The effect of parents' background on youth unemployment duration
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
The effect of parents’ background on youth unemployment duration * Fernanda Mazzotta October 2008 Abstract Very Preliminary draft Please don’t quote Comment are welcome The paper analyses the relation between the economic and cultural background of parents and the unemployment of their adult children. A search theory model is used to identify the effects exerted by the household’s economic circumstances and the parents’ cultural/education level on the children’s monetary and non-monetary constraints and chances of receiving job offers. The empirical specification of the model features a simultaneous estimation suggested by Lancaster (1985) of the duration of unemployment and of the accepted wage in a new job. The data are drawn from the European Community Household Panel considering the eight waves currently available for Italy (1994-2001), and the sample consists of children aged under 36, cohabiting with their parents during the search of a job. The main results are that graduates from deprived social backgrounds find it more difficult to find jobs than do graduates from affluent families and this is true in particular in the South of Italy. While in the North, graduate, young male with ability are favoured. Also, for other educated young unemployed children particular important are work experiences and ability specially in the North These findings once again raise questions about differential quality of education in Italy in the North and South, and about the job-finding difficulties faced by young people deriving form deprived family in particular where the labour market is stagnant, regardless of individual abilities . C3, J64, J62. Keywords: Simultaneously equation models, unemployment, duration job search, intergenerational mobility * University of Salerno Department of Economics and Statistics CELPE mazzotta@unisa.it 1
1. Introduction Individual school attainment and success in the labour market are important determinants of income distribution and are often thought to be among the key factors explaining the wealth of nations as well as cross-nation differences in economic growth. At the micro level, it is customary to assume a strong correlation between schooling attainments and household background variables (income and parents’ education). The effect of these variables on individual schooling attainments can take various forms and the net impact is far from obvious. While enrolled at school, young individuals receive parental support. On the one hand, wealthier households may transfer more resources to their children and reduce the opportunity cost of school attendance; on the other, the opportunity cost of spending time with children is higher for these households. At the same time, innate ability, which is also correlated with household background variables, should have an independent impact on the decision to attend school and on labour market wages. If skill endowments are strongly correlated with household background variables (especially the father's and mother's education), those young individuals raised in households endowed with a high level of human capital will have a high level of school ability but will also have a high level of market ability (absolute advantage in the labour market). Moreover, the family background may influence the reservation wage (or the accepted wage, since the accepted wage in a new job is an increasing function of the reservation wage) of the adult children and thereby also influence their decision whether or not to accept a given wage offer. Finally, the advantage in the labour market may depend on the opportunity and the ability to activate the most effective job search channel. In summary, household background variables (income and education) may influence individual success in the labour market, exerting both a direct impact on the characteristics of the labour supply (education, ability and reservation wage) and an indirect impact on the labour demand (more job opportunities thanks to an efficient job search). These simultaneous effects of the parents’ background variables on the opportunity cost, the reservation wage and on both school and market abilities are the central concerns of this study. The main objective is to estimate a structural model of unemployment duration and answer the question of whether the household background influences the duration of unemployment, after controlling for the children’s educational level, ability and the level of the accepted wage in a new job. The household background variables are identified with the economic condition of the household (monetary poverty condition) and the cultural level of the parents. These two variables are used to distinguish between a liquidity constraints effect (i.e. income constraints on the choice of a better education or of the optimal job) and non- monetary effects linked to the family’s cultural origins. Such distinction is important for designing better targeted policies to improve labour market performances. The data used are drawn from the Italian sample of the European Community Household Panel (ECHP), waves 1 to 8 (1994-2001), and includes all the unemployed children aged under 36 (born after 1958 and before 1985) cohabiting with their families during the unemployed period, reporting a completed duration of unemployment and an accepted wage for a new job finding during the seven years of the survey.. All other young adults in the labour market and under 36 are used to correct the model for sample selection. Young people not in the labour force (students, non–active individuals, etc.) or never unemployed and those aged over 35 are dropped from the sample. 2
