Polls and Elections Two Paradigms of Presidential Nominations
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Polls and Elections Two Paradigms of Presidential Nominations WAYNE STEGER DePaul University This article uses forecasts of the contested vote in presidential primaries to assess competing hypotheses about political power in presidential nominations. Forecasts are estimated using information from the invisible primary and from the earliest nominating elections as a means of assessing which nominations were largely settled during the invisible primary consistent with Cohen et al. (2008) and which were influenced more by momentum during the primaries as Aldrich (1980) and Bartels (1988) argue. Both patterns exist, which suggests that future research on presidential nominations should focus on why party elites and mass partisans unify more in some years than in other years. The time frame at which presidential nominations can be forecast accurately provides us with a clue about when a winning nominating coalition coalesces in a political party, which in turn provides insights about political power in the nomination process. This article uses updated forecasts of the contested vote in presidential primaries to assess competing hypotheses from different theoretical approaches to the study of presidential nominations. One theoretical perspective holds that presidential nomina- tions are largely determined during the invisible primary (e.g., Cohen et al., 2003, 2008; Hadley 1976; Haynes et al. 2004; Mayer 1996; Steger 2000). In this scenario the caucuses and primaries play a plebiscitary role, confirming the results of the campaign occurring before the primaries when party elites, activists, donors, and groups evaluate candidates and coordinate among themselves in order to unify behind a presidential candidate—before the mass membership of the party weigh in on the selection of the nominee. The other theoretical approach focuses on candidates’ campaign momentum during the caucuses and primaries (e.g., Aldrich 1980; Bartels 1988; Norrander 1993, 2006; Popkin 1991). We can get a sense of which argument is correct by assessing the accuracy of presidential primary vote forecasts that use information from different points in time. Wayne Steger is professor of political science at DePaul University. His current research focuses on presidential nominations and on the implications of partisan ideology and budgetary process for patterns of taxes, spending, and deficits. Presidential Studies Quarterly 43, no. 2 (June) 377 © 2013 Center for the Study of the Presidency
378 | PRESIDENTIAL STUDIES QUARTERLY / June 2013 Forecasts of the presidential primary vote differ from general election forecasts and other kinds of static explanatory models in a critical respect. Since presidential nominees are chosen through a sequential process that begins years before and continues through a series of caucuses and primaries, the process can be thought of as a Bayesian updating model (e.g., Morton and Williams 1999). In Bayesian terms, the nomination campaign leading up to the caucuses and primaries establishes an expectation for the outcome of the campaign, and this baseline expectation is updated through successive caucuses and primaries. As such, it is possible to use forecast models to assess the relative impact of conditions and events at different points in time to determine which phases of the campaign are critical to the determination of the outcome. This article estimates forecast models using information known at the end of the invisible primary period and compares these with forecast models using information from the earliest caucuses and primaries— the events considered to have the greatest impact on subsequent primary vote. If the nominee can be predicted accurately using information from the invisible primary, then the caucuses and primaries would appear to confirm the results of the earlier processes. However, if pre-primary forecasts have substantial error and that error is reduced by information about the results of the earliest nominating elections, then the caucuses and primaries can be said to have an independent influence on the outcome and thus campaign momentum affects the outcome. Rather than affirming one perspective or the other, this study shows that both patterns exist in different presidential nomination campaigns. One pattern is evidenced by substantial coalescence of party elites and mass partisans during the invisible primary behind a “front-runner” who goes on to win the nomination. Party elites, activists, and groups, however, do not always unify behind a candidate before the caucuses and primaries. These campaigns are distinguishable in forecasting models by larger errors in the prediction of candidate vote shares. In these nomination cycles, models incorporating information from the