The decline of the working-class vote, the reconfiguration of the welfare support coalition and consequences for the welfare state

Page created by Anna Aguilar
 
CONTINUE READING
556970
research-article2015
                       ESP0010.1177/0958928714556970Journal of European Social PolicyGingrich and Häusermann

                                                                                                                                                               Journal Of
                                                                                                                                                                 European
                                                 Article                                                                                                     Social Policy

                                                                                                                                             Journal of European Social Policy

                                                 The decline of the working-class                                                            2015, Vol. 25(1) 50­–75
                                                                                                                                             © The Author(s) 2015
                                                                                                                                             Reprints and permissions:
                                                 vote, the reconfiguration of the                                                            sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav
                                                                                                                                             DOI: 10.1177/0958928714556970

                                                 welfare support coalition and                                                               esp.sagepub.com

                                                 consequences for the welfare state

                                                 Jane Gingrich
                                                 University of Oxford, UK

                                                 Silja Häusermann
                                                 University of Zurich, Switzerland

                                                 Abstract
                                                 The central political claim of Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism is that class actors, through the instruments
                                                 of the democratic process, can modify capitalism. Where working-class mobilization is strong, left parties
                                                 have sufficient electoral support in the political arena to alter markets politically in ways that decommodify
                                                 and thereby empower workers. The decline of traditional class voting, however, has profoundly changed
                                                 this dynamic of welfare politics. We show that the political support coalition for welfare states has been
                                                 reconfigured through two processes. On the one hand, the Left may have lost support among the traditional
                                                 working class, but it has substituted this decline by attracting substantial electoral support among specific
                                                 parts of the expanding middle class. On the other hand, the welfare support coalition has been stabilized
                                                 through increasing support for the welfare state among right-wing political parties. We discuss the possible
                                                 consequences of this ‘middle-class shift’ in the welfare support coalition in terms of policy consequences.

                                                 Keywords
                                                 Class voting, electoral realignment, partisan politics, social investment, welfare state

                                                 Introduction
                                                 The central political claim of Three Worlds of                in the political arena grows, left political parties
                                                 Welfare Capitalism is that class actors, through the          look to ‘decommodify’ labour, transforming labour
                                                 instruments of the democratic process, can modify
                                                 capitalism. For Esping-Andersen, where unions
                                                                                                               Corresponding author:
                                                 and other actors organizing the labour market are
                                                                                                               Jane Gingrich, University of Oxford, Magdalen College, High
                                                 powerful, they provide crucial electoral support to           Street, Oxford OX1 4AU, UK.
                                                 their representatives in the political arena. As power        Email: jane.gingrich@politics.ox.ac.uk
Gingrich and Häusermann                                                                                          51

markets to serve workers’ aims. In this framework,          the welfare state have simultaneously stabilized the
working-class power begets working-class power,             welfare state in the face of declining working-class
as left parties both draw on the support of workers         support for the Left, but also changed it. The post-
and, by means of policies, sustain and enlarge it.          industrial welfare support coalition is predominantly
   Class, however, as the basis for both political          anchored in the middle class, which tends to prefer
mobilization and ensuing coalitions, has changed            social investment and activation policies over tradi-
profoundly. When Esping-Andersen published Three            tional redistributive policies.
Worlds in 1990, the industrial class structure had              These claims contribute to the literature in two
already entered its economic twilight. Today, the           key ways. First, despite widespread acceptance in the
size of the manual working class is dramatically            literature on political parties and party systems that
smaller than in the post-war period, with service sec-      traditional class voting is in decline, much of the wel-
tor employment outnumbering manufacturing in all            fare state and comparative political economy research
European countries (Oesch, 2006: 31). At the same           has largely neglected these dynamics and their conse-
time, social groups that cut across traditional class       quences. Most work on the partisan politics of the
boundaries have emerged (Oesch, 2013). In short,            welfare state continues to conceptualize the prefer-
the socio-economic structure that defined the growth        ences and behaviour of left parties through the lens of
of the welfare state has dramatically changed.              a traditional working-class constituency (for a critical
   What are the implications of these trends for the        assessment of this literature, see Häusermann et al.,
political coalitions around the welfare state in a post-    2013). Even work explicitly examining changes in
industrial setting and – consequently – for the wel-        the electoral base of the Left, such as David Rueda’s
fare state itself? Can advanced welfare states survive      (2007) analysis of insider–outsider divides within the
without a clear electoral foundation in the working         Social Democratic electorate, theorizes changes
class? In Three Worlds, Esping-Andersen himself             within the working class rather than the consequences
suggests an affirmative answer, arguing that the            of its broader decline. Second, we argue that the Left
institutions of the welfare state would supplant, in        has found a new electoral constituency in parts of the
some ways, their political origins. For Esping-             middle class that substitutes for declining working-
Andersen (1985), more universal social programmes,          class support. While much work has analysed the
such as those in the Scandinavian countries, would          changed electoral behaviour of the (new) middle
sustain a coalition of blue- and white-collar workers       classes (e.g. Kitschelt, 1994; Kriesi, 1998; Oesch,
around social programmes, thereby ‘endogenously’            2008), the consequences of these shifts for welfare
stabilizing welfare support.                                politics remain clearly under-analysed. We show
   In this article, we build on these arguments, argu-      that while the ‘middle-class shift’ in the welfare
ing that there has been a substantial reconfiguration in    support coalition has cemented new electoral foun-
the underpinning support coalition for the welfare          dations for the welfare state, it has also led to a
state; however, these changes are more general and          change in policy prioritization, away from tradi-
less regime-based than Esping-Andersen suggested.           tional ‘pro-worker’ policies. In short, understanding
We build on a large body of research showing that           the contemporary politics of the welfare state still
pro-welfare left parties have lost support among the        requires attention to class, but it equally requires
working class. However, far from spelling an overall        explicit attention to the changed class character both
decline of the pro-welfare coalition, we make two           within the Left and the Right.
arguments. First, left parties have attracted substantial
electoral support among specific parts of the expand-       Changing coalitions, changing
ing middle class, substituting for a shrinking working-
                                                            welfare states?
class base. Second, right-wing political parties have
moved towards more political support for the welfare        In the late 1980s, when Esping-Andersen was writ-
state. This reconfiguration of support within the Left      ing Three Worlds, the question of how de-industrial-
and the reconfiguration of the cross-party support for      ization and the concomitant rise of new post-industrial
52                                                                           Journal of European Social Policy 25(1)

