The Impact of Single-family Mortgage Foreclosures on Neighborhood Crime

Page created by Miguel King
 
CONTINUE READING
Housing Studies,
Vol. 21, No. 6, 851–866, November 2006

The Impact of Single-family Mortgage
Foreclosures on Neighborhood Crime
DAN IMMERGLUCK* & GEOFF SMITH**
*Georgia Institute of Technology, City and Regional Planning Program, Atlanta, GA, USA, **Woodstock
Institute, Chicago, IL, USA

(Received April 2005; revised October 2005)

ABSTRACT Foreclosures of single-family mortgages have increased dramatically in many parts of
the US in recent years. Much of this has been tied to the rise of higher-risk subprime mortgage
lending. Debates concerning mortgage regulation, as well as around other residential finance
policies and practices, hinge critically on the social as well as personal costs of loan default and
foreclosure. This paper examines the impact of foreclosures of single-family mortgages on levels of
violent and property crime at the neighborhood level. Using data on foreclosures, neighborhood
characteristics, and crime, the study found that higher foreclosure levels do contribute to higher
levels of violent crime. The results for property crime are not statistically significant. A standard
deviation increase in the foreclosure rate (about 2.8 foreclosures for every 100 owner-occupied
properties in one year) corresponds to an increase in neighborhood violent crime of approximately
6.7 per cent. The policy implications of these findings are discussed.
KEY WORDS : Foreclosures, subprime loans, mortgages, crime

Introduction
In March of 2000, Mayor Richard M. Daley of Chicago held a press conference in front of
a boarded-up brick bungalow on Chicago’s Southwest Side to announce a proposed
ordinance aimed at reducing mortgage foreclosures in city neighborhoods (Washburn,
2000). The mayor compared the ‘menace’ of abusive mortgage lending and resulting
foreclosures to the problem of criminal street gangs. He went on to say that “vacant
buildings are ugly. They attract gangs . . . They are the most frequent problems
encountered by the (community policing program) and by block clubs and community
organizations” (Spielman, 2000, p.24). In the next few months, a high-profile series of six
murders in abandoned buildings in one South Side neighborhood brought increased
attention to the problem of abandoned properties. By September, the City had passed the
first municipal ordinance in the country aimed at reducing predatory lending. Supporters

Correspondence Address: Dan Immergluck, Associate Professor, Georgia Institute of Technology, City and
Regional Planning Program, Atlanta, GA 30332-0155, USA. Email: dan.immergluck@coa.gatech.edu
ISSN 0267-3037 Print/1466-1810 Online/06/060851–16 q 2006 Taylor & Francis
DOI: 10.1080/02673030600917743
852   D. Immergluck & G. Smith

of the law continually referred to the scourge of abandoned buildings stemming from high-
risk home loans as a principal reason for passing the law.
   Community concern over the problem of boarded-up and abandoned buildings, many of
which stemmed from increased mortgage foreclosures, provided important political
support for passage of the City’s hotly contested predatory lending ordinance. Certainly
concern for the more direct victims of predatory mortgages and the other effects that
blighted buildings may have on a community played a role as well, but the notion that such
buildings lead to increased crime was a critical factor. Yet despite the clear convictions of
the Mayor and many other policy makers and community groups around the country that
vacant and abandoned homes can lead to crime, the systematic research in this area is quite
scarce. In fact, the authors are aware of only one study that systematically links abandoned
buildings to crime and none that measure the effect of foreclosures on crime. Spencer
(1993) found that crime rates on blocks with open abandoned buildings were twice as high
as rates on similar blocks without open buildings.
   This paper seeks to measure the effect of foreclosures of single-family homes on levels
of violent and property crime at the neighborhood level. It is not suggested that any effect
of foreclosures on crime is more important than other harms that foreclosures might cause.
Effects on the directly affected households as well as other neighborhood impacts (e.g.
aesthetics, stability or property value) may be as or more important than any effects on
crime. However, effects on crime are clearly of concern, especially in many of the
neighborhoods that have been hit hard by the growing levels of foreclosures in cities across
the US.

The Foreclosure Problem
Nationally, foreclosure levels in the US have generally risen significantly since the 1970s.
During the 1980s, foreclosure rates on conventional loans rose significantly from about 0.3
to 0.4 per cent up to levels of around 0.8 per cent by the end of the decade (Elmer & Seelig,
1998). This may have been expected to some degree due to the strong economic
restructuring during the 1980s. However, even as the economy improved in the latter part
of the decade foreclosure rates increased. In the 1990s, despite a strong economy during
most of the decade, foreclosures continued a generally upward trend reaching 1.04 per cent
by 1997. In the late 1990s and early 2000s, the pattern remained one of historically high
foreclosure levels, peaking at 1.3 per cent in late 2003 before declining a small amount in
2004 (Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, 2004).
   States such as Indiana, Ohio, Kentucky, South Carolina, Pennsylvania and
Mississippi all had foreclosure rates above 2 per cent in late 2003 (Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation, 2004). Twenty-three states saw increases in foreclosures of more
than 24 per cent from the end of 2001 to the end of 2003, with eight of these seeing
increases of more than 50 per cent over the period. While the weak economy certainly
contributed to this problem, the magnitude of these increases was particularly large
and is certainly related to the underlying vulnerability of the mortgages to economic
downturns.
   Immergluck & Smith (2005) show that, in the Chicago area, foreclosure starts rose 238
per cent from 1995 to 2002. Although foreclosures of government-guaranteed mortgages
rose by 105 per cent, conventional foreclosures increased at a much faster pace of 350 per
cent. As a result, while conventional loans accounted for only slightly more than half of
Single-family Mortgage Foreclosures and Neighborhood Crime              853

