. The remaining $9.5 billion represents the effect that actual, adjacent, and potential competition from Southwest had on other carriers’ fares. These savings amount to 20 per cent of the airline industry’s 1998 domestic scheduled passenger revenue and slightly more than half the fare reductions attributed to airline deregulation. From a policy perspective, these results are both troubling and encouraging. On the one hand, it is troubling to find that a large part of the fare reductions from airline deregulation is due to one carrier. On the other hand, if entry by a carrier with the appropriate characteristics can make such a difference, policies that encourage entry Ð for example, relaxing the restriction on entry by foreign-owned carriers Ð may have a large impact on passenger welfare. Date of receipt of ® nal manuscript: July 2000 239
Journal of Transport Economics and Policy Volume 35, Part 2 Introduction ``Probably the most signi® cant development in the U.S. airline industry during the past decade has been the continued expansion of Southwest Air- lines and the resurgence of low-fare entry generally.’’ Transportation Research Board (1999) Southwest Airlines has a unique position in the US domestic aviation industry. It was one of two carriers (along with Paci® c Southwest Airlines) whose low fares as intrastate carriers not regulated by the federal gov- ernment led to airline deregulation in 1978.1 Indeed, its combination of low fares, high frequency, and point-to-point service has become a model for other carriers both in the United States and abroad. As exempli® ed by the quote above, Southwest Airlines is often cited as a major reason for the success of airline deregulation in the United States. This paper uses an original set of competition variables to quantify the impact that Southwest Airlines has on airfares through actual, adjacent, and potential competi- tion. Previous Research Previous research has estimated Southwest’s aggregate impact on fares on the routes that it serves.2 Dresner et al. (1996) hypothesised that the eŒect of Southwest (and other low-fare carriers) may be greater than previously estimated because of possible spillover eŒects that Southwest’s service on one route has on adjacent competitive routes that involve nearby airports. They found a signi® cant eŒect of service on adjacent competitive routes but did not aggregate the results to estimate the aggregate impact of Southwest. This paper’s contribution is to specify the eŒect that Southwest may have on a route’ s fares in an original disaggregate way, which includes the eŒect of various forms of actual, adjacent, and potential competition from Southwest. The results are then aggregated to obtain an estimate of the eŒect that Southwest has had on airfares. This estimate is 1 See Breyer (1982). Southwest Airlines started service in 1971 as a Texas intrastate carrier serving three Texas cities. It began interstate service shortly after airlines were deregulated in 1978. In 1999, it served 57 airports (in 29 of the 48 contiguous states) and had operating revenue of $4.7 billion, which placed it seventh among US passenger airlines. 2 See, for example, Bennett and Craun (1993) and US Department of Transportation (1996). 240
Actual, Adjacent, and Potential Competition Morrison compared with estimates of the fare reductions attributed to airline deregulation to gauge Southwest’s role in this policy’ s success. Methodology Airfares on a route can be in¯ uenced by an airline in three ways. First, the airline can serve the route in question. Second, the airline can serve an adjacent route that consumers view as a reasonable substitute for the route in question. Third, although the airline may not serve the route in question or an adjacent route, it may still aŒect fares on the route if airlines lower their fares to make entry by potential competitors less attractive.3 This could happen if the airline has a presence at the airports in question or at nearby airports. Figure 1 illustrates the various ways that an airline may aŒect fares on a particular route. In the ® gure, the route of interest is from airport A to airport B. The dashed circles around airports A and B form the bound- aries of zones of in¯ uence Ð any carrier serving an airport within those zones may exert a competitive in¯ uence on the carriers serving the airports in question. In the diagram, airports C and D fall within the zones of A and B, respectively, and airport E is outside both zones. The possible ways in which a carrier may aŒect fares on a given route A-B are: . It may serve the route A-B (denoted by AAS, for At the origin airport, At the destination airport, and Serves the route). . It may serve a route A-D, where airport D is ``near’ ’ airport B (denoted by ANS, for At, Near, Serves). . It may serve a route C-D, where C is near airport A and D is near airport B (denoted by NNS, for Near, Near, Serves). . It may serve both airports A and B but not serve the route (denoted by AAX, for At, At, does not serve the route). . It may serve airport A and airport D, which is near airport B, but not serve the route (denoted by ANX, for At, Near, does not serve the route). . It may serve airports C and D but not serve the route (denoted by NNX, for Near, Near, does not serve the route). 3 The role of potential competition was formalised by Baumol et al. (1982). In their model, the threat of entry by potential competitors disciplines those ® rms serving the market to price at a level that maximises consumer welfare. 241
