The Origins of Ethnic Power-Sharing Coalitions: How Uncertainty Fosters Cooperation
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
The Origins of Ethnic Power-Sharing Coalitions: How Uncertainty Fosters Cooperation Nils-Christian Bormann∗ April 11, 2015 Abstract Why do ethnic elites share power in government coalitions? Existing explanations are pessimistic about the prospects of ethnic power-sharing unless institutional incen- tives encourage cooperation. In contrast, I argue that ethnic leaders usually form gov- ernments with secure majorities because they anticipate defections by their supporters and allies, and fear revolutionary threats by excluded groups. Moreover, ethnic elites prefer coalition partners with whom they share cross-cutting cleavages since defections by supporters along shared identity markers occur within the ruling coalition. To test this hypothesis, I collected new data on linguistic, religious, and racial intra-group di- visions. Using conditional choice models on formation opportunities in 134 ethnically divided societies between 1946 and 2009 I find that, regardless of regime type, ethnic elites most frequently opt for oversized multiethnic coalitions that share as many iden- tity markers as possible. These findings challenge important assumptions about the nature of ethnic politics and the efficacy of power-sharing institutions. ∗ Center of Comparative and International Studies, ETH Zurich, Switzerland. Email: bor- mann@icr.gess.ethz.ch 1
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann Why do ethnically diverse elites form governmental power-sharing coalitions? This is a central question for scholars who study the prevention and resolution of civil wars (Lijphart, 1977; Walter, 2002; Hartzell and Hoddie, 2003) and policy-makers who attempt to solve violent ethnic conflicts in places such as South Sudan and Iraq. Beyond war and peace, the composition of the ruling coalition influences important outcomes such as economic growth (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003), authoritarian regime stability (Pepinsky, 2009), and pa- tronage politics (Bates, 1974; Chandra, 2007). Studying the origins of ethnic power-sharing is of particular interest because conventional wisdom holds that it should be very difficult to accomplish. Students of ethnically divided societies conceptualize political elites and their co-ethnic supporters as rational actors who want to maximize their own share of power (e.g., Fearon, 1999; Posner, 2005), or even subordinate members of other groups (Horowitz, 2000). In the absence of institutional rules, such as guaranteed government inclusion, minimum- winning coalitions or even minority rule should predominate in ethnically divided societies (Horowitz, 1993; Rabushka and Shepsle, 2008; Roessler, 2011). The resulting large-scale ethnic exclusion is a fertile breeding ground for violent conflicts (see Cederman, Gleditsch and Buhaug, 2013). Yet despite an extensive literature that links so-called power-sharing institutions, such as proportional representation (PR) or authoritarian parties, to desirable outcomes including stability and economic growth (e.g., Norris, 2008; Gandhi, 2008), there is relatively little direct evidence that the same institutions affect the formation of government coalitions. In fact, Figure 1 shows no evidence for the link between institutions and coalitions that include political elites from at least two distinct ethnic groups.1 The frequency of ethnic coalitions (grey bars) in 2009 is larger than the frequency of one-group rule (black) in states without power-sharing institutions in the preceding year (on the left) while the pattern reverses in states with power-sharing institutions (on the right). The absence of ethnic coalitions in large number of countries with power-sharing institutions questions the hypothesized effectiveness of these institutions. That ethnic elites form coalitions where no power-sharing institutions exist is even more puzzling from the pessimist perspective that prevails in the literature on 1 Data on power-sharing institutions comes from Cheibub, Gandhi and Vreeland (2010) and Bormann and Golder (2013). Data on ethnic coalitions comes from the Ethnic Power Relations dataset by Cederman, Wimmer and Min (2010). 2
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann ethnic politics (Horowitz, 2000, cf.). Figure 1: Power-sharing institutions in 2008 and ethnic regime type in 2009. 0.5 One−group rule Ethnic coalition 0.4 Share of governments in 2009 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 No power−sharing Power−sharing Institutions Institutions Challenging the common notion that power-sharing institutions are necessary for ethnic cooperation to emerge, I argue that ethnic government coalitions are far more frequent than suggested by existing theories because ethnic elites are uncertain about the true distribu- tion of power. Since group boundaries are fuzzy and support for ethnic leaders is strategic rather than honest, leaders of ethnic groups operate in an environment of incomplete in- formation where they fear future revolutions from competing groups and defections from their own ranks. Anticipating these challenges, ethnic elites form oversized coalitions with leaders from other groups. Only elites from those groups with an overwhelming majority of the population can afford to rule alone. I show that governments with secure majorities rather than minimum-winning or minority governments are the most common form of rule in ethnically divided societies regardless of regime type.2 My argument builds on recent work on self-enforcing coalitions in weakly-institutionalized environments (Acemoglu et al., 2008; Driscoll, 2012; Francois, Rainer and Trebbi, 2014). Yet 2 Secure majorities consist of (1) oversized coalitions that include at least two groups which represent a majority of the population that exceeds minimum-winning size, and (2) mono-ethnic rule by a group that includes an overwhelming majority of the population. 3
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann my paper goes beyond these contributions both in its wider empirical scope and in its the- oretical contributions. Regarding the latter, I extend the focus of these models from the competition over power between groups with fixed boundaries to contests among ethnic elites who cannot be completely certain about co-ethnic support because group boundaries are less rigid. Linking the older sociological literature on cross-cutting and reinforcing cleav- ages (Lipset and Rokkan, 1990 (1967)) with more recent work on individual ethnic identity (Posner, 2005; Hale, 2008; Chandra, 2012), I argue that the presence of cross-cutting cleav- ages enables individuals to shift their support between competing elites by highlighting the salience of alternative ethnic markers, for example, from language to religion. In turn, elites anticipate defections by their co-ethnic supporters and attempt to prevent them by inter- nalizing cross-cutting cleavages into the ruling coalition. Supporter shifts due to changes in the salient identity markers therefore remain inside the ruling coalition. To test my