Technical appendix to Vacancies, unemployment and labour market slack in New Zealand
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
September 2020 AN2020/7 Technical appendix to Vacancies, unemployment and labour market slack in New Zealand Finn Robinson Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note Series ISSN 2230-5505 Reserve Bank of New Zealand PO Box 2498 The Analytical Note series encompasses a range of types of background Wellington papers prepared by Reserve Bank staff. Unless otherwise stated, views NEW ZEALAND expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily represent the views of the Reserve Bank. www.rbnz.govt.nz
Appendix A: Vacancy data sources and issues A key limitation with empirical studies of the Beveridge curve and matching function is the lack of quality vacancy data. Often the data are only available over a short time period and vacancies may not be measured consistently across countries (Consolo and da Silva, 2019). In New Zealand, two important data sources for vacancies data have been the ANZ Bank job advertisement series and the Ministry of Business, Innovation, and Employment (MBIE)’s Jobs Online data. The ANZ series stretches from 1990 to 2018 and counts advertisements placed in newspapers and online. See Silverstone (2004) for an early example of labour market analysis carried out using this dataset. The ANZ series was discontinued in 2018 (figure A.1). The MBIE Jobs Online data is an index which tracks changes in the number of vacancies advertised online. The data are available at occupational, industry, and regional levels. The vacancy data is reported as an index for ‘commercial sensitivity reasons’ (Fale and Tuya, 2010, p. 3). The data is sourced from four online jobs platforms: SEEK, TradeMe Jobs, Education Gazette, and Kiwi Health jobs. The Jobs Online data are available from 2010 and continue to be published. Currently, the base year for the MBIE Jobs Online index is 2010. Since this Note focuses on aggregate variables, the All Vacancies Index is used, which is based on all of the job-ads captured in Jobs Online (MBIE, 2018). This index is plotted in Figure A.1. One concern with counting vacancies posted on multiple job platforms is the possibility of duplicates. For example, if a job is posted on both SEEK and TradeMe Jobs then it could be counted twice even though there is only one vacant position. When MBIE receive raw data from its suppliers a few days after the reference month, part of their data-processing involves removing such duplicates. They check both for duplicates on the same website and across each of their source websites (MBIE, 2018). The ANZ data were not cleaned in this way, so the level of vacancies may be overstated by this measure. Figure A.1: ANZ online job advertisements and MBIE All Vacancies Index Source: ANZ, MBIE, Hall and McDermott (2016), author estimates. Note: Grey shading indicates the 2008 recession in New Zealand, based on the Hall and McDermott (2016) dates. 2 ANALYTICAL NOTE | AN2020/7
In order to construct a long time series of vacancy data in New Zealand, it is necessary to combine the ANZ and MBIE job vacancies data. Since the MBIE All Vacancies Index captures online advertisements, only the ANZ count of online vacancies is used, starting in 2000 Q1. Following the method used by Dutu, Holmes, and Silverstone (2016) the All Vacancies Index is regressed against the ANZ advertisements series over the period for which they are both available (2010 Q4 – 2018 Q4). Then using the estimated coefficients from that regression, quoting Dutu, Holmes and Silverstone I ‘backward forecast’ from 2009 Q4 to 2000 Q1 to obtain a proxy for the MBIE vacancies data over this period (p. 92). Figure A.2 plots the MBIE All Vacancies Index in red, with the back-cast constructed from the ANZ advertisements data in blue. Figure A.2: MBIE All Vacancies Index and ANZ-based proxy Source: ANZ, MBIE, Hall and McDermott (2016), author estimates. Note: Grey shading indicates the 2008 recession in New Zealand, based on the Hall and McDermott (2016) dates. 3 ANALYTICAL NOTE | AN2020/7
