2 The Potential Gains from International Migration - World Bank ...
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
2 The Potential Gains from International Migration International migration can generate substan- migrants and for their origin countries. Here tial welfare gains for migrants, their countries we can refer to a broader range of economic of origin, and the countries to which they mi- issues than are captured by the model, al- grate. The main focus of this report is on gains though without the ability to quantify that the from the remittances that migrants send home model-based simulation provides. (discussed in chapters 4–6); chapters 2 and 3 Starting from the base-case forecast of eco- address the economic costs and benefits of nomic activity described in chapter 1, we in- migration and the impact of migration on troduce an additional increase in migration poverty. In this chapter, we use an economic from developing to high-income countries suf- model to estimate the size of the welfare gains ficient to raise the labor force of high-income resulting from migration from developing to countries by 3 percent over the period high-income countries.1 It must be recognized 2001–25. The assumed increase, roughly one- at the outset that the model fails to capture eighth of a percentage point a year, is close to some known costs and benefits of migration; that observed over the 1970–2000 period. We that the results are dependent on the specifica- imply no judgment concerning whether such tion of the model and its key parameters; an increase is likely or politically feasible, but and that the model cannot incorporate social rather view the rise in migration as an exoge- or political considerations.2 The results of this nous shock. As discussed in chapter 3, pres- simulation do not provide a precise forecast of sures to migrate are likely to rise over the next the likely impact of migration; instead, they few decades, but the actual size of the migrant provide a consistent framework that offers in- flows will depend heavily on political deci- sights into (a) the economic gains that can be sions in destination countries. This exercise expected from changes in policy or circum- presents us with the following key findings. stances, and (b) the channels through which migration affects welfare—and both are diffi- The expected decline in the labor force in cult to measure in reality. The conclusions high-income countries will increase depen- drawn from the model are supported by sev- dency ratios, which could add to the benefits eral empirical studies, and they hold up well from migration. However, such increases in under various alternative assumptions for migration are unlikely to be large enough to model specification and parameters. have a significant impact on dependency ra- In chapter 3, we complement this model- tios in high-income countries. based approach to measuring the gains from migration with a review of the economic liter- Under the assumptions adopted in this model- ature, which covers the implications for ing exercise, the rise in migration—small 25
G L O B A L E C O N O M I C P R O S P E C T S 2 0 0 6 relative to the labor force of high-income coun- The costs of adjusting to increased migration tries, but large relative to the existing stock of and the gains from migration depend, in part, migrants—would generate large increases in on the investment climate. Adjustment costs global welfare. Migrants, natives in destination as a result of migration will be lower if more countries, and households in origin countries flexible labor markets and more efficient cap- would experience gains in income, although mi- ital markets in high-income economies reduce grants already living in high-income countries transitional unemployment and the cost of re- would see a decline in wages relative to the base placing capital as economies adjust to the rise case. Estimates of these gains and losses are par- in immigration. Similarly, developing coun- ticularly sensitive to assumptions about the de- tries with strong investment climates will be gree of differentiation among workers (between able to use increased remittances more effi- natives and migrants and between old and new ciently, and enable workers who do not mi- migrants), the impact of migrants on fiscal bal- grate to respond to improved labor market ances, and the extent of remittances. conditions. The cost of adjustment may also be lower if migration is spread over time Empirical studies of the impact of migration rather than concentrated in spurts. on natives’ wages have had mixed results. In this simulation exercise, the rise in migration A principal conclusion from this exercise is leads to a small decline in average wages in that migration can generate significant eco- high-income countries relative to the baseline, nomic gains for migrants, origin countries, which one would anticipate from a labor sup- and destination countries—but migration also ply shock. But the decline has a barely per- can have important political and social conse- ceptible impact on the long-term growth rate quences. For example, natives in destination for wages. countries may become concerned about main- Native households in high-income countries taining cultural identity in the middle of a enjoy a rise in income, on average, as returns growing diversity, which also has implications to capital increase, offsetting the mild decline relative to minority languages and other issues in wages. The impact on developing countries surrounding the integration of migrants. To is nearly the reverse, with wage income rising some extent, opposition to migration is driven as labor-market conditions for workers im- by these concerns, and not by an economic prove, while returns on capital decline with calculation of the gains and losses. the smaller supply of workers. In developing We begin with a discussion of recent trends countries the gain from increased remittances and discuss how migration to high-income greatly exceeds that from changes in factor countries has grown over the past 30 years. returns. We then turn to the prospects for migration, including the intense pressures generated by The economic benefits for high-income demographic changes. We describe the base- economies could be even larger than those pre- case scenario for migration and the model- dicted by the model, due to several factors: the based analysis of the welfare gains from in- model excludes the increased productivity of creased migration. We conclude with issues migrants (and the benefits to their offspring) that the model does not consider. over time; investment levels could increase substantially in response to higher returns to International migration trends capital; labor-force participation could rise among natives with the greater availability of Migration to high-income countries migrant labor (for household help, for exam- has accelerated ple); the labor market would become more The United Nations (UN) estimates that mi- flexibile, and diversity would increase. grants account for some 3 percent of the 26
