Some Unpleasant Euro Arithmetic* - CEPII
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
No 21 – January 2018 Policy Brief Some Unpleasant Euro Arithmetic* Guillaume Gaulier & Vincent Vicard Summary Current estimates of misalignments in real effective exchange rates show that euro area imbalances are still large: Germany exhibits a 20 percentage point undervaluation compared to the rest of the euro area (EA). Within a monetary union, rebalancing requires price adjustments through differentials in inflation rates. The rebalancing process therefore involves a 2 percentage point higher inflation in Germany than in the rest of the EA over a decade, or a 1 pp over two decades. It also requires above 2% inflation in surplus countries to meet the 2% ECB inflation target. At the current pace, rebalancing is a 20 year process and requires sustained very low inflation rates in the rest of the euro area. * This Policy Brief reflects the opinions of the authors and do not necessarily express the views of the Banque de France.
Some Unpleasant Euro Arithmetic 2. Introduction show a gap of 20 percentage points between Germany and the rebalancing Current account imbalances have been at the heart of the the rest of the euro area. The euro area crisis (Baldwin and Giavazzi, 2015). Over the last rebalancing process therefore process involves a five years, crisis countries have drastically reduced their involves a 2 percentage point 2 percentage point current account deficits to the point that they post surplus higher inflation in Germany than in higher inflation in or are near balance in 2016 whereas the level of surplus of the rest of the EA over a decade, northern countries has not weakened. Upon this background, or a 1 pp higher inflation over two Germany than in we ask three simple questions in this policy brief: decades. It also requires above the rest of the EA • How far has the process of current account rebalancing 2% inflation in surplus countries to over a decade been? meet the 2% ECB inflation target. • What is the current state of current account imbalances or alternatively real effective exchange rate misalignments within the euro area? 1. 1. Current account deficits • How long will rebalancing take? are gone but imbalances remain The short answers are: the process of current account rebalancing has not gone far, imbalances are still large, and The first decade of the euro area has been characterized rebalancing will take a long time. Corrections of current account by growing divergences of current accounts across country imbalances are still on the agenda of the euro area and a long members, creating large and sustained current account term process. The current adjustment through unprecedented surpluses and deficits at the national level while the euro area surplus of the euro area only as a whole remained near balance. Before the financial crisis, exports excess savings to Greece, Portugal, Spain and Ireland posted deficit reaching imbalances are still the rest of the world. Without 15%, 12%, 9% and 7% of GDP respectively, while Germany, large, and rebalancing internal rebalancing, external the Netherlands and Luxembourg posted current account will take a long time adjustment of the euro area will push some members surpluses larger than 5% of GDP. By 2016, all deficit countries were near balance (in the into deficit, fueling similar case of Greece) or in current account surplus (in the cases risks of quasi sudden stop at the heart of the euro area crisis, of Ireland, Spain, Portugal), after having experienced a particularly so given cumulated divergence in net foreign drastic adjustment of more than 10 percentage points of assets positions. Dealing with such legacy of the first decade GDP. Italy also switched from a current account deficit to of the euro should therefore be full part of any credible plan for a surplus, experiencing a similar adjustment of more than the future of the EA. 5 percentage points over the last five years. In most cases, Within a monetary union, rebalancing requires price such corrections have been costly, owing more to expenditure adjustments through differentials in inflation rates. Current contraction reducing imports than expenditure switching estimates of misalignments in real effective exchange rates towards tradable sectors. Figure 1 – Current accounts imbalances within the euro area Current account (% of EA GDP) Current accounts (Mn EUR) 5% 500000 70000 4% 450000 60000 3% 400000 00000 350000 50000 2% 300000 40000 1% 250000 200000 30000 0% 150000 20000 -1% 100000 -2% 10000 50000 -3% 0 0 19999 20000 2001 20022 20033 20044 20055 20066 20077 20088 20099 20100 20122 20133 20144 20155 20166 2011 -4% Germany Spain France Netherlands Italy Other deficit Others EA Sum of absolute values Standard deviation Source: Eurostat. 2 CEPII – Policy Brief No 21 – January 2018