Journal of Transport Economics and Policy Volume 35, Part 2 Figure 1 Ways in which a Carrier may aŒect Fares on Route A± B . It may serve a route A-E, where E is not near B (denoted by AFS, for At, Far, Serves). . It may serve a route C-E, where C is near A, but E is not near B (denoted by NFS, for Near, Far, Serves). In the ® rst of these cases, the airline serves the route in question. In the next two cases, the airline provides service on adjacent routes. In the remaining ® ve cases, a carrier provides various degrees of potential competition (the 242
Actual, Adjacent, and Potential Competition Morrison extent of which will be estimated) by serving one or both of the airports A and B or airports nearby, but not serving routes connecting them.4 The Data and the Model The primary dataset for this study was the US Department of Trans- portation’s Ticket Origin and Destination Survey (Data Bank 1A) for the calendar year 1998, a 10 per cent sample of airline tickets, which carriers report quarterly to the Department.5 Although the eŒect of Southwest Airlines will be empirically estimated below, the extent of its possible in¯ uence is shown in Table 1, which shows the percentage of domestic passenger miles ¯ own on routes in each of the categories above. To avoid double counting, Southwest’ s (potential) in¯ uence on each route was classi® ed into the highest category for which it quali® ed. During 1998, Southwest was in a position to (potentially) in¯ uence fares on the routes it served and on adjacent routes amounting to 44.8 per cent of domestic passenger miles ¯ own. In addition, in its role as a potential competitor, it was in a position to (potentially) in¯ uence fares on routes accounting for an additional 49.4 per cent of domestic passenger miles. Thus, Southwest was in a position to potentially in¯ uence fares on routes comprising 94 per cent of domestic passenger miles.6 4 The last two cases are considered as potential competition even though the carrier oŒers service on A-E or C-E because airport E is outside the zone of in¯ uence for the A-B route. 5 In order to be reasonably assured that the tickets for a particular trip re¯ ect travel from one origin to one destination, only tickets with one (directional) destination were used. Round trips had to return to the initial point of departure (with no ground segments, i.e., ``open jaw’’ tickets). Only one-way tickets with two or fewer coupons (i.e., ¯ ight segments) and round-trip tickets with two or fewer coupons on the outbound and return legs were used. Further, only tickets involving airports in the 48 contiguous states were used. Finally, tickets that were coded with the generic codes for Chicago, Detroit, New York City, and Washington, DC were omitted because it was not possible to identify the airport actually used. 6 What characterises those routes that are beyond any (potential) impact of Southwest? The 20 most heavily travelled routes (based on passenger miles) that Southwest did not (potentially) in¯ uence in 1998 (amounting to 24 per cent of the passenger miles of that unaŒected group) involved routes between the following 13 airports: Atlanta, BuŒalo, Charlotte, Denver, Hartford, LaGuardia, Memphis, Minneapolis-St. Paul, Newark, Raleigh-Durham, Richmond, Philadelphia, and Pittsburgh. Eight of these airports are hubs for major airlines. Eleven are in the eastern US. One is slot constrained. (In 1999, Southwest entered Hartford and Raleigh-Durham.) 243
Journal of Transport Economics and Policy Volume 35, Part 2 Table 1 Competitive Pro® le of Southwest Airlines in 1998 Category Variable Percentage of Domestic Passenger Miles Actual Competition 44.8% At-At-Serves 21.0% At-Near-Serves 18.0% Near-Near-Serves 5.7% Potential Competition 49.4% At-At-Does not Serve 6.5% At-Near-Does not Serve 2.7% Near-Near-Does not Serve 0.1% At-Far-Serves 30.7% Near-Far-Serves 9.4% Total 94.2% Source: Author’s calculations. See text for a detailed explanation of the variables. Cal- culations are based on a zone of in¯ uence with a 75-mile radius. Totals may not add due to rounding. The standard approach to assessing the eŒect of competition Ð both actual and potential Ð on airfares is to estimate a fare equation.7 In a fare equation, the average fare on a route is regressed on measures of actual and potential competition and other control variables that are believed to in¯ uence the cost and demand characteristics of the route. Here, quarterly data from the 1,000 most heavily travelled routes in 1998 were used to estimate a fare equation to assess the eŒect of Southwest Airlines on fares.8 The Dependent Variable For each ticket in the sample, the price each passenger paid was reduced by the amount of ticket taxes and passenger facility charges (PFCs).9 Average one-way fare (logarithm) was then calculated for each route in the sample.10 7 This fare equation may be regarded as a reduced form equation derived from a structural model. See, for example, Bailey and Panzar (1981), or Morrison and Winston (1995). 