With this splice in place, we now have a time series of vacancies spanning from 2000 Q1 to 2019 Q4 – 80 data points. While this is by no means a large sample, it is an improvement on the short All Vacancies Index which only has 37 data points. Figure A.3 plots the spliced online vacancy index. Figure A.3: Spliced online vacancy index Source: ANZ, MBIE, Hall and McDermott (2016), author estimates. Note: Vertical line indicates the start date of the All Vacancies Index. Data points prior to the vertical line are estimated using the ANZ job advertisements data. Grey shading indicates the 2008 recession in New Zealand, based on the Hall and McDermott (2016) dates. Appendix B: Econometric approach B.1: Econometric model The aggregate matching function summarises the complicated process by which jobs are created in a frictional labour market, where unemployed people search for jobs and firms post vacancies to try and fill empty positions (Blanchard and Diamond, 1989a). The matching function can be written as; = (1) where hires ( ) is the number of jobs created each quarter, vacancies ( ) is the number of vacancies posted by firms, and job-seekers ( ) is the number of people looking for a job. is interpreted as matching efficiency and is akin to the Solow residual in a Cobb-Douglas production function (Borowczyk-Martins, Jolivet, and Postel-Vinay, 2013). When = 1 − β this means the matching function has constant returns to scale (CRS) (Borowczyk-Martins, Jolivet, and Postel-Vinay, 2013). Under CRS, if unemployment and vacancies were to double, the number of jobs created would also double. Matching functions have been estimated for many countries using many statistical methods and different data (see Petrongolo and Pissarides (2001) for an overview). The estimation is often carried out in log-levels. For example, Blanchard and Diamond (1989a) estimate the following regression: ln = 0 + 1 ln + 2 ln + 3 (2) where is a time trend, which is often found to be negative in these regressions. A negative time trend implies that matching efficiency has declined over the sample period (Petrongolo and Pissarides, 2001). 4 ANALYTICAL NOTE | AN2020/7
For the current Note, an autoregressive distributed lag model (ARDL) approach is chosen to estimate equation 2. This approach has the advantage that, when properly specified, ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates of the parameters of the model will be consistent, and valid standard errors will be obtained for inference, even when one or more of the variables in the regression are integrated of order one (Pesaran and Shin, 1999). In addition, the ARDL model can be transformed into an error correction representation. This allows us to determine whether there is a long-run equilibrium relationship between job-creation, job-seeking, and vacancies whilst controlling for short-run dynamics (Pesaran and Shin, 1999). The ARDL approach is used by Raines and Baek (2016) to estimate the Beveridge curve in the US, allowing them to estimate the equilibrium relationship between vacancies and unemployment whilst controlling for the short run dynamics of these variables. Bell (1997) conducts a cointegration analysis of matching functions in France, Great Britain and Spain using the ARDL approach, and finds evidence of the existence of an aggregate matching function in each country. However, Bell does not find evidence in favour of CRS, which highlights the importance of testing this assumption before imposing it on the data. The ARDL model to be estimated is specified as follows: ( ) = 0 + 1 + ∑ ( − ) + ∑ ( − ) + ∑ ( − ) + (3) =1 =0 =0 where the parameters , , are the number of lags of , , and included in the regression.1 is a trend which should capture any trend deterioration in labour market performance over the sample. We can re-parameterise the ARDL model as an error correction model: ∆ ( ) = 0 + + ∑ ∆ ( − ) + =1 ∑ ∆ ( − ) + ∑ ∆ ( − ) + =0 =0 1 ( −1 ) + 1 ( −1 ) + 1 ( −1 ) + As Raines and Baek (2016) note in their cointegration analysis of the Beveridge curve, we can now test the existence of a long-run relationship. The null hypothesis of no cointegration is : 1 = 1 = 1 = 0 against the alternative : 1 ≠ 0, 1 ≠ 0, 1 ≠ 0. The null hypothesis is assessed using the bounds testing approach developed by Pesaran, Shin, and Smith (2001). The results of the test for cointegration are reported in table B.4.2. B.2: Data selection Petrongolo and Pissarides (2001) offer a survey of the early literature on estimating matching functions. There is considerable variation in the choice of data used to measure the dependent and independent variables in the matching function, with the choice of data often restricted by availability. A common measure of job creation or hires ( ) is the number of people moving from unemployment to employment each quarter. This measure of job creation is used in this Note. The data are from the Household Labour Force Survey conducted by Statistics New Zealand and are available at a quarterly frequency. ——— 1 A dummy variable to control for the impact of the GFC was included initially, however it was insignificant in all specifications tested. 5 ANALYTICAL NOTE | AN2020/7