The next two sections review the literature on reservation wage and unemployment duration. There follows a description of the data and of the sample selection model featuring two simultaneous equations for estimation of the accepted wage in a new job and of unemployment duration. The estimation results are then reported, and the paper concludes with a summary of policy implications. 2. Literature Research on the relation between parents’ economic and cultural background and children’s success in the labour market has mainly addressed intergenerational mobility, with economists focusing principally on the relation between the father’s and the son'/daughter’s income. Since the milestone study published by Becker and Thomes in 1979, economists have sought to measure the link between an individual’s socioeconomic position and that of his/her father. Interest in the transmission of economic status from one generation to another is generally prompted by the wish to determine the extent of the equality of opportunity in a country. Since Becker and Thomes’ study, a large part of the literature has sought appropriate methods with which to measure mobility or to study the intergenerational correlations of educational attainment, such as transition matrices (or some synthetic measures) and probit (or ordered probit) estimations of the determinants of children’s success. As regards income, the most frequently used measure of mobility is the regression coefficient relating a child’s log earnings to his/her father's. A high value indicates a very marked persistence of economic status, because an individual's position in the earnings distribution is largely a reflection of his/her father’s position in his own distribution. A low value indicates a very mobile society in which an individual's socio-economic position does not depend on that of the father. Data availability is a crucial factor: in fact, information about the incomes of the two generations is needed, and long panel data or cross-sections with retrospective information about parents' income are typically used. Although a large body of economic literature has studied the correlation between father’s and son/daughter’s socioeconomic status, only fewer and more recent works have analyzed the causes of this strong link. With specific reference to Italy, the possible causes of low intergenerational mobility are seen to reside in the liquidity (monetary) constraints which prevent individuals from taking advantage of incentives to acquire an education level more compatible with their preferences. Consequently, the children of less well-off households invest less in education because they are unable to attain the optimal level of education, where optimal refers to the costs/benefits structure of investment in education. An additional alleged reason is dependence on family origins, and it is strengthened by the so-called ‘peer effect’, i.e. the social context within and outside the school. The offspring of poor and less-educated parents must make greater efforts to acquire education because they live in a social context which does not help them to learn. Policy measures designed to increase intergenerational mobility should be double pronged, seeking to reduce liquidity constraints on the one hand, while improving the workings of the education system, for example by fostering integration 3
among students from different social backgrounds and reducing the initial disparities. A final causal factor is ability, which according to an extreme hypothesis, is pre-determined by genetics. Checchi and Zollino (2001) and Checchi and Bertola (2001) have studied the effects of parental background on scholastic performance, while Brunello, Checchi and Comi (2003) have examined the effects on labour market performance. The findings are that, although attendance at an expensive school is a necessary but not sufficient condition for better performance, more important are the peer effects exerted by the neighbourhood and differences in student cultural backgrounds originating in the family. Moreover, Checchi, Ichino and Rustichini (1999) have compared Italy and the USA in regard of their different school systems and the degree of intergenerational mobility. Their finding is that Italy is less mobile than the USA, possibly because the way the educational system and the labour market are structured does not offer real opportunities for the children of lower income families to emerge and to retain the returns on their educational investment. In a world where family background is important for labour market success – it is argued - an excessively centralized education system with uniform quality, particularly at university level, does not necessarily help poor children and may deprive them of a fundamental tool to prove their talent and to compete with rich children. Two approaches can be adopted in analysis of employment probabilities or hazards rate from unemployment: a reduced form approach and a structural one. The former (see e.g. Nickell, 1979; Lancaster and Nickell, 1980; Atkinsons et al. 1984; Narendranathan et al., 1985) involves direct estimation of the hazard function, with the rate of job arrivals and the reservation wage of the unemployed individual as the variables of interest. However, since the specification of the hazard function makes no explicit reference to the behaviours of the reservation wage, the results from the reduced form estimation do not allow to directly testing various hypotheses on the reservation wage function postulated by the job search model. Although a job search model is developed, it serves only as a basis for interpretations and indirect inferences to be made from the results of the estimation. The structural approach to estimation, on the other hand, uses information concerning the structure of the job search model and imposes appropriate restrictions on the data. The ability to identify and estimate the underlying structural relationship of a job search model is of importance to the policymaker involved in the design and evaluation of policies affecting the job search process. The availability of reservation wage data should makes it possible to estimate the structural parameters of the job search models. Pioneering work in this area has been done by Lancaster and Chesher (1983, 1984) and Lancaster (1985). Recognition of the potential two-way causal link between unemployment duration and the reservation wage accounts for the techniques developed in L-C (1984) and Lancaster (1985), where all the structural parameters are estimated using the two-stage least squares method (2SLS). For the Italian case, direct estimates of the reservation wage are provided by Mazzotta (1998), Bettio and Mazzotta (2002) and Boeri and Pagani (1998), which focuses on the demographic and territorial differences in asking wages. Of particular interest is the evidence of the great importance, both theoretical and empirical, of desired working hours. (Bettio and Mazzotta, 2002). An important aspect is the availability of a correct reservation wage. A new study (Bettio and Mazzotta 2008) show that the reservation wage revailed in the ECHP is not the really 4