8 The 1,000 routes account for 70 per cent of passengers and 67 per cent of passenger miles in the full dataset containing more than 29,000 routes. 9 During the ® rst three quarters of 1998, the federal domestic ticket tax was 9 per cent of the ticket price plus $1 per ¯ ight segment. During the fourth quarter of 1998, the tax was 8 per cent plus $2 per segment. 290 airports assessed PFCs during 1998; all but one airport charged the statutory maximum of $3 per enplanement; one airport charged $2. 10 Because of possible coding errors in the data carriers submit to the Department of Transportation, the US General Accounting O ce’s (1990) fare screen was used to screen out fares that seemed too high. In order to keep frequent ¯ ier tickets, a low-fare screen was not used. The eŒect on the results of omitting frequent ¯ ier tickets is discussed below in the section on sensitivity. 244
Actual, Adjacent, and Potential Competition Morrison The Competition Variables As above, Southwest’s (potential) in¯ uence on each route was classi® ed into the highest category for which it quali® ed. In addition, competition variables giving the number of carriers from each group serving the route were included for three other groups of carriers:11 Low-Fare carriers (other than Southwest), Major carriers (other than Southwest), and Other carriers.12 A zone of in¯ uence with a radius of 75 miles was used because it provided the best ® t compared with zones of 25, 50, 100, and 125 miles.13 Control Variables Although we are primarily interested in the eŒect that Southwest Airlines has on fares, it is important to control for other in¯ uences in order that we are reasonably certain that the competition variables capture just that, rather than some other eŒect. Distance: Other things being equal, we expect fares to be higher the longer the trip because costs are higher. The logarithm of the (great circle) distance from the origin to the destination was used. Density: Because of ® xed station costs and economies of aircraft size, airline service is characterised by economies of density.14 An airport is classi® ed into one of four ``hub’’ categories (Large, Medium, Small, and Non) based on its 11 A carrier was considered as serving a route if it had at least a 10 per cent share of the route’s passengers. Attempts to estimate an equation with a complete set of competition variables to capture the eŒect of adjacent and potential competition for major, low fare, and other carriers resulted in implausible estimates for all competition variables. 12 The Low-Fare carriers identi® ed by the US Department of Transportation that were operating during 1998 (other than Southwest) were AirTran, American Trans Air, Frontier, Kiwi, ProAir, Reno, Spirit, Tower Air, Vanguard, and Western Paci® c. The US Department of Transportation de® nes a Major carrier as one with annual revenue over $1 billion. In 1998, the Major (passenger) carriers (in addition to Southwest) were Alaska, American, America West, Continental, Delta, Northwest, Trans World, United, and US Airways. The Other carriers used in this analysis were Casino Express, Eastwind, Hawaiian, Midway, and Midwest Express. Carriers with fewer than 1,000 sampled passengers during 1998 were not assigned a competition variable, nor were trips involving changing airlines, i.e., interline connections. 13 Dresner et al. (1996) used a 50-mile radius to de® ne adjacent competitive routes. Sensitivity results for zones of 25, 50, 100, and 125 miles are reported below. 14 See, for example, Caves et al. (1984). 245
Journal of Transport Economics and Policy Volume 35, Part 2 share of enplanements nationwide.15 Since there are four hub classi® ca- tions, a given route is in one of ten possible origin-hub-destination-hub classi® cations (for example, Large-Small). To control for density, nine dummy variables were used representing all but one of the possible combinations of service between the four airport hub classi® cations. (A Non-Hub-Non-Hub variable was not used because there were no routes in the top 1,000 in that category.) Because dummy variables were included for all hub categories in the sample, a separate constant term was not included. Slots: Four airports in the United States have limits on the number of takeoŒs and landings that may take place during any given hour. To account for the eŒect on fares of the demand restrictions at these so-called ``slot- controlled’’ airports, four dummy variables were included for the four airports: Chicago