social groups might reshape welfare support coali-         however, he argues that the existing social structure
tions was far from clear. The literature on electoral      does not fully determine either the interests or the
dealignment argued that class was becoming increas-        strength of class actors. In Three Worlds, Esping-
ingly irrelevant for electoral choice; not only had        Andersen (1990) argues that ‘we cannot assume
traditional class groups shrunk but also electoral         that a numerical increase in voters, unionization, or
volatility had been increasing since the 1970s             seats will translate into more welfare-statism’ (p.
(Dalton et al., 1984; Franklin et al., 1992). Indeed,      17). Instead, the electoral coalitions at the basis of
some analysts even predicted an eclipse of tradi-          left power – and thus of comprehensive welfare
tional class voting in favour of more issue-oriented       states – are political products, constructed by par-
voting (Dalton, 2008; Katz and Mair, 1995, 2009).          ties and the coalitions they strike. In building sup-
While this work did not elaborate what such radical        port for the welfare state, unions and Social
partisan dealignment would imply for welfare state         Democratic parties needed to both mobilize inter-
politics, a clear implication was that as the working-     nally and create coalitions with other groups. We
class vote would no longer serve as a reliable politi-     contend that these assertions still hold: a reconfigu-
cal foundation for pro-welfare parties, dealignment        ration of the pro-welfare support coalition implies a
could undermine support for the welfare state itself.      reconfiguration of the welfare state itself.
    However, more recent electoral research has con-           Building on these insights inspired by both
tested this early characterization of an entirely vola-    Esping-Andersen and the realignment literature, we
tile electorate. A newer body of work argues that          contend that it remains fruitful to conceptualize the
class, conceived in terms of individuals’ occupation,      politics of the welfare state in terms of societal class
continues to matter. This work, drawing on either          coalitions or – more generally – class groups;3 in
better sources of longitudinal data (Knutsen, 2006)        doing so, we develop our argument in three steps:
or – crucially – new conceptualizations of class and       first, structural change has led to the expansion of a
class voting (Elff, 2007; Evans, 1999), shows that         specific segment of the middle class with pro-wel-
class continues to predict political preferences and       fare attitudes, as well as a rightward shift of the
vote choices (even if these preferences and the            working-class vote. Both left- and right-wing parties
choices may have become different ones). Put differ-       have mobilized these changing electoral potentials.
ently, there has been electoral class realignment, not     Hence, these shifts have neither doomed the welfare
dealignment (Kitschelt and Rehm, in press). Hout           state nor left it with a ‘classless’ base; rather, left par-
et al. (1995) argue, for instance, even where ‘tradi-      ties have gained a new class support base, and right-
tional class-voting’ (i.e. the blue-collar vote for the    wing parties have moved towards more pro-welfare
Left) has declined, ‘total class voting’ (i.e. the pre-    positions. Second, the extent of this electoral recon-
dictive power of occupational class on vote choice)        figuration of the welfare state support coalition var-
remains strong.1 This shift in the literature from a       ies between different institutional regimes. And
focus on traditional to total class voting coincides       third, it is likely to have considerable consequences
with a definitional shift in the understanding of class,   for the welfare state, because the pro-welfare middle
one which we adopt. Contrary to earlier works on           classes show particularly strong support for policies
class formation and mobilization, this work under-         of activation and social investment, rather than tradi-
stands ‘class’ in terms of socio-structural groups         tional income protection and decommodification
defined by a particular occupational task structure,       policies. In the following, we discuss these three
which contributes to shape their resources, latent         claims in turn.
interests and preferences (Oesch, 2006).2                      First, structural change has driven the transforma-
    What are the implications of these socio-struc-        tion of European electorates. Deindustrialization,
tural shifts for the welfare state? Esping-Andersen’s      tertiarization of the workforce and especially the
work suggests that the answer is political. For            educational expansion have all led to a decline of
Esping-Andersen, the preferences of class actors           employment in the skilled and low-skilled industries
are partly derived from their economic position;           and massive ‘occupational upgrading’, that is, the
Gingrich and Häusermann                                                                                       53

expansion of occupational performance in the high-        the occupations of the members of the ‘new’ middle
skilled service sector (Oesch, 2013, in press). While     classes are often closely related to the welfare state
early scholarship on the expansion of an educated         itself. Thereby, welfare states have to some extent
(service sector) middle class, namely, by Goldthorpe      created their own support coalition among the
(1982), speculated that it would be a conservative        growing share of people whose employment is
social force, he was soon proven at least partly          directly linked to the state, that is, both public sec-
wrong. Rather, the educated middle classes, particu-      tor workers and those employed in the welfare ser-
larly in interpersonal service sector occupations         vices such as health and education more generally
(Kitschelt, 1994), have become the main progressive       (Heath et al., 1991).
force in European politics. Much work traces the              Political parties have played a role in both driv-
way these shifts in the post-industrial economic          ing and mobilizing these electoral shifts and trans-
structure have affected voter preferences. A promi-       formations. As Esping-Andersen (1985) reminds us,
nent line of work investigating these changes empha-      individuals with shared attitudes towards the state
sizes the rise of non-economic issues that rival for      do not automatically form into organized political
voters’ attention. Attention to non-economic issues       actors. While changes in the economic structure
is not new: scholars of electoral behaviour have long     have both put a variety of non-economic issues on
noted the crucial role of religiously motivated con-      the agenda and created a new cadre of middle-class
servative voting within parts of the working class        voters employed in services with more economi-
(Bartolini, 2000; Lipset and Rokkan, 1967). What          cally left-wing preferences, in order for these to
the ‘new politics’ literature identifies, however, is a   manifest politically, parties needed to act on them.
transformed cultural conflict between post-material-      We argue that parties of the Right and the Left have
ist and materialist values (Inglehart, 1984), libertar-   shaped the way these economic changes have
ian–authoritarian values (Kitschelt, 1994) or             emerged politically in crucial ways, simultaneously
universalism–particularism (Bornschier, 2010;             stabilizing support for the welfare state and modify-
Häusermann and Kriesi, in press). Although these          ing its underpinning support coalition.
differing terminologies reflect varying temporal and          Parties of the Left first responded to these shifts
substantial conceptualizations of a ‘second’ ideolog-     by targeting middle-class voters. Kitschelt (1994),
ical dimension, they all point to a new line of con-      Müller (1999) and Kriesi (1998) were the first to
flict that cuts across the traditional class cleavage.    systematically examine realignment in Western
They share the argument that the new middle classes       European party systems. Collectively, they argue
have become the main electoral potential of the Left      that voters in interpersonal service occupations have
for reasons of cultural, rather than economic-distrib-    become the core electorate of the New Left, some-
utive attitudes. However, it is important to note that    thing we investigate further below. While this con-
although these social groups prioritize issues of cul-    stituency fostered in particular the rise of green
tural liberalism, they also hold clearly pro-welfare      parties, it has also increasingly transformed the elec-
preferences (Häusermann and Kriesi, in press;             toral profile of the traditional left parties.
Kitschelt and Rehm, 2014).                                    On the right, Pierson (1996, 2001) influentially
    Scholars debate the reasons for these pro-welfare     theorized that the sheer electoral importance of the
attitudes of the new middle class. Some work empha-       welfare state implied that mainstream parties would
sizes the interpersonal profile of new middle-class       converge on a welfare state stabilizing position.
occupations as fostering egalitarian and solidaristic     Moreover, culturally conservative parties have been
values (Kitschelt and Rehm, 2014); others stress that     attracting a substantial number of working-class
the oftentimes atypical and more vulnerable occupa-       votes over the past decades. These groups have
tional situation of these workers, many of whom are       explicitly mobilized working-class voters with
women, may explain their interest in state interven-      regard to conservative and authoritarian attitudes,
tion (Häusermann, 2010; Häusermann et al., 2014;          arguably as a counter-reaction to the aforementioned
Marx and Picot, 2013), and yet others point out that      moves by progressive movements of the 1980s
54                                                                         Journal of European Social Policy 25(1)