results of early caucuses and primaries substantially improve predictive accuracy. The occurrence of both patterns raises an important question about why political party elites and mass identifiers unify during the invisible primary period in some election cycles more than during others. The next section briefly reviews models of presidential primary vote forecasts. Then I estimate the models for a common set of candidates and nomination campaigns from 1980 to 2012 to compare these models on an equal footing. The following section compares the pre-Iowa forecasts with “momentum” models that incorporate the results of the Iowa caucus and New Hampshire primary to predict the remaining primary vote. The discussion focuses on the implications for future research on presidential nominations. Presidential Primary Vote Forecasts Forecasting models implicitly assume that the critical period in the presidential nomination process occurs before the primaries (e.g., Adkins and Dowdle 2000; Mayer 1996; Steger 2000). Only those candidates who emerge from the pre-primary campaign
Steger / TWO PARADIGMS OF PRESIDENTIAL NOMINATIONS | 379 as viable options for primary voters have a realistic chance of winning the nomination. Viable candidates are those raising money, gaining the backing of party insiders and the support of party identifiers in national polls prior to the caucuses and primaries (e.g., Butler 2004; Cohen et al. 2008; Haynes, et al. 2004; Hull 2008; Mayer 1996; Steger, Dowdle, and Adkins (2004). If the pre-primary competition for support and resources affects candidate support in the primaries, then models accounting for these effects should predict the presidential primary vote. Mayer’s (1996) presidential primary vote forecast model found that candidates’ support in the last national Gallup poll taken before the Iowa caucus was a powerful predictor of the aggregate primary vote in contested presidential nominations. Mayer argues that that candidates’ personal and programmatic appeal are integrated into aggre- gate level, national polls of party identifiers and leaners—the people most likely to vote in the presidential primaries. Forecast models consistently show that national opinion polls are a powerful predictor of the presidential primary vote. Adkins and Dowdle (2000, 2005) forecast the presidential primary vote in open nominations from 1980 to 2004.1 In addition to mass partisan support before the primaries, their model showed that candidates’ cash reserves—how much money they have on hand when the primaries begin also is a significant predictor of the primary vote. Steger (2007, 2009) found that endorsements by party elected officials were a significant predictor of the presidential primary vote. Cohen et al. (2003, 2008) find the same result with a somewhat different data set including endorsements by political activists and groups active in presidential nomination campaigns.2 Endorsements by party elites and activists reflect an insider game, as opposed to a mass partisan effect, with candidate endorsements serving as cues to attentive publics about which candidates are viable and desirable. Such cues may be important when voters cannot use party labels to differentiate candidates and when prospective primary voters have little information about candidates’ policy positions (Jamieson et al. 2000). Steger (2008) also argued that the predictive effects of Gallup polls and cash reserves vary with the competitiveness of the pre-primary nomination campaign. Gallup polls predict well in noncompetitive campaigns in which there is a front-runner before the Iowa caucus, while cash reserves help predict winners in competitive races without a clear front-runner. Forecast models based on information from the period before the primaries, however, have substantial error in some nomination campaigns. Pre-primary forecast models predict well when party elites and rank-and-file partisans are fairly unified in their support of a candidate for their party’s presidential nomination. Party elites, activists, and identifiers do not always unify behind a presidential candidate before the primaries, and in such cases, pre-primary forecasts miss the mark substantially. Candidates who gain momentum by beating expectations for their vote share in early caucuses and primaries receive a surge in media coverage, fund-raising, and support in subsequent primaries (Bartels 1988), while others drop out as they fall behind in the delegate count or run out 1. Open nominations are those without an incumbent president seeking renomination (see below). 2. The differences between the Steger (2008, 2009) models and those of Cohen et al. (2008) are relatively small since the number of endorsements by party activist endorsements is small relative to endorsements by elite elected officials, particularly once endorsements are weighted.