hypotheses, I employ conditional choice models from the government forma- tion literature (Martin and Stevenson, 2001; Glasgow, Golder and Golder, 2012) on potential ethnic coalitions in 134 ethnically divided states taken from the Ethnic Power Sharing (EPR) dataset (Cederman, Wimmer and Min, 2010).3 I also introduce new data on multiple lin- guistic, religious, and racial intra-group cleavages to measure cross-cutting and reinforcing cleavages within potential coalitions. The statistical tests confirm my two main theoretical expectations. First, the results indicate that ethnic elites mostly form oversized coalitions while mono-ethnic regimes are only possible where overwhelming majorities exist. Secure majorities are by far the most likely type of government in ethnically divided societies while minority rule is very rare. Second, most coalitions form around cross-cutting cleavages as ethnic elites anticipate shifts in salient identity markers and erect reinforcing cleavages to excluded groups. At the same time, the coalition behavior of ethnic elites does not dif- fer significantly between democratic and authoritarian regimes or under different electoral regimes. Studying ethnic coalitions helps explain some puzzling findings in the power-sharing lit- 3 In parliamentary democracies formation opportunities are regulated by well-defined in- stitutional rules such as elections. In contrast, the ethnic composition of governments in different regimes form at more diverse occasions in the cases studied here, for example, after coups. I will discuss the challenges of coding ethnic formation opportunities in greater detail below. 4
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann erature. Whereas Mattes and Savun (2009) argue that political power-sharing in the central government is the most relevant aspect of post-conflict settlements, Jarstad and Nilsson (2008) report that implemented pacts that guarantee government inclusion have no positive effect on conflict recurrence. My theoretical focus on uncertainty shows that assurances of government inclusion should reduce the incentive of elites to cooperate, which explains the difference between promised and implemented settlements. Additionally, my focus on eth- nic coalitions allows me to study power-sharing in pre- and post-conflict environments as well as across regime types. Since ethnicity is so closely related to individual perceptions of identity (Hale, 2008, Ch.3), the concept of ethnic groups as bases for political power travels globally. Coalitions between distinct ethnic elites therefore offer a new field for the empir- ical evaluation of theoretical coalition dynamics beyond the common setting of European parliamentary democracies (cf. Martin and Stevenson, 2001; Glasgow, Golder and Golder, 2012), for example, by helping to overcome the observation problems that make the study of secretive authoritarian politics difficult. Ethnic coalition formation Why do ethnic elites share power in coalition governments? Almost every theory of coalition formation draws on Riker’s (1967) formative work that captures the importance of the distri- bution of power in the “size principle.” According to this logic, utility-maximizing actors aim to form minimum-winning coalitions, that is the smallest possible coalition that maximizes their own influence. Later studies of coalition formation in democratic regimes explore other aspects of coalition formation such as ideological congruence or proposal sequencing but the distribution of power among the key actors remains central to these studies (e.g., Axelrod, 1970; Baron and Ferejohn, 1989; Laver and Shepsle, 1996). In the context of ethnically divided societies,4 it follows that ethnic coalitions should only form where the largest ethnic group does not constitute more than 50% of the population (Horowitz, 2002, 20). Yet even minority groups might dominate the government when insti- tutional prescriptions for majority rule are absent such as in democracies that run plurality 4 These are multi-ethnic states where at least some politicians advance ethnic claims in the national arena. 5
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann elections and in dictatorships (Horowitz, 2000, 433–434). This pessimistic view underwrites analyses that attribute political violence and other suboptimal social outcomes to the lack of cooperation between ethnically distinct groups (see, e.g., Easterly and Levine, 1997; Alesina, Baqir and Easterly, 1999; Roessler, 2011; Esteban, Mayoral and Ray, 2012). In reaching these conclusions, existing work on ethnic power-sharing usually builds on three central assumptions: (1) ethnic elites and their followers are utility-maximizing ac- tors; (2) authoritarian regimes and some democracies lack commitment technologies, that is mechanisms that incentivize cooperation across ethnic boundaries; and (3) ethnic groups are homogeneous and unified actors.5 While I share the first assumption of utility-maximizing actors (also see Posner, 2005; Chandra, 2012; Francois, Rainer and Trebbi, 2014), I disagree with the remaining two statements. With respect to commitment technologies, I assume that violent revolutions and coups in authoritarian regimes are substitutes for elections and partisan defections in democracies (also see Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003; Svolik, 2009; Francois, Rainer and Trebbi, 2014).6 Ethnic elites depend on sufficient support from their co-ethnics and rival elites from other ethnic groups to obtain power regardless of regime type. While receiving disproportional attention in academic writing and public discourse, ethnic minority regimes such as As- sad’s Syria and South Africa during Apartheid should be the exception rather than the rule. Excluded majorities usually find ways to cooperate against a minority government since their demographic superiority often comes with additional access to power resources such as economic or military influence. Majority coalitions have successfully overthrown minority regimes in Afghanistan, Liberia, Uganda, South Africa, and Zimbabwe, and obtained their own states in Pakistan and Sudan. Only if an ethnic minority government such as Mestizos in Guatemala can balance demographic inferiority with vast superiority in coercive capacity should it be able to defend its position in the long run. Overall though, larger excluded groups are more likely to violently challenge the government directly than smaller groups (Buhaug, 2006), and Cederman, Gleditsch and Buhaug (2013, 196–198) show that “stronger rebels” are more likely to win civil wars. In sum, even in autocracies ethnic elites often 5 I follow Weber (1978) in defining ethnicity as a “putative belief in common ancestry” that builds on shared identity markers such as language, religion, caste, and race. 6 Conceptually, I distinguish autocracies and democracies by the method of leader selection and the degree to which elites in most democratic regimes are accountable to their supporters. 6