(Bornschier, 2010). As more working-class voters           middle-class for working-class support has not been
have moved to non-left parties for predominantly           neutral. As argued above, new middle-class voters
cultural reasons, however, they potentially alter the      support state intervention generally and redistribu-
economic preference profiles of these parties, too,        tive policies specifically. In this sense, they do sup-
creating welfare state support among even the far-         port income protection policies that aim at what
right (see Betz and Meret, 2012, or Mudde, 2007, on        Esping-Andersen has famously called decommodifi-
welfare chauvinism).                                       cation. However, there is a shift in emphasis on other
    The political coalition underpinning the welfare       policies. The recent welfare state literature has
state, then, has undergone two changes; the prime          extensively analysed the emergence of ‘new social
defenders of the welfare state, left-wing parties, now     policies’ (Bonoli, 2005), ‘social investment policies’
rely mainly on voters from the educated middle             (Hemerijck, 2013; Morel et al., 2012) and the spread
classes, and at the same time, the rightward move-         of ‘labour market activation’ policies (Bonoli, 2010)
ment of workers has created a more heterogeneous           on the welfare reform agendas of European welfare
set of partisan actors supporting the welfare state.       states, well beyond the Nordic countries. These poli-
    Second, cross-sectional variation is important.        cies deviate from traditional social policy instru-
While the shift towards growing service sector             ments, because they aim at fostering labour market
employment and left-mobilization of the new middle         participation rather than compensating for income
classes is occurring across all advanced welfare           loss (Gingrich and Ansell, in press) and they pro-
states, its translation into a large welfare state sup-    mote social inclusion through work and human capi-
port coalition does not occur in an institutional vac-     tal investment, rather than transfers (Cantillon and
uum. The existing institutional structure of the           Van Lancker, 2013). The main instruments are child-
welfare state itself crucially shapes the options for      care services, education and active labour market
parties. On the one hand, the shift to a post-industrial   policies. In this sense, they have ‘commodifying’,
employment structure is partly a product of existing       rather than decommodifying objectives. Although
regime structures. The tertiarization of employment,       there is not yet a consensus in the literature about the
the extent of public sector jobs and the overall size of   precise profile and delimitation of social investment
the service class vary across welfare regimes. Indeed,     and activation policies, existing evidence suggests
welfare regimes contribute to shifts in the underlying     that the middle class is both the main beneficiary and
group structure. On the other hand, welfare regimes        the main supporter of such a supply-side-oriented
also provide varying resources to left parties. Left       welfare state (e.g. Van Lancker, 2013, on the distrib-
parties who long relied on extensive cross-class coa-      utive effect of childcare policies). Geering and
litions have had more success in attracting the new        Häusermann (2013) have looked at policy support
middle classes, reproducing their existing strength        on the basis of European Social Survey (ESS) 2008
through new social groups. More precisely, we argue        and International Social Survey Programme (ISSP)
that the reconfiguration of the welfare support coali-     2006 data, which provide information on support for
tion is most pronounced in the Social Democratic           different types of social policies. They find that the
regimes – where both partly endogenous shifts to a         ‘new middle class’ (i.e. high-skilled employees in
post-industrial economic structure and the existing        interpersonal service occupations) has the highest
left mobilizing capacity are extensive – followed by       predicted probability of supporting public childcare
the Christian Democratic countries, with less change       and education, considerably higher than the indus-
in the Southern and Liberal regimes, where the             trial working class. Conversely, support for provid-
expansion of the middle class has been less pro-           ing the unemployed with a decent living standard
nounced (in the Southern case) or where the struc-         and support for income redistribution are highest
tural power of the Left to mobilize new actors is          among the industrial working class.
more limited (the Liberal case).                               Taking these preference profiles into account
    Third, what are the implications of these shifts for   implies that when building welfare state support
the welfare state? Within the Left, the substitution of    around a new core of new middle-class voters, left
Gingrich and Häusermann                                                                                         55