T H E P O T E N T I A L G A I N S F R O M I N T E R N A T I O N A L M I G R A T I O N Table 2.1 Growth in international migration by destination, 1970–2000 Percent change per year in stock of migrants 1970–80 1982–90 1990–2000 World 2.0 4.4 1.3 High-income countries 2.4 2.9 3.1 Developing countries 1.8 5.5 –0.1 Excluding former USSR 1.9 2.1 0.0 Former USSR 0.5 25.0 –0.3 Source: United Nations. world’s population, or about 175 million tion growth, the share of migrants in develop- persons.3 The stock of immigrants to high- ing countries’ population (excluding the for- income countries increased at about 3 percent mer Soviet Union) fell (figure 2.1).4 per year from 1980 to 2000, up from the Most high-income countries saw immigra- 2.4 percent pace in the 1970s (table 2.1). At tion rise by at least 2 percent per year from that rate of growth, the share of migrants in 1980 to 2000.5 This increase reflected, in high-income countries’ population almost part, increased demand for services accom- doubled over the 30-year period, and popula- panying rising incomes, global competition tion growth (excluding migration) fell from for highly educated workers as technological 0.7 percent per year in the 1970s to 0.5 per- advances boosted the premium for skills, the cent in the 1990s. Immigration has had a par- growth of networks of immigrants in high- ticular impact on population growth in several income countries that facilitated new immi- high-income countries. For example, without gration, and increased refugee movements. immigration Germany, Italy, and Sweden Almost 70 percent of the increase in immi- would have experienced a decline in popula- gration is accounted for by the United States tion in the past few decades (OECD 2005; and Germany, which together make up less IOM 2005). By contrast, migration to devel- than 40 percent of the population of the oping countries rose by only 1.3 percent per high-income countries. In the United States, year from 1970 to 2000. With rapid popula- the Immigration Reform and Control Act (IRCA) of 1986, which provided permanent status to 2.7 million migrants, facilitated fur- Figure 2.1 International migrants as a ther immigration through rules governing share of destination countries’ population family reunification and may have encour- Percentage aged further irregular immigration (Passel 9 2005) by encouraging expectations of future 8 amnesties.6 Germany saw a large inflow of 7 ethnic Germans following the breakup of the 6 Soviet Union (Dustmann and Glitz 2005), as 5 well as an increase in temporary migration 4 1970 3 2000 under bilateral agreements. 2 Though the stock of migrants has acceler- 1 ated sharply relative to the population in the 0 industrial countries, in some respects the com- World Developed Developing Developing countries countries countriesa position and patterns of international migra- tion have exhibited continuity over the past Source: United Nations. Note: a. Excluding countries of the former USSR. few decades. The share of female migrants has remained almost unchanged (47 percent 27
G L O B A L E C O N O M I C P R O S P E C T S 2 0 0 6 Figure 2.2 Share of females in Figure 2.3 Immigration to selected international migration countries, reasons for admittance, 2001 Percentage Percent 51 80 United 50 70 Kingdom Australia 49 2000 60 United 48 1970 50 States 47 40 France 46 30 45 20 44 10 43 0 World Developed Developing Workers Reuniting Refugee/ countries countries families asylum Source: United Nations. Source: United Nations. Note: Stock data, reported by countries of destination. Note: Stock data, reported by destination countries. of global migrant populations in 1970, com- It should be emphasized that the migration pared with 49 percent in 2000—figure 2.2), data on which these judgments are based although women are the great majority of tend to be unreliable and incomplete. Many migrants from some countries. More women countries and international agencies do not today are migrating as independent wage distinguish between regular and irregular earners, rather than to accompany their hus- migration or among types of temporary migra- bands (IOM 2005). Migration continues to be tion. Some record migrants’ country of birth; heavily determined by geographic proximity others their nationality (OECD 2005). (from Mexico to the United States, from National estimates of the number of migrants North Africa to Southern Europe, and from can be vastly different depending on whether Eastern to Western Europe), as well as by “migrant” is defined as foreign born or of for- colonial ties (from Latin America to Spain and eign nationality. from a number of Sub-Saharan African coun- tries to Belgium, France, Portugal, and the Migration is set to increase United Kingdom—OECD 2005). The major It is likely that the number of people who wish countries of destination continue to admit the to migrate from developing to high-income largest share of permanent immigrants for countries will rise over the next two decades. family reunification (or, in the case of the EU About 31 percent of developing countries’ countries, for humanitarian or refugee resettle- population is below the age of 14, compared ment), although some countries are refocusing with 18 percent in high-income countries. We their migration policy toward economic can thus anticipate a large influx in the age (largely skilled) immigration (figure 2.3).7 But categories most suitable for emigration, as international migration is also changing, par- lifetime earnings from migration tend to be ticularly in the direction of flows. For exam- largest for those emigrating early in their ple, more Asians are today seeking work in working life. The surge in immigration since other Asian countries rather than in the Mid- the 1980s has established large diasporas in dle East (Wickramasekera 2002; OECD 2005; high-income countries, which help to reduce IOM 2005), while more Latin Americans are the costs and risks of migration (see chap- turning to Europe for work opportunities, in ter 3). The demand for immigrant services in addition to North America. high-income countries will also rise as the 28
T H E P O T E N T I A L G A I N S F R O M I N T E R N A T I O N A L M I G R A T I O N aging of the population shrinks the workforce suming no change in labor-force participation and increases demand for services that rates, the high-income countries may lose immigrants can supply (such as nursing care). about 20 million workers by 2025, relative to As income standards rise, the demand for peak employment.8 other services that employ migrants (such as The expected decline in the labor force is household and restaurant help) should grow accompanied by a rise in the overall depen- rapidly. The intensifying competition for dency ratio, defined as the ratio of nonworkers skilled workers may also draw migrants, espe- to workers. For the high-income countries as a cially from countries with strong systems of group, this ratio is forecast to remain at just higher education. under one through 2009. However, by 2025, 100 workers will be supporting 111 depen- Policies in destination countries dents, largely reflecting the increased number can affect migration of the elderly (also, in most countries the num- Forecasts of migration flows remain problem- ber of children under 15 will fall). The largest atic. But with the underlying demand for and rise in the dependency ratio will be in Europe. supply of migrants likely to increase in com- If we focus more narrowly on the number of ing decades, the number of migrants will de- elderly per worker, every 100 European work- pend on policy decisions governing admit- ers now support 36 elderly people; by 2025 tance and the effectiveness of efforts to police they will have to support 52. In Japan 100 borders and enforce workplace rules. Opposi- workers will support 60 elderly in 2025. tion to immigration may grow as the number of migrants increases, as it did in major In the developing countries the labor countries of destination before World War I. force will expand But it is likely that the main policy issue will Developing countries show considerable di- be how best to