reservation wage and more realistic is the first wage accepted for a new job2. Besides in a simultaneously analysis it must take care to the time duration available, in fact the reservation wage depends form the elapsed duration of search (until that moment) and for the accepted wage the casual relation is with the completed duration. In the echp, we have the availabily of the completed spell, I can reconstruct the elapsed or not completed duration of the job search, but non è precisa ed a costo della perdita di molte osservazioni, dato che gli individui possono aver interrotto la ricerca ed essere usciti temporaneamente durante il periodo rilevazione. Inoltre, per le durate di ricerca che iniziano nel primo anno di rilevazione, se l’individuo non trova un lavoro durante le otto rilevazioni, e non dichiara la durata della disoccupazione, non si può ricostruire il momento in cui ha inziato a cercare un lavoro. Per tutte queste ragioni si è scelto di analizzare la durata completa della disoccupazione controllando per il salario di ingresso accettato. To the best of my knowledge, however, there are no analyses that carry out structural estimation of a job search model using both the accepted wage in a new job (or last reservation wage) and the hazard function as is done here; nor are there analyses which introduce family background variables to capture, on the supply side, the influence of the family on the accepted wage and, on the demand side, family influence on the chances of receiving job offers. By carrying out structural estimation of a job search model this study seeks to determine whether, controlling for educational level, reservation wage and the ability of children, family backgrounds still influence – and in which direction – the duration of unemployment. For the reasons spelt out below, theory provides no clear a priori expectations on the strength and the sign of this influence. As noted, parents influence the occupational statuses of their children through the educational attainment of the latter. Hence, the children of less well-off households chose the best school or prolong the studies, then the expected marginal returns from the job search increase. The cultural level of the parents also influences the reservation wage of the offspring: the higher the educations of the father and mother, the higher the level attained by the son. For example, Checchi and Zollino (2001) estimated that the son of a graduate has a 43% better chance of obtaining a college degree than the son of a non-graduate. However, the economic and cultural condition of the parents may influence the labour- market success of their children independently of education, by affecting the children’s expectations, and therefore search for a suitable job. In fact, higher parental income directly increases the amount of resources available for the children’s education. Higher parental income increases the benefits received during the search, which boosts the children’s reservation wage and the accepted wage in turn. However, if the reservation wage is interpreted as a threshold wage, it may happen that a lower family income induces the individual to ask for and accepted more in order to obtain a minimum standard of living for the whole family. 2 Infatti, risulta che in Italia in media il salario di ingresso o re-ingresso nell’occupazione accettato dai disoccupati meridionali non solo è inferiore in livello assoluto a quello nel resto del paese (€ 3.2 contro € 4 medi al Centro Nord tra il 1994 e il 2001, a prezzi 1995), ma equivale ad una rinuncia del 31% rispetto al salario di riserva orario dichiarato. La cifra corrispondente per il Centro-Nord è il 10%. 5
Besides the accepted wage, family origins may also impinge on information asymmetries on the labour demand and supply sides. That is to say, they may influence in various ways both the information available to the children and the signal the latter send firms. The net effect on intergenerational mobility, however, is unclear because poor and low-educated families may favour information concerning with job offers lower pay, so that the duration of unemployment is shorter, but at the same time intergenerational mobility is not improved. 3. Estimation Methodology: completed durations and accepted wages. Following Lancaster (1985) model there are two casual relationships between the reservation wage (wr) and the duration of search (t), in one of which the reservation wage is a deterministic function of the date and in the other the elapsed duration is a (stochastic function of the reservation wage. The duration observed is both the date and a realisation of the random elapsed duration in a way rather analogous to a market model in which the quantity we observe is both the quantity supplied and the quantity demanded. Further, since the accepted wage in a new job, w, is an increasing function of the reservation wage, a very similar heuristic argument indicates that there will be two casual relation between w and t, where t is the completed rather than the elapsed duration. 