O’Hare; New York Kennedy and LaGuardia; and Washington Reagan National. The variable equalled one if the airport was on the route in question, and zero otherwise. Percentage Business: Airlines use yield management to charge business travellers higher fares than pleasure travellers. Thus, other things being equal, trip purpose is expected to aŒect airfares. Data used were the percentage of air travellers travelling between the states where the origin and destination airports were located, whose trip purpose was business.16 Concentrated Hubs: Previous research (see, for example, Borenstein, 1989) has shown that other things being equal, fares at concentrated hub airports are higher 15 Those airports that accounted for 1 per cent or more of passenger enplanements were classi® ed as Large Hubs; those enplaning 0.25 per cent or more but less than 1 per cent were classi® ed as Medium Hubs; airports enplaning 0.05 per cent or more but less than 0.25 per cent were classi® ed as Small Hubs; airports enplaning less than 0.05 per cent were classi® ed as Non Hubs. These classi® cations were determined based on the US Department of Transportation’s Airport Activity Statistics data (Form 41, Schedule T-3, Data Bank 22) for 1998. This de® nition diŒers from the US Federal Aviation Administration’s de® nition of hub class in that here airport level enplanements were 16 This was calculated from data in the US Department of Transportation’s (Bureau of Transportation Statistics), 1995 American Travel Survey. Given that state-level data were used and that the data come from an earlier year, this variable is likely to be exogenous. 246
Actual, Adjacent, and Potential Competition Morrison than at other airports. This analysis uses the US General Accounting O ce’s (1990) de® nition, in which an airport was considered concentrated if it was among the top 75 in the country in terms of passenger enplane- ments and one carrier accounted for 60 per cent or more of enplaned passengers at the airport, or two carriers accounted for 85 per cent or more of enplaned passengers at the airport. The resulting variable equalled one if one or both of the airports involved on the route were concentrated using the above de® nition.17 Regional EŒects: To account for unobserved eŒects that are regional in nature (such as weather), a ``Sun-Belt’’ variable was created.18 The variable equalled the number of airports in the Sun Belt on the route in question, that is 0, 1, or 2. Quarterly EŒects: To control for quarterly ® xed eŒects, three dummy variables for quarters 1± 3 were used. Estimation Results Full regression results are in the Appendix. Although we are interested in the Southwest competition variables, plausible values for the other 17 This was calculated from the enplanements data in the US Department of Transportation’ s Airport Activity Statistics data (Form 41, Schedule T-3, Data Bank 22) for 1998. 18 The de® nition of ``Sun-Belt’’ states that provided the best ® t to the data was a group including California, Nevada, Arizona, New Mexico, Texas, Louisiana, Mississippi, Alabama, and Florida. Alternatively, the results did not change qualitatively when regional eŒects were captured using eight of the following nine US Department of Transportation regional variables: Region 1 (the base case): Connecticut, Maine, Massachusetts, New Hampshire, Rhode Island, and Vermont; Region 2: New York, New Jersey, and Pennsylvania; Region 3: Delaware, District of Columbia, Florida, Georgia, Maryland, North Carolina, South Carolina, Virginia, and West Virginia; Region 4: Illinois, Indiana, Michigan, Ohio, and Wisconsin; Region 5: Alabama, Kentucky, Mississippi, and Tennessee; Region 6: Iowa, Kansas, Minnesota, Missouri, Nebraska, North Dakota, and South Dakota; Region 7: Arkansas, Louisiana, Oklahoma, and Texas; Region 8: Arizona, Colorado, Idaho, Montana, Nevada, New Mexico, Utah, and Wyoming; Region 9: California, Oregon, and Washington. 247
Journal of Transport Economics and Policy Volume 35, Part 2 coe cients will lend credence to the model. The quarterly dummies reveal that fares are higher in quarter 1 than in the other periods (per- haps due to a smaller fraction of price-sensitive vacation travellers in that period). The density dummies are all statistically signi® cant, but their relative magnitudes do not appear to show any interesting relationship. Two of the slot coe cients have positive signs, but only one (O’ Hare) is statistically signi® cant at the 5 per cent level. The coe cient for Washington National is negative, but is not statistically signi® cant. Finally, the coe cient for New York’ s Kennedy Airport has a negative sign and is statistically signi® cant. However, slots at Kennedy are not in eŒect throughout the entire day and, given its greater distance from New York population centres, it may cater to more price-sensitive pleasure travellers. The distance coe cient indicates that, as expected, fares increase less than proportionately with distance, other things being equal, due to