manage and live with in- versity in demographic trends, but overall the creased migration. In the simulations that fol- bulge of youths born over the last two decades low, we explore the impact of an increase in is now entering the labor force, the number of migration to 2025 in line with recent histori- elderly is as yet still rising slowly, and the cal experience. number of births is falling rapidly. Thus developing countries are forecast to add nearly one billion workers to the world’s labor The demographic challenge force by 2025, again assuming no change in the labor-force participation rate, and depen- The labor force in the high-income dency ratios are expected to fall. countries is set to decline The expected expansion of the labor force A key driver in the demand for international in developing countries, coupled with large migrants over the next 20 years will be slow- wage premiums in high-income countries, ing growth, and then decline, of the labor means that migration could help reduce de- force in high-income countries. The age group pendency ratios in high-income countries. that supplies the bulk of the labor force However, increases in immigration sufficient (15–65 years old) is expected to peak near to have a noticeable impact on dependency ra- 500 million in 2010, and then fall to around tios would have to be very large. The scenario 475 million by 2025 (figure 2.4). In Japan this discussed below envisions an increase in the age group has already begun to shrink, while labor force in high-income countries of 3 per- in Europe the peak will be reached in cent through migration, or a hike of nearly 2007–08. In the other high-income countries, 50 percent in working migrants in high-income the peak will occur later—around 2020 for countries. Even if migrants come with no the United States and 2015 for the rest. As- elderly, the dependency ratio in the host coun- 29
G L O B A L E C O N O M I C P R O S P E C T S 2 0 0 6 Figure 2.4 Labor force and dependency rates Europe Japan Labor force, millions Dependency rate Labor force, millions Dependency rate 200 1.3 70 1.3 195 65 1.2 1.2 190 60 1.1 1.1 185 55 1.0 1.0 180 50 0.9 0.9 175 45 170 0.8 40 0.8 1 4 7 0 3 6 9 2 5 1 4 7 0 3 6 9 2 5 2 00 200 200 201 201 201 201 202 202 2 00 200 200 201 201 201 201 202 202 United States Other high-income countries Labor force, millions Dependency rate Labor force, millions Dependency rate 170 1.3 80 1.3 165 75 1.2 1.2 160 70 1.1 1.1 155 65 1.0 1.0 150 60 0.9 0.9 145 55 140 0.8 50 0.8 0 1 04 07 10 13 1 6 19 22 25 0 1 04 07 10 13 16 19 22 25 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 Total, High-income countries Total, Developing countries Labor force, millions Dependency rate Labor force, millions Dependency rate 500 1.3 3,600 1.3 495 3,400 1.2 1.2 490 3,200 1.1 1.1 485 3,000 1.0 1.0 480 2,800 0.9 0.9 475 2,600 470 0.8 2,400 0.8 0 1 04 07 10 13 1 6 19 22 25 0 1 04 07 10 13 16 19 22 25 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 Labor force Dependency rate Source: World Bank databanks (DDP). Note: The dependency rate is measured as the ratio of the nonworking population to working population. 30
T H E P O T E N T I A L G A I N S F R O M I N T E R N A T I O N A L M I G R A T I O N tries would fall by only about 3 percent under numbers hold up well as an approximation of such a scenario. In the case of Japan, it would the gains to global output, regardless of vari- lower the number of elderly dependents in ous assumptions made about taxes, non-wage 2025 from 60 per 100 workers to 59 per 100 income distribution, key model parameters, workers—barely a dent. Nevertheless, as and other factors. discussed in more detail below, selective Our modeling exercise uses a global gen- migration—for example, of experienced and eral equilibrium model to measure the impact skilled workers—can help mitigate the transi- of migration (box 2.1).10 One of the purposes tional costs of financing pension benefits for of the global model is to verify the basic intu- rapidly aging populations in high-income ition described above—that migration pro- countries. duces a sizeable global gain. But it also is a powerful tool to evaluate distributional impacts—between skilled and unskilled work- Migration and its development ers, between native- and foreign-born workers, impact between capital and labor, and across T o illustrate the potential gains from increased migration, we compare the base- case forecast for output and consumption regions—and to show how these distribu- tional impacts vary with policy choices and parameters (for example, the role of fiscal in chapter 1 with an alternative scenario, in policies or the propensity to remit). which the stock of migrant workers is allowed to increase in the high-income countries so The assumption is that migrants as a as to raise the overall stock of workers by 3 per- share of population remain constant cent (a movement of 14.2 million workers in the baseline scenario from developing countries to high-income We begin with a base case for global eco- countries by the year 2025). A first nomic activity (outlined in chapter 1), demo- approximation of the global gains from such a graphic trends (described at the outset of this scenario is simply to calculate the income gains chapter), and for migration. For the base case, accruing to the new migrant workers—this the proportion of migrants in each region re- will reflect the gains to the global economy, mains the same over time—somewhat con- because it approximates the increase in global trary to the trends of the last two decades. productivity derived from equipping the mi- This does not imply that gross migration is grants with more and improved capital and stagnant, or even declining. The stock of mi- technology. This back-of-the-envelope calcula- grants in any year will equal the previous tion yields an increase in gross wage income of stock of migrants, plus new migrants, less the $772 billion in 2025.9 As we will see later, attrition through death and return migration. when corrected for differences in prices that We chose a relatively neutral assumption be- migrants face in high-income versus develop- cause of the difficulty in forecasting these ing countries, and taking into account other complex processes. For some countries—for impacts of migration (on prices, for example) example Japan and those in Europe—the as- as calculated by the model, global gains fall to sumption results in an absolute decline in the $356 billion—an 0.6 percent increase in global stock of migrant workers. This decline paral- income. The scenario is particularly beneficial lels the overall decline in the European and to developing countries relative to high-income Japanese labor forces.11 For the high-income countries. The aggregate percentage gain to countries as a group, the stock of migrant developing countries (including the new mi- workers would increase by some 760,000 grants) is 1.8 percent, whereas the gains to between 2001 and 2025, just a small increment natives in high-income countries amount to from the estimated 27.8 million in 2001. The 0.4 percent relative to baseline income. These main issue, however, is not the base case, 31