parties in post-industrial contexts are under pressure      meaning that Sweden, Finland and Austria are not
to move away from policies supporting traditional           included until 1995 and Switzerland not at all.
income replacement and decommodification and                Norway is included, but only from 1993. Moreover,
towards new middle-class reform priorities. At the          not all countries participated in all six waves of the
same time, welfare politics is coalitional politics.        ESS. We discuss the implications of these data limi-
Thereby, the coalition space around broader welfare         tations where relevant.
reform draws on new combinations of actors, such as             To measure vote choice over time, we combine
middle-class and employer-based coalitions in               two sets of questions. The EB asks respondents both
favour of labour market activation or middle- and           a retrospective vote choice question and a vote inten-
working-class coalitions in favour of encompassing          tion question. The ESS asks respondents a retrospec-
reform strategies that involve both activation and          tive vote choice question. Although the EB
compensation.                                               retrospective vote choice question is more similar to
    In sum, we argue that there is a new class profile at   the ESS vote choice question, it was asked only
the core of left parties and a new space for cross-class    infrequently. In the EB, the correlation between the
alliances around the welfare state, which has real          prospective and retrospective question is quite high
implications for its future politics and distributive       (r = 0.81, p < 0.01), leading us to use the vote inten-
policies. In this article, we show this argument in a       tion item in the EB. This yields a time series of vote
number of steps. In the section ‘The decline of elec-       choice from 1973 to 2012 with limited gaps.
toral support of the working class for the Left’, we            We use the combined vote intention measure to
demonstrate that the working-class vote for the Left        create a dichotomous ‘Left party choice’ variable,
has indeed declined almost uniformly across advanced        limited to social democratic, green, socialist and
European welfare states. The section ‘Sources of wel-       communist parties (“the Left”) as measured by the
fare state support’ turns to the two new stabilizing        original EB ZEUS coding schema. A dichotomous
support bases: the rise of middle-class voting for the      measure of voting for the main social democratic
Left and party system reconfiguration around the wel-       party yields similar patterns when used as an alterna-
fare state. In both sections, we show that while these      tive dependent variable (see Appendix 1 for coding
trends are common across countries, the existing            choices).
regimes shape their implications in varying ways. In            In order to measure class across the different sur-
the section ‘Implications of this reconfiguration of the    veys, we create four dummy variables, based on
electoral support coalition for the welfare state’, we      respondents’ occupation and education levels
argue that this reconfiguration has – albeit not unam-      (Appendix 2 outlines the coding choices and their
biguous – policy implications, namely, leading to a         reliability), dividing respondents into employers
less pro-worker welfare state.                              (small and large), middle classes, manual workers
                                                            and routine workers (low-skilled non-manual). We
The decline of electoral support                            exclude retired voters and the non-employed from
                                                            our analyses. While the ESS data allow for a more
of the working class for the Left                           varied operationalization of the middle classes, the
To investigate the electoral coalitions underpinning        EB data do not contain continuous information
pro-welfare parties over the long term, we turn to          regarding industry, sectors or work logics.
data for 15 countries from the 1970s to present, com-           We first examine the evolution of working-class
bining the 1972–2002 Eurobarometer (EB) survey              voting over time among employed voters. The
trend file with six waves of the European Social            decline of traditional class voting, that is, working-
Survey (2002–2012). Together, these data allow us           class support for the Left, is largely uncontroversial
to examine the evolution of class voting over a long        (Knutsen, 2006), leading us to only briefly demon-
time period for a number of countries.4 The panel,          strate these trends. To assess the class basis of vot-
however, is somewhat unbalanced. The EB was only            ing, we first look at a classic measure of vote choice,
conducted in European Union member states,                  a modified Alford index. This index involves a
56                                                                           Journal of European Social Policy 25(1)

simple difference between the percentage of the             the difference between working-class voters and
workers voting for the Left and all other employed          middle-class voters in their propensity to vote Left.
voters, using the above outlined definition of left-        Except the Southern countries, this outcome is simi-
wing parties.                                               lar in all regimes: there has been a reduction in the
   We examine these results at both the country and         size of the coefficient on working class over time.
regime levels. We follow Esping-Andersen’s regime              At the beginning of the observation period, in the
categorization, adding a fourth Southern Category.          early 1980s, working-class voters were clearly more
The Social Democratic regime includes Denmark,              likely to vote Left than middle-class voters, espe-
Sweden, Norway and Finland; the Christian                   cially in Liberal and Scandinavian countries. While
Democratic regime includes Austria, Belgium,                the working-class vote was always more split in the
France, Germany and the Netherlands; the Liberal            continental regimes and also in Southern Europe
regime includes the United Kingdom and Ireland              (Bartolini, 2000), workers were still clearly more
and finally, the Southern countries include Greece,         likely to vote for the Left than the middle classes.
Spain, Portugal and Italy.                                  However, by the late 2000s, this difference has com-
   Figure 1 shows the results (using a 3-year moving        pletely withered in Scandinavia and even turned neg-
average to compensate for small numbers of respond-         ative (albeit not always significantly so) in liberal and
ents). The clear story that emerges from Figure 1 is        continental welfare regimes, indicating that in some
one of declining class-based differences, with only         cases middle-class voters are now more likely to vote
limited regime-based differences. In all welfare            for the Left than working-class voters. Multivariate
states, even those with a traditionally strong work-        analysis confirms the above results: time has a nega-
ing-class base of the Left, the difference between          tive effect – meaning a reduction in the coefficient on
workers’ and non-workers’ support for the Left has          working class – across the sample. This erosion is not
shrunk.                                                     less extensive in the Social Democratic regimes than
   Because of concerns that descriptive data can be         the Liberal or Christian Democratic, with only the
misleading in assessing class differences (Evans,           Southern regime demonstrating a different, more sta-
1999), we further run a two-stage regression model          ble pattern (Appendix 3).
to evaluate class voting. In the first stage, we run a
series of country-year level logistic regressions (this
                                                            Sources of welfare state support
process yields 407 separate country-year regressions
since 1980). In each regression, we regress the             The previous section showed that the working-class
dichotomous left vote choice variable on a range of         vote for communist, socialist, green and social dem-
variables, including a dummy for being a member of          ocratic parties has clearly declined in both relative
the working class, a dummy for being an employer            and absolute terms, especially in Social Democratic,
and a dummy for being a routine worker (middle-             Christian Democratic and Liberal regimes, with a
class respondents are the reference group), a coun-         somewhat more stable development in the countries
try-year standardized measure of income, age in             of Southern Europe. It is true that the working class
years, gender and education. The first stage model is       and workers’ parties always needed allies to support
kept relatively parsimonious because of missing data        and develop the welfare state – such as the agrarian
on other relevant variables.5                               parties in Scandinavia or the Christian Democrats in
   Comparing the coefficient on working-class sta-          continental Europe. Nevertheless, the political
tus over time (Figure 1b, again using a 3-year mov-         organization of the working class was the crucial
ing average) reveals a similar pattern to the               political foundation of most welfare states (Esping-
descriptive data. In the first stage, a positive value on   Andersen, 1985, 1990; Stephens, 1979). Hence,
working-class status suggests that working-class            what does this decline of working-class mobilization
voters are more likely than middle-class voters to          for the Left imply for the political support of the wel-
vote for left parties. Over time, a move towards a          fare state? What does its nearly uniform nature imply
zero or negative coefficient suggests an erosion of         for differences among welfare states?
Gingrich and Häusermann                                                                                         57

Figure 1. Declining working-class vote: (a) Alford index and (b) coefficient on working class for vote Left.
SD: Social Democratic; CD: Christian Democratic.