For job-seekers, the majority of papers surveyed by Petrongolo and Pissarides (2001) simply use the number of unemployed people. By definition, unemployed people in New Zealand are part of the labour force and are looking for work, therefore they should be a reasonable proxy for job seekers.2 Unemployment data is also sourced from the Household Labour Force Survey. The number of vacancies in New Zealand is proxied using the All Vacancies Index produced by the Ministry of Business, Innovation, and Employment. These data are timely, but are only readily available from 2010. The discontinued ANZ job advertisement data are used to backdate the All Vacancies Index to 2000 Q1 (see Appendix A). Data are seasonally adjusted using the X-13 ARIMA SEATS programme developed by the US Census Bureau. B.3: Unit root tests As noted above, OLS estimates of the ARDL model will be consistent and provide valid standard errors for inference if variables are integrated of order zero or one. It is therefore important to establish the order of integration of each variable included in the matching function estimation. Augmented Dickey-Fuller tests indicate the log-levels of unemployment to employment transitions ( ), number of unemployed ( ), and vacancies ( ) are all nonstationary (table B.3.1). However, the null hypothesis of a unit root is rejected for first-differences of each variable. All the variables are integrated of order one over the sample period of 2000Q1 to 2019 Q4, therefore we can proceed with estimating the ARDL model. B.4: ARDL model baseline results The ARDL model of the matching function is estimated from 2000Q1 to 2019Q4 using data on unemployment to employment transitions, the stock of unemployed people, and the All Vacancies Index spliced together with the ANZ job advertisements data. The analysis is carried out in Stata, using the ardl package developed by Kripfganz and Schneider (2018). Table B.3.1: Augmented Dickey-Fuller test results Variable Test statistic Constant Drift Trend Lags -1.652 X 9 ∆ -3.448*** 2 -2.080 X X 8 ∆ -3.560*** 7 -3.056 X X 3 ∆ -4.048*** 7 Note: Schwert criterion is used to select maximum lags for Dickey-Fuller regressions (11 for each variable), then testing down until lags are significant at the 10 percent level. *** p
For the current analysis, the Bayesian information criterion (BIC) was used to select the lag length. Then, additional lags of the dependent and independent variables were added to ensure that residuals were not serially correlated. The model specification is an ARDL(1,2,1), with one lag of hires (the dependent variable), two lags of the vacancy index, and one lag of the number of unemployed. A battery of residual diagnostic tests finds evidence favouring the conclusion that the regression residuals are not serially correlated. The results of the ARDL model, including residual diagnostics, are outlined in Table B.4.1. The estimated coefficient on the linear time trend is negative and significant (although only at the ten percent significance level). This indicates there has been a decline in the efficiency of the New Zealand labour market since 2000, consistent with findings in other countries (Petrongolo and Pissarides, 2001). The decline in matching efficiency indicates the labour market has become worse at matching unemployed job-seekers with vacant jobs, reducing the productivity of the matching function in New Zealand at creating jobs. This decline is consistent with the outwards shift observed in the Beveridge curve outlined in Section 2. The estimated long run coefficients on vacancies and unemployment are reported in table B.4.2. These are obtained from estimating the error correction representation of the ARDL model. The long run coefficients on vacancies and unemployment are positive and statistically significant at the one percent significance level. The bounds test confirms there is a long run equilibrium relationship between hires, vacancies, and unemployment that is statistically significant at the one percent level.3 Since the regression is run in logs, we can interpreted the estimated long-run coefficients on vacancies and unemployment as elasticities. Specifically: A one percent increase in the online vacancy index is associated with a 0.23 percent increase in hires. A one percent increase in the number of unemployed job seekers is associated with a 0.58 percent increase in hires. Finally, I fail to reject the null hypothesis that the sum of the coefficients on vacancies and unemployment is equal to one, indicating the matching function in New Zealand has constant returns to scale.4 This is in contrast to Razzak (2008) who found decreasing returns to scale for the New Zealand matching function.5 ——— 3 The null hypothesis of no levels relationship is rejected at the 1 percent significance level. The F-statistic is 28.509, which is above the one percent upper critical value of 7.962. 4 Similar results are obtained using the Akaike information criterion (AIC) to select the lag length of the ARDL model. However, this model was less parsimonious, with the AIC favouring an ARDL(4,3,2), compared to the ARDL(1,2,1) in the baseline specification. 5 Razzak (2008) uses a similar approach to this paper. However, the source of vacancy data is different (only using ANZ job-ads), and the sample period is also very different. It could be the case that over this time the returns to scale of the matching function may have changed. In addition, the ANZ data is not cleaned to remove duplicates, which could artificially reduce the number of hires per vacancy posted. 7 ANALYTICAL NOTE | AN2020/7