G L O B A L E C O N O M I C P R O S P E C T S 2 0 0 6 Box 2.1 The model used in this study including estimates of population and the stock of T he underlying analytical framework used in this chapter is the World Bank’s standard global general equilibrium model—LINKAGE—which has workers, both skilled and unskilled (Walmsley, Ahmed, and Parsons 2005).a World Bank data (de- been used in previous reports for trade policy analy- scribed in more detail in chapter 4 of this report) sis. It has been modified to differentiate between mi- was used to provide the total level of remittances, grant and native workers and to incorporate remit- and the bilateral stock of migrants was used to esti- tances. The model is based on release 6.0 of the mate the bilateral remittance flows subject to the GTAP database (base year 2001), developed by the overall total flows. Global Trade Analysis Project (www.gtap.org), a The standard horizon for the LINKAGE model has global network of researchers and policymakers en- been 2015. For the work described here, the model gaged in the quantitative analysis of international horizon has been extended to 2025, in part because policy issues. It is supplemented for use in our demographic dynamics play a more important role model with a new database developed jointly by over the longer-term horizon, and in part to allow GTAP and the University of Sussex (Parsons and for more time to phase in the increase in migration. others 2005). That database contains a comprehen- sive estimate of bilateral stocks of migrants for 226 countries and territories. aThe 87 regions of GTAP have been aggregated into 21 re- While the new migration database is undergoing constant improvements as new data become avail- gions for the purposes of this study. Six of these are high-in- able and obvious errors are corrected, its developers come regions using World Bank definitions—the European Union and the European Free Trade Area, Canada, the United have done a remarkable amount of detective work, States, Japan, Australia/New Zealand, and the newly-industrial- largely in national data sources. The GTAP center izing economies. The fifteen developing countries/regions in- has used this underlying migration database to build clude China, the Philippines, India, Russia, Turkey, South a bilateral migration database for the 87-region level Africa, and Mexico as individual countries, plus 6 regions that of aggregation of the main GTAP database— represent the remaining countries in each geographical area. but rather the impact of deviations from of high-income countries by 3 percent, phased it—although significantly different base as- in from 2010 through 2020.12 As migrants sumptions could affect the deviations aswell. make up about 6 percent of high-income According to the base-case scenario, mi- countries’ labor force, a 3 percent rise in the grant workers would make up about 6 percent labor force (through migration) implies a of the labor force of high-income countries in 50 percent increase in the number of migrant 2025, though with sharp differences across workers. This may seem like a large change, regions and skills (table 2.2). The vast major- but the resulting stock of migrants in Europe, ity of migrant workers are unskilled—some Japan, and the United States would remain a 25.3 million migrant workers out of a pro- far smaller share of population than current jected total of 28.5 million, or 7.8 percent of levels in some high-migration countries. (In high-income countries’ labor force. Skilled mi- Australia, for example, about a quarter of the grants, on the other hand, represent just 2.2 per- population are migrants, in Canada 19 per- cent of the total skilled workforce on average. cent, in Kuwait 50 percent). The percentage increase in migrants is large in Japan (as the There are welfare implications if baseline share of migrants is relatively low), migration rises significantly and lower in the United States. The increase The alternative scenario involves a rise in corresponds to an annual growth rate of migration sufficient to increase the labor force about 1.9 percent, somewhat slower than the 32
T H E P O T E N T I A L G A I N S F R O M I N T E R N A T I O N A L M I G R A T I O N Table 2.2 Labor force structure in the base case and after increases in migrants In millions except where noted Baseline Migration shock 2001 2025 Change in millions 2001–25 Change in percent 2001–25 High-income countries Total labor force 480.8 474.0 14.2 3.0 Developing-country migrant workers 27.8 28.5 14.2 49.9 Unskilled 24.6 25.3 9.8 38.6 Skilled 3.1 3.2 4.5 137.9 Developing-country migrant workers as share of total labor force, percenta 5.8 6.0 8.8 Unskilled, percent 7.4 7.8 10.5 Skilled, percent 2.1 2.2 5.0 Developing countries Total labor force 2,596.2 3,561.0 –14.2 –0.4 Unskilled 2,395.9 3,294.3 –9.8 –0.3 Skilled 200.4 266.7 –4.5 –1.7 Source: Initial 2001 data from migration database under development by GTAP/University of Sussex (Parsons and others 2005 and Walmsley, Ahmed, and Parsons 2005). Scenarios based on World Bank assumptions. Note: a. The percentage of migrant workers as a share of the total labor force is assumed to be the same for each individual region of the model throughout 2001–25, but the share averaged across all developed regions will change through aggregation effects. average increase over the period 1980–2000. reflect the likely migration pressures implied Moreover, the growth rate is unbalanced, with by large differences in demographic trends in an annual increase of only 1.5 percent in un- sending regions (for example, Sub-Saharan skilled workers, but 3.8 percent in skilled Africa versus Latin America). workers. A number of additional assumptions Third, foreign workers are assumed to are critical to the results. bring family members in proportion to the First, the high-income countries’ labor dependency ratio in their home country. As a force of both skilled and unskilled workers result, the total number of migrants in high- increases by 3 percent.13 As the share of skilled income countries increases from 65 million workers among migrants is much smaller than (6.5 percent of high-income countries’ popula- the share of skilled workers among high- tion) in the baseline for 2025, to 93 million income country natives, the shock results in a (9 percent of population) after the shock. This much larger percentage increase for skilled assumption can change the average depen- migrants. The number of unskilled migrant dency ratio of the host country. It can workers increases by 39 percent, while the also have other implications not modeled number of skilled migrant workers rises by explicitly—including fiscal impacts, because 138 percent.14 the families of new migrants may require ad- Second, the share of migrants by region of ditional public services (such as schooling), origin remains constant; in other words, the not fully compensated by the taxes paid by the new migrants reflect the same allocation by new migrants. region of origin as existing ones. Thus if Fourth, remittances are assumed to be a Mexicans constitute 30 percent of foreign mi- fixed proportion of migrants’ labor income, grants in the United States in the base case, equal to the level in the base year. The average they maintain the same share after the increase for developing countries is 17 percent, although in migration. This assumption is made to sim- the level varies with the migrant’s origin and plify the analysis, although it does fail to destination countries. New migrants are 33