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann require the support from a majority of the population. While the necessity of majority support for governance in dictatorships has been more controversial than in democracies, several experts of ethnic politics argue that first-past- the-post democracies are prone to minority rule due to their winner-takes-it-all institutional setup (Lijphart, 1977; Horowitz, 2000). However, these authors fail to appreciate that there is no direct relationship between plurality elections and minority rule. In fact, Sartori (1997) convincingly argues that first-past-the-post elections are essentially equivalent to elections run under proportional representation (PR) where ethnic groups are spatially separated.7 As this is the case in many ethnically divided societies in Africa and Asia, I argue that majority pressures should exist in all types of electoral democracies as well as in authoritarian regimes. Coalition formation under uncertainty So far I have argued that ethnic elites are most likely to form majority-sized coalitions no matter the institutional rules under which they operate. Yet even if ethnic leaders form majority governments, existing theoretical models of coalition formation predict that these coalitions should be minimum-winning (Riker, 1967). Therefore, a large number of ethnic groups should still be excluded from power-sharing pacts. Research on civil war alliances (Christia, 2012) and government formation in ethnically divided societies (Rabushka and Shepsle, 2008) provides evidence for this minimum-winning dynamic. However, the con- ditions under which Riker’s logic holds have received less attention in these analyses. As discussed above, one central assumption that undergirds the minimum-winning logic is that ethnic leaders obtain the full support from their co-ethnics and know how large this sup- port is. With this fixed and indivisible conceptualization of ethnic groups, existing research presupposes that ethnic elites have complete information over the distribution of power. In contrast, I argue that ethnic groups are neither fixed nor indivisible units that support their political elites unconditionally. Although ethnicity is perhaps the most wide-spread social cleavage that affects politics globally, the boundaries between ethnic groups are neither impenetrable nor unchangeable (Barth, 1969). Ethnic boundaries are least telling of political allegiance where identity markers allow membership in multiple sub-groups. Posner (2005) 7 National minority groups constitute local majorities. Also see Calvo and Rodden (2015, 4). 7
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann argues that individuals stress the one identity marker that guarantees their inclusion in the smallest possible winning coalition (also see van der Veen and Laitin, 2012). Similarly political elites compete over predominance within their ethnic group (Pearlman, 2009). This implies that political elites who draw on the support of their co-ethnics to gain and stay in power operate in an environment of incomplete information: they only know the approximate distribution of power gauged from the headcount of different ethnic groups. There is ample evidence that coalitions in multiethnic states are indeed unstable. Recent research shows that ethnic voting is less likely when material benefits are neither distributed along ethnics lines nor excludable (Dunning and Nilekani, 2013; Ichino and Nathan, 2013). Brass (1968) describes the fluidity of coalitions in Indian state parliaments, and Ferree (2012) shows that governments in Sub-Saharan Africa that include ethnic groups with majority sub-segments are unstable. Once the ethnic distribution of power becomes uncertain, the minimum-winning logic no longer applies: The uncertainty of the real world and the bargaining situation forces coalition members to aim at subjectively estimated minimum-winning coalition rather than at an actual minimum. In decision-systems large enough so that participants do not know each other or what each is doing, the actual size and weight of a coalition may be in doubt, if only because of lack of communication or because of participants’ inability to estimate each other’s weights (Riker, 1967, 77–78). It is notable how well this quote captures the political competition in ethnically divided states where communication between members from different ethnic groups is more difficult than within the group but group membership is still not fixed (Hale, 2008, Ch.3). Even in states where ethnic tensions run high, group members hardly ever throw their support con- sistently behind just one ethnic party.8 As a consequence, ethnic elites anticipate defections from their supporters and allies, and form secure majorities by which I mean single-group governments with vast numerical superiority such as most monoethnic governments in West- ern Europe and Latin America, and oversized coalitions elsewhere. 8 The Kurds in Iraq, for example, split their support between two major parties, the Kurdistan Democratic Party and the Patriotic Union of Kurdistan. Yet sometimes, elites from both parties cooperate in the Kurdistan Alliance to further their interests vis-a-vis Sunni and Shi’a Arab elites. 8
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann My argument does not only challenge the pessimist view on ethnic power-sharing but also disagrees with alternative theories in which ethnic leaders share their power out of good will or “statesmanship” as originally argued by Lijphart (1969). Grand coalitions that include leaders from all groups should be rare as the value of the coalition decreases in its degree of inclusiveness. In spite of Persian and Russian majority status, power-sharing between Persian and Azeri elites in Iran and between Russian and Ukrainian leaders in the Soviet Union are examples of oversized but not grand coalitions as numerous other ethnic groups are still excluded from power in both states. That the Russian-Ukrainian coalition was not a result of statesmanship is further supported by Russian elite behavior after the dissolution of the Soviet Union. The increased relative population share in the new state and the resulting decrease in uncertainty about ethnic dominance made Russian leaders confident enough to govern without the inclusion of other ethnic elites into the central government after 1991. Recent theories of power-sharing in weakly institutionalized environments share more parallels with my theory by highlighting the fear of future violence as driver for power- sharing coalitions but they also differ in some important aspects. Acemoglu et al. (2008), for example, assume that a revolutionary threat only exists at the time of coalition formation but is not acute thereafter. Their model might therefore underestimate the stability and size of coalitions. In contrast, Francois, Rainer and Trebbi (2014, 11) assume that all excluded groups join a revolution once it breaks out. These authors likely overestimate inclusiveness and underestimate the risk of civil war as they find a pattern of near-grand coalitions in fifteen Sub-Saharan African countries. In sum, I predict that in ethnically divided societies, oversized coalitions should be more common than either minority, minimum-winning, or grand coalitions, and that this pattern should hold across different regime types. Coalition formation and ethnic cleavage configurations Thus far, I have argued that elites will form oversized coalitions because they fear future defections. However, in almost all states several coalition options exist across multiple real and latent cleavages that are oversized but do not include elites from all groups. Which coalitions will elites then choose? 9