380 | PRESIDENTIAL STUDIES QUARTERLY / June 2013 of money (Norrander 2006). Forecasts based on factors from before the primaries do not account for the effects of positive or negative momentum during the primaries. Thus, forecasts incorporating the results of the earliest caucuses and primaries—the events considered to have the greatest impact on the subsequent primary vote—correct for under- and overpredictions of the precaucus forecasts for candidates who gain or lose momentum during these events. Adkins and Dowdle (2001), Steger et al. (2004), and Steger (2007) developed forecast models that incorporate various measures of the Iowa caucus and New Hampshire primary results to predict the remaining primary vote. Data and Methods This article estimates models for a common set of candidates and nomination campaigns to compare these models on an equal footing.3 Assessing the consistency or divergence of the results generated by different models provides evidence on the robust- ness of estimates for individual predictors in the models. The unit of analysis is the candidates’ vote shares in contested primaries (CPV), which is the vote in primaries prior to the date on which a candidate gains a majority of convention delegates, in open nominations without an incumbent president. In the “momentum” models, the depen- dent variable is calculated as candidates’ shares of the CPV minus their shares of the New Hampshire primary vote.4 The pre-Iowa models use data from the last the Federal Election Commission reporting period proximate to the Iowa caucus.5 This ensures that variables are measured at roughly the same point in political time—at a point closest to the Iowa caucuses when media and public attention is relatively high. Explanation of the measurement and coding of variables can be found in Steger (2008, 2009). Analysis and Discussion The results presented here differ somewhat from the original published results for the respective models as a result of using nominations and a primary vote measure that may differ from those of the original studies. Estimating the models using the same dependent variable over the same set of candidates and elections, however, is valuable because it allows us to make reliable comparisons of the relative impacts of variables. Mayer’s model is the most parsimonious but is somewhat less accurate than the other forecast models (see Table 1). The model correctly predicts the nominee in eight of 12 open nomination races—nine of 12 if we recognize that Hillary Clinton won the most 3. See Steger (2008, 2009) for extended discussion of the methodological issues involved in forecast- ing the presidential primary vote. 4. Data on candidate vote shares were obtained from Congressional Quarterly (2005) and from http://www.thegreenpapers.com (accessed January 22, 2013) for 2008 and 2012. 5. When the Iowa caucus occurs in January, all of the pre-Iowa variables are measured at the end of December of the preceding calendar year. For nominations in which the Iowa caucus occurs in February, all of the pre-Iowa variables are measured at the end of January of the election year.
Steger / TWO PARADIGMS OF PRESIDENTIAL NOMINATIONS | 381 TABLE 1 Pre-Iowa Forecasts of the Vote in Contested Presidential Primaries, 1980-2012 Mayer Gallup + Adkins & Dowdle Steger Endorse + Funds1 Gallup + Reserves Competitive Interactions Constant -.95 (2.46) -1.17 (2.57) 1.74 (1.75) Gallup relative to leader(last pre-IA) .35 (.06)** .31 (.07)** Gallup(last pre-IA) .51 (.25)** Gallup(last pre-IA) x non-competitive race .51 (.31)* % S Funds Raised relative to leader(closest pre-IA) .10 (.05)* % S Funds Spent relative to leader(closest pre-IA) .08 (.06) % Cash Reserves relative to leader(closest pre-IA) .06 (.06) % Cash Reserves(closest pre-IA) -.26 (.16) % Cash Reserves(closest pre-IA) x competitive .42 (.22)* Southern Democrat dummy -.05 (5.32) Elite Party Endorsements(prior to Iowa) .28 (.12)** 2 Adj. r .53 .52 .64 F 45.48 22.69 28.47 DW 2.19 2.19 2.38 80 80 80 Avg. absolute error, all candidates 8.97 8.99 7.78 ** denotes coefficients significant at the p < .05 level, * at the p < .10 level. primary votes in 2008. The model generates a slightly higher absolute percentage error in the prediction of candidates’ contested primary vote shares (m = 8.97%). While getting the winner right in most of the nominations, the model has substantial error in estimating the nominee’s share of the vote in contested primaries (see Table 2). The predicted vote share of the eventual nominee differs by an average of 17.5% from the nominees’ actual vote share. Updated through the 2012 nomination cycle, the model yields a significant coefficient for fund-raising for the first time. The variable was shown in all prior years to have been insignificant, including in Mayer’s original model. The Adkins and Dowdle model performs about the same as the Mayer model. The model has a similar absolute error of predicted vote shares across all candidates (m = 8.99%) and predicts correctly the winner in nine of 12 counting Hillary Clinton as the winner of the primary vote in 2008 (see Table 1). The model has a marginal improvement in the prediction of the contested primary vote shares of the eventual nominees (see Table 2). Candidates’ cash reserves are no longer a significant predictor as was the case for the nomination campaigns of the 1980s and 1990s. The Internet and the emergence of super political action committees provide sufficient capacity for fund- raising in very short time periods so that candidates with large cash reserves no longer have the advantage that they had in prior years. The Steger endorsement and competition model yields a lower absolute error of vote share prediction (m = 7.78%) and correctly predicts the winner of the CPV in 10 of 12 open nominations if we count Hillary Clinton as the winner of the primary vote in 2008. The improvement in the model comes mainly from the inclusion of candidate endorsements by elite elected officials in the political parties. Both elite and mass party
382 | PRESIDENTIAL STUDIES QUARTERLY / June 2013 TABLE 2 Predicted Primary Vote Share for the Eventual Nominee in Open Nominations, 1980-20121 Adkins & Dowdle Steger Endorsements & Mayer Gallup + Funds Gallup + Reserves Competitive Interaction Pred. rank Vote Error2 Pred. rank Vote Error2 Pred. rank Vote Error2 Ronald Reagan 1980 R 1 -19.24 1 -16.85 1 -16.99 Walter Mondale 1984 D 1 5.72 1 6.09 1 0.18 Michael Dukakis 1988 D 2 -11.92 2 -10.05 1 -21.28 George H. W. Bush 1988 R 1 -15.69 1 -18.81 1 -4.14 Bill Clinton 1992 D 1 -8.25 1 -7.93 1 0.17 Bob Dole 1996 R 1 -10.10 1 -9.73 1 -2.89 Al Gore 2000 D 1 -27.08 1 -28.78 1 -0.46 George W. Bush 2000 R 1 -15.32 1 -14.95 1 4.93 John Kerry 2004 D 4 -42.32 4 -41.80 3 -44.71 Barack Obama 2008 D3 2 -19.08 2 -19.02 2 -21.64 John McCain 2008 R 4 -21.00 4 -21.98 2 -22.78 Mitt Romney 2012 R 1 -14.33 1 -4.51 1 -3.45 Average absolute error 17.50 16.71 11.97 1 Models based on data from the end of January for primaries in 1980, 1984, 1988, and 1992; and data from the end of December for primaries in 1996, 2000, 2004, 2008, and 2012. 2 Predicted minus actual vote share. Negative signs indicate under prediction. 3 Clinton received the most votes across all primaries, including the Michigan and Florida primaries in 2008. preferences for candidates are strong predictors of the primary vote, although elite party endorsements have less predictive power than do candidates’ standings in pre-primary national polls. As in prior years, the model also indicates that effect of cash reserves is limited to competitive races lacking a clear front-runner.6 Compared to the other models, the Steger model substantially reduces the degree of error in predicting the vote shares of the eventual nominee. The model yields a lower absolute error of prediction of for the eventual nominees (m = 11.97%), compared to a mean absolute error of prediction of about 17% in the other models (see Table 2). The nominee usually is the candidate with the most support from political party insiders. Though these prediction errors are large compared to those of general election forecasts, error rates of this magnitude are expected given multiple candidates, low levels of public knowledge of candidates, and sequential primaries. The models accurately predict the vote share of the nominee in nomination campaigns when party insiders and mass partisans coalesce around a front-runner during the invisible primary. Races in which no clear front-runner emerges are competitive at the end of the pre-primary season, and these are the nominations that are influenced by the results of the early caucuses and primaries consistent with arguments about campaign momentum. The errors in the pre-Iowa forecast models are greatest for the candidates who gained the most momentum (e.g., Gary Hart in 1984, John McCain in 2000, John Kerry in 2004, and Barack Obama 6. Competitive races are defined as nominations without a pre-Iowa front-runner with more than 50% in Gallup polls in 1988, 1992, 2004, and 2008 for Democrats and 2008 and 2012 for Republicans (see Mayer 2008; Steger 2008).