G L O B A L E C O N O M I C P R O S P E C T S 2 0 0 6 assumed to send remittances to their home nearly 0.9 percent from baseline levels.18 A country at the same rate (relative to income) significant portion of the increase is due to the as existing migrants.15 remittances from the new migrants, with some improvement in labor-market conditions for remaining workers. Those who are likely to Returns to households lose—in the absence of any compensatory The gains from increased migration mechanism—are the existing migrants in are large high-income countries, who are relatively With the labor force moving, it is best to close substitutes for the new migrants. Their assess the effects on real income in terms of private consumption would decline by over households as opposed to the national level 9 percent and overall consumption (including (as is typically done in analyses of trade re- public services) by 6 percent compared to form). Households are broken down into four baseline levels. groups. First are the native households in high-income countries.16 Second are previous New migrants and their countries migrants from developing countries now liv- of origin reap benefits ing in high-income countries, that is, those (through remittances) who were in place in the baseline scenario. The main gains come from the higher incomes Third are native households in developing the new migrant workers can earn in the des- countries—households that do not migrate.17 tination country relative to what they would And finally, we have the households of the have earned in their country of origin. New new migrants. Each household’s welfare is migrants earn $481 billion in real (after-tax) broken down between the change in private income in 2025 over the base case. However, consumption and the change in the consump- the dollar increase in income overestimates the tion of public services. welfare gains for migrants. Essentially, an Natives in high-income countries gain additional $1 spent in the high-income coun- $139 billion in real income, or 0.4 percent of tries does not provide the same amount of the baseline, as a result of the rise in migration welfare as an additional $1 spent in the home (table 2.3). Nonmigrating households in de- country, because prices are higher in high- veloping countries see a rise in real income of income countries. Whereas the prices of Table 2.3 Change in real income across households in 2025 relative to baseline Real income adjusted for Real income cost of living Private Public Total Private Public Total Change, $ billions Change, $ billions Natives in high-income countries 139 –1 139 139 –1 139 Old migrants in high-income countries –88 0 –88 –88 0 –88 Natives in developing countries 131 12 143 131 12 143 New migrants 372 109 481 126 36 162 World total 554 120 674 308 48 356 Change, % Change, % Natives in high-income countries 0.44 –0.01 0.36 0.44 –0.01 0.36 Old migrants in high-income countries –9.41 –0.02 –6.02 –9.41 –0.02 –6.02 Natives in developing countries 0.94 0.44 0.86 0.94 0.44 0.86 New migrants 584 607 589 198 203 199 World total 1.20 1.15 1.19 0.67 0.45 0.63 Source: World Bank model simulations. 34
T H E P O T E N T I A L G A I N S F R O M I N T E R N A T I O N A L M I G R A T I O N traded goods (for example, cars and electron- using purchasing power parity (PPP) exchange ics) are the same worldwide, at least in princi- rates from the World Bank’s database.20 Thus ple, the prices of nontraded goods and services instead of an increase of $481 billion, the rise (for example, housing and haircuts) are much in welfare for new migrants is $162 billion.21 higher in high-income countries. Table 2.3 shows the change in these com- A simple example may clarify the idea. ponents for the four household groups and the Take a household of two persons living in world. Measured in national accounting their home country. One works and earns terms, that is, with no adjustments for the dif- $200. The other does not work. Each spends ference in the cost of living for the new mi- $100, half on tradable goods (each priced at grants, global real income rises under the $1) and half on nontradable goods (likewise model by 1.2 percent relative to the baseline, priced at $1). Now the worker moves to a or 0.6 percent with the cost-of-living adjust- high-income country and earns $700. Assume ment. Global private consumption increases in that spending patterns do not change. The real terms by $308 billion in 2025 (with the worker remits $200 back to the home country, cost-of-living adjustment), with real govern- so the income (and welfare, in money terms) ment expenditures increasing by an additional of the other doubles. The new migrant buys $48 billion. The total real gain—with equal the same goods—50 units of tradable goods weight for high-income—and developing- and 50 units of nontradable,19 but the price of country gains—is $356 billion, with just the latter is now $9 and not $1. The migrant under half accruing to the new migrants, thus spends $500, but welfare is unchanged, though natives in both high-income and devel- because the basket of purchased goods is oping countries also are better off. In percent- identical. age terms—where relative weights between Welfare evaluations are of course more high-income and developing countries are complex than this simple example illustrates. irrelevant—the scenario clearly indicates that For one thing, new migrants will have to adjust the relative gains are much higher for their spending patterns to deal with their new developing-country households than high- environment. Heating oil and warm clothes income country households, rivaling gains are necessities that will not boost a migrant’s from global reform of merchandise trade. welfare above what it was in the home coun- Obviously, global income and global gains try. For another, the decision to migrate is not would also be larger if expressed in PPP terms. taken for simply static reasons; there are sig- As the percentage increase in welfare for mi- nificant dynamic reasons for migrating—for grants living (originally) in developing coun- example, better opportunities for one’s chil- tries is larger than the percentage increase for dren that are not captured in this simple frame- those living in high-income countries, a switch work. Nonetheless, the difference in purchas- to PPP measures would also increase the ing power illustrated in the example is a strong global gains as a percentage of global income. motivation for migrating, even on a temporary If in the migration scenario presented here the basis. The more wage income earned in high- gains are PPP-adjusted, the global gains would income countries that can be spent in lower- amount to 0.9 percent of global income in the income countries, the greater will be the wel- baseline, instead of 0.6 percent using the EV fare benefits. Box 2.2 provides additional aggregation. This scenario illustrates that mi- detail on the computation and interpretation grants living (originally) in developing coun- of global welfare gains from migration. tries gain the most from migration in percent- To account for the change in prices faced age terms. by the new migrants, their “new” consump- The impact of higher migration on prices is tion in the destination country is adjusted to mild in aggregate in high-income countries, account for differences in the cost of living, with a small decline in the average price of 35