Table B.4.1: ARDL estimation results VARIABLES −1 0.0686 (0.102) 0.144 (0.166) −1 -0.122 (0.201) −2 0.190** (0.0924) -0.398** (0.167) −1 0.942*** (0.158) Trend -0.00231* (0.00124) Constant -0.517 (0.612) 78 Observations R-squared 0.708 Residual diagnostic tests White test (p-val) 0.4415 Cameron and Trivedi (p-val) 0.2498 Breusch-Godfrey (p-val) 0.4644 Portmanteau (p-val) 0.2162 Note: Standard errors in parentheses. Dependent variable is the natural logarithm of hires (unemployment to employment transitions) each quarter. Independent variables are the natural logarithms of the number of unemployed people and the spliced online vacancy index (outlined in detail in Appendix A), a linear trend, and a constant. *** p
One concern is that the regression relies on a vacancy index constructed from two different sources, where one is a vacancy index and one is a vacancy count. In Appendix C the matching function is estimated using only the MBIE data, and then separately using just the ANZ data. The results for the ANZ data are almost identical to the main results reported in table B.4.2. For the MBIE data, the estimated long-run coefficients were larger than the baseline results in table B.4.2 for both vacancies and unemployment, although I still failed to reject the null hypothesis of constant returns to scale. The smaller sample size using the MBIE data made the estimates very imprecise, with vacancies found to be statistically insignificant despite an increase in the estimated coefficient of around 25 percent. This highlights the benefit of using the spliced online vacancy index to obtain more precise estimates. Appendix C: Robustness tests C.1: Estimation using MBIE All Vacancies Index In order to estimate the matching function in Appendix B, I had to combine two measures of vacancies in New Zealand to get the longest possible sample. This section reports the results of running the baseline ARDL(1,2,1) model using only the MBIE All Vacancies Index, from 2010 Q4 – 2019 Q4. The estimation results are detailed in Table C.1.1, noting the small sample of just 36 observations. Table C.1.1: ARDL model estimated using All Vacancies Index (1) VARIABLES −1 -0.0474 (0.146) 0.589 (0.626) −1 0.228 (0.931) −2 -0.494 (0.617) -0.158 (0.275) −1 1.183*** (0.247) Trend 0.00261 (0.00828) Constant -3.366* (1.750) Observations 36 R-squared 0.544 Note: Standard errors in parentheses. Dependent variable is the natural logarithm of hires each quarter, independent variables are the natural logarithms of the MBIE All Vacancies Index and the number of unemployed. *** p
The estimated long-run coefficients on vacancies are reported in table C.1.2. Column 1 shows the estimated coefficients from the baseline ARDL model and column 2 shows the estimated coefficients when restricting the regression to only using the MBIE All Vacancies Index. For the smaller sample, the coefficients on vacancies and unemployment are larger although the sample size means the estimates are imprecise and the coefficient on vacancies is statistically insignificant. I fail to reject the null hypothesis of constant returns to scale, which is unsurprising given the large standard errors. The results in tables C.1.1 and C.1.2 indicate that running the matching function analysis using only the All Vacancies Index leads to qualitatively similar results as using the spliced online vacancies index outlined in Appendix B, although the small sample means the coefficients are imprecisely estimated. The benefits of using the longer time-series are that firstly, a larger sample leads to more precise estimates of the regression coefficients and secondly, it allows us to make conclusions about the New Zealand labour market over a much longer period of time. Figure C.1.2: Estimated long-run coefficients on vacancies and unemployment (1) (2) VARIABLES 0.227*** 0.308 (0.0847) (0.339) 0.584*** 0.978*** (0.0757) (0.275) Constant returns to scale p-value 0.2015 0.4492 ( : + = 1) Observations 78 36 Note: Newey-West standard errors in parentheses. First column shows baseline results from ARDL model with spliced online vacancies, second column shows results obtained using MBIE All Vacancies Index as a proxy for the number of vacancies. *** p