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann Lipset and Rokkan (1990 (1967)) pointed to the multi-dimensionality of ethnic identities and the underlying potential for change in the cleavages that structure political conflict. At the same time, they stress critical junctures that locked in certain cleavage configurations in the long run. More recently, a number of scholars have studied which ethnic identity marker is most salient for individuals under changing political circumstances (Laitin, 1998; Posner, 2005; Chandra, 2005; van der Veen and Laitin, 2012). The ability of individuals to support elites who speak the same language at one point in time and other elites with whom they share religious affiliations at a later point is analogous to shifting the vote between two ideologically similar candidates in democratic elections. It is unlikely that liberal voters support a conservative party but they might alternate between social-democratic and other liberal parties.9 While this shift in support is less consequential in states where ethnic cleavages are reinforcing, it has important implications for the winning coalition in states with cross-cutting cleavages (Chandra, 2005; Posner, 2005). Ethnic leaders fear the restructuring of salient cleavages because it realigns their support base and therefore threatens their power position. Conversely, excluded elites that represent smaller groups have every incentive to stress less salient cleavages that cross-cut the border between the government coalition and the opposition in order to delegitimize their own exclusion. Should support realignments pose a threat to the power access of governing elites, it is likely that those leaders threatened by defections anticipate their possibility and take counter-measures wherever they can. To illustrate this line of argument, consider the case of India where the Congress Party had dominated Indian politics since independence on a platform of cross-caste, cross-linguistic/regional, and cross-religious appeal.10 While Congress was out of government for short spells in the 1970s and late 1980s, the first opposition party that posed an effective challenge to Congress’ dominance, and managed to stay in power for a full legislative term between 1999 and 2004, was the Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP). The more conservative BJP portrays itself as a de- fender of the Hindu identity of the Indian state. Its strategy is to drive a wedge in the 9 It is entirely possible that individuals shift their support from elites with an ethnic agenda to other elites who run on a non-ethnic platform. While more realistic, this possibility is beyond the scope of this paper. 10 After a split in 1977 the largest emerging faction was known as Congress (I), named after its leader Indira Gandhi. 10
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann Congress coalition by polarizing the Hindu-Muslim cleavage in India. Thus, its Hindu-only message is in principle directed at a significant portion of the Congress electorate by stress- ing Hindu identity over caste or linguistic markers. In practice though, the BJP has mainly attracted upper-caste or -class Hindus, and the need for coalitions with smaller, regional partners has moderated the message of the BJP (Chandra, 2005, 238). Nonetheless the success of the BJP can be explained in part by taking a chunk of voters out of the Congress coalition by appealing to overlapping identity markers.11 What does the threat of support realignment imply for the type of government that ethnic elites form? In anticipation of defections along cross-cutting cleavage constellations, group leaders attempt to undercut such attempts from the very beginning. Instead of simply forming the smallest government coalition that promises sufficient support to deter external challengers, elites also consider the ethnic compatibility of their coalition partners. Where elites internalize cross-cutting cleavages into the government coalition, support realignment may shift the balance of power within the coalition but not between the government and the opposition. This argument suggests that ethnic elites prefer to form coalitions among groups that share more identity markers with each other and are, thus, internally less diverse to more heterogeneous coalitions that share several cross-cutting cleavages with excluded groups.12 To conclude the theoretical discussion, I summarize my two central expectations in the following hypotheses: H1 : Ethnic elites are more likely to form secure majorities than minimum-winning coalitions, minority governments, and grand coalitions. H2 : Ethnic elites are more likely to form a coalition that includes a small number of ethnic cleavages than a coalition that encompasses a large number. 11 For a discussion of the BJP and changes in the Indian party system refer to Varshney (2002, 244–5) and Guha (2007, 634–641). 12 Note that this does not mean that elites choose to minimize the number of groups in the coalition. Consider the case of three groups that only differ linguistically and share no markers with excluded groups. According to my argument elites should prefer this outcome to a coalition of two groups that differ on the linguistic and religious dimensions, and each share identity markers with excluded groups. 11
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann Research design and data While there are different ways to model ethnic power-sharing this paper estimates the choice of ethnic coalitions directly with so-called conditional choice models (Train, 2003). This approach was originally introduced into political science by Martin and Stevenson (2001) in the context of parliamentary government formation, and it models the choice situation of elites in one country at a given point in time by comparing all potential government coalitions rather than only the observed outcome. In other words, conditional choice models estimate the choice of a government relative to alternatives in the same country. This within-country comparison is superior to country-level analyses that estimate the share of the included population (Ch.5 Wimmer, 2013) or the presence of a coalition government (Reilly, 2005) because it takes into account the differences in countries’ ethnic configuration. Consider, for example, France with its dominant French population and fractionalized Chad. A government in France that only includes French politicians makes up a large percentage of the population and it is very unlikely that French politicians would form a coalition with Basque or Corsican elites. Conversely, Chad’s largest ethnic group, the Sara, constitute just one quarter of the country’s population which is why a coalition with any of the five other politically relevant ethnic groups