3: In fact, when a person accept a occupation at date t, the wage accepted is a realisation of the random variable whose distribution is that of the wage offer truncated on the left at wr(t). Lancaster (1985) shows that the structural form of a model with completed duration and accepted wage is: log w = constant − η log t + Xβ + u1 [1] log t = constant + α log w − Xθ + u2 [2] Lancaster call this model the structural form because its coefficients are the structural coefficients of the search model specification, η , θ , α e β . This form exhibits clearly the two casual relations that we argued earlier should obtain between t and w . The first equation say that people who have been searching a long time should have cut their asking 3 Lancaster Chesher (1984) assume that the wage offer distribution is the Pareto which is a constant elasticity hypothesis for the hazards/reservation wage relation and can be thought as a log –linear approximation to the true relation. The log normal, thought it may be of course be more accurate, does not have this interpretation as a linear approximation 6
wage a lot (if η >0) and therefore get a low wage in the new job. The second equation corresponds to the idea that people who go back to work at a high wage have had a high asking price and therefore have taken a long time to get an acceptable offer. Noting that if at least one element of θ is zero while the corresponding element of β is not, α and the remaining elements of θ , can be identified form the first moments of the data regardless of the distribution of the error terms u1 and u2 as long as these have means that do not depend on X . Contrarywise Lancaster argued that no variable in Xβ can fail to be present in Xθ so that η e β are unidentifiable from the first moments of the data done. Tuttavia, Lancaster note that, if one or more zero restrictions can be placed on θ , the equation [2] can be consistently estimated by 2SLS and standard errors computed form the usual formula since the covariance matrix of log w and log t is independent of X for small η . Lancaster (1985) uses the number of dependent children in the job searcher’s household to achieve identification. Dolton and O’Neill (1995) use the amount of benefits received by the job seeker, the presence of children in the household and the presence of a working partner as exclusion restrictions. Here I assume that the number of dependent (aged less than 15 year old) and the private and social monetary transfers influences the costs of search and hence the reservation wage, but not the job arrival rate or the wage offer distribution. Another econometric issue is that the sample of the respondents reporting accepted wages is restricted to those who are finding a job during the period 1995 - 2001. Consequently only this group is generally used to estimate unemployment duration. However, this selective sample may be unrepresentative of the population of workers, in fact excluded those constantly unemployed, and estimations using the sample may yield biased regression coefficients. Moreover, for the purposes of this study, the sample selected consists only of persons identified as children at the beginning of the survey (1994), and this latter restriction is necessary in order to estimate average education for the parents as well as the poverty condition of the household in which the individual lives. The first potential selection bias problem is the same as encountered in estimation of a standard wage equation that uses only people in employment. Recall that Heckman's solution to this problem is first to estimate a probit model that relates the probability of an individual being in the labour force to a set of determinants, and then to use the probit estimates to compute the inverse Mills ratio. This variable is then included as a covariate in the wage equation. In the present case, however, there are two not independent decisions determining the inclusion of the individual in the sample: the decision to accepted a job and the decision to live in the original household Hence Heckman’s methodology must be adapted, and this involves the step procedure described below. 1. In order to address selectivity the following model is run in step one 7
1 = Π 1 Z 1i + U 1 if w > w r (find a job) Y1i = 0 otherwise (constantly unemployed ) [3] 1 = Π 2 Z 2 i + U 2 if u(in family) > u(out of family) (children) Y2 i = 0 otherwise (not children) where Z 1 should contain all the exogenous variables in X 1 and X 2 . In practice, the two equations are run using all the observations in the sample, whereby information collected exclusively for the unemployed is lost (e.g. reservation wage and job offer variables). Z 2 contains all the exogenous variables that influence the decision to cohabit with the original household. 2. In step two the bivariate probit estimates from step one are used to calculate the two selectivity bias terms. The corresponding expressions are (Meng and Schmidt, 1985; Baffoe - Bonnie, 2004): λ1i = [ φ ( Z i Π 1 )Φ (Z i Π 2 − ρZ i Π 1 ) / 1 − ρ 2 ] [4] F ( Z i Π1 , Z i Π 2 ; ρ ) λ 2i = [ φ ( Z i Π 2 )Φ (Z i Π 1 − ρZ i Π 2 ) / 1 − ρ 2 ] [5] F ( Z i Π1 , Z i Π 2 ; ρ ) 3. In step three the selection bias terms are included on the right hand side of both the reservation wage and the duration equation [1 and 2]; 4. In step four the selectivity bias adjusted equations 1 and 2 are estimated using 2SLS (Hui, 1991; Haurin and Sridhar, 2003). Per quanto concerne le variabili considerate, the crucial covariates for the purposes of this study are the economic conditions and cultural level of the household in which the individual lives. For the children of more affluent and better educated parents, a greater investment in education may affect both labour supply and demand. If the concept of reservation wage is used in the job search approach, a higher level of education results on the supply side in a higher reservation wage: that is, a higher threshold at which the individual is willing to accept a job. According to this approach, a higher family income means lower search costs for the adult children, and as a consequence their reservation wages increase. However, if there is a ‘threshold effect’ (which the original model does not envisage), a lower family income may induce the individual to decide on a higher reservation wage in order to reach a minimum standard of living. Overall, therefore, on the supply side, a priori we would expect a high 8