   When we turn from class differences in the pro-           (see, for example, Gingrich, 2011; Häusermann,
pensity to vote for the Left to overall Left support,        2010; Hemerijck, 2013; Palier, 2010; Pierson, 2001)
we see two quite different patterns. Figure 2 shows          – the overall size of the state in spending terms has
overall support for left parties across regimes, as          remained predominantly stable.
well as support among the working class and middle              How then do we account for the combination of a
class. Despite declining working-class support, there        near-uniform decline in working-class support for the
has been neither a generalized decline of Left vote          Left with an overall stability in support for the Left
shares nor a cross-regime convergence in left                and the welfare state? As explained above, we argue
strength. The Left remains strongest in the South,           that there has been a dual substitution in the support
with similar levels of strength in the Social and            coalition for the welfare state: at the individual and
Christian Democratic regimes and lower support in            partisan levels. First, while left parties have mas-
the Liberal counties of the United Kingdom and               sively lost working-class votes, they have gained new
Ireland. Assuming that these parties of the Left             constituencies among specific parts of the educated,
remain a pro-welfare force (something we confirm             pro-welfare middle class. Second, under pressure
in Figure 4), Figure 2 suggests that the decline in          from both electoral shifts, as well as institutional
traditional class voting has not led to decline in polit-    feedback, traditionally right-wing parties have moved
ical support for the welfare state.                          towards more pro-welfare positions. We examine
   Furthermore, not only has the support for the Left        these two sources of welfare support sequentially.
remained remarkably stable, but so too have welfare             In order to investigate the first ‘substitution’,
states themselves. Although almost all welfare states        within the electoral constituency of the Left, we
have been extensively reformed – retrenched in               return to the EB–ESS combined data. As Figure 2
some instances, expanded and recalibrated in others          shows, the middle-class vote for the Left has
58                                                                           Journal of European Social Policy 25(1)

                                 Percentages of Respondents Voting for a Left Party
        .8

                                                           .8
        .6

                                                           .6
        .4

                                                           .4
        .2

                                                           .2
        0

                                                           0
             1980      1990           2000          2010        1980      1990          2000           2010
                      Social Democratic Regimes                         Christian Democratic Regimes
        .8

                                                           .8
        .6

                                                           .6
        .4

                                                           .4
        .2

                                                           .2
        0

                                                           0
             1980       1990          2000          2010        1980       1990         2000           2010
                           Liberal Regimes                                   Southern Regimes

                                % of Middle Class Vote                 % of Working Class Vote
                                % of Overall Vote

Figure 2. Percentage of workers, middle classes, routine workers and the employed electorate voting Left.

increased over time relative to the working-class              Figure 3 shows, in line with our theoretical argu-
vote. In the Social Democratic welfare states, the         ment, a clear story of electoral substitution. With the
middle-class vote for the cumulative Left is now           exception of the Southern countries, the middle
almost exactly equal to the working-class vote, at         classes are now a very substantially more important
slightly above 40 percent. Since the mid-2000s, the        part of the Left’s employed base than workers. Left
share of middle-class voters choosing the Left in          parties became predominantly middle-class based
Christian Democratic and Liberal regimes has actu-         around 1990 in the Nordic, Continental and Southern
ally exceeded the working-class vote. Southern             European countries. In 2012, across the countries
Europe, by contrast, shows a more stable pattern,          included in the sample, there were three middle-class
with the working-class vote for the Left being clearly     voters casting a ballot for a left party for every worker
above average across the entire time period and the        doing so.6 Together, Figures 2 and 3 show that the
middle-class vote remaining stable (at the Left vote       proportion of the middle-class voting for the Left has
share average).                                            grown, and the expanding size of this group means
    When we combine this information on the shift in       that it has become the core base for the Left. While
the behaviour of these groups with the massive             these shifts are occurring everywhere (even in the
changes in the structural size of the groups, the pic-     Southern regimes where they are less pronounced),
ture that emerges testifies to a radical reshaping of      there are regime differences. Both the propensity of
the electoral base of the Left. Figure 3 shows how         middle-class voters to vote Left and the importance
the relative shares of working-class voters and mid-       of the middle class for left parties are higher in the
dle-class voters in the total electorate of the Left       Social Democratic and Christian Democratic regimes
have developed over time. Middle-class voters have         than the Liberal and Southern regimes.
clearly become the largest share in the Left electoral         Who are these new middle-class left voters? The
base in all regimes.                                       literature suggests that they are largely drawn from
Gingrich and Häusermann                                                                                                                  59

                                                  Class Composition of Employed Left Voters

                 1

                                                                                1
                        .8

                                                                                       .8
           % of Left Base

                                                                          % of Left Base
                    .6

                                                                                   .6
              .4

                                                                             .4
         .2

                                                                        .2
                 0

                                                                                0
                             1980     1990          2000        2010                        1980       1990         2000          2010
                                    Social Democratic Regimes                                         Christian Democratic Regimes
                 1

                                                                                1
                        .8

                                                                                       .8
           % of Left Base

                                                                          % of Left Base
                    .6

                                                                                   .6
              .4

                                                                             .4
         .2

                                                                        .2
                 0

                                                                                0
                             1980     1990         2000         2010                        1980       1990        2000          2010
                                        Liberal Regimes                                                 Southern Regimes

                                                 Working class voters                              Middle class voters

Figure 3. Changes in left parties’ electoral base.

a clearly identifiable group of professionals and                         pro-welfare parties’ employed base (16 percent of the
semi-professionals in interpersonal services; by                          total base, when we include retirees and those out of
contrast, professionals in managerial and technical                       the labour force), while workers constitute 21 percent
occupations continue to vote predominantly for the                        of the employed base (10 percent of the total base).
right (Geering and Häusermann, 2013; Häusermann                               When we look to further unpack the new service
and Kriesi, in press; Kitschelt and Rehm, 2014;                           groups, distinguishing between private and public
Oesch, 2008). Our EB–ESS combined data do not                             employees, we again face data constraints in terms
allow us to operationalize variation within the mid-                      of longitudinal analysis. However, two EB surveys,
dle class, but the ESS data from the 2000s bear out                       1988 and 1994, and the ESS in the mid-2000 meas-
these claims. In the ESS sample, 51.2 percent of a                        ure employment sector. We use these items to create
combined group of socio-cultural professionals,                           a measure of public employment, including all gov-
semi-professionals and skilled service workers                            ernment and public sector employees and employees
voted for a left-wing party, compared with only                           of state-owned enterprises. Here, we again find
47 percent of higher and associate manual and rou-                        interesting regime variation regarding both the size
tine workers. By contrast, only 40 percent of high-                       of these groups and their electoral choice. The Social
skilled managers, associate managers and office                           Democratic regimes have clearly the highest share of
workers voted for the Left. We see, then, a remarka-                      public sector workers with around 35 percent in both
ble shift towards socio-cultural professional and                         time periods, followed by Christian Democratic and
skilled service workers as a core base for the Left.                      Liberal regimes, each with between 25 percent and
From the perspective of these parties, and across the                     30 percent of public sector workers, and finally the
six ESS surveys, socio-cultural professionals and                         Southern regimes with a little below 20 percent on
skilled service groups amount to 28 percent of                            average. We find similar differences when looking at
60                                                                                                                 Journal of European Social Policy 25(1)