G L O B A L E C O N O M I C P R O S P E C T S 2 0 0 6 Box 2.2 Calculating and interpreting global welfare gains from migration T wo sets of issues arise with respect to the so- called global gains from a policy shock. First, how should the gains of specific groups be evaluated national accounting standards. However, the stan- dard real income measure is still a good approxima- tion of the welfare gains for the other households in and how do the gains compare with traditional mea- the model. sures, such as GDP or national accounting stan- To the extent that new migrants remit part of dards? Second, how should the gains be aggregated their income to their country of origin and that over groups and countries, and how should the income is spent in that country of origin, the increase aggregated gains be interpreted? in the cost of living that new migrants face is not Evaluation of the welfare gains of specific relevant. Therefore, the EV measure of remittances is groups. In standard applications of general equilib- larger than the same nominal income spent by the rium (GE) models, the welfare impacts of specific new migrant in the host country. This difference groups are evaluated using a concept from welfare illustrates the incentive for new migrants to remit theory called equivalent variation (EV). The con- income home. cept is relatively straightforward. Welfare changes Aggregation. The second issue relates to the inter- as a result of changes in nominal income and pretation of the “global” gains. Typically, to derive changes in prices. EV calculations summarize this aggregate or global gains, EV (expressed in a com- welfare change in terms of an equivalent change mon currency, typically the U.S. dollar) is summed in income alone, showing by how much income across all households. For individual persons or ho- at original prices would have to change to mogeneous groups this EV aggregation, expressed as achieve the same change in welfare as observed in a percentage of original income, is a good approxi- a simulation.a mation of the change in welfare (or more precisely, it For most households, the standard notion of the is a good indication of the change in welfare).e change in real income, that is, the difference in nomi- However, no clear link exists between global wel- nal income adjusted by the change in the CPI, is a fare and the aggregation of EV across heterogeneous good approximation of EV.b groups, because we do not know how to weigh indi- This is not the case for new migrants, however. vidual welfare across heterogeneous groups (a partic- There is no standard price index that can be used as ularly difficult issue in aggregating across countries a deflator for the change in the nominal gains for the at very different stages of development, as is done new migrants, since the prices they face in their new here). For example, while most groups gain from mi- host country have no linkages to the prices they paid gration in the scenario discussed in the text, some in their home countries. GE and macro models typi- lose. The fact that the change in global welfare (ex- cally calibrate base-year prices in each region to one pressed as the aggregation of EV across groups) is (or unit value) by choosing corresponding volume positive does not mean that the welfare gains of the units.c winners are considered more important than the wel- This approach does not allow one to take into ac- fare losses of the losers. Thus, global gains as ex- count the price increases that new migrants face as pressed in aggregate EV should not be interpreted as a result of their migration. In the simulations, the a value judgment on how to weigh individual or macro PPP exchange rate (as an approximation of local welfare gains. the rise in prices faced by migrants from developing The aggregation of EV across groups does, to high-income countries) has been used to adjust the however, have a useful interpretation, which is gains to the migrants—although this is just an ap- linked to the notion of compensation and Pareto proximation of the true welfare gains.d optimality. As long as the global gains are positive— Because of the cost-of-living adjustment to the using the standard practice of adding up EVs across welfare gain of new migrants, the real gain reported households—then it is possible through redistribu- is no longer equal to real income gains of tion to compensate households that lose (so that no countries—and real output gains—measured using one is worse off relative to the baseline scenario), 36
T H E P O T E N T I A L G A I N S F R O M I N T E R N A T I O N A L M I G R A T I O N Box 2.2 (continued) when some households are better off. In that sense developing countries in global aggregates would in- the global gain can be compared with an equal rise crease in the measurement of both global income in global output plus redistribution. levels and global welfare gains. However, the per- In this report we maintain this standard practice centage increase in income for developing countries of reporting EV aggregates, making the gains compa- would not be affected. rable to global gains in many other studies. An alternative approach to calculating global aOne of the advantages of the EV measure is that it trans- gains would be to add up changes in income mea- forms the ordinal concept of welfare into a cardinal concept of sured in PPP terms. The rationale for that alterna- income. While it is impossible to measure how much one welfare level differs from another (one can only conclude that one level is tive is that because prices of nontraded goods are preferred to another), the corresponding increase in income can lower in developing countries, the addition of a dol- be measured, and the size of the increase has a clear meaning. lar to a developing country would enable the pur- bFor example, in trade-reform scenarios, the change in the chase of a larger amount of goods and services than price index is a relatively good approximation of the welfare in an high-income country. In that case, both base impact, since the new price is approximately the old price less income and gains for new migrants and for those the tariff. cThere are exceptions. For example, in the case of climate- who remain in developing countries would be change models, it is necessary to know the relative prices of the roughly three times as large as reported here. This different fuels to accurately determine the carbon tax. is true for all gains, whether they come from migra- dSee Timmer and van der Mensbrugghe (2005) for more tion itself, from remittances, or from changes in details. eThe size of the change in individual welfare is undeter- wages and prices in developing countries. As a re- sult, the share of those who live (originally) in mined, since welfare is an ordinal concept. absorption (private consumption, private in- For the new migrants, the real income vestment, and government spending) of 0.1 gains—cost-of-living adjusted—increase by percent. However, prices of some key nontrad- nearly 200 percent. There are large differences ables decline by larger amounts—0.8 percent across regions, with the highest gains (in per- on average for public services (including centage terms) accruing to migrants from Sub- health-related services) and 0.2 percent for con- Saharan Africa (619 percent) and the lowest struction and recreational services. These price to migrants from the Middle East and North declines will be even sharper for specific sub- Africa and Europe and Central Asia. The main sectors where migrant workers are concen- reason for the disparity is the relative differen- trated (for example, household help), for which tial between wages in origin and destination we currently have no comprehensive data. countries. Variations in wages paid to mi- The allocation of the gains across develop- grants from different regions in destination ing countries depends on various factors, in- countries are minor, whereas there are very cluding the skill loss and the resulting impact wide variations in wages in countries of ori- on production, the locations to which mi- gin. For example, the average wage for a mi- grants move and the relative wage differential, grant in Europe in the base year is about and the propensity to remit. By developing re- $16,500—with only minor variation across gion, the gains to households under the model migrants. However, the average wage in Sub- vary from 0.6 percent for Europe and Central Saharan Africa is only $470, whereas in the Asia to 1.1 percent for South Asia and Latin Middle East and North Africa it is $2,700. America and the Caribbean (table 2.4). Thus, the migrant from Sub-Saharan Africa 37