the ® xed ¯ ight costs that are independent of the length of the ¯ ight (such as takeoŒ and landing). The concentrated hub dummy indicates that fares are about 4 per cent higher on routes involving concentrated hubs, even after controlling for route competition and other eŒects. The percentage business coe cient indicates that fares are 28 per cent higher on routes with 75 per cent business travellers compared with otherwise comparable routes with 25 per cent business travellers.19 The sun-belt variable indicates that fares involving ¯ ights to or from that region are 6 per cent lower than elsewhere, all else being equal. The competition variables for carriers other than Southwest seem quite rea- sonable: additional competition lowers fares, and Low-Fare and Other carriers have a larger impact on fares than Major carriers.20 On balance, the model seems to produce plausible results. Estimation results for the Southwest Airlines competition variables of interest are reported in Table 2. All the estimated coe cients are sig- ni® cantly diŒerent from zero at the 1 per cent level. Although all coe - cients are precisely estimated, it is useful to see if their relative magnitudes seem reasonable before we look at their absolute magnitude. The relative magnitudes of the actual competition variables seem rea- sonable because the magnitude of the coe cient declines as the service 19 Calculated as follows: exp(0.75*coe cient)/exp(0.25*coe cient)-1. 20 The diŒerential impact of Major carriers on fares compared with the relatively large impact of Southwest and other Low-Fare carriers is consistent with the ® ndings of Bailey et al. (1985), Strassman (1990), and Windle and Dresner (1995). 248
Actual, Adjacent, and Potential Competition Morrison Table 2 Estimation Results for Southwest Airlines Competition Variables Category Variable Coe cient Standard Error EŒect on Fares* Actual Competition At-At-Serves 0:620 0:023 46:2 At-Near-Serves 0:306 0:023 26:4 Near-Near-Serves 0:167 0:029 15:4 Potential Competition At-At-Does not Serve 0:401 0:027 33:0 At-Near-Does not Serve 0:140 0:033 13:1 Near-Near-Does not Serve 0:188 0:033 20:7 At-Far-Serves 0:125 0:021 11:8 Near-Far-Serves 0:067 0:024 6:5 Source: Author’s calculations. See Appendix for full regression results and main text for a detailed explanation of the variables. *Given that the regression equation explains the logarithm of fares, the eŒect on fares is exp(coe - cient)-1. becomes less of a substitute for travel on the route in question. The same is true for the potential competition variables, with the exception of Near- Near-Does not Serve.21 It is also reasonable that the magnitude of the eŒect of actual competition is greater than the eŒect of potential compe- tition in the two cases where a plausible eŒect of potential competition was estimated (that is At-At-Serves vs. At-At-Does not Serve, and At-Near- Serves vs. At-Near-Does not Serve).22 Thus, the relative magnitudes of the coe cients seem reasonable. As far as the absolute eŒects are concerned, when Southwest serves a route (At-At-Serves), fares are 46 per cent lower than on otherwise com- parable routes that it does not serve. If it serves an adjacent route (At- Near-Serves and Near-Near-Serves), fares are from 15 to 26 per cent below otherwise comparable routes. Potential competition from South- 21 The eŒect of Southwest in the Near-Near-Does not Serve case is to raise fares by 21 per cent. It should be noted, however, that this estimate is based on only four quarterly observations for one route in the sample (Dayton-Washington Reagan National). 22 Morrison and Winston (1987) estimated the impact (for all types of carriers combined) of actual competition on a route (AAS in this paper’s terminology) and potential competition (de® ned as carriers serving one or both airports on a route, but not the route itself, AAX, ANX, and AFS in this paper’s terminology). They found that a potential competitor had 1/3 the eŒect on passenger welfare that one actual competitor had. Here, depending on the speci® c type of (comparable) potential competition considered, the eŒect on fares of Southwest as a potential competitor ranges from 50 to 71 per cent of the eŒect of actual competition from Southwest. 249
Journal of Transport Economics and Policy Volume 35, Part 2 west is most eŒective when it serves both endpoints of a route but not the route itself (lowering fares by 33 per cent) and least eŒective when it only serves one airport that is near one of the airports in question, in which case fares are reduced by 6 per cent.23 Simulation The model was used to estimate the impact that Southwest Airlines has on airfares. For each route in the complete data set of all routes (not just the top 1,000) passenger expenditure (predicted fare times number of pas- sengers) was estimated with and without Southwest Airlines.24 The results in Table 3, decomposed into the eŒect of each variable, show the savings to air travellers in 1998 because of Southwest.25 Not surprisingly, the