foreclosures in 1995, they accounted for almost three out of four just seven years later.
Much of the increased foreclosure activity in the Chicago area was concentrated in lower-
income and minority communities. Neighborhoods with minority populations of less than
10 per cent in 2000 saw an increase in foreclosures of 215 per cent, while neighborhoods
with 90 per cent or greater minority populations experienced an increase of 544 per cent.
Neighborhoods with 90 per cent or more minority residents in 2000 accounted for 40 per cent
of the 1995 –2002 increase in conventional foreclosures. These same tracts represent
only 9.2 per cent of the owner-occupied housing units in the region. Tracts with 50 per cent
or greater minority populations accounted for more than 61 per cent of the increase in
conventional foreclosures.
   Foreclosures can entail significant costs and hardships for the families affected.
McCarthy et al. (2000) describe how foreclosures can involve losing not only accumulated
home equity and the costs associated with acquiring the home, but also access to stable,
decent housing. Moreover, foreclosures can damage credit ratings, hurting the owners’
prospects not only in credit markets but also in labor and insurance markets and in the
market for rental housing. Moreno (1995) estimated average losses to a foreclosed family
of $7200.
   But the economic and social costs of foreclosures may affect more than the families most
directly involved. Foreclosures can have implications for surrounding neighborhoods and
even for their larger communities. Cities, counties and school districts may lose tax revenue
from abandoned homes. In examining FHA foreclosures, for example, Moreno (1995)
estimated average city costs of $27 000 and neighborhood costs of $10 000. Moreover,
these figures do not account for all of the social and psychic costs of foreclosures, either to
the family or the community. One of the possible social costs is increased crime.

Subprime Lending and Increasing Foreclosures in Urban Areas
The problem of high foreclosure levels in recent years has been linked to the increasing
activity of subprime mortgage lenders that specialize in lending to borrowers with
imperfect credit. A number of studies have identified some relationship between subprime
lending and foreclosures at the neighborhood level (Burnett et al., 2002; Collins, 2003;
Gruenstein & Herbert, 2000; Newman & Wyly, 2004). In Atlanta, Abt & Associates found
that foreclosures attributed to subprime lenders accounted for 36 per cent of all
foreclosures in predominantly minority neighborhoods in 1999, while their share of loan
originations was between 26 and 31 per cent in the preceding three years (Greunstein &
Herbert, 2000). In Essex County, New Jersey, researchers found that the percentage of
foreclosures attributed to subprime lenders increased from 19 per cent in 1995 to 30 per cent
in 2000, although they also admitted that these figures substantially underestimated the
subprime share of foreclosures (Newman & Wyly, 2004).
   In general, these studies tend to underestimate the proportion of foreclosures due to
subprime originators because many subprime loans are sold to financial institutions
identified by the US Department of Housing and Urban Development as ‘prime’ lenders or
are held in trusts at prime lending institutions (usually banks). Thus, foreclosures of
subprime loans sold to prime lenders or trusts would list only the prime lender who
currently holds the loan, not the originating subprime lender. The reverse generally does
not occur. That is, subprime lenders do not tend to buy loans from prime lenders and
generally do not have trust capacity.
854    D. Immergluck & G. Smith

   Immergluck & Smith (2005) found that subprime lending has a very substantial effect
on foreclosures. In the case of refinance lending, for example, a tract with 100 more
subprime loans over a five-year period (compared to a standard deviation of 73 loans),
other things equal, corresponds to almost eight foreclosures in the year following this
period. The effect of subprime lending on foreclosures is generally on the order of 20 to 30
times the effect of prime lending, after controlling for neighborhood economic and
demographic conditions.
   Quercia et al. (2005) found that 20.7 per cent of all first-lien subprime refinance loans
originated in 1999 had entered foreclosure by December 2003 and that the rate at which
subprime loans entered foreclosure in late 2003 was more than ten times the rate for prime
loans.

From Foreclosure to Vacancy and Abandonment
In most middle- and upper-income neighborhoods where demand for residential property
is strong, where foreclosures are not very densely concentrated, and where homebuyers
and lenders have a great deal of certainty about property values and the ability to resell
properties at reasonable levels of appreciation, the negative impacts of foreclosures on a
neighborhood or larger community are unlikely to be very high.
   However, in low- and moderate-income neighborhoods, or neighborhoods in which
residents are struggling with various forms of economic duress, foreclosures may impose
significant negative externalities. Race may play a role too, as property value trajectories
in minority neighborhoods may be more easily destabilized by visible, confidence-
reducing events such as foreclosure sales. For example, Lauria & Baxter (1999) found that
foreclosures encouraged white flight and speedier racial transition in neighborhoods that
already had substantial black populations.
   A chief mechanism through which foreclosures harm neighborhoods is through the
triggering of extended vacancies or, worse, abandoned and blighted buildings. This is not
to say that concentrated foreclosures in a middle or even upper-income neighborhood may
not have a deleterious effect on property values or other negative effects. However, the
concentration of foreclosures in a short period of time in such areas is less common and,
even if they are subject to high levels of foreclosures over a certain period, upper- and
middle-income neighborhoods are generally more resilient.
   Figure 1 presents a simplified depiction of the difference in the chain of events likely to
be spurred by foreclosures in a struggling, lower-income neighborhood versus an
economically stronger neighborhood. In lower-income areas, a substantial percentage of
foreclosures are likely to lead to buildings being vacant for some extended period of time.
This extended vacancy alone may cause a partial loss of confidence among homeowners.
More importantly, as some of these vacancies age, the buildings are likely to be the targets
of vandalism, provide havens for criminal behavior, and generally become sources of
significant negative externalities to neighboring residents. Thus, it is through longer-term
vacancy and abandonment that foreclosures affect neighborhood crime.
   In higher-income neighborhoods, foreclosures will generally lead to the property being
sold fairly quickly to new homeowners. Depending on the particulars of the local housing
market, some foreclosures may result in modest short-term vacancies. However, few
homes will be exposed to extended vacancies and the sorts of physical blight that will
sometimes occur in lower-income areas.
Single-family Mortgage Foreclosures and Neighborhood Crime            855