C.2: Estimation using ANZ advertisements data As a final check, the matching function analysis is carried out using the ANZ job advertisements data, which gives us a count of the number of vacancies rather than an index. The ANZ data is not cleaned to remove duplicates and may therefore overstate how many vacancies are posted in a given quarter. The regression is carried out over the full range of the ANZ job advertisements data – 2000Q1 to 2018Q4. Table C.2.1 shows the results for the estimated ARDL model. Table C.2.1: ARDL model estimated using All Vacancies Index (1) VARIABLES −1 0.0813 (0.103) 0.105 (0.150) −1 -0.0804 (0.175) −2 0.153** (0.0744) -0.415** (0.172) −1 0.941*** (0.161) Trend -0.00203 (0.00127) Constant -1.482 (1.055) Observations 74 R-squared 0.714 Note: Standard errors in parentheses. Dependent variable is the natural logarithm of hires each quarter, independent variables are the natural logarithms of the ANZ job advertisements count and the number of unemployed. *** p
Table C.2.2 shows the estimated long run coefficients on vacancies and unemployment when using the ANZ job advertisements data (column 2), compared with the baseline specification (column 1). The estimated long run coefficient on the ANZ job advertisements variable is very similar to the estimated coefficient for the spliced online vacancies index. Once again, the null hypothesis of constant returns to scale is not rejected at all conventional significance levels. Figure C.2.2: Estimated long-run coefficients on vacancies and unemployment (1) (2) VARIABLES 0.227*** 0.194** (0.0847) (0.0785) 0.584*** 0.573*** (0.0757) (0.0796) Constant returns to scale p-value 0.2015 0.1067 ( : + = 1) Observations 78 74 Note: Standard errors in parentheses. First column shows baseline results from ARDL model with spliced online vacancies, second column shows results obtained using ANZ job advertisements measure of the number of vacancies. *** p
Fale, A and C Tuya (2010) ‘Measuring job vacancies in New Zealand through Jobs Online’, New Zealand Department of Labour, pp. 1-9. Hall, V and C McDermott (2016) ‘Recessions and recoveries in New Zealand’s post-Second World War business cycles’, New Zealand Economic Papers, Vol. 50, No. 3, pp. 261-280. Hobijn, B, and A Şahin (2013) ‘Beveridge curve shifts across countries since the Great Recession’, IMF Economic Review, Vol. 61, No.4, pp. 566-600. Kripfganz, S and D Schneider (2018) ‘ardl: Estimating autoregressive distributed lag and equilibrium correction models’, Proceedings of the 2018 London Stata Conference. Lubik, T, and K Rhodes (2014) ‘Putting the Beveridge curve back to work’, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Brief, EB14-09, pp. 1-5. Ministry of Business, Innovation, and Employment (2018), ‘Jobs Online background and methodology report’, Ministry of Business, Innovation, and Employment, pp. 1-6. Pesaran, M and Y Shin (1999) ‘An autoregressive distributed lag modelling approach to co-integration analysis’, Chapter 11 in Econometrics and Economic Theory in the 20th Century: The Ragnar Frisch Centennial Symposium, Strom S (ed.). Cambridge University Press: Cambridge. Pesaran, M, Y Shin and R Smith (2001) ‘Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of level relationships’, Journal of Applied Econometrics Vol. 16, No.3, pp. 289-326. Petrongolo, B and C Pissarides (2001) ‘Looking into the black box: A survey of the matching function’, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 39, No. 2, pp. 390-431. Pissarides, C (2000) ‘Equilibrium unemployment theory’, 2nd Edition, MIT Press Books. Raines, R and J Baek (2016) ‘The recent evolution of the U.S. Beveridge curve: Evidence from the ARDL approach’, Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 6, pp. 14-24. Razzak, W (2008) ‘On the dynamic of search, matching, and productivity in New Zealand and Australia’, New Zealand Department of Labour, pp. 1-32. Robinson, F, J Culling, and G Price (2019) ‘Evaluating indicators of labour market capacity in New Zealand’, Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note, AN2019/09, pp. 1-12. Sedláček, P (2016), ‘The aggregate matching function and job search from employment and out of the labour force’, Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 21, pp. 16-28. Silverstone, B (2004) ‘Help wanted in New Zealand: The ANZ Bank job advertisement series’, University of Waikato Working Papers in Economics, No. 3/04, pp.1-11. StataCorp (2019) Stata 16 Base Reference Manual. College Station, TX: Stata Press. 13 ANALYTICAL NOTE | AN2020/7
You can also read