Steger / TWO PARADIGMS OF PRESIDENTIAL NOMINATIONS | 383 TABLE 3 Momentum Forecasts of the Contested Post–New Hampshire Primary Vote in Open Nominations, 1980-2012 Adkins & Dowdle + Momentum Steger + Momentum Constant -1.62 (1.56) -.94 (1.29) Gallup relative to leader(last pre-IA) .19 (.04)** Gallup(last pre-IA) .74 (.17)** Gallup(last pre-IA) x non-competitive race -.11 (.20) % S Funds Spent relative to leader(closest pre-IA) -.02 (.05) % Cash Reserves relative to leader(closest pre-IA) .05 (.04) % Cash Reserves(closest pre-IA) .07 (.11) Cash reserves(closest pre-IA) x competitive -.07 (.15) Southern Democrat dummy 4.16 (3.23) Elite party endorsements(prior to Iowa) .07 (.08) Iowa winner 17.37 (3.82)** 13.94 (3.48)** Iowa vote share -.16 (.11) Iowa vote share—Gallup(last pre-IA) .23 (.12)* New Hampshire winner 18.55 (4.17)** 18.84 (3.64)** New Hampshire vote share .42 (.14)** New Hampshire vote share—Iowa vote share .36 (.12)** Adj. r2 .83 .85 F 49.43 52.22 DW 2.00 2.17 N 80 80 Average absolute error, all candidates 5.35 5.03 ** denotes coefficients significant at the p < .05 level, * denotes p < .10. and John McCain in 2008) and for those who lost the most momentum (e.g., John Glenn in 1984, Howard Dean in 2004). Including variables that reflect the effects of “momen- tum” from the Iowa and New Hampshire elections largely corrects for under- and overpredictions resulting from gains or losses of momentum from these elections. Models with information from the Iowa caucuses and the New Hampshire primary reduce by more than half the remaining variance unaccounted for by the pre-Iowa forecast models (compare Tables 2 and 4). The momentum models greatly reduce absolute error of predictions in candidates’ vote shares (bottom row, Table 3), as well as the prediction errors for the vote shares of the eventual nominees (bottom row, Table 4). The addition of cases for 2012 improve slightly the predictive accuracy of the Adkins and Dowdle’s (2005) momentum model, which yields an average absolute error of 5.35% for all of the candidates compared to 8.90% in their pre-Iowa model. The actual minus predicted vote share is 7.49% for the eventual nominees compared to 16.71% in their pre-Iowa model. Their momentum model predicts the winner of the CPV in 11 of 12 open nominations since 1980—and all 12 if Hillary Clinton is recognized as the winner of the 2008 Democratic primary vote. The model also shows that the candidates’ vote shares in the New Hampshire primary (but not the Iowa caucuses) also significantly affect candidates’ shares of the vote in the remaining contested primaries. The Steger momentum model has a slightly lower absolute average error of pre- diction, and there is very little difference in the errors for the eventual nominees (6.05%)
384 | PRESIDENTIAL STUDIES QUARTERLY / June 2013 TABLE 4 Predicted Vote Share in Contested Primaries for the Eventual Nominee in Open Nominations, 1980-20121 Adkins & Dowdle + Momentum Steger + Momentum Pred. rank Vote Error2 Pred. rank Vote Error2 Ronald Reagan 1980 R 1 -6.56 1 -9.57 Walter Mondale 1984 D 1 2.97 1 4.67 Michael Dukakis 1988 D 1 0.08 1 -6.77 George H. W. Bush 1988 R 1 -7.72 1 -3.74 Bill Clinton 1992 D 1 -18.23 1 -10.92 Bob Dole 1996 R 1 -10.45 1 -6.87 Al Gore 2000 D 1 -4.03 1 1.39 George W. Bush 2000 R 1 -15.67 1 -4.00 John Kerry 2004 D 1 -7.32 1 -10.39 Barack Obama 2008 D3 2 -10.86 2 -10.74 John McCain 2008 R 1 -1.44 1 -2.71 Mitt Romney 2012 R 1 4.59 1 0.76 Average absolute error 7.49 6.05 1 Models based on data from the end of January for primaries in 1980, 1984, 1988, and 1992; and data from the end of December for primaries in 1996, 2000, 2004, 2008, and 2012. 2 Predicted minus actual vote share. Negative signs indicate under prediction. 3 Clinton received the most votes across all primaries including the Michigan and Florida primaries in 2008. as for the average candidate (5.03%). This model also correctly predicts the winner in all 12 open nominations since 1980 if we recognize Clinton as the winner of the 2008 primary vote. In contrast to the estimates after the 2008 elections, the updated model shows that party elite endorsements are not significant predictors of the primary vote once the momentum variables are taken into account. There are several possibilities for this result. One is that elite party endorsements, the party establishment type, have less effect than in the past. Party activist effects, not measured in the Steger model, could be gaining relative to party establishment influence. The other possibility is that the information provided by endorsements of party elites is eclipsed by the informational effects of the first nominating elections consistent with a Bayesian updating process. Party elite endorsements also may be having less impact because fewer political party elites are making an endorsement prior to the caucuses and primaries. In 2012, for example, more than three-quarters of the Republican governors, senators, and represen- tatives stood on the sidelines waiting for a front-runner to emerge before committing to a candidate. In the 2004 and 2008 Democratic and the 2008 Republican campaigns, the eventual nominee ran behind other candidates in endorsements. Romney had more elite endorsements than had John McCain prior to the 2008 Iowa caucuses. That a greater proportion of party elites are refraining from making an endorsement during the invisible primary is not consistent with the theoretical argument that political party insiders coordinate among themselves to pick their party’s nominee. If these results hold up in other kinds of analyses, then it might suggest that the influence of party elites may be waning relative to party activists and relative to the impact of primary voters.