     0 5 10 15 20

                                                                              0 5 10 15 20
     welfare expansion

                                                                              welfare expansion
                          1970       1980      1990       2000         2010                       1970   1980        1990      2000            2010
                                     Social Democratic Regimes                                            Christian Democratic Regimes

                                     socialist/soc−dem       green                                       socialist/soc−dem                green
                                     agrarian                conservative                                christ−dem. & cons.              right−pop
                                     right−pop               liberal                                     liberal
                         20

                                                                              0 5 10 15 20
                                                                              welfare expansion
     welfare expansion
                         15
                         10
                         5

                                                                                                  1970    1980         1990      2000          2010
                         0

                              1970   1980       1990      2000         2010                                         Southern Regimes
                                            Liberal Regimes
                                                                                                          soc/social−dem             green
                                       soc/social−dem             green                                   christ−dem                 conservatives
                                       conservative               liberal                                 right−pop                  liberal

Figure 4. Party positions on welfare expansion over time, Manifesto data.

the share of respondents employed by the welfare                                       We hypothesized above in terms of a second substi-
state more directly. We cumulate the share of work-                                    tution effect that as workers move to the right, this
ers in public administration, education, health and                                    could foster support among right parties for the wel-
social work for the mid-2000s (ESS data, NACE                                          fare state, whereas the pro-redistributive attitudes of
sector coding) and find about 27 percent in                                            new socio-cultural professionals would solidify wel-
Scandinavia, 23 percent in Liberal and Christian                                       fare support on the Left.
Democratic regimes and only 13 percent in Southern                                         In order to trace and categorize party positions
European countries. More importantly, our data                                         over time, we use the Comparative Manifesto Project
show that support for the Left among both public                                       database and aggregate political parties into party
sector workers and welfare state employees is clearly                                  families (Appendix 4). The Comparative Manifesto
higher than average in all regimes, with a particu-                                    Project provides systematic over-time coding of
larly strong difference in Scandinavia. Again, the                                     party positions in election manifestos. We examine
Southern regimes are different since support for the                                   the average position of parties of a party family on
Left from public and welfare state workers is not sig-                                 the item ‘welfare state expansion’ (per 504).
nificantly different from the other employees. In line                                 Although manifesto data arguably measure both sali-
with other work, these data confirm that the welfare                                   ency and ideological positioning, they nonetheless
state shapes the occupational structure of societies,                                  provide a continuous time series from the 1970s to
directly feeding back into its own support (Esping-                                    2010 that allows us to tap underlying party support
Andersen, 1993).                                                                       for the welfare state. Figure 4 shows the average
    As parties’ electoral base changes, the question                                   position of the relevant party families on the issue of
arises of whether the parties themselves continue to                                   welfare state expansion over time. High values indi-
represent clear stances vis-à-vis the welfare state.                                   cate high levels of welfare state support.
Gingrich and Häusermann                                                                                        61

    Two observations are important regarding               cross-class support coalition for the welfare state. In
Figure 4: first, on aggregate, the position of left par-   the Christian Democratic regimes, the left parties are
ties has not shifted to the right, despite the massive     now even more strongly supported by the middle
inflow of middle-class voters to the Left. In Social       class than by the working class, but again their
Democratic and Southern regimes, left parties have         favourable position towards welfare state expansion
even shifted to the left, and the level of welfare state   has remained stable. Here too, the Christian
support remained more or less stable in Christian          Democratic and right-wing populist parties have
Democratic regimes. The Liberal regimes, however,          shifted towards more welfare-supporting positions.
do not follow this trend; here, left parties have indeed   It seems that the continental European countries
shifted towards less pro-welfare positions than since      exhibit a pattern of reconfiguration that comes clos-
the early 1980s.                                           est to the kind of status quo convergence Pierson had
    The second important finding in Figure 4 is that       hypothesized.
right-wing parties have indeed shifted towards more            In Liberal countries, by contrast, the electoral
pro-welfare positions in most countries. This is par-      shifts of workers to the right and middle-class voters
ticularly true for the conservative and liberal parties    to the left have rather led to a more welfare-critical
in Scandinavia and for the Christian Democrats in          convergence. The Left’s support for welfare state
continental and Southern Europe.7 Right-wing popu-         expansion has declined over time and almost con-
list parties, where they exist, have also tended to        verged with the conservatives on a comparatively
shift to more pro-welfare positions over time, espe-       low level, which may be due to the smaller endoge-
cially in Christian Democratic regimes, but the            nous institutional effects of the more residual liberal
development is less clear and certainly far from           welfare state, and also to the majoritarian dynamic of
strong pro-welfare positions (as some probably pre-        party competition in these countries. Finally, the
mature arguments about the rise of welfare chauvin-        Southern countries show a more stable picture than
ism may suggest).                                          the others: there is little electoral reconfiguration,
    While the move of moderate right parties towards       and party positions have also remained more stable,
more welfare-supporting positions may also be due          although some right-wing parties have moved
to institutional feedback mechanisms, as hypothe-          slightly towards more pro-welfare positions. This
sized by Pierson (1996, 2001), there is also a rather      stability may result from the less programmatically
close correspondence of shifts in the electorate and       structured political space in Southern countries,
party positions. Figure 5 shows the working-class          where parties have long adopted more particularistic
vote for moderate and populist right parties over          policies (see the contribution by Manow, 2015). As a
time. In Scandinavia and Continental Europe, over          result, the working-class support for the Left remains
time support for moderate right parties among work-        high and stable in these countries, but equally, the
ers has grown and, more recently, for right-wing           Left has been more limited in its ability to attract
populist parties, as well. In Liberal and Southern         additional constituencies. This picture suggests an
regimes, the patterns are more stable, with fewer          interpretation of the Southern regimes as increas-
right-wing populist parties (except for Italy, but they    ingly traditional insider welfare states.
do not mobilize the working class strongly).
    What do these data imply for the reconfiguration
of welfare support coalitions across different             Implications of this
regimes? In Scandinavia, the Left is now equally           reconfiguration of the electoral
strongly supported by the working and parts of the         support coalition for the
middle classes. Nevertheless, the positions of the
main left parties have become decidedly more pro-
                                                           welfare state
welfare over time. More importantly even, the mod-         Does this dual substitution matter for the welfare
erate right-wing parties have also moved towards           state itself? As developed in section ‘Changing coa-
pro-welfare positions so that there is a very broad        litions, changing welfare states?’ of this article, a
62                                                                                 Journal of European Social Policy 25(1)