reservation wage or first accepted wage to be associated with a higher family income and then the expected result is a negative association between better economic conditions in the family and the probability that the children will find a job in the short term.4 On the demand side, a higher education level favorably signals the abilities of the young person, thereby increasing the probability that he or she will find a job.5 One aspect less considered in the literature on job search is the influence of the family’s economic and cultural circumstances on the information asymmetries that characterise labor supply and demand. As they search for work, the adult children of affluent families probably have access to privileged information channels from which others are excluded, and which signal the abilities of the former to employers. It is not easy to formulate hypotheses a priori on the effects of economic and cultural circumstances defined as such, but it is likely that they favor information about matches between the children of poor or lower-educated families with less well-paid or less skill-demanding jobs: vice versa for the children of rich families. If this is the case, we may find a reduction in unemployment among young people from poor and lower-educated families without this improving intergenerational mobility. Vector X other then the families’ backgrounds, includes the individual characteristics such as ability in a foreign language, regularity in the completion of schooling6, sex, age, and zone of residence. These are indicators of individual productivity, conditions in the local labour market, and the intensity of the job search, and all may affect the rate of job arrivals. Previous experience and job offers received proxy the signal sent by job seekers to potential employers and consequently influence job offers received. Infine, si ricorda che per l’identificazione dell’equazione della durata completa, I use the number of dependent (aged less than 15 year old) and the private and social monetary transfers. Assumendo che queste variabili influence the costs of search and hence the reservation wage, but not the job arrival rate or the wage offer distribution. 4 However, a threshold effect would invert this relationship. 5 . The signal may differ according the family background. For instance, a degree held by the child of a poor and/or lower- educated family would indicate greater ability than a degree held by the son of a more affluent and better-educated family. 6 See the previous note. 9
4. Data and measurement issues The data are drawn from the European Community Household Panel, waves 1-8 (survey years 1994 - 2001) [Details of the survey are given in the Appendix]. The sample consists of unemployed persons cohabiting and not cohabiting with their original families, aged under 36 years (born after 1958 and before 1985), and participating in all the waves. Those who did not report a reservation wage once during the eight years of the survey and consequently did not experience even one episode of active job search are considered ‘employed7’. ‘Unemployed’ refers to those who were jobless and searching for a job at least once during the seven years. ‘Cohabitants’ are those who live with their parent during the unemployment duration (1994), all other subjects (heads of household, spouses, etc.) are treated as non-cohabitants with the original family. The final sample consist of those unemployment who find a job and report e completed duration of unemployment. Resuming, the observations for the regression equations are unemployment young children aged under 36 cohabiting with the family during unemployment who complete a duration of unemployment during the 7 wave (from 1995 to 2001) finding a work during the period. The remaining observations – unemployed people aged under 36 not cohabiting with the original household (not adult children in 1994), and all children (cohabiting) constantly unemployed, – are used in the selection equations. Young people not in the labour force (students, non–active persons, etc.) or constantly in work and those aged over 36 are omitted altogether from estimation. Tab. 1 Table 1 lists all the covariates while average values for these variables are reported in the appendix. Note that for time varying variables influencing unemployment duration, the values chosen are those registered when employment begun. The accepted wage is the net income form the work 8 In the present analysis the monthly accepted wage is estimated conditional on the hours worked The duration of unemployment is measured by the response to the question ''For how long have you been seeking such work'' (number of months). Some missing data were recovered using the following procedure. Information was obtained on the duration of unemployment by calculating the difference between the year and month in which the current job began and the year in which the previous job terminated or full-time education was completed. This procedure is obviously susceptible to imprecision, but it served to fill up some missing data. Solo la durata completa è disponibile dai dati, non c’è informazione sulle durate di ricerca non complete. Tuttavia, quest’ultima potrebbe essere ricostruita, ma a costo di una notevole 7 Of course, all observations included reported non missing values for the covariates 8 Riscalando I dati considerando che nella ECHP i redditi rilevati in una survey si riferiscono ai redditi guadagnati nell’anno precedente e tenendo conto della variazione del potere di acquisto negli anni (base 1995). 10