Steger / TWO PARADIGMS OF PRESIDENTIAL NOMINATIONS | 385 These models indicate that the winners of the Iowa and New Hampshire nominat- ing elections gain a substantial increase in their shares of the remaining contested primary vote. In these and other variants of the models presented here, adding informa- tion on the results of the early caucuses and primaries improves the predictive accuracy of the models by reducing underprediction of candidates who gain momentum and by reducing overprediction of primary vote shares for candidates who lose momentum. Both models have greater errors of prediction for the nominees in those campaigns in which the nominees gained momentum in caucuses or primaries following New Hampshire, as happened in 1992 for Bill Clinton, 2004 for John Kerry, and 2008 for Barack Obama. Conclusions Across nominations, the pre-Iowa forecast models predict the winner correctly when one candidate gains a substantial lead in polls and endorsements during the invisible primary. That is, information from the invisible primary phase of the campaign is predictively accurate when party insiders and mass partisans coalesce behind a front- runner in advance of the Iowa caucuses. The Pre-Iowa forecasts have greater error in open nominations in which several candidates are roughly evenly matched in party elite support and pre-primary national polls. The important take away is that party insiders and party identifiers do not always coalesce strongly around a front-runner before the caucuses and primaries, and in in these races, the earliest caucuses and primaries continue to have substantial effects on primary votes in subsequent primaries (indicated by the substantial reduction in forecast errors of the predicted vote shares for the eventual nominees). Overall, the impact of momentum during the caucuses and primaries is greater in nomination campaigns when party insiders and identifiers fail to coalesce behind a front-runner during the invisible primary. Future research needs to recognize that we have two patterns in presidential nomination campaigns. Steger (2000) and Cohen et al (2003, 2008) emphasize the importance of the invisible primary as a period of intraparty coordination and coales- cence. Others emphasize campaign momentum (e.g., Aldrich 1980; Bartels 1988) or winnowing during the primaries (e.g., Norrander 2006). These two views are not incompatible. They both exist to some extent in every election, though one model or the other tends to be dominant in a given nomination cycle. These patterns of presidential nomination campaigns, however, reflect real differences in how nominees are selected, even though the rules for electing delegates to the national nomination campaigns have remained largely the same since the mid-1970s. These patterns also reflect differences in who exercises influence over the nomination. Political party elites can influence presidential nominations when (and perhaps only when) they weigh in on the nomination in large numbers and are unified in their support of a particular candidate. The presi- dential nominations from 2004 through 2012 differ from those of the late 1980s through 2000 in that fewer party insiders are making endorsements prior to the Iowa caucuses. Party elites also vary in their unity across elections—coalescing to a greater degree in some nomination cycles than in others. Republican Party insiders were relatively divided
386 | PRESIDENTIAL STUDIES QUARTERLY / June 2013 during the invisible primaries of 1980 (splitting into Reagan and anybody-but- Reagan camps), 2008, and 2012. The lack of public declarations of support and unity by Republican Party insiders in 2008 and 2012 could reflect uncertainty about the candi- dates, or it could signal the onset of Republican Party coalition fragmentation. Demo- cratic insiders were divided or undecided in 1988, 1992, 2004, and 2008—unifying only in the nominating elections of 1984 and 2000 when a vice president entered the race. Overall, this variation suggests caution is warranted before embracing the argument that political parties are able to resolve intraparty differences and coordinate support during the invisible primary. Given that both kinds of causal dynamics seem to exist, future research on presi- dential nominations needs to focus on the process of coalition formation in the context of evolving political parties. Both political parties and the candidates who seek nominations play important roles here. Presidency scholars need to develop a theoretical framework that melds these pieces into a cogent whole. References Adkins, Randall E., and Andrew J. Dowdle. 