        Figure 1. Results of foreclosures in lower- versus higher-income neighborhood

From Vacancy and Abandonment to Crime
Before analyzing the effect of foreclosures on neighborhood crime, it is important to place
this research in the context of a substantial literature on the effect on neighborhood crime
of what sociologists refer to as social and physical disorder. Vacant and abandoned
buildings are often considered a component of neighborhood physical disorder (as opposed
to social disorder). Physical disorder involves “signs of negligence and unchecked decay”
in a neighborhood (Skogan, 1990, p. 4). Physical disorder refers more to sustained
conditions than to particular events. However, these conditions are, of course, created by
events and actions. Moreover, Skogan (1990, p. 36) suggests that physical disorder is more
often caused by legal, if destructive, actions by perpetrators rather than by criminals or
offenders. Social disorder, on the other hand, is comprised specific undesirable events
and behavior (e.g. aggressive panhandling or public drinking) that may in turn cause
more serious problems, including crime, although this causation is disputed (Sampson &
Raudenbush, 1999).
   Several observers and researchers have argued that physical and social disorder causes
crime (Kelling & Coles, 1996; Skogan, 1990; Wilson & Kelling, 1982). They argue that
disorder undermines the ways in which communities maintain social control. Fewer
residents are concerned about or take responsibility for disorder in public spaces outside
their own households. Criminals flock to such communities because they do not fear being
caught. Thus, social and physical disorder leads to more serious criminal acts.
   However, Sampson & Raudenbush (1999) argue that disorder is not typically a cause of
crime, but that many elements of disorder are a component—perhaps not always well
measured—of crime itself. Moreover, they argue that physical disorder, such as smashed
856    D. Immergluck & G. Smith

windows and drug vials in the streets, is evidence either of crime or violations of
ordinances.
   Given this definition of physical disorder, vacant and abandoned houses should be seen
as a phenomenon distinct from disorder. While some vacant or abandoned homes may be
in violation of housing ordinances, the conditions of the homes are rarely caused by the
violations. While such buildings may be the result of illegal activity or social disorder on
the part of those having some physical presence in the neighborhood, they are generally
unlikely to be. An act of arson can result in abandonment if the owner of the victimized
house lacks adequate insurance. However, if a homeowner suffers a crisis of some kind
and cannot pay her mortgage, her home may be foreclosed upon and the house may
become vacant and then perhaps boarded up and eventually abandoned. While the effect
of this calamity is to increase neighborhood blight, the causation is quite external and not
caused by local crime, ordinance violations or social disorder. It may have more to do with
a layoff at an employer far from the neighborhood. Likewise, if an abandoned building
results from a foreclosure due to a high-risk subprime mortgage loan, no local crime or
ordinance violation was instrumental in creating the problem.
   Skogan (1990) argues that abandoned buildings can harm a neighborhood in different
ways. First, they can harbor decay. They may be havens for trash, rats or other stray
animals, squatters or even criminals. Abandoned houses may also be used as places where
drugs are sold and used, or used by predatory criminals who may attack neighborhood
residents. Finally, vacant or abandoned homes may be targets of vandalism, the theft of
wiring or other building components, or arson. However, property theft from such
buildings may be less likely to be reported than theft from occupied buildings. Indirectly,
the presence of boarded-up and abandoned buildings may lead to a lack of collective
concern by neighborhood residents with neighborhood crime.

Methods and Data
To identify the effect of foreclosures on neighborhood crime, we first attempt to estimate a
reduced form equation relating foreclosures and other neighborhood conditions to
neighborhood crime:
                        ln Ci ¼ a þ b1 Pi þ b2 Bi þ b3 Z i þ b4 Fi þ 1i                     ð1Þ
where ln Ci is the natural log of the number of crime incidents in census tract i, which will
later be disaggregated into violent and property crime. Pi is the population of the tract, Bi is
the number of businesses in the tract, and Zi is a vector of resident characteristics that
might be expected to affect neighborhood crime rates based on the literature. Fi is the tract
foreclosure rate, measured by the number of foreclosures divided by the number of owner-
occupiable housing units in tract i.1
   While some attempts to estimate neighborhood crime levels use per-capita crime rates
as the dependent variable (Kubrin & Squires, 2004), in this study a less restricted
specification is preferred, in which the raw number of crime incidents is a function of
population level, the number of businesses and characteristics of the population. First,
violent crimes occur against those who work as well as those who live in neighborhoods.
Neighborhood retail centers and business clusters are frequently crime ‘hot spots’. In the
case of property crime, it might be expected that the number of businesses would be an
especially strong factor. Ideally, the study would have additional information on the
Single-family Mortgage Foreclosures and Neighborhood Crime            857

businesses, particularly total number of employees in the tract, but such data are not
available at a census tract level in the City of Chicago.
   The dependent variable is transformed as the log of the raw crime figure because the
crime figures are substantially skewed in their distribution. Logging these variables creates
dependent variables that follow the normal distribution much more closely, fulfilling an
important assumption of ordinary least squares regression. To illustrate this point, Figure 2