biggest impact of competition from Southwest comes when it serves the route in question, lowering fares by nearly $7 billion. When the eŒect of competition on adjacent routes is taken into account, the total eŒect of actual competition from Southwest increases to nearly $10 billion. Adding the eŒect of Southwest as a potential competitor raises the total impact of Southwest Airlines to $12.9 billion. Given that Southwest had passenger revenue of nearly $4.0 billion in 1998, and that its presence on a route lowers fares on that route by an estimated 46.2 per cent, Southwest’s low fares were directly responsible for $3.4 billion of savings to passengers. The remaining $9.5 billion represents the eŒect that actual, adjacent, and potential competition from Southwest had on other carriers’ fares. These 23 When a comparison is possible, these results are comparable with Dresner et al. who found that fares are 41 per cent lower when Southwest serves a route and 8 to 36 per cent lower when Southwest serves an adjacent route. 24 The simulation only used those coe cients for Southwest that were statistically diŒerent from zero at the 5 per cent level of signi® cance. Because Southwest’s enplanements, passenger miles, and revenue in the sample ranged from 9.9 per cent to 10.1 per cent of their respective population values, the results of the simulation were multiplied by ten to obtain the ® gures reported in the Table. 25 These savings do not re¯ ect the change in consumer surplus but represent how much more costly the trips currently taken would be without Southwest. Assuming a constant elasticity of demand, the change in consumer surplus would be $10.9 billion with an elasticity of (minus) 0.75, $9.4 billion with an elasticity of 1.5, and $7.2 billion with an elasticity of 3.0. Furthermore, this analysis is short-run in nature and does not consider that if Southwest did not exist, other carriers may have taken its place on some of the routes served. If it was replaced on all the routes it serves, the savings attributable to Southwest would be $9.9 billion if replaced by a low-fare carrier, $11.3 billion if replaced by an ``other’’ carrier, and $12.5 billion if replaced by a major carrier. (This calculation only considers the direct eŒect of carriers other than Southwest because, as noted in footnote 11, it was not possible to estimate a plausible equation with a complete set of competition variables for all types of carriers.) 250
Actual, Adjacent, and Potential Competition Morrison Table 3 Decomposition of Savings Attributed to Southwest Airlines in 1998 (billions of dollars) Category Variable EŒect Actual Competition 9:58 At-At-Serves 6:55 At-Near-Serves 2:56 Near-Near-Serves 0:47 Potential Competition 3:30 At-At-Does not Serve 0:95 At-Near-Does not Serve 0:18 Near-Near-Does not Serve 0:01 At-Far-Serves 1:76 Near-Far-Serves 0:42 Total Savings 12:88 Source: Author’s calculations. See text for a detailed explanation of the variables. savings amount to 20 per cent of all domestic airline passenger revenue and imply that Southwest is responsible for 53 per cent of the fare reductions attributed to airline deregulation.26 Sensitivity of Results To assess the sensitivity of the results to the radius of the assumed zone of in¯ uence and to the inclusion of frequent ¯ ier tickets, nine additional regressions were estimated with the radius of the zone set at 25, 50, 75, 100, and 125 miles, including and excluding frequent ¯ ier tickets. As shown in Table 4, the estimated savings attributed to Southwest Airlines range from $8.73 billion to $13.80 billion. Both including and excluding frequent ¯ ier tickets, the estimated savings increase as the radius of the zone of in¯ uenced is increased, reach their maxima at 50 miles, and then decrease. Estimated savings including frequent ¯ ier tickets are always less 26 This is based on an update to the estimate in Morrison and Winston (1995) of the fare reductions attributable to airline deregulation. For 1998, fares were 28 per cent lower than an estimate of what they would have been had regulation continued. Given actual industry domestic passenger revenue of $64 billion in 1998, this amounts to savings of $24.4 billion. $12.9 billion is 53 percent of $24.4 billion. To the extent that the estimate of the fare reductions from deregulation is understated, Southwest’s contribution is overstated. But any plausible estimate of the fare reductions from deregulation still shows Southwest making a signi® cant contribution. Morrison and Winston (1995) also found that fare reductions represented about 2/3 of the bene® ts to passengers from airline deregulation. 251