G L O B A L E C O N O M I C P R O S P E C T S 2 0 0 6 Table 2.4 Real income impacts across developing regions Change in 2025 relative to the baseline, adjusted for differences in cost of living Natives in region New migrants from region $ billions Percent $ billions Percent Total developing 143 0.9 162 199 East Asia and Pacific 37 0.7 32 215 South Asia 21 1.1 2 175 Europe and Central Asia 14 0.6 25 138 Middle East and North Africa 18 0.9 11 134 Sub-Saharan Africa 7 0.9 7 619 Latin America and the Caribbean 47 1.1 85 224 Source: World Bank model simulations. will gain much more in both absolute and per- several channels, some of which increase, and centage terms than one from the Middle East others that decrease, trade flows: and North Africa. • First, the rise in incomes due to migra- The impact of migration on trade tion produces a small rise in global trade would be mild flows, with regional differentiation (be- Whether migration and trade are substitutes cause income gains differ considerably for each other is an old debate. For exam- among regions). In addition to higher in- ple, in the discussions leading up to the sign- comes, the rise in migration changes the ing of NAFTA—the free trade agreement size of regional economies, with implica- among the United States, Canada, and tions for their demand for imports and Mexico—one of the key arguments was that ability to export. trade would replace migration and reduce • Second, the nature of the shock assumed the pressure for Mexicans to migrate to the in our model differs from the standard North. Likewise, allowing for increased debate over trade and migration. The migration—for example of unskilled share of skilled workers in total migrants workers—could reduce trade, because it is larger in the shock than in actual mi- would enable the high-income countries to gration over the recent past. A large continue producing low-skill-intensive prod- proportion of skilled workers will find ucts at competitive cost. employment in nontraded sectors—for Evidence of the link between trade and example, as doctors and nurses—rather changing the comparative advantage emerges than in producing traded goods. This in the migration scenario described here. For will have general equilibrium effects to example, the largest gains in export revenue the extent that the price of nontraded for high-income countries come in agriculture, goods will decline by more than the price clothing, other manufacturing, recreational of traded goods. Thus there will be a rel- services, and public services—all labor- ative shift to nontraded goods and a intensive sectors, the first four being relatively potential reduction in demand for im- intensive in unskilled workers and the last in ports of traded goods. Overall, the larger skilled workers. share of skilled versus unskilled workers Change in comparative advantage has only does tend to reduce trade flows. a mild impact on trade flows in this scenario, • Third, the increase in remittances pro- however, as migration affects trade through vides an opportunity for developing 38
T H E P O T E N T I A L G A I N S F R O M I N T E R N A T I O N A L M I G R A T I O N countries to import more and export less, Migrants’ impact on government fiscal as their current-account balance will in- accounts is broadly neutral crease by the size of the remittances ($98 The assumption concerning the level of billion in net terms). The model results consumption of public goods and services by show that total imports into developing new migrants has important implications for countries would increase by $58 billion individual gains, and global gains, under the in 2025 (1.1 percent relative to the base- modeled scenario. We assume that the new line), as aggregate exports decline by migrants’ level of consumption of public $40 billion (0.7 percent).22 The change goods and services equals the amount they pay in remittances leads to an appreciation of in taxes, that is, their impact on the public the real exchange rate and therefore a budget is revenue-neutral. This is broadly con- loss in relative export competitiveness.23 sistent with the available evidence (box 2.3). For instance, the output price index in To provide some sense of how different ap- developing countries rises by 0.6 percent proaches would affect the scenario results, we on average, whereas it declines by 0.1 per- present two alternative assumptions regarding cent for high-income countries. the distribution of public goods and services to the new migrants (table 2.5). The default In summary, the scenario provides evidence assumption had a largely neutral impact for that changes in comparative advantage due to existing residents in the host country. Under migration do influence trade flows. However, another assumption—new migrants pay taxes overall migration and trade are not substitutes but receive no benefits from public goods and for each other, because migration has many services—existing residents, native and mi- other economic effects that have more power grant, enjoy a rise in real incomes of $126 bil- to stimulate or reduce trade. One implication lion ($117 billion for natives and $9 billion of this finding is that migration policies should for existing migrant households). Note that not be pursued because of their specific impact the global welfare gains increase as well, since on trade flows. Likewise, in trade policies the the income accruing to natives (and existing impact on migration should not be a main migrants) is not adjusted for the differences in focus.24 Trade and migration policies should the cost of living between developing and be evaluated on their own merits. high-income countries.25 A second extreme Table 2.5 Impact of different assumptions on the consumption of public goods and services by selected groups in 2025 Change in cost-of-living-adjusted real income in 2025; billions of dollars Default assumption— “New” migrants “New” migrants receive benefits receive no public “New” migrants equal to their benefits but pay receive per capita taxes taxes average benefit Private Public Total Public Total Public Total Natives in high-income countries 139 1 139 117 256 85 54 Old migrants in high-income countries 88 0 88 9 79 6 94 Natives in developing countries 131 12 143 12 143 12 143 New migrants 126 36 162 18 108 75 201 World total 308 48 356 120 428 4 304 Source: World Bank model simulations. 39