            Figure 2. Frequency distributions of total crime and log of total crime
858     D. Immergluck & G. Smith

compares the distribution of total crime and the log of total crime. Coincidentally, the
resulting semilog functional form provides for a convenient interpretation of the
coefficients of the independent variables. That is, the coefficients represent the percentage
change in absolute crime levels for a one-unit change in the independent variable.
   To estimate equation (1), tract-level data from the 2000 census, business count data from
Dun and Bradstreet and crime data from the Chicago police department are combined for
tracts in the central city. The available police and business count data are from 2001. Crime
data are aggregated into violent crime and property crime, the sum of which yields total
crime. Based on recent literature on neighborhood crime (Kubrin & Squires, 2004;
Morenoff et al., 2001), the following variables were constructed that described resident
characteristics that might be expected to affect neighborhood crime rates:
. the proportion of residents living below the poverty line in 1999;
. the proportion of residents on public assistance in 2000;
. median family income in 1999;
. the unemployment rate in 2000;
. the percentage of residents who are black;
. the percentage of residents who are Hispanic;2
. the proportion of residents who are males aged 14 to 24;
. the proportion of households headed by females and with children below 18;
. the proportion of persons aged 15 and over who are divorced;
. the proportion of persons aged 5 and above who have changed residences in the last
  five years (percentage of recent residents); and
. the proportion of occupied housing units occupied by renters
  Table 1 gives the mean and standard deviation of the dependent and independent
variables used in estimating equation (1). Table 2 gives the Pearson correlations between the
dependent variables and each of the independent variables. As expected, population and

                                 Table 1. Summary statistics

                                                               Mean        Std. deviation
      Log of violent crime incidents                             3.5699        0.9968
      Log of property crime incidents                            4.9037        0.7240
      Log of total crime incidents                               5.1833        0.7235
      Population                                              3520.60       2593.45
      Number of businesses                                      85.44        220.81
      Median family income in 1999                          46 789        26 957
      Unemployment rate                                          7.01%         5.39%
      Proportion below poverty                                   0.2156        0.1524
      Percent female headed households                           0.2272        0.1755
      Proportion 15 and over divorced                            0.0894        0.0385
      Proportion on Public Assistance                            0.0880        0.0872
      Proportion of residents who are male aged 14 to 24         0.1694        0.0713
      Proportion of households that rent                         0.5676        0.2206
      Proportion of residents who have moved within 5 years      0.5191        0.1561
      Per cent black                                            41.45%        43.25%
      Per cent Hispanic                                         23.38%        28.67%
      Foreclosures in 2001 per owner-occupiable structures       0.0238        0.0287
Single-family Mortgage Foreclosures and Neighborhood Crime                   859

          Table 2. Pearson correlations between independent variables and crime levels

                                                     Log of              Log of             Log of
                                                  violent crime      property crime       total crime
Population                                             0.429               0.620              0.601
Number of businesses                                   0.056               0.344              0.296
Median family income in 1999                         2 0.456               0.058            2 0.083
Per cent unemployed                                    0.373             2 0.007              0.120
Proportion below poverty                               0.458             2 0.064              0.102
Per cent female headed households                      0.542               0.017              0.188
Proportion 15 and over divorced                        0.165               0.130              0.149
Proportion on Public Assistance                        0.459             2 0.044              0.120
Proportion of males aged 14 to 24                      0.161             2 0.007              0.035
Proportion of households that rent                     0.252               0.001              0.082
Proportion of residents moved within 5 yrs           2 0.130               0.081              0.026
Per cent black                                         0.532               0.052              0.208
Per cent Hispanic                                    20.040                0.003            20.030
Foreclosures in 2001 per owner-occupiable              0.425             2 0.018              0.119
structures
Notes: Italic and underlined ¼ Significant at p , 0.01; Italic ¼ Significant at p > 0.01 but p , 0.05;
       Underlined ¼ Significant at p > 0.05 but p , 0.10.