is far more likely. Country-level investigations cannot take the complexity of these different choice environments into account. The unit of analysis in conditional-choice models is the formation opportunity that in- cludes between three and over a million government choices depending on the number of groups in a state.13 Table 1 shows the basic data setup for one formation opportunity in Iraq after 2003 where a Shia-Kurdish coalition had replaced Saddam Hussein’s Sunni minor- ity regime. Conditional choice models estimate the probability that one of the alternatives in Table 1 is selected and do so for each formation opportunity. Put differently, these models accommodate a highly unbalanced set of coalition choices across formation opportunities. A large number of choices in one state does not disproportionally influence the estimated coefficients at the expense of the formation opportunity in a different state with fewer choices 13 The number of coalition choices at a formation opportunity is 2n − 1 as the empty coalition is excluded. Since the number of choices rises exponentially, a state like Sudan with 16 relevant groups presents 65535 coalition opportunities compared with 3 in Trinidad and Tobago. In a state with 20 groups there would be more than one million choices. 12
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann since each formation opportunity only counts as one unit. Similarly, the estimator accounts for a changing number of relevant groups within states over time. Table 1: Ethnic coalition formation opportunities in Iraq. Formation Coalition Member(s) Pop. Actual Opportunity Size Coalition (1) Sunni 0.19 0 (2) Shia 0.63 0 (3) Kurds 0.17 0 (4) Sunni & Shia 0.82 0 (5) Sunni & Kurds 0.36 0 (6) Shia and Kurds .8 1 (7) Sunni, Shia & Kurds 1 0 Using conditional choice models has two additional advantages over alternative estimation strategies. First, there is no trade-off between coalition-, country-, and group-level inference that would be present in a regular multinomial logit model on the country-level. Conditional choice models make it possible to recover the probability of inclusion for individual groups, for specific coalitions, and general types of governments. Second, relying on the mixed logit enables me to estimate entire parameter distributions rather than simple point estimates, and thereby model unobserved heterogeneity that, for example, reflects diverging preferences of elites.14 Moreover, the mixed logit does not suffer from bias due to violation of the irrelevance of independent alternative (IIA) assumption (Glasgow, Golder and Golder, 2012).15 I test my hypotheses on a sample of formation opportunities from the updated Ethnic Power Relations (EPR-ETH) dataset (Cederman, Wimmer and Min, 2010; Cederman, Gled- itsch and Buhaug, 2013), which codes politically relevant ethnic groups in all states where leaders make claims on behalf of their groups, or where the state politically discriminates any group.16 Although political coalitions are usually formed between political organiza- tions that represent ethnic groups, these organizations are at least implicitly included in EPR through the coding requirement that demands political relevance. The EPR codebook 14 Consider the different political outlooks by Nelson Mandela and Robert Mugabe. 15 The online appendix includes a more detailed description of the mixed logit model. 16 Discrimination is usually negative as in Apartheid-South Africa or in the United States before 1965. However, it can also be positive as exemplified by the case of Hispanics in the United States who became politically relevant through the Voting Rights Act of 1965. 13
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann notes that “[an] ethnic group is considered politically relevant if at least one political organi- zation claims to represent it in national politics. . . ” (Min, Cederman and Wimmer, 2008). While it would be preferable to have data on political organizations, existing datasets usually only include a much smaller number of groups or states.17 Moreover, some regimes included in this study legally ban all political organizations. For most military dictatorships, it would be impossible to collect organizational actor information. I construct my dependent variable, the actual government choice, from information on the political access of group representatives to executive power provided by EPR-ETH. When group representatives are considered as being included in the executive, I code the group as a participant in the actual government.18 Token membership by ethnic elites but cannot or do not effectively represent a group does not qualify for an “inclusion” coding. In other words, only if elites effectively represent their group members, do I count a coalition. I assess the relative power of groups by their relative size, and coalition size by the sum of group sizes included in the coalition. Assessing the relative influence of political elites through the size of their ethnic group is not only common in academic writings on conflict (Cederman, Wimmer and Min, 2010; Metternich, 2011). In authoritarian regimes ethnic headcounts during the census are often the basis for bureaucratic appointments, and thus the basis for relative influence over the distribution of resources (Jackson and Rosberg, 1984; Diamond, 1988; Bayart, 2009). Drawing on its constructivist understanding of ethnicity, EPR-ETH codes the reconfig- uration of ethnic group boundaries. In a number of states, ethnic groups split into smaller segments – for example, Blacks in South Africa after the end of Apartheid – or merge into larger ones, for example, along territorial lines.19 Ethnic groups might become or cease to be politically relevant in national politics at any point in time when elites start or stop to make claims on behalf of these groups. In the same vein, relative group sizes change over 17 Birnir (2006) codes organizations for a subset of ethnic groups in the Minorities at Risk dataset by Gurr (2000) which includes a third of the ethnic groups in EPR and does not have the same temporal reach. 18 Included groups are coded as holding “monopoly” power or being “dominant” in mo- noethnic governments. Coalition governments feature one or more “senior partners” and “junior partners.” Refer to Cederman, Wimmer and Min (2010, 93 & 100-1). 19 Horowitz (2002, 20) describes the ethnic polarization of political allegiances between northern and southern groups in many African states. 14