                                          % of Voters Supporting Right Parties

         1

                                                             1
         .8

                                                             .8
         .6

                                                             .6
         .4

                                                             .4
         .2

                                                             .2
         0

                                                             0
              1980       1990         2000           2010         1980           1990          2000         2010
                        Social Democratic Regimes                              Christian Democratic Regimes
         1

                                                             1
         .8

                                                             .8
         .6

                                                             .6
         .4

                                                             .4
         .2

                                                             .2
         0

                                                             0
              1980       1990          2000          2010         1980           1990         2000          2010
                            Liberal Regimes                                         Southern Regimes

                     % of Working Class Vote for Populist                % of Working Class Vote for Moderate Right
                     Overall Moderate Right Vote

Figure 5. Support for right-wing parties.

changed electoral base might imply new policy pri-            1999) or ‘social investment’ (Gingrich and Ansell, in
orities for the Left and thus transformed welfare             press; Hemerijck, 2013; Morel et al., 2012) – have
politics, even if on aggregate, we see stable support         made the point that other, typically post-industrial
for left parties. In this section, we examine the evo-        risk groups face different (or at least additional) risks
lution of labour market policy and family policy              requiring distinct policies. These new social policies
across European welfare states to investigate whether         comprise most clearly issues of work-care reconcili-
we see evidence for such a shift.                             ation. Left voters from the ‘new middle classes’ are
    In the traditional class-power model, labour mar-         highly sensitive to these policies, because for them
ket policy assumes a crucial role. For Esping-                the type and extent of labour market participation
Andersen (1990) and other power-resource scholars,            and family obligations are a key choice they have to
one of the central goals for left-wing parties involved       make in the interest of their family’s welfare. In this
insuring against the risks of unemployment. Recent            sense, family policy services can be seen as a typical
work on occupational risk and the insurance func-             example of a more ‘middle-class’ welfare state
tions of the welfare state continues to focus on              strategy.
unemployment-related policies, which are particu-                 Our expectation thus is that where left-wing par-
larly crucial to those with specific skills or occupa-        ties have a relatively stronger working-class base,
tional risks (e.g. Bonoli, 2010; Gingrich and Ansell,         they will tend to pursue more pro-worker policies
2012; Rehm, 2009; Rueda, 2007).                               (i.e. more generous unemployment insurance
    By contrast, scholars focusing on the social poli-        replacement rates). Where parties are competing
cies key to the post-industrial societies – notably the       more directly for the middle-class vote, we expect
literature on ‘new social risks’ (Armingeon and               more investment in family policy and services,
Bonoli, 2006; Bonoli, 2005; Esping-Andersen,                  reflecting the interests of a broadened constituency.
Gingrich and Häusermann                                                                                         63

    In order to see whether the priorities of parties on   5-point scale of partisan control of cabinet (1 = right-
the Left shift as the composition of their base shifts     wing hegemony to 5 = left-wing hegemony) with the
towards a more middle-class electorate, we construct       modified Alford index discussed in section ‘The
a dataset combining the descriptive data on the com-       decline of electoral support of the working class for
position of the voting base from the EB–ESS com-           the Left’. We further include a measure of the over-
bined dataset with policy outcomes data. We focus          all percentage of the working class that supports the
on two policies: unemployment replacement rates as         Left. In the analysis of unemployment replacement
a typical welfare benefit in the direct interest of        rates, we include controls for overall union density
working-class voters and parental leave replacement        (Visser, 2011), the unemployment rate and gross
rates as a typical hedge against ‘new social risks’ and    domestic product (GDP) growth (Armingeon et al.,
‘social investment’-policy instrument, which               2012). In the analysis of leave replacement rates, we
responds most directly to the needs and demands of         include a measure of female labour force participa-
the educated middle classes.                               tion (OECD, 2013) and the percentage of the popu-
    Data on replacement rates for unemployment and         lation under 65 years and GDP growth (Armingeon
parental leave come from two sources. First, we            et al., 2012)
draw on the Comparative Welfare Entitlements                   Table 1 shows the results. In line with expecta-
Dataset Version 2, which provides replacement rate         tions, the interactive effect of the Alford index and
data for all 16 countries in our sample from 1970 to       cabinet control is highly statistically significant for
2011 (Scruggs et al., 2014). The replacement rates         unemployment replacement. Substantively, these
data have the advantage of providing a measure of          results are quite strong: dominant Left cabinets with
generosity based on existing policy, rather than           a predominantly working-class electorate are associ-
spending data, which is affected by current macro-         ated with predicted unemployment replacement
economic conditions. Unemployment replacement              rates that are more than two percentage points higher
rates for single ‘average production workers’ are a        than those associated with left cabinets under the
standard measure of the generosity of the unem-            control of parties that have lost their working-class
ployment insurance system. To capture a similar            profile. These effects are yearly, so the cumulative
measure for family policy, we examine the com-             effects are substantial.9
bined replacement for maternity and parental leave             Columns 3 and 4 of Table 1, however, show that
for the first 26 weeks of leave.8 This measure pro-        there is no significant interactive effect between cab-
vides a gauge of the generosity of parental leave          inet control and the Alford index for parental leave
benefits (Gauthier, 2011).                                 replacement rates.10
    In order to provide some preliminary and illustra-         Figure 6 shows the interaction visually using in-
tive evidence of the effects of the left parties’ con-     sample predicted probabilities based on the first and
stituency profile on policy priorities, we run two         third specifications. It shows that left governments
types of time-series specifications. First, we run a       with high levels of concentrated working-class sup-
pooled regression with a lagged dependent variable,        port appear to expand unemployment replacement
year dummies, and with error terms adjusted for one-       rates more; by contrast, left governments with a
period autocorrelation and country-specific heter-         strong middle-class voter base are significantly less
oskedasticity. Second, we run a country fixed-effects      generous in terms of unemployment replacement
regression, also with a lagged dependent variable,         rates. However, contrary to expectation, we find no
year dummies, and country-clustered standard errors.       differences in the propensity to support parental
In both cases, we lag all independent variables by         leave policies based on working-class concentration:
1 year. We linearly impute data for missing years.         where left-wing parties have a strong middle-class
    Our key interest lies in whether left parties          basis (i.e. whether the Alford index is low), the level
behave systematically differently based on the             of generosity in leave replacement rates is not sig-
degree of support from the working class. To meas-         nificantly distinct to where its base is more concen-
ure this, we interact Armingeon et al.’s (2012)            trated in the working class.
64                                                                                Journal of European Social Policy 25(1)

Table 1. Determinants of unemployment and family policy replacement rates, in-kind spending.