number of businesses are positively correlated with crime levels, although the correlation
between number of businesses and violent crime is quite weak. This is somewhat expected
because businesses are a major target of property crime. Many of the demographic variables
are significantly correlated at substantial levels with violent crime. These variables include
proportion female headed households, percentage black, proportion on public assistance,
median family income (negative sign) and, importantly, foreclosure rate. The correlations
with property crime are smaller and generally at lower significance levels. Of course, these
are just simple bivariate correlations and tell us relatively little about how foreclosure rate,
or any of the other variables, independently affects crime.
   Ordinary least squares regression was used to estimate equation (1) with all of the
independent variables listed in Table 2. However, in examining the partial regression plots
for all independent variables a significant non-linearity was identified for the residential
population variable. Figure 3 is the partial regression plot of the total crime residual versus
population, together with a fitted quadratic curve. It demonstrates the non-linear nature of
the impact of population on the dependent variable. To correct for this, the square of
population is added as an independent variable. This improves the regression fit
significantly (from R-square ¼ 0.717 to R-square ¼ 0.750).
   Table 3 gives the results of the estimation of equation (1) for all three dependent variables
(violent crime, property crime and total crime) with the square-of-population included
along with the original independent variables listed in Table 2. As predicted by the
examination of the partial plots, the sign of the coefficient for population is positive, but for
population squared it is negative. Therefore, crime incidents increase with population, but
increase at a slower rate at higher population levels. This non-linearity appears to be
somewhat stronger in the case of violent crime than in the case of property crime.
   The non-linearity in the effect of population on crime may be due to a problem of crime
occurring to employees working in what are essentially non-residential tracts or some
860    D. Immergluck & G. Smith

Figure 3. Partial regression plot of log of total crime on population (assuming exogenous variables
                                          listed in Table 2)

other phenomenon. For example, tracts with larger populations may have more street
activity or ‘eyes on the street’, providing a deterrent to crime (Jacobs, 1961).
   As anticipated, the number of businesses in a tract has a significant effect on crime rates.
The marginal effect is substantially larger for property crime than for violent crime.
Standardized coefficients suggest that variations in business counts are a substantial
determinant of property crime (beta ¼ 0.237) and also affect violent crime levels in a non-
trivial way (beta ¼ 0.119).
   Six of the demographic characteristic variables are statistically significant determinants
of neighborhood violent crime. These include percentage black, percentage Hispanic, the
proportion below poverty, the proportion of families headed by single females, the
proportion renting and the proportion that have moved in the last five years. Four
demographic characteristics are statistically significant determinants of neighborhood
property crime, including proportion divorced, proportion that have moved in the last five
years, percentage Hispanic, and percentage black.
   A word of caution is warranted in interpreting the results with regard to the
demographic variables. The objective here is not to identify all of the root causes of
neighborhood crime. That is left to the wider criminology literature. Rather, the goal here
is to provide a measure of the impact of foreclosures on crime that is not vulnerable to
charges that variables that have been found to be associated with crime have been omitted
from the analysis. The most convincing evidence of an independent effect of foreclosures
on crime needs to control for the impact of the neighborhood demographic factors
associated with neighborhood crime in the criminology literature. The results here do not
Table 3. Regressions of neighborhood crime on neighborhood characteristics and foreclosure rate, City of Chicago tracts
                                             Log of violent crime                             Log of property crime                             Log of total crime

                                                                Stdzd                             Std.          Stdzd                              Std.          Stdzd

                                                                                                                                                                                     Single-family Mortgage Foreclosures and Neighborhood Crime
                               Coeff.          Std. error       coeff.    Sig.       Coeff.       error         coeff.     Sig.       Coeff.       Error         coeff.      Sig.
(Constant)                    0.767           0.142                       0.000   2.689      0.135                         0.000   2.859      0.127                          0.000
Population                    4.03E   2 04    2.08E 2 05   1.050          0.000   3.40E 2 04 1.98E 2 05   1.219            0.000   3.49E 2 04 1.87E 2 05   1.251             0.000
Population squared          2 1.93E   2 08    1.88E 2 09 2 0.547          0.000 2 1.60E 2 08 1.79E 2 09 2 0.628            0.000 2 1.65E 2 08 1.69E 2 09 2 0.645             0.000
Number of businesses          5.37E   2 04    8.63E 2 05   0.119          0.000   7.76E 2 04 8.19E 2 05   0.237            0.000   7.54E 2 04 7.75E 2 05   0.230             0.000
Median family income          7.50E   2 07    1.08E 2 06   0.020          0.489   4.01E 2 06 1.03E 2 06   0.149            0.000   3.85E 2 06 9.73E 2 07   0.143             0.000
Unemployment rate           2 4.07E   2 03    4.84E 2 03 20.022           0.401   3.66E 2 04 4.60E 2 03   2.73E 2 03       0.937   9.81E 2 04 4.35E 2 03   0.007             0.822
Proportion below              0.804           0.252        0.123          0.002 20.184       0.240      20.039             0.442   0.110      0.227        0.023             0.629
poverty
Proportion female HH          0.597           0.251          0.105        0.018    0.353       0.239          0.086        0.139     0.461      0.226           0.112        0.041
Proportion divorced         2 0.225           0.596         28.70E 2 03   0.706    2.451       0.566          0.130        0.000     1.758      0.535           0.094        0.001
Proportion Public Asst      2 0.300           0.403         20.026        0.457   20.024       0.383         22.91E 2 03   0.950     0.074      0.362           8.89E 2 03   0.839
Proportion male             2 0.234           0.300         20.017        0.436    0.259       0.285          0.025        0.364     0.030      0.270           2.96E 2 03   0.911
14– 24
Proportion renting            0.226           0.136            0.050      0.098   20.113       0.129         20.034        0.384   2 0.045      0.122         2 0.014        0.710
Proportion moved in           0.529           0.178            0.083      0.003    0.897       0.169          0.194        0.000     0.782      0.160           0.169        0.000
5 yrs
Per cent black                0.017           0.001            0.749      0.000     6.10E 2 03 1.03E 2 03      0.365       0.000     7.96E 2 03 9.74E 2 04      0.476        0.000
Per cent                      0.013           0.001            0.372      0.000     4.66E 2 03 9.40E 2 04      0.184       0.000     5.94E 2 03 8.89E 2 04      0.235        0.000
Hispanic
Foreclosure                   2.328           0.873            0.067      0.008     0.084      0.829           3.32E 2 03 0.920      0.556      0.784           0.022        0.478
rate
N                           806                                                   806                                              806
R2                            0.750                                                 0.572                                            0.617

Notes: Italic and underlined ¼ Significant at p , 0.01; Italic ¼ Significant at p > 0.01 but p , 0.05; Underlined ¼ Significant at p > 0.05 but p , 0.1.