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann time, for example, in Lebanon due to differential birth rates between ethnic groups. I code new formation opportunities whenever the EPR dataset records a change in group size, in the set of politically relevant ethnic groups in a state, or in the power position of any group.20 I argue that these events indicate a change in the bargaining environment for ethnic elites and therefore offer the potential for a renegotiation over the ethnic composition of the government. The data then include a new formation opportunity that concludes all possible combinations of ethnic groups, and highlight the realized government as in Figure 1.21 Due to computational limitations the analysis does not include China, Russia/the Soviet Union, and India.22 In sum, the sample includes 338,591 potential coalitions across 467 formation opportunities in 134 ethnically divided states between 1946 and 2009. My explanatory variables proxy power relations through the number of groups in a po- tential coalition, and four dummy variables that note whether the largest group in a state is included, whether one group rules by itself, and whether a coalition is minimum-winning or oversized.23 In line with H1 , oversized coalitions and dominant rule by one group, what I call secure majorities, should be more likely than minority- and minimum-winning-coalitions. In addition, the largest ethnic group in a state is likely to be an important player in the government formation process, and therefore more likely to be included than not. Finally, elites should prefer to rule with few other groups over ruling with many coalition partners in order to maximize their own share of power. In order to measure cleavages for each potential government constellation, I collected new data on the linguistic, religious, and racial sub-segments of each ethnic group in the EPR data.24 As suggested by constructivist theories of ethnicity, individuals usually possess mul- 20 Note that this might include a relative change within the government coalition or the granting of territorial autonomy to excluded groups that does not affect the ethnic compo- sition of the government. 21 The online appendix provides an alternative strategy to identify formation opportunities based on changes in the institutional setup and leadership alternations that likely indicate a change in the bargaining environment. Analyses based on this sample do not alter the fundamental conclusions. 22 While the exponential growth in the number of combinations does not allow me to include Russia and China that each feature more than 40 groups into my dataset, India’s 20 groups and more than 4.4 million potential government choices at 6 formation opportunities stretch the demands on computing power but do not exceed it. 23 Minority coalitions constitute the residual category. 24 I derived most of the information from the Ethnologue catalog of languages by Lewis (2009) and the Joshua Project, an online database that codes the religious affiliation of 15
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann tiple identity markers but not all of them are politically salient at the same time (Chandra, 2012). The politically relevant groups included in the EPR data usually differ from other groups on at least one but not necessarily on all ethnic dimensions. Using two ethnic groups from Nigeria as examples, Figure 2 shows that the data provide information on the relative share of up to three sub-segments per identity marker and ethnic group.25 The Yoruba and Hausa-Fulani are primarily divided by language but members of both groups adhere to the Sunni Muslim faith. To assess how much potential exists for members of a group to defect to elites who stress alternative identity segments, I first count the number of unique cleavages, that is the number of different ethnic segments minus one, for each potential coalition. In another operationalization, I divide this count by the total number of unique cleavages in a state. The higher the count (or the share), the more likely it becomes that the coalition is to suffer defections (H2 ). Figure 2: Example of linguistic and religious identity segments for the Hausa-Fulani and Yoruba in Nigeria. Hausa-Fulani Adamawa Hausa Fulfulde Nigerian Fulfulde Sunni Muslims (Maliki) Yoruba Yoruba Sunni Muslims Anglican Other (Maliki) Christians Christians To control for the impact of the past, I code the lag of the ethnic composition of the government by the population share that was also represented in the previous government. Ethnologue groups. See Joshua Project: Unreached Peoples of the World (2011). 25 Since the racial affiliation of both groups is coded as Sub-Saharan African, Figure 2 omits this dimension. 16
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann Alternative measures in the appendix replace this variable by a simple dummy that records whether the government remained the same at a new formation opportunity.26 Analysis Before turning to multivariate choice models of coalition formation, I begin to explore the global patterns of ethnic coalitions descriptively. Between 1946 and 2009, ethnic leaders form coalitions in more than half of all formation opportunities (246). Out of these, Lijphart’s grand coalition, in which elites of all relevant ethnic groups in a state are represented, is selected at 76 different formation opportunities. The Central African Republic features the smallest ethnic coalition between the Yakoma and Mbaka in 1982. It represents just below 9% of the total population. Figure 3 shows the distribution of all realized government types in all ethnically divided states over the sample period. Black bars denote monoethnic governments while grey bars identify ethnic coalitions. The pattern revealed by the bar graph is definite: the vast majority of ethnic governments are majority governments, and the combination of grand and oversized coalitions constitute the modal government type. Moreover, the average share of the included population in monoethnic governments is about 84% while the median is even higher. In fact only 14% of all mono-ethnic majority governments represent less than sixty per cent of the population. This is strong evidence that monoethnic governments tend to present an overwhelming majority of the population and that these governments are unlikely to ever be challenged by ethnic minority groups for predominance in the state. Turning to multivariate comparisons, I evaluate my hypotheses in three mixed logit models presented in Table 2. Each model includes estimates for the average effect, which is equivalent to effect estimates in common choice models such as the multinomial logit, and its standard deviation (SD) that provides information on the empirical variance of the choice. Both of these estimates come with their own uncertainty estimate. Where the estimated SD is significant and large, a substantial number of elites make choices that differ from the average.27 26 As all initial coalitions are missing by construction when lagged variables are included in the analysis, the sample shrinks to 328 formation opportunities. 27 A statistically significant standard deviation does not imply that the estimate of the average effect is imprecise. An in-depth explanation of the mixed logit can be found in the 17