2000. “Break out the Mint Juleps in New Hampshire? Is New Hampshire the ‘Primary’ Culprit Limiting Presidential Nomination Forecasts?” American Politics Quarterly 28 (2): 251-69. Adkins, Randall E., and Andrew J. Dowdle. 2001. “How Important Are Iowa and New Hampshire to Winning Post-Reform Presidential Nominations?” Political Research Quarterly 54 (2): 431- 44. Adkins, Randall E., and Andrew J. Dowdle. 2005. “Overcoming Pitfalls in Forecasting Presidential Nominations.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 35 (December): 646-60. Aldrich, John. 1980. “A Dynamic Model of Presidential Nomination Campaigns.” American Political Science Review 74 (3): 651-69. Bartels, Larry M. 1988. Presidential Primaries and the Dynamics of Public Choice. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Butler, Richard. L. 2004. Claiming the Mantle: How Presidential Nominations Are Won and Lost Before the Votes Are Cast. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Cohen, Marty, David Karol, Hans Noel, and John Zaller. 2003. “Polls or Pols: The Real Driving Force behind Presidential Nominations.” Brooking Review 3 (3): 36-39. Cohen, Marty, David Karol, Hans Noel, and John Zaller. 2008. The Party Decides: Presidential Nominations before and after Reform. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Congressional Quarterly. 2005. Guide to U.S. Elections. 5th ed. Washington DC: CQ Press. Hadley, Arthur. 1976. The Invisible Primary. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Haynes, Audrey A., Paul-Henri Gurian, Michael H. Crespin, and Christopher Zorn. 2004. “The Calculus of Concession: Media Coverage and the Dynamics of Winnowing in Presidential Nominations.” American Politics Research 32 (3): 310-37. Hull, Christopher C. 2008. Grassroots Rules: How the Iowa Caucus Helps Elect American Presidents. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Jamieson, Kathleen Hall, Richard Johnston, and Michael G. Hagen. 2000. “The 2000 Nominating Campaign: Endorsements, Attacks, and Debates.” Research Report. Annenberg Public Policy Center. University of Pennsylvania. Mayer, William G. 1996. “Forecasting Nominations.” In In Pursuit of the White House: How We Choose Our Presidential Nominees, ed. William G. Mayer. Chatham, NJ: Chatham House. 44-71. ———. 2008. “Handicapping the 2008 Nomination Races: an Early Winter Prospectus.” The Forum 5 (4): art. 2.
Steger / TWO PARADIGMS OF PRESIDENTIAL NOMINATIONS | 387 Morton, Rebecca B., and Kenneth C. Williams. 1999. “Information Asymmetries in Simultaneous versus Sequential Elections.” American Political Science Review 93 (September): 51-67. Norrander, Barbara. 1993. “Nomination Choices: Caucus and Primary Outcomes, 1976-1988.” American Journal of Political Science 37 (April): 343-64. ———. 2006. “The Attrition Game: Initial Resources, Initial Contests and the Exit of Candidates during the US Presidential Primary Season.” British Journal of Political Science 36 (3): 487-507. Popkin, Samuel L. 1991. The Reasoning Voter. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Steger, Wayne P. 2000. “Do Primary Voters Draw from a Stacked Deck? Presidential Nominations in an Era of Candidate-Centered Campaigns.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 30 (December): 727-53. ———. 2007. “Who Wins Nominations and Why? An Updated Forecast of the Presidential Primary Vote.” Political Research Quarterly 60 (March): 91-99. ———. 2008. “Forecasting the Presidential Primary Vote: Viability, Ideology and Momentum.” International Journal of Forecasting 24 (2): 193-208. ———. 2009. “How Did the Primary Vote Forecasts Fare in the 2008 Nominations?” Presidential Studies Quarterly 39 (March): 141-54. Steger, Wayne P., Andrew J. Dowdle, and Randall E. Adkins. 2004. “The New Hampshire Effect in Presidential Nominations.” Political Research Quarterly 57 (3): 375-90.
You can also read