                                                                                                                                                                                     861
862    D. Immergluck & G. Smith

support a conclusion that demographic traits are root causes of crime. Rather they serve to
provide a conservative measure of the impact of the foreclosure rate on crime.
   Even after controlling for all of these factors, the key variable of interest, foreclosure
rate, remains a statistically significant determinant of violent crime. The results for
property crime are not statistically significant. Because property crime figures are higher
than violent crime figures, the variable is also not significant in the total crime regression.
   The nature of the semilog functional form makes the interpretation of the effect of
higher foreclosure rate on violent crime relatively straightforward. However, because the
independent variable never reaches a level close to one, a one-unit change in the variable is
not meaningful. The mean and standard deviation of foreclosure rate are only 0.0238 and
0.0287, respectively, so instead the expected change in violent crime is considered to be
due to a one standard deviation change in foreclosure rate. A 0.0287 increase in the
foreclosure rate yields an expected increase in violent crime of 6.68 per cent. A smaller
increase in the neighborhood foreclosure rate, of say 1 in 100 properties, would yield an
increase in violent crime of 2.33 per cent.

Concerns about Multi-collinearity
Although not examining the role of foreclosures, Kubrin & Squires (2004) find a similar
estimation of neighborhood crime rates in Seattle to be afflicted by problems of multi-
collinearity and employ principal components analysis to reduce the number of
independent variables. Therefore, when estimating equation (1) diagnostics for
collinearity were examined quite carefully. While significant bivariate correlations were
found among some of these variables, multivariate collinearity diagnostics did not suggest
that collinearity was a major problem. Variance inflation factors were examined and none
exceeded 7 before the square of population variable was added. Even after this variable
was added, all variance inflation factors remained under 10 and most remained under 5.
Moreover, the regression was re-run using standardized independent variables to compute
a collinearity condition index. The condition index was less than 10 even after the square
of population variable was added. Thus, the diagnostics did not suggest that multi-
collinearity was a serious problem, and no data reduction techniques were used.

Checking for Possible Simultaneity
Another possible concern with the results in Table 3 is that the model used may ignore
simultaneity between foreclosure rate and crime. That is, there is a look at whether violent
crime could cause higher foreclosure rates as well as the other way around. If simultaneity
occurs, the results in Table 3 would result in biased coefficients. To address this potential
problem, a Hausman test is conducted for simultaneity (Pindyck & Rubinfeld, 1991,
pp. 303 – 305). To do this, first it is necessary to identify an instrument that is significantly
correlated with the foreclosure rate but that is uncorrelated with the residual in the results
of the regression from Table 3. A variable that meets these criteria is median home value.
This variable is negatively correlated with foreclosure rate (2 0.395) and uncorrelated
with the regression residual. With this value the instrument and the exogenous
independent variables (excluding foreclosure rate) are regressed on foreclosure rate. The
resulting residual is then taken and included as an additional independent variable in the
estimation of tract crime (equation (1)). The results (shown in the Appendix) of this
Single-family Mortgage Foreclosures and Neighborhood Crime              863

exercise show that the residual does not come in as a statistically significant predictor of
tract crime (significance level equals 0.317). This means that there is no evidence that
simultaneity is a problem in the results in Table 3.