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann Figure 3: Realized government types in 134 states, 1946–2009. As indicated by the positive mean effects for single-group majorities and oversized coali- tions, governments that include groups representing more than 50% of the ethnically relevant population in a state are more likely than minority governments (the baseline category). Po- litical elites that represent majority ethnic groups often opt to govern alone, although in a substantive minority of cases, they choose not to embrace one-group majority rule as indi- cated by the significant estimate for the standard deviation of single-member governments. The strong positive average effect likely reflects the outcome of successful nationalist projects in which one groups dominates the state, as is the case in many Latin American countries. Contrary to predictions of general models of coalition formation and experts on ethnic con- flict, minimal-winning coalitions are not more likely than minority governments. Both the estimated average and the dispersion effect are insignificant across all three models in Ta- ble 2. Where ethnic group elites cooperate, they overwhelmingly form oversized coalitions. Moreover, there is hardly any deviation from this pattern as indicated by the insignificant estimates for the standard deviation. Overall then, these models provide strong evidence in support of H1 that expects ethnic elites to form secure majorities. Turning to the control variables, the estimate for the largest group dummy is positive appendix. 18
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann Table 2: Mixed logit models of coalition formation in 133 states, 1946–2009. (1) (2) (3) Mean SD Mean SD Mean SD Single-Group Maj. 3.023∗∗∗ 4.684∗∗∗ 3.365∗∗∗ 5.620∗∗∗ 2.955∗∗∗ 3.340∗∗∗ (0.664) (0.911) (0.718) (1.106) (0.750) (0.979) M.-W. Coalition -0.017 -0.376 0.378 0.602 -0.336 0.400 (0.458) (0.604) (0.595) (0.765) (1.172) (1.410) Oversized Coal. 1.579∗∗∗ -0.399 2.231∗∗∗ -0.749 2.327∗∗∗ 0.792∗ (0.345) (0.576) (0.394) (0.491) (0.451) (0.380) Largest Group 1.215∗∗ 1.505∗∗∗ 1.107∗ 1.592∗∗∗ 0.390 -0.613 (0.426) (0.335) (0.441) (0.434) (0.443) (0.418) No. of Groups -0.551∗∗ 1.231∗∗∗ -0.199 1.389∗∗∗ 0.011 1.207∗∗∗ (0.186) (0.167) (0.187) (0.288) (0.206) (0.166) Cleavage Count -0.712∗∗ 1.212∗∗∗ -1.048∗∗∗ -1.149∗∗∗ (0.218) (0.247) (0.269) (0.249) % of Incumbents 2.553∗∗∗ 1.578∗∗ (0.434) (0.558) Formation Opportunities 467 467 328 Potential Governments 338591 338591 295288 ` -1021.64 -990.213 -727.204 χ2 443.938 451.171 298.480 Country-clustered standard errors in parentheses. ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < 0.01, ∗∗∗ p < 0.001 19
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann in Models 1 and 2 which might point to a formateur advantage (also see Francois, Rainer and Trebbi, 2014, 1). More often than not, the largest group in a state is included in the governing coalition, though again there are a substantial number of exceptions as the significant standard deviation shows. In Model 1, the negative estimate for the number of groups in a coalition implies that ethnic elites try to maximize their own relative share of power with respect to other ethnic groups, even while they are building secure majorities. However, the high variability in the estimate points to consociational leadership behavior in Switzerland, India, and Ghana. Once I add a cleavage count variable to the specification in Model 2, the group count estimate becomes indistinguishable from zero while the cleavage effect is negative and statis- tically significant. Political elites try to minimize the ethnic connectivity of their coalitions with excluded groups. The fewer cleavages included in the government coalition, the more overlap exists between different coalition partners on a subset of the ethnic identity dimen- sions. When members of the government groups choose to stress alternative identity markers, they are more likely to shift their support within ruling coalition than to elites of excluded groups. This result yields support for H2 and calls for further research on the interaction of ethnic voting, individual ethnic identity, and elite responses to potential defections. Model 3 adds a variable that measures the population share included in both the previous and newly formed government. Its positive mean estimate indicates that incumbency exerts a strong influence on the subsequent ethnic composition of governments. However, the large and significant estimate of its standard deviation accounts for the instability of ethnic relations in states like Sierra Leone, the Democratic Republic of Congo, and Afghanistan. Including an incumbency proxy weakens some of the other regressors – especially the largest group dummy which is no longer statistically significant – but does not change the substantive insights regarding H1 and H2 . Alternative explanations and robustness checks The most important alternative explanation to the theory advanced by this paper is that ethnic coalitions result from formal rules that encourage or prescribe elite cooperation. In addition to the standard government characteristic variables, Model 3 now includes a dummy 20
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann variable on institutions that is interacted with all government-type variables. Lijphart and others expect that democracies and PR electoral rules should make minority rule unlikely while increasing the probability of ethnic coalition formation relative to single-group rule (Lijphart, 2002; Norris, 2008). Figure 4 displays the distribution of predicted probabilities across all formation opportunities for various government types on the x-axis. For each type, there are two probability distributions that distinguish democratic and autocratic systems (Przeworski et al., 2000; Cheibub, Gandhi and Vreeland, 2010), and electoral systems within democracies (Bormann and Golder, 2013). The bars inside the boxes indicate the median predicted probability while the whiskers represent the 90% confidence intervals. The most striking insight provided by Figure 4a is that there are hardly any differences between democracies (white boxes) and dictatorships (black) in the overall patterns of gov- ernment formation. Only minority rule by one ethnic group is more likely in dictatorships than in democracies, and the difference is statistically significant. The graph also confirms that ethnic elites are far more likely to form either single-group majority regimes or oversized coalitions than any other type of government. Again, no notable differences between demo- cratic and autocratic rule exist within these categories. Although it seems as if oversized coalitions are even more likely in dictatorships than in democracies, the relationship is not statistically significant. Whether or not governments are elected has little effect on their ethnic inclusiveness.28 Turning to institutional variation within democracies, Figure 4b compares majoritarian and PR electoral systems, and lend little support to the assertion that PR (black boxes) promotes ethnic power-sharing. To the contrary, majoritarian electoral systems (white) are more often associated with oversized coalitions and less often connected to oversized majorities than their PR counterparts. Even more surprisingly, ethnic leaders opt for single- member majorities significantly more often than for oversized coalitions under PR as the confidence intervals of either category do not overlap with the median effect of the other. Uncertainty is again a possible explanation for this finding. In contrast to PR systems, small changes in the vote distribution can lead to large shifts in parliamentary representation under majoritarian rule, and thus result in loss of power. Elites hedge against this possibility by 28 Using an alternative index of democracy, the Polity IV measure by Marshall, Jaggers and Gurr (2011) and adding anocracies as a third category does not change this insight. 21