riduzione delle unità di osservazione dovuta alla difficoltà a ricostruite la data di inizio della ricerca. Table 2 The household poverty is calculated by considering all household incomes net of the children’s income from work, from transfers, and from financial capital. Considered to be poor is a household whose disposable income net of the adult child’s income is equal to or below the standard poverty line. Incomes are scaled using the modified OECD equivalence scale, which yields an equivalent number of components by calculating the adult head of household as 1, members aged 14 or over as 0.5, and members aged under 14 as 0.3. In merito al momento temporale in cui valutare la condizione di povertà della famiglia si è deciso di creare una variabile che consiste del numero di anni in cui la famiglia cade povertà nel periodo precedente l’occupazione del figlio,in altri termini, durante il periodo di ricerca del lavoro del giovane figlio. La linea di povertà è standard9 Table 3 9 Il 50% della valore mediano calcolato sul reddito totale disponibile equivalente. 11
5. Results For reasons that will be clear from the commentary below, three set of estimates are presented, in order of successive refinement. In the first one it is considered the monthly reservation wage in Italy distinguendo per titolo di studio. whereas in the second and third set of estimates the sample is broken down by education level and geographical region and is proposed as the best set. One first result from the first set of estimates on unemployment duration is that duration not to depend significantly on the accepted wage for any educational level. Then we cannot say that people who go back to work at a high wage must have had a high asking wage and therefore have taken a long time to get an acceptable offer. Graduates from deprived social backgrounds find it more difficult to find jobs than do graduates from affluent families, since the estimates suggest that unemployment duration is around 52% longer for the former. This differential in the length of unemployment decreases but remains high at 19% among job seekers with upper secondary-school education. For the latter, however, age matters more than family background, in that as age increases so does the difficulty of finding a job. A turning point in the unemployment duration function occurs at about 36 -37 years. INvece, la provenienza da famiglie con genitori poco istruiti favorisce l’entrata nella occupazione per i diplomati. Le altre variabili che significativamente influiscono sulla durata completa della disoccupazione, sono la regolarità nel completare gli studi (ability) e la conoscenza di almeno una lingua straniera e le esperienze di lavoro che per i graduates riducono la durata della disoccupazione Per i bassi livelli di istruzione per ridurre la durata della disoccupazione ciò che conto è l’esperienza lavorativo che rappresenta un segnale di abilità. One might think that, besides the level, also the quality of education is inferior for poor children, or that they have less ability. Although it was not possible to directly control for quality in the estimation described here, ‘abiling’ and ‘regular’, which respectively stand for an ability to speak English fluently, and conclusion of studies within the statutory time limit proxy ability. However, only the first of them is found to significantly influence unemployment duration among graduates, while for high-school diploma holders the ‘abiling’ coefficient is negative and significant –as expected - but that for ‘regular’ is positive. This latter finding is puzzling and invites speculation that indecision about whether or not to continue in full-time education reduces the intensity of the job search. Previous studies (Mazzotta, 2007) have shown that the interaction between family background, occupational status (unemployment rate) and economic condition (individual poverty) is not the same in the three macro areas of Italy. In the South, where labour market conditions are less favourable independently of children’s and parent’s education and/or household economic condition, the adult offspring of poorly-educated parents faces higher disadvantage with respect to residents in the North coming from equally poor families. 12
In view of the well established importance of regional factors in the process of job search the third and final set of estimates is broken down by education and broad region (tab. ?).10 The results add fresh details to the salience of regional differences, but modify the preceding results on whether and for whom family conditions matter. With regard to unemployment duration, the disadvantage of living in the South is of 78% longer for graduates and 20% for compulsory school holders if the parents are poor. In the south and for graduates is the only variables which matter. Then w can say that graduates of poor family non riescono a superare le rigidità dei canali informativi nel mercato del lavoro in cui si offrono, come accade anche per chi ha solo la scuola dell’obbligo, anche se con minore svantaggio. Al sud, solo per i diplomati non sussiste una maggiore difficoltà per chi proviene da famiglie mediamente povere. Quindi la probabilità di trovare una lavoro ha un andamento a U rovesciata rispetto al livello di istruzione al Sud. Al nord invece, i laureati maschi, abili con esperienze di lavoro sono favoriti, rispetto alle donne ed i meno abili. Invece, esperienza e giovane età sono fattori di successo per livelli di istruzione medio bassi al Centro-Nord. Tab 4 Tab 5 Tab 6 6. Summary and conclusions Da completare 10 The difference between the Centre-North and the South was tested for graduates and individuals with below upper-secondary educations. In the case of upper-secondary diploma holders (more numerous), the difference was tested for all three areas. 13