                                   (1)                     (2)                    (3)                    (4)

                                   RR UE                   RR UE                  RR leave               RR leave
Lagged DV                           0.973* (0.0092)         0.914* (0.0356)         0.992* (0.0109)        0.863* (0.0303)
Union density                      −0.0001 (0.0001)        −0.0007 (0.0004)
Alford index                       −0.121* (0.0367)        −0.0697 (0.0509)        −0.0336 (0.0363)      −0.0111 (0.107)
Cabinet composition                −0.0031* (0.0012)       −0.0024* (0.001)         0.0005 (0.0013)      −0.0007 (0.0012)
Alford*Cabinet                      0.0384* (0.0098)        0.0340* (0.0101)
WC support for Left                 0.00745 (0.0137)       −0.0236 (0.0215)         0.0099 (0.0180)      −0.0090 (0.0487)
GDP growth                         −0.00116 (0.0009)       −0.0009 (0.0008)         0.0011 (0.0015)      −0.0009 (0.0011)
Unemployment                       −0.0004 (0.0004)        −0.0004 (0.0005)
Female LFP                                                                        −0.0002 (0.0002)        0.0032* (0.0013)
Non-elderly population share                                                       0.0019 (0.0036)       −0.0007 (0.0036)
Constant                            0.0221 (0.0133)         0.0951* (0.0322)      −0.152 (0.126)         −0.0013 (0.325)
Year dummies                       Yes                     Yes                    Yes                    Yes
Observations                       377                     377                    382                    382
R2                                 0.984                   0.894                  0.964                  0.831
*significant at the 0.05 level.
RR: replacement rate; UE: unemployment insurance; DV: dependent variable; WC: working class; GDP: gross domestic control;
LFP: labour force participation.

Figure 6. Predicted values of unemployment and parental leave replacement rates for different levels of working-
class concentration in Left electoral support.
Gingrich and Häusermann                                                                                             65

   While we do not find a mirror effect for the two        has been pushed to more welfare-supporting posi-
policy strategies, we nonetheless think that the           tions. In Continental Europe, there has been a narrow-
absence of an effect regarding family policy may           ing of partisan differences around a pro-welfare
actually provide some evidence that declining work-        equilibrium. In the Liberal regimes, we see a right-
ing-class support does shape policy priorities for the     ward shift, as few left-wing competitors remain.
Left. Left governments with a strong working-class         Finally, in the residual and particularistic welfare
profile do not lead to lower parental leave replace-       regimes of Southern Europe, we see more stability
ment rates (as their voters also benefit from them),       over time. Indeed, although declining class voting,
but left governments with a strong middle-class base       which cuts across regimes, would seem to belie their
support this policy equally strongly.                      analytic utility, we confirm many of Esping-
                                                           Andersen’s early suspicions. Regimes have bred their
                                                           support base, and they have done so in distinct ways.
Conclusion                                                    However, these shifts do not imply stasis in the
The electorate in 2014 looks, in many ways, quite          state itself; the new electoral coalition space has con-
differently to how it did in 1990 when Three Worlds        sequences. Where the working class is less aligned
was published and most certainly to the period of          to the Left, it allows less generous unemployment
welfare state expansion from the 1940s to the 1970s        policies, but not less generous social investment pol-
at the heart of Three Worlds’ analysis. Traditional        icies. Both dynamic suggest a key transformation in
working-class voters now make up a much smaller            the state alongside its electoral constituencies.
share of the electorate, and indeed, the concept of
class itself has changed along with the socio-eco-         Acknowledgements
nomic structure. Moreover, in this article, we have        We would like to thank Patrick Emmenegger, Jon Kvist,
shown that the working-class vote for the Left, in         Paul Marx, Klaus Petersen and the reviewers for helpful
both relative and absolute terms, has declined, a          comments.
decline that has occurred across regime boundaries.
    This erosion would seemingly portend quite radi-       Funding
cal changes for the welfare state and for scholarship      This research received no specific grant from any funding
on it. For scholars of power resources, in particular      agency in the public, commercial or not-for-profit sectors.
Esping-Andersen, the electoral foundations of work-
ing-class power were crucial to the longevity of the       Notes
welfare state. And yet, despite these shifts, the wel-      1. Many recent contributions have confirmed the
fare state remains in place. We are hardly the first to        ongoing structuring power of occupational location
note this situation; indeed, Paul Pierson’s (1996,             and occupational risk on political preferences and
2001) influential theorization of the ‘new politics’           choice (e.g. Bornschier, 2010; Häusermann, 2010;
pointed to precisely a replacement of old cleavages            Häusermann and Walter, 2010; Kitschelt and Rehm,
with generic support for the welfare state. While the          in press; Marx, 2014; Marx and Picot, 2013; Oesch,
findings here are, to some extent, supportive of these         2008; Rehm, 2011; Walter, 2010).
claims, they are also substantially distinct in empha-      2. We also deliberately use ‘too broad’ notions of work-
sis. We find a real decline in working-class support           ing and middle class, which do not denote homogene-
                                                               ous occupational groups anymore (Oesch, 2006). We
for left parties – not simply a generalized levelling
                                                               do so in order to relate our argument to the earlier and
up of welfare support. This decline occurs partly              broader literature on welfare state politics.
from a pro-welfare move by right-wing parties, but          3. One could argue that electoral realignment is rel-
also partly from a leftward move among middle-                 evant for welfare politics only if welfare issues have
class voters.                                                  remained salient for voters’ party choice. Except for
    The result is shifting welfare state coalitions that       the working-class vote for the populist right (which
look quite different from those of the past. In Social         is predominantly culturally motivated), this assump-
Democratic countries, the entire political spectrum            tion indeed seems to hold. At the individual level,
You can also read