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann Figure 4: Estimated government type probabilities in democracies and dictatorships (top panel) and under PR and majoritarian electoral rules within democracies (bottom panel). Predicted probabilities by regime type 0.8 Democracy Dictatorship Predicted Probability 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 Minority Majority Minority Minimum−Winning Oversized Single−Member Coalition (a) Democracy data from Cheibub, Gandhi and Vreeland (2010). Predicted Probabilities by Electoral System Majoritarian 0.8 PR Predicted Probability 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 Minority Majority Minority Minimum−Winning Oversized Single−Member Coalition (b) Electoral systems data from Bormann and Golder (2013). 22
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann forming oversized coalitions that allow them to continue their rule even if they are losing support.29 To test the robustness of my results, I rerun the main specifications with a simpler but biased model, the conditional logit, that is able to compute estimates for the complex configuration of ethnic coalitions in India. The results do not differ in any meaningful way from the ones in Table 2.30 The results also remain robust when I use an alternative sample of formation opportunities that records a potential change in the ethnic composition of the government whenever major institutional changes occur.31 To ensure that the results are not driven by cases in which ethnicity has arguably less political salience, I rerun Model 3 by on various subsets of countries. Neither the removal of OECD states, nor the exclusion of Western countries more generally, or states from the former Soviet Union challenges my findings. I am thus confident that sample idiosyncrasies are not driving my results. In alternative models, I test whether the effect of cleavages on coalition formation holds up when using alternative operationalizations. Rather than the total count I employ the relative share of cleavages included in the coalition, and continue to find support for my hypotheses. Additional tests assess whether the cleavage finding is driven by any one ethnic dimension. Some scholars expect that cooperation across religious divisions should be less likely (Huntington, 1996; Laitin, 2000; Toft, 2007) while others point to the strong visibility of racial divisions that impedes cooperation (Caselli and Coleman, 2013). Indicators of linguistic, religious, or racial fractionalization and polarization do not show any systematic relation with patterns of ethnic coalition formation. Conclusion In this paper, I have argued that governmental power-sharing, the coalition among different ethnic groups in the executive, is a result of elite uncertainty about future support by their co-ethnics and coalition partners. In contrast to a largely pessimistic view on the prospects 29 In the appendix, I also explore the variation between autocratic regimes with and without a ruling party, and with and without a legislature. Once more, I fail to find any evidence for the purported power-sharing effects of these institutions. 30 While easier to estimate via standard maximum-likelihood techniques, conditional logit models do not capture the variance of the average effect (Glasgow, Golder and Golder, 2012). 31 See the online appendix for more details. 23
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann of ethnic cooperation that prevails in the literature, my findings indicate that ethnic elites form secure majorities, mostly oversized coalitions, due to their desire to obtain and remain in power in an environment of incomplete information. This paper does not only answer the question what type of government ethnic elites form but also addresses which specific coalition will be chosen. My results support and comple- ment an important theoretical argument from the literature on ethnic politics that argues that rational individuals stress the identity marker that allows them to be a member of the smallest possible winning coalition (Posner, 2005; van der Veen and Laitin, 2012). Focusing on political elites, I argue that leaders anticipate potential defections by their co-ethnics. Therefore, they attempt to form coalitions between groups with cross-cutting cleavages that keep supporter switches inside the ruling coalition. Indeed, I find that coalitions that en- compass a smaller number of cleavages are more likely than those including a larger number. My elite-centered explanation diverges from previous studies of power-sharing by de- emphasizing the role of formal institutions in overcoming commitment problems. In fact, I do not find any evidence that the difference between democracies and dictatorships, or institutional variation within these regime types affects the likelihood of ethnic coalition formation. This finding has two major implications for the literature on power-sharing and conflict research. First, if institutions that are commonly considered to induce cooperative behavior do not affect ethnic coalition formation, the key mechanism for conflict resolution is void. As Diermeier and Krehbiel (2003, 127) point out: “It cannot be stressed enough that (. . . ) behavior within the institution – not just the institution in isolation – deter- mines whether institutions are outcome-consequential, or, as is more often uttered, whether institutions matter.” 32 Second, if my theory is correct that coalitions are most likely when leaders are uncertain, institutions that reduce uncertainty such as guaranteed government inclusion are less likely to induce cooperation among ethnic leaders. At the same time, existing research argues that high uncertainty also increases the risk of civil war (Walter, 2009; Mattes and Savun, 2010). If both these accounts of conflict and my theory were correct, one implication would be that elites embrace power-sharing when conflict is likely. This poses a dilemma for policy-makers 32 See Pepinsky (2014) for a similar plea to students of power-sharing in authoritarian regimes. 24
Origins of Ethnic Coalitions Bormann who want to promote power-sharing for normative reasons of political equality. Future research needs to pay more attention to the conditions under which ethnic coalitions form, when formal institutions are helpful, and how the interaction of coalitions and institutions affect civil war risk. Beyond conflict research, coalitions are a fundamental concept in political science (cf. Humphreys, 2008) but their quantitative study mostly focuses on parliamentary democracies in Europe (see Laver, 1998). Studying ethnic coalitions provides one empirical alternative by which to test the many theoretical models of coalition formation that often predict the for- mation of minimum-winning governments, and thereby further our theoretical understanding of coalition formation. 25
You can also read