Appendix A Survey Selection of the sample The data used are those on Italian households gathered by the European Community Household Panel survey. Coordinated by Eurostat and carried out by national units, this survey annually interviews around 6000 (7115 in 1994 and 5606 in 2001) households and 16000 individuals (17729 in 1994 and 13392 in 2001). The first survey was conducted in 1994 and the last in 2001. This study uses information collected in all waves and consequently only individuals who experise an unemployment condition during the period. The sample consisted of unemployed young children cohabiting with their original families in the 1994, aged under 36 years that start a new job during the period 1994 - 2001, (n. 650 individual with 1495 observations). People not in the labour force (students, non-active persons, housewives, etc.) or constantly at work were dropped. As ‘cohabitants’ I considered those declared children during the unemployment duration all other subjects (heads of household, spouses, etc.) are non-cohabitants with the original family. All the others – unemployed people aged under 36 not cohabiting with the original household (not children in 1994), and all children (cohabiting) who are constantly in unemployed – were used to correct the model for sample selection. Tab B 14
Bibliography Addabbo, T., (2000), "Poverty Dynamics: Analysis of Household Income in Italy", Labour, 14(1), pp. 119 - 144. Atkinson, A. B. & Gomulka, J. & Micklewright, J. & Rau, N., 1984. "Unemployment benefit, duration and incentives in Britain : How robust is the evidence?," Journal of Public Economics, Elsevier, vol. 23(1-2), pages 3-26. Becker, G., (1993), Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with social Reference to Education, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, Ill. Bettio F., Mazzotta F., (2002), “Il salario di riserva è davvero più alto al Sud? Nuovi riscontri sul Panel Europeo”, Quaderni dell’Università di Siena Dipartimento di Economia Politica, n. 356. Blau, D.M., (1991), “Search for nonwage job characteristics: a test of the reservation wage hypothesis”, Journal of labor Economics, 91, pp. 182-205. Boeri, T., Pagani, L., (1998) “Caratteristiche e Aspirazioni Salariali di Chi Cerca Lavoro nel Pubblico Impiego”, in Dell’Aringa, C. (ed. by), Rapporto Aran sulle Retribuzioni, 1997, Franco Angeli, Milano. Boemen stancanelli Boffoe - Bonnie, J., (2004), Black-White wage differentials in a multiple sample selection bias model, Manuscript. Brunello, G., Checchi, D., Comi S., (2003), "Qualità della formazione scolastica, scelte formative ed esiti sul mercato del lavoro", in Banca d'Italia (2003), L'efficienza dei servizi pubblici, Roma Checchi, D., (1998), "Povertà e istruzione", Politica Economica, v. 14, f. 2, pp. 245 -- 282. Checchi, D., (1997), "Education and intergenerational mobility in education", American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 4, pp. 331 -- 352. Checchi, D., Bertola G., (2001), "Sorting and Private Education in Italy", Lavoro e Relazioni Industriali, 2, pp. 87-124 Checchi, D., Ichino, A., Rustichini, A., (1999), "More equal but less mobile? Education financing and intergenerational mobility in Italt and in the US", Journal of Public Economics, 74, pp. 351 -- 393. Checchi, D., Zollino, F., (2001) "Struttura del sistema scolastico e selezione sociale", Rivista di Politica Economica 7-8/2001: 43-84, [also in L.Barca-M.Franzini (ed. by), La cittadinanza difficile, Editoriale il Ponte 2001] Comi, S., (2004), “Intergenerational mobility in Europe: evidence from ECHP”, Working Papers CHILD, n. 18. D'Alessio, G., Signorini, L.F., (2000), “Disuguaglianza dei redditi individuali e ruolo della famiglia in Italia”, Temi di discussione della Banca d'Italia, n. 390. Favro - Paris, M.M., Gennari, P., Oneto, G.P., (1996), "La Durata della Disoccupazione in Italia: un'Applicazione dell'Indagine sulle Forze di Lavoro", Ricerche Economiche, Istat, Roma. Gronau , R., (1974), "Wage Comparison -- a Selectivity Bias", Journal of Political Economy, vol. 82, no. 6, pp. 1119 - 1143. Haurin, D. R., Sridhar, K.S., (2003), "The impact of local unemployment rates on reservation wages and the duration of search for a job", Applied economics, 35, pp 1469 - 1476. Hui, W.T., (1991), "Reservation wage analysis of unemployed youths in Australia", Applied Economics, 23, pp. 1341 - 1350. 15
Kiefer, N.M., Neumann, G. R., (1979), “An Empirical job search model with a test of constant reservation wage hypothesis”, Journal of Political Economy, 87, pp 89 – 107. Lancaster, T., (1985), “Simultaneous equation models in applied search theory”, Journal of Econometrics, 28, pp. 113-126. Lancaster, T., Chescher, A.D., (1983), “An econometric analysis of reservation wage”, Econometrica, 51, 1661-1676. Lancaster, T., Chescher, A.D., (1983), Simultaneous equation with endogenous hazards, in Studies in Labor Market Dynamics, Neumann, G. R. and Westergaard-Nielsen, N.C. (eds), Spring –Verlag, Heidelberg. Lancaster, T., Nickell, S., (1980), “The analysis of reemployment probabilities for the unemployment”, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, A, 143, pp. 141-165. Mazzotta, F., (1998), “Salario di riserva e probabilità di successo della ricerca di lavoro in Italia: una stima sul nuovo panel ISTAT”, Lavoro e Relazioni Industriali, n. 2, pp. 115 - 173. Mazzotta, F., (2007), “Disoccupazione e povertà giovanile: il ruolo del background familiare”, Economia & Lavoro, Maggio Agosto 2007, n. 2, pp. 35 – 59. Meng, Chun-Lo, Schmidt, P., (1985), “On the Cost of Partial Observability in the Bivariate Model,” International Economic Review, 26:1, pp. 71-85. Narendranathan, W., Nickell, S., Stern, J., (1985), “Unemployment benefits revisited”, Ecomomic Journal, 95, pp. 307 – 329. Neumann, G.R., (1999), “Search Model and Duration Data” in Handbook of applied economics, Pesaran, M.H., Schmidt, P., (ed. By), Blackwell Publishing. Nickell, S.J., (1979), “Estimating the probability of leaving unemployment”, Econometrica, 47, pp. 1249-1266. 16
TABLE Tab 1 List of Covariates RESERVATION WAGE UNEMPLOYMENT EQUATION DURATION Lnmonthly wage Lndur (months) Ability Fluent English in Abiling 1/0 Abiling 1/0 social contexts Completion of studies Regular 1/0 Regular 1/0 on schedule Family Poverty condition of Number of time in poverty Number of time in poverty Background the household Average years of Highscparen1/0§ Highscparen1/0§ education for father and mother Lowscparen 1/0 Lowscparen 1/0 Medscparen 1/0 Medscparen 1/0 Local Labor Area of residence North1/0§ North1/0§ market South&I1/0 South&I 1/0 Centre 1/0 Centre 1/0§ Local GDP growth rate Gender Female1/0 Female1/0 Female 1/0 Age Children Age Etafig Etafig Sample selection term Lambda1 Lambda1 (employed) Sample selection term Lambda2 Lambda2 (cohabitants) Job arrival rate Number of job offers Joboffer and Wage offer (start 1994) distribution Job arrival rate Work experience Esper 1/0 and Wage offer (previous last job) distribution Number of members Child013 of household aged under 14 (Log) hours of work Lnor offered (Log) per month Social benefits Lnsocialben 17