Conclusions and Implications for Planning and Policy
The problems of foreclosures are certainly not limited to impacts on crime. Foreclosures
can harm the financial standing of a family, leave them without ready or quality shelter,
and can have other negative impacts. Foreclosures might also make neighborhoods less
appealing for reasons of aesthetics or affects on property values that have nothing to do
with crime. Boarded up buildings due to foreclosures may weaken the commitment of
residents to a neighborhood and weaken their interest in reinvesting in their property. But
the concern over foreclosures in many communities lies in part with their effect on the
safety and security of the neighborhood. More research is needed on any additional social
or economic costs of foreclosures.
   This study finds that higher neighborhood foreclosure rates lead to higher levels of
violent crime at appreciable levels. While the effect on property crime is not found to be
statistically significant, the coefficient in the regression is positive. This effect may be due
to more property crimes not being reported when they are related to vacant and abandoned
structures. Another possible explanation is that, because the effects are greater in lower-
income neighborhoods, this finding may be due to an under-reporting of property crime in
lower-income areas. Higher income areas are more likely to report crimes generally
considered of less consequence compared to lower-income areas. More research is needed
on the relationship between foreclosures and property crime.
   A one percentage point (0.01) increase in foreclosure rate (which has a standard
deviation of 0.028) is expected to increase the number of violent crimes in a tract by 2.33
per cent other things being equal. A full standard deviation increase in the foreclosure rate,
other things equal, is expected to increase violent crime by 6.68 per cent.
   These findings suggest that foreclosures may have important social and economic
consequences on neighborhoods beyond effects on the finances of households directly
affected by the foreclosure. An increase in violent crime is an important social cost, as well
as an economic cost, that must be incorporated into policy making concerning real estate
and mortgage lending policies and regulation.
   In particular, previous research has shown that subprime mortgage lending leads to
foreclosures at much higher rates than prime lending (Immergluck & Smith, 2005; Quercia
et al., 2005). This is the first study that systematically estimates the effect of
foreclosures—many of which followed from subprime loans—on neighborhood crime
rates. While the results estimating the effect of foreclosures on property crime are
statistically inconclusive, the results for violent crime are significant.
   One area of policy making that these findings apply to is that of mortgage lending
regulation. Substantial evidence now exists that the growth of foreclosures and their
concentration in lower-income and especially minority neighborhoods in recent years has
been driven largely by the growth and concentration of the subprime mortgages in these
areas. It has been shown that foreclosures have a significant, non-trivial impact on violent
crime at the neighborhood level. Others have found that foreclosures entail substantial
other costs to neighborhoods and municipalities. Apgar & Duda (2005) found that the
direct costs to city government in Chicago involve more than a dozen agencies and two
864        D. Immergluck & G. Smith

dozen specific municipal activities, generating governmental costs that in some cases
exceed $30 000 per property.
   Despite the evidence on the social costs of high-risk mortgage loans, federal and state
regulators appear timid. Most policy debates concerning ‘predatory’ lending and the
regulation of higher-risk loans continue to center around arguments of whether increased
regulation might possibly restrict access to credit for some potential borrowers. While the
potential for such effects should be studied, the types of negative effects of higher-risk
lending, such as the crime effect shown here, should be cause to shift the debate more
towards questions of costs versus benefits of different regulatory regimes. Perhaps some
restriction of credit does occur with increased regulation, although the evidence currently
is that stronger regulation does not have this result (Ho & Pennington-Cross, 2005). The
findings here suggest that some reduction in high-risk credit flows may be merited, since it
appears that they may be leading to social ills that impact those beyond the lender or
borrower.

       Notes
       1
           Owner-occupiable units are calculated by taking the percentage of occupied units that are owner
           occupied and multiplying it by the total number of housing units in the tract, including vacant units.
       2
           Kubrin & Squires (2004) do not include percentage of Hispanic in their study of Seattle neighborhoods.
           However, in Chicago well over 20 per cent of the population is Hispanic and Hispanic segregation is
           significant.

References
Apgar, W. & Duda, M. (2005) Collateral damage: the municipal impact of today’s mortgage foreclosure boom,
     11 May (Washington DC: Homeownership Preservation Foundation). Available at http://www.hpfonline.
     org/images/Apgar-Duda%20Study%20Final.pdf (accessed on 20 June 2005).
Burnett, K., Herbert, C. & Kaul, B. (2002) Subprime originations and foreclosures in New York State: a case
     study of Nassau, Suffolk, and Westchester Counties, August (Cambridge: Abt Associates, Inc).
Collins, M. (2003) Chicago’s homeownership preservation challenge: foreclosures, presentation, February
     (Washington: Neighborhood Reinvestment Corporation).
Elmer, P. & Seelig, S. (1998) The rising long-term trend of single-family mortgage foreclosure rates, Working
     Paper 98-2 (Washington DC: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation).
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (2004) Economic conditions and emerging risks in banking. 26 April.
     Available at http://www.fdic.gov/deposit/insurance/risk/ecerb.pdf (accessed 6 January 2005).
Gruenstein, D. & Herbert, C. (2000) Analyzing trends in subprime originations and foreclosures: a case study of
     the Atlanta metro area, February (Cambridge: Abt Associates, Inc).
Ho, G. & Pennington-Cross, A. (2005) The impact of local predatory lending laws. Working Paper 2005-049A,
     June (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis).
Immergluck, D. & Smith, G. (2005) Measuring the effects of subprime lending on neighborhood foreclosures:
     evidence from Chicago, Urban Affairs Review, 40, pp. 362–389.
Jacobs, J. (1961) The Death and Life of Great American Cities (New York: Random House).
Kelling, G. & Coles, C. (1996) Fixing Broken Windows: Restoring Order and Reducing Crime in Our
     Communities (New York: Touchstone).
Kubrin, C. & Squires, G. (2004) The impact of capital on crime: does access to home mortgage money reduce
     crime rates? Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Urban Affairs Association, Washington DC,
     April.
Lauria, M. & Baxter, V. (1999) Residential mortgage foreclosure and racial transition in New Orleans, Urban
     Affairs Review, 34, pp. 757 –786.
McCarthy, G., Vanzandt, S. & Rohe, W. (2001) The economic benefits and costs of homeownership: a critical
     assessment of the research, Working Paper 01-02, May (Washington DC: Research Institute for Housing
     America).
Single-family Mortgage Foreclosures and Neighborhood Crime                          865