G L O B A L E C O N O M I C P R O S P E C T S 2 0 0 6 Box 2.3 The impact of immigrants on fiscal balances 60s generally imposed a long-term burden. Studies I mmigrants’ net contribution to fiscal revenues is usually considered to be small. The net fiscal im- pact of immigration on the United States has been that follow immigrants over time generally conclude that in net-present-value terms, immigrants and their minimal (Coppel, Dumont, and Visco 2001; descendants tend to contribute more in terms of tax Auerbach and Oreopoulos 1999). The U.S. revenues than they absorb in expenditures, but the or- Binational Study on Migration (1997) found that ir- ders of magnitude are typically small (OECD 1997). regular migrants did impose a significant fiscal bur- Intergenerational models are sensitive to the discount den on state and local government. However, school rate used and assumptions concerning the allocation expenses accounted for the bulk of these costs, and of the fiscal burden over future generations. (as the authors note) education is an investment Third, the computation will depend on the level that may readily be recovered in greater future pro- of skills, experience, education, and fertility of immi- ductivity. Moreover, Lee and Miller (2000) found grants. Rowthorn (2004) calculates that skilled mi- that the overall fiscal consequences of altering the grants to the United States typically make a large volume of immigration to the United States would positive contribution to the fiscal balance, whereas be quite small. Gott and Johnston (2002) and unskilled immigrants cost more on average than the Sriskandarajah, Cooley, and Reed (2005) estimated that immigrants made a positive contribution to taxes they pay. Storesletten (2000) calculates that the public finances in the United Kingdom. Gustafsson net-present-value contribution of the average high- and Osterberg (2001) found that new immigrants to skilled immigrant to the U.S. budget is $96,000; the Sweden generated a net fiscal cost, but this turned medium-skilled immigrant’s contribution is $2,000; into a positive contribution after a few years. Nana and low-skilled immigrant’s contribution is and Williams (1999) found that immigrants to New $36,000. Zealand had a positive fiscal impact. Bonin, The results may change over time, as migrant Raffelhuschen, and Walliser (2000) found that the characteristics and government policies change. The net fiscal contribution of immigrants to Germany probability that an immigrant to the United States could be significant if the government selects for will receive public benefits has risen since the 1970s, skills. probably due to an increasing share of immigrants Calculations of the net fiscal cost of immigration from poorer countries (Gustmann and Steinmeier are fraught with difficulties, for several reasons. 1998). First, the computation at any point in time An issue of particular concern has been the im- depends heavily on the methodology used, what pact of migration on government-financed pensions. expenditures and revenues are included, which public Likely increases in immigration can make only a services should be regarded as pure public goods (and small net contribution to strengthening the financing the extent of economies of scale in expenditures), and of pensions in the United States (Fehr, Jokisch, and whether households or individuals are considered. Kotlikoff 2004), although selecting immigrants for Second, static calculations of the current net fiscal working age and high skill levels could improve the impact fail to take into account the age structure of picture (Storesletten 2000). By contrast, increases in the immigrant population. Smith and Edmonston immigration could make a significant contribution (1997) found that immigrants arriving between the to financing pensions in Germany (Bonin, Raffel- ages of 10 and 25 years produced fiscal benefits under huschen, and Walliser 2000) and Spain (Collado, most scenarios, while immigrants arriving in their late Iturbe-Ormaetxe, and Valera 2004). assumption is that new migrants receive the taxes.26 In this case natives in high-income same amount in public benefits as the average countries would lose $85 billion in aggregate household in the destination country. This public goods and services, although this would imply a net positive transfer to the new amount would not translate one-for-one into a migrant households, since they would receive benefit for new migrants due to the cost-of- more in public benefits than they paid in living adjustment. These simulations underline 40
T H E P O T E N T I A L G A I N S F R O M I N T E R N A T I O N A L M I G R A T I O N the effect of public policy on the distribution those from an increase in migration, and those of gains from migration. from global trade reform—are scaled to the same reference year, 2001, the gains from trade reforms are $155 billion versus $175 bil- Additional gains from migration lion from the migration scenario.29 This can be substantial leaves little doubt that easing restrictions on The gains for migrants from this scenario the movement of labor could provide a sig- essentially provide the same message as ear- nificant boost to the global economy. More- lier estimates. In their seminal paper, Walmsley over, in comparison with the most recent and Winters (2003) estimate that a relax- work on global merchandise trade reform, ation on the movement of temporary work- the gains from an increase in migration are ers on the same order as that modeled more balanced toward income increases for here—that is, 3 percent of the labor force of developing countries relative to developed the high-income countries—would yield countries. In a study by Anderson, Martin, global income gains of $150 billion (using a and van der Mensbrugghe (2005), the gains 1997-based comparative static model). The to high-income and developing countries are result from our scenario that is roughly 0.6 and 0.8 percent, respectively, relative to comparable to their figures (that is, global baseline income. In the scenario modeled gains before adjustment for cost of living here, the income increases are 0.4 percent and measured relative to 2001, rather than for native households in high-income coun- 2025) are more than double their results.27 tries and 1.8 percent for developing coun- However, our figures are comparable with tries (including the new migrants). the more recent work done by Walmsley and her colleagues.28 One of the key reasons for the increase in the global welfare impact Returns to factors of production is a reevaluation of the assumed wage dif- ferential between the home and host coun- try. In their initial work, Walmsley and F our critical factors determine the distribu- tion of gains from migration among skilled workers, unskilled workers, and owners of Winters had assumed that new migrants capital: (a) the size of the increase in migra- made up 50 percent of the difference be- tion; (b) the distribution of nonwage income tween the home and host country’s wages. (profits); (c) the degree of substitution between Their new assumption (used in our model as workers by region of origin; and (d) the degree well) is 75 percent, based in part on the fact of substitution or complementarity between that the migrants are permanent rather than workers and capital. We have already posited temporary. Hamilton and Whalley (1984) that the increase in migration is large, with an and Moses and Letnes (2004) have shown average increase in the migrant labor force of that removing all restrictions on labor around 50 percent over a 20-year period, and movement, admittedly not a realistic sce- comparable (if somewhat less) to the rise in the nario, would yield a huge increase in world share of migrants in high-income country pop- output. Overall, these papers suggest that ulation over 1970–2000. In the absence of any labor-market restrictions are imposing a specific data on the source of migrant income, much larger burden on the global economy we assume that migrants—both existing and than are trade restrictions. The World Bank’s new—receive no nonwage income. In essence, trade model suggests that removing all re- their real income will be driven by changes in maining merchandise trade barriers would wages. The effects of this simple assumption yield $287 billion in global real income gains on the distribution of gains are significant, and in 2015. For the purpose of comparison, when the implications of relaxing it are discussed the gains from the two different scenarios— below. 41
You can also read