Tab 2 Reservation wage, hours of work offered and unemployment duration by gender, education level and geographical area (sample averages) Upper University secondary Less than Men Female degree school upper North South Reservation wage (euros per 806,12 741,89 966,20 727,83 781,19 785,72 778,42 month) New Wage (euros per month) 585,81 508,26 620,37 551,50 529,94 620,44 520,94 Completed unemployment duration 22,49 19,29 12,99 21,62 24,23 12,51 24,46 (months) Elapsed Duration of unemployment 15,72 13,69 8,91 15,72 16,04 19 8,94 (months) 37,40 35,91 33,11 36,90 38,30 35,35 37,87 Hours of work offered (per week) Hours of work (per week) 39,85 36,01 36,09 38,06 40,26 37,29 39,15 Tab 3 Poverty Lines YEAR OF COMPETENCE 1994,00 1995,00 1996,00 1997,00 1998,00 1999,00 2000,00 Poverty Line (50% of median) (Euro) Yearly Net equivalent total income 3822,74 4083,02 4152,31 4510,73 4738,49 5035,46 5267,86 18
Table 4 Accepted wages and completed unemployment durations, Italy Log duration Log duration Log duration Laureati Diplomati Obbligo Coefficient (S.E.) Coefficient (S.E.) Coefficient (S.E.) Log monthly accepted wage -0,030 (0.455) +0.230 (0.298) -2.306 (2.985) Age +0,074 (0.086) +0.266*** (0.048) +0.004 (0.344) Age^2 -0,001 (0.002) -0.003*** (0.001) -0.0006 (0.004) Gender Female +0,265 (0.341) +0.267 (0.175) -0.411 (0.494) Abilità Regolar -0,125 (0.313) +0.359*** (0.148) +0.357 (0.506) English -0,674*** (0.272) -0.195 (0.191) +0.196 (1.064) Family background Povertà della famiglia prima di trovare +0,519*** (0.219) +0.190*** (0.059) -0.025 (0.321) lavoro Livello basso Istruzione media del/I -0,491 (0.492) -0.951*** (0.327) +1.406 (2.766) genitore/i Livello medio Istruzione media del/I -0,324 (0.474) -0.676* (0.361) genitore/i Region South & Island -0,937* (0.482) +0.796*** (0.185) +0.789 (1.063) Tasso di crescita nell’area -0,061 (0.069) -0.0005 (0.041) -0.130 (0.146) Media delle offerte nell’area +0,038 (0.091) +0.007 (0.037) +0.235 (0.461) Esperienze di lavoro -1,315*** (0.285) -1.178*** (0.164) -1.679*** (0.471) Sample selection correction Lambda1 (employed) 0,157 (0.202) -0.147* (0.069) -0.462 (0.474) Lambda2 (convivente) 0,484 (0.870) -0.445 (0.297) +1.135 (2.054) Constant 1,028 (2.469) -2.000 (0.346) +15.147 (18.915) N 191 824 480 R2 0,73 0.69 0.22 The equation estimated is the second of the number [2],with three zero restriction on θ, the omission of number of youngest children con età inferiore ai 15 anni, reddito da benefici sociali e le ore lavorate. 19
Table 5 Accepted wages and completed unemployment durations, Sud Log duration Log duration Log duration Laureati Diplomati Obbligo Coefficient (S.E.) Coefficient (S.E.) Coefficient (S.E.) Log monthly accepted wage +0.635 (0.645) +1.738 (1.364) -0.830 (0.664) Age -0.096 (0.145) +0.246*** (0.086) +0.179* (0.098) Age^2 +0.0006 (0.003) -0.003 (0.002) -0.003 (0.001) Gender Female 0.224 (0.753) 0.538 (0.548) -0.387 (0.342) Abilità Regolar -0.049 (0.510) 0.454 (0.355) -0.071 (0.228) English -0.691 (0.610) -0.141 (0.488) +0.878 (0.629) Family background Povertà della famiglia prima di trovare lavoro 0.784* (0.448) 0.144 (0.131) 0.199** (0.097) Livello basso Istruzione media del/I -1.024 (0.677) -0.989 (0.849) 0.096 (0.542) genitore/i Livello medio Istruzione media del/I -0.572 (0.815) -0.932 (0.873) genitore/i Region Tasso di crescita nell’area -0.010 (0.120) -0.004 (0.082) -0.059 (0.071) Media delle offerte nell’area +0.186 (0.218) +0.042 (0.072) -0.149 (0.138) Esperienze di lavoro -0.991 (0.632) -2.199*** (0.562) -1.577*** (0.271) Sample selection correction Lambda1 (employed) +0.445* (0.268) +0.086 (0.298) -0.290 (0.183) Lambda2 (convivente) +1.035 (1.420) -1.195 (1.451) 0.174 (0.613) Constant 0.233 (4.747) -10.300 (9.671) 7.024 (4.897) N 87 446 297 R2 0.76 0.29 0.7532 The equation estimated is the second of the number [2],with three zero restriction on θ, the omission of number of youngest children con età inferiore ai 15 anni, reddito da benefici sociali e le ore lavorate. 20
Table 6 Accepted wages and completed unemployment durations, Nord Centro Log duration Log duration Log duration Laureati Diplomati Obbligo Coefficient (S.E.) Coefficient (S.E.) Coefficient (S.E.) Log monthly accepted wage -0.013 (0.654) +0.023 0.187 1.983 (1.551) Age +0.229* (0.123) +0.239*** 0.076 0.459 (0.324) Age^2 -0.003 (0.002) -0.003* 0.001 -0.004 (0.005) Gender Female 0.704** (0.303) 0.428* 0.244 -0.575 (0.788) Abilità Regolar -0.629** (0.284) 0.560*** 0.217 -0.182 (0.672) English -0.653* (0.330) -0.257 0.217 0.059 (1.327) Family background Povertà della famiglia prima di trovare lavoro +0.533 (0.382) 0.099 0.139 0.083 (0.236) Livello basso Istruzione media del/I -0.657 (0.418) -0.489 0.422 -3.087 (2.618) genitore/i Livello medio Istruzione media del/I -0.450 (0.471) -0.237 0.458 genitore/i Region Tasso di crescita nell’area -0.138 (0.106) -0.002 0.059 +0.408 (0.322) Media delle offerte nell’area -0.079 (0.122) 0.085 0.074 -0.275 (0.298) Esperienze di lavoro -0.172*** (0.305) -0.748*** 0.240 -1.461*** (0.566) Sample selection correction Lambda1 (employed) +0.131 (0.241) -0.171 0.097 -0.153 (0.323) Lambda2 (convivente) -0.448 (1.044) -0.623 0.484 -1.522 (1.546) Constant -0.221 (3.512) -1.799 1.667 -12.347 (10.962) N 104 378 183 R2 0.68 0.55 -0.60 The equation estimated is the second of the number [2],with three zero restriction on θ, the omission of number of youngest children con età inferiore ai 15 anni, reddito da benefici sociali e le ore lavorate. 21
Appendix Tab A Average Values of the variables Da completare 22
You can also read