Moreno, A. (1995) The Cost-Effectiveness of Mortgage Foreclosure Prevention (Minneapolis: Family Housing
     Fund).
Morenoff, J., Sampson, R. & Raudenbush, S. (2001) Neighborhood inequality, collective efficacy, and the spatial
     dynamics of urban violence, Criminology, 39, pp. 517–559.
Newman, K. & Wyly, E. (2004) Geographies of mortgage market segmentation: the case of Essex County, New
     Jersey, Housing Studies, 19, pp. 53–83.
Pindyck, R. & Rubinfeld, D. (1991) Econometric Models and Economic Forecasts, 3rd edn. (New York: McGraw
     Hill).
Quercia, R., Stegman, M. & Davis, W. (2005) The impact of predatory loan terms on subprime foreclosures: the
     special case of prepayment penalties and balloon payments, 25 January (Chapel Hill: Center for Community
     Capitalism at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill).
Sampson, R. & Raudenbush, S. (1999) Systematic social observation of public spaces: a new look at disorder in
     urban neighborhoods, The American Journal of Sociology, 105, pp. 603 –651.
Skogan, W. (1990) Disorder and Decline: Crime and the Spiral of Decay in American Neighborhoods (Berkeley:
     University of California Press).
Spencer, W. (1993) Abandoned buildings: magnets for crime?, Journal of Criminal Justice, 21, pp. 481–495.
Speilman, F. (2000) City to target hazards of abandoned buildings, Chicago Sun Times, 15 March, p. 24.
Washburn, G. (2000) Mayor targets lenders preying on homeowners: fast-buck artists force foreclosures, he says,
     Chicago Tribune, 15 March, p. 3.
Wilson, J. Q. & Kelling, G. (1982) Broken windows: the police and neighborhood safety, The Atlantic, March,
     pp. 29–38.

Appendix

A Hausman Test for Simultaneity
In the model described in equation (1), there may be a concern about reverse causality.
That is, there may be a concern that crime, in fact, causes foreclosures as well as the other
way around, a problem referred to as simultaneity. Crime, for example, may encourage
homeowners to flee neighborhoods without paying off their loans, increasing foreclosure
levels. If simultaneity occurs between crime and foreclosures, ordinary least squares
would not accurately measure the effect of foreclosures on crime. If simultaneity is a
problem, then, in addition the relationship hypothesized in equation (1), the complete
model would require the incorporation of a second equation explaining the effect of crime
on foreclosures, such as:

                                    Fi ¼ a þ b1 ln Ci þ b2 Xi þ y i                                        ð2Þ

where Xi is not correlated with the error term, 1, in the estimation of equation (1). Xi is an
instrument used to adequately identify the model. Xi must be correlated with foreclosures,
but not with the residual in the regression estimating equation (1). A variable that fulfills
these criteria is the median housing value of the census tract. It is negatively correlated
with foreclosure rate, but not correlated with the residual of the crime estimation.
   To test for simultaneity with respect to the log of crime variable, in a first stage
foreclosures are regressed on all the other independent variables in equation (1), plus the
instrument (median home value):

                            Fi ¼ a þ g1 Pi þ g2 Bi þ g3 Zi þ g4 Xi þ vi                                    ð3Þ
866    D. Immergluck & G. Smith

      Table A1. Results of second stage of Hausman test for simultaneity (estimation of
                                       equation (1a))

                                                   Log of violent crime
                                       Coeff.         Std. error    Stdzd coeff.   Sig.
      (Constant)                    0.65483         0.18065                        0.000
      Population                    4.103E 2 04     2.191E 2 05        1.06738     0.000
      Population squared          2 1.957E 2 08     1.911E 2 09      2 0.55656     0.000
      Number of businesses          5.367E 2 04     8.628E 2 05        0.11889     0.000
      Median family income          1.376E 2 06     1.252E 2 06        0.03722     0.272
      Unemployment rate           2 0.00154         0.00546          2 0.00835     0.777
      Proportion below poverty      0.71623         0.26709            0.10953     0.007
      Proportion female HH          0.60723         0.25140            0.10688     0.016
      Proportion divorced           0.25475         0.76519            0.00984     0.739
      Proportion Public Asst      2 0.83886         0.67273          2 0.07339     0.213
      Proportion male 14 – 24     2 0.23039         0.30034          2 0.01647     0.443
      Proportion renting            0.28865         0.14998            0.06388     0.055
      Proportion moved in 5yrs      0.50447         0.17951            0.07901     0.005
      Per cent black                0.01397         0.00346            0.60612     0.000
      Per cent Hispanic             0.01223         0.00121            0.35166     0.000
      Foreclosure rate             10.59037         8.30579            0.30528     0.203
      Residual from stage 1 (v)   2 8.35434         8.35207          2 0.16934     0.317
      N                           806
      R2                            0.750

Then, in a second stage, v is included, the residual from the estimation of equation (3), as
an additional independent variable in the estimation of a modified equation (1). This is
done to ‘correct’ for simultaneity (Pindyck & Rubinfeld, p. 305). Thus, the original model
is expanded as follows:
                    ln Ci ¼ a þ b1 Pi þ b2 Bi þ b3 Zi þ b4 Fi þ b5 vi þ 1i                 ð1aÞ
If vi is statistically significant in the estimation of equation (1a), the null hypothesis that
there is no simultaneity can be rejected. However, as shown in Table A1, the results of
estimating this new equation (shown for the log of violent crime, since that is the
significant result in Table 3), indicate that this is not the case. The null hypothesis that
there is no simultaneity cannot be rejected at any reasonable p value. Thus, there is no
evidence of simultaneity.
You can also read