Journal of Transport Economics and Policy Volume 35, Part 2 Table 4 Sensitivity of Savings Attributed to Southwest Airlines in 1998 (billions of dollars) Radius (miles) of Including Excluding Zone of In¯ uence Frequent Flier Tickets Frequent Flier Tickets 25 9.62 10.00 50 13.19 13.80 75 12.88 13.30 100 11.00 11.45 125 8.73 9.15 Source: Author’s calculations using estimated coe cients that were signi® cant at the 5 per cent level. than if they are excluded. Thus, the results reported above (which were chosen because they yielded the best ® t for regressions that included fre- quent ¯ ier tickets) are reasonably robust.27 Comparison with Other Studies Table 5 compares the results of this study with the results of three previous studies of the aggregate impact of Southwest Airlines on airfares. These previous studies assessed Southwest’s eŒect on the routes that it served, Table 5 Comparison with Other Studies Study Year Amount that Southwest’ s Share of of Data Southwest Lowers Fares Domestic Scheduled as a Percentage of Industry Revenue Passenger Miles Domestic Passenger Revenue Morrison and Winston (1995) 1988± 92 8.5% on routes served 2.9% (1990) Bennett and Craun (1993) 1992 5.6% ± 6.7% on routes served 4.0% (1992) U.S. DOT (1996) 1995 8.4% ± 10.1% on routes served 5.9% (1995) Morrison (2000) 1998 10.2% on routes served 6.9% (1998) 4.7% on adjacent routes 5.2% from potential competition Sources: Listed above and Air Transport Association (various issues) and Southwest Airlines (www.southwest.com). 27 If the simulation is limited to only those 1,000 routes used in the regression equation, the eŒect is $9.7 billion. 252
Actual, Adjacent, and Potential Competition Morrison but did not capture the additional eŒects of competition on adjacent routes or from potential competition. Based on a fare model and entry and exit models, and using data from 1988-92 for the 1,000 most heavily travelled routes, Morrison and Winston (1995) estimated that if Southwest Airlines exited the airline industry, fares nationwide would increase by 8.5 per cent after ® ve years, even after taking into account the subsequent entry that would probably occur. Bennett and Craun (1993) found that if fares on Southwest’ s routes in 1992 were raised to the level of fares on non-Southwest routes, industry revenue would rise by $2.5-$3.0 billion (holding tra c constant), which amounts to 5.6-6.7 per cent of 1992’s domestic scheduled passenger revenue. The US Department of Transportation (1996) estimated that low-fare carriers saved passengers $6.3 billion during the four quarters ending in 1995:3. If we conservatively assume that Southwest’s and other low-fare carriers’ eŒect on fares is the same, because Southwest accounted for 71 per cent of low-fare carriers’ revenue passenger miles during the four quarters studied, Southwest’ s eŒect would be $4.5 billion, amounting to 8.4 per cent of domestic scheduled passenger revenue. If, on the other hand, we assume that Southwest’ s presence on a route exerts a stronger in¯ uence on fares as indicated by the estimates in this paper, Southwest’ s eŒect rises to $5.4 billion, amounting to 10.1 per cent of domestic sched- uled passenger revenue.28 The Table also shows Southwest’s relative size during the time periods covered by these studies. Given that Southwest accounted for a larger share of the industry in 1998, and that this study includes both the eŒect of competition on adjacent routes and the eŒect of potential competition from Southwest, which the other aggregate studies did not, the results seem reasonable, although dramatic.29 Summary and Conclusion This paper reports estimates of the savings that Southwest Airlines has brought to air travellers in the United States during 1998 using an original set of actual, adjacent, and potential competition variables. The estimated savings due to competition from Southwest was $12.9 billion. Southwest’ s 28 Here, we assume that the eŒect of a Southwest passenger mile is 2.25 times more powerful than other low-fare carriers’ passenger miles; 2.25 is the ratio of the eŒect of Southwest (1-exp(-0.62)) to the eŒect of other low-fare carriers (1-exp(-0.23). 29 The US Department of Transportation (1996) notes that the impact of low-fare carriers has been growing at an increasing rate. 253
Journal of Transport Economics and Policy Volume 35, Part 2 low fares were directly responsible for $3.4 billion of these savings to passengers. The remaining $9.5 billion represents the eŒect that actual, adjacent, and potential competition from Southwest had on other carriers’ fares. These savings amount to 20 per cent of the airline industry’ s 1998 domestic scheduled passenger revenue and slightly more than half of the fare reductions attributed to airline deregulation Ð a sizable impact from a carrier that accounts for about 7 per cent of the industry’s domestic scheduled passenger miles. From a policy perspective, these results are both troubling and encouraging. On the one hand, it is troubling to ® nd that a large part of the fare reductions from airline deregulation is due to one carrier Ð albeit one, along with Paci® c Southwest Airlines, whose performance as an intrastate carrier not regulated by the Civil Aeronautics Board provided a natural experiment that contributed to the passage of the Airline Deregulation Act. On the other hand, if entry by the ``right’ ’ carrier can make such a diŒerence, policies that encourage entry Ð for example relaxing the restrictions on entry by foreign-owned carriers-may have a large impact on passenger welfare. References Air Transport Association (various years): Annual Report. Washington, DC: Air Transport Association. Bailey, Elizabeth E., David R. Graham, and Daniel P. Kaplan (1985): Deregulating the Airlines. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Bailey, Elizabeth E. and John C. Panzar (1981): ``The Contestability of Airline Markets during the Transition to Deregulation.’’ Law and Contemporary Problems, 44, 125± 45. Baumol, William J., John C. Panzar, and Robert D. Willig (1982): Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industrial Structure. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. Bennett, Randall D. and James M. Craun (1993): ``The Airline Deregulation Evolution Continues: The Southwest EŒect.’’ O ce of Aviation Analysis, O ce of the Secretary, US Department of Transportation. Borenstein, Severin (1989): ``Hubs and High Fares: Dominance and Market Power in the US Airline Industry.’’ Rand Journal of Economics, 20, 344± 65. Breyer, Stephen (1989): Regulation and its Reform. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Caves, Douglas W., Laurits R. Christensen, and Michael W. Tretheway (1984): ``Economies of Density versus Economies of Scale: Why Trunk and Local Service Airlines Costs DiŒer.’’ Rand Journal of Economics, 15, 471± 89. Dresner, Martin, Jiun-Sheng Chris Lin, and Robert Windle (1996): ``The Impact of Low- Cost Carriers on Airport and Route Competition.’’ Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 30, 309± 28. Morrison, Steven A. and CliŒord Winston (1987): ``Empirical Implications and Tests of the Contestability Hypothesis.’’ Journal of Law and Economics, 30, 53± 66. Morrison, Steven A. and CliŒord Winston (1995): The Evolution of the Airline Industry. 254
Actual, Adjacent, and Potential Competition Morrison Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution. Strassmann, Diana L. (1990): ``Potential Competition in the Deregulated Airlines.’’ The Review of Economics and Statistics, 72, 696± 702. Transportation Research Board, National Research Council (1999): Entry and Competition in the US Airline Industry: Issues and Opportunities. Washington, DC: National Academy Press. US General Accounting O ce (1990): Airline Competition: Higher Fares and Reduced Competition at Concentrated Airports. GAO/RCED-90-102, Washington, DC. US Department of Transportation (1996): ``The Low Cost Airline Service Revolution.’’ Windle, Robert and Martin Dresner (1995): ``The Short and Long Run EŒects of Entry on US Domestic Air Routes.’’ Transportation Journal, 35, 14± 25. 255
Journal of Transport Economics and Policy Volume 35, Part 2 Appendix Ordinary Least Squares Regression Results Dependent Variable: Logarithm of Average Fare White Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Standard Errors Variable Coe cient Standard Error t-Statistic Probability Quarter 1 Dummy 0.052490 0.01053 9 4.98075 3 0.0% Quarter 2 Dummy 0.015028 0.00977 2 1.53786 7 12.4% Quarter 3 Dummy 0.000123 0.00983 1 0.01249 3 99.0% Large Hub-Large Hub Dummy 2.377770 0.05973 5 39.80539 0 0.0% Large Hub-Medium Hub Dummy 2.364472 0.05876 3 40.23772 0 0.0% Large Hub-Small Hub Dummy 2.268900 0.05629 8 40.30147 0 0.0% Large Hub-Non Hub Dummy 2.053422 0.06593 4 31.14338 0 0.0% Medium Hub-Medium Hub Dummy 2.305377 0.05921 5 38.93204 0 0.0% Medium Hub-Small Hub Dummy 2.247348 0.06119 1 36.72657 0 0.0% Medium Hub-Non Hub Dummy 2.217791 0.06889 0 32.19310 0 0.0% Small Hub-Small Hub Dummy 1.956237 0.05487 5 35.64899 0 0.0% Small Hub-Non Hub Dummy 2.177449 0.08914 7 24.42544 0 0.0% Washington Reagan National Dummy 0.022675 0.021961 1.03251 7 30.2% New York Kennedy Dummy 0.159651 0.026972 5.91912 9 0.0% New York LaGuardia Dummy 0.029887 0.01591 5 1.87797 3 6.1% Chicago O’Hare Dummy 0.068581 0.01812 3 3.78423 0 0.0% Percent Business Travel 0.494438 0.024715 20.00529 0 0.0% Distance (logarithm) 0.408168 0.007605 53.67442 0 0.0% Number of Airport in Sunbelt 0.057146 0.006638 8.60893 8 0.0% Concentrated Hub Dummy 0.055875 0.009511 5.87500 8 0.0% Southwest: At-At-Serves 0.619880 0.022826 27.15637 0 0.0% Southwest: At-Near-Serves 0.306484 0.023236 -13.19014 0 0.0% Southwest: Near-Near-Serves 0.167483 0.028573 5.86166 1 0.0% Southwest: At-At-Does Not Serve 0.401170 0.027317 14.68575 0 0.0% Southwest: At-Near-Does Not Serve 0.140334 0.033032 4.24836 4 0.0% Southwest: Near-Near-Does not Serve 0.188314 0.032628 5.77155 4 0.0% Southwest: At-Far-Serves 0.124500 0.020706 6.01268 9 0.0% Southwest: Near-Far-Serves 0.066610 0.023775 2.80165 7 0.5% Number of Low Fare Carriers on Route 0.233511 0.010366 22.52553 0 0.0% Number of Major Carriers on Route 0.029259 0.004696 6.23018 4 0.0% Number of Other Carriers on Route 0.117270 0.020069 5.84335 4 0.0% Number of Observations = 4,000 R2 ˆ 0:739 Source: Author’s calculation. See text for a detailed explanation of the variables. 256
You can also read