Policy Brief The rebalancing process has however remained asymmetric, Table 1 – REER and current account gaps with no symmetric adjustment in surplus countries. After a Current account REER gap (wrt. norm) decade of near balance, the euro area as a whole leans level gap (wrt norm) midpoint range toward surplus, standing at 3.5% of euro area’s GDP in 2016 (Figure 1, panel a). Excess savings in Northern Europe, now (% of GDP) percentage unmatched by financing needs in Southern Europe, are now Euro area 3,3 0,3 -1,0 -5 / 3 exported to the rest of the world. Germany 8,3 4,5 -15,0 -20 / -10 Even more so as not only have current account surpluses France -1,0 -2,8 11,0 8 / 14 not been reduced but heightened, reaching unprecedented Spain 2,0 -2,0 7,5 5 / 10 levels in excess of 8% of GDP in 2016 in Germany and the Italy 2,6 -2,0 9,0 6 / 12 Netherlands. Increasing surpluses matched the decrease in deficit so that imbalances within the euro area have Netherlands 8,4 3,0 -9,0 -12 / -6 not been reduced despite the disappearance of deficits in Belgium 0,0 -1,5 6,0 2 / 10 most countries. 1 Overall, the absolute value of surpluses and deficits of EA countries has not been reduced but has Source: IMF External Sector report 2017. concentrated on some countries. The right panel of figure 1 shows that the sum of absolute values of current account the other side of the spectrum, France, Italy and Spain are balances (in euro) of EA members as well as the standard significantly overvalued, but on different trends with the deviation between countries have increased up to 2008 and Spanish REER gap improving and the French and Italian have not decreased significantly afterwards. deteriorating. Figure 2 shows that REER increasing surpluses have even diverged between 2. 2. Misalignments in real matched the decrease in l a r g e e u r o a r e a c o u n t r i e s effective exchange rates deficit so that imbalances since 2011. The difference in have not corrected percentage points between within the euro area have not the most overvalued and the An alternative way of considering imbalances, been reduced despite the most undervalued large EA in a more normative way, is to look at real disappearance of deficits in c o u n t r i e s i n c r e a s e d f r o m effective exchange rate misalignments, i.e. 17.5 percentage points in the divergence with respect to an equilibrium most countries. 2011 to 26 pp in 2016, the or desirable long term norm that depends on most undervalued being an economy’s fundamentals and/or the state of the business Germany all along and the most overvalued Spain until cycle. We focus here on one such exercise, the External 2015, overtaken by France in 2016. This widening of REER Balance Assessment conducted every year since 2012 by misalignments reflects the fact that some of the current the IMF for 28 countries, including 6 EA members and the account adjustments in deficit countries have been driven euro area as a whole. The External Sector Report assesses by cyclical factor (e.g. output gap), deficit therefore being excess imbalances at the global and national level based on a methodology developed by the IMF research department and provides (range of) estimates of the REER gaps/ Figure 2 – REER misalignments within the euro area (2011-2016) misalignments and the associated current account gaps as reported in Table 1. 2 15 In 2016, the IMF estimates the euro area to be broadly 10 aligned with the norm, despite its strong current account 5 surplus. This alignment however hides wide misalignments 0 between euro area members. Germany stand out as strongly 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 undervalued (-10% to -20%), as are the Netherlands. On -5 -10 -15 1. In 2016, all deficit were lower than (Belgium, Greece, France, Lithuania Slovakia) or close to (Finland) to 1% of GDP except for Cyprus (-5.3%). -20 2. See IMF (2013) for the methodology. Note that the norm considered Min Max Euro area accounts for structural determinants of the current account such as demographic factors, productivity or domestic institutions, and cyclical factors Source: IMF External Sector reports 2012 to 2017. (output gap, commodity terms of trade,…). CEPII – Policy Brief No 21 – January 2018 3
Some Unpleasant Euro Arithmetic likely to resume with sustained growth in Southern European Table 2 – Inflation in Germany and the rest of the EA under different countries. 3 adjustment scenarios In the following, we take stock of the estimated divergence Inflation Inflation Inflation in REER between Germany and the rest of the euro area, Duration Euro Area Germany Rest of euro area and investigate the required price adjustments to achieve 10 1.0 2.4 0.4 rebalancing under different scenarios. 10 2.0 3.4 1.4 10 3.0 4.4 2.4 20 1.0 1.7 0.7 3. 3. Rebalancing will take time 20 2.0 2.7 1.7 and require inflation significantly above 2% in Germany 20 3.0 3.7 2.7 Source: Author’s calculation. Within a monetary union, the REER misalignments across member countries cannot be adjusted through the nominal depending on the length of the adjustment and the overall exchange rate. Rebalancing therefore requires price adjustments EA inflation rate. The conclusions are clear: rebalancing through differentials in inflation rates sustained over a long would require a large inflation differential sustained over period of time.4 a long period of time. It requires a 2 percentage point Let’s illustrate the challenge higher inflation rate in Germany over a 10 year period and ahead of the EA with some within a monetary a 1 percentage point inflation differential over a 20 year back of the envelope period. Moreover, an average inflation close to the ECB union, the REER calculations on the required 2% target involves an inflation rate significantly above 2% inflation differentials depending misalignments per year in Germany. Were the overall EA inflation at 1%, on the overall EA inflation across member the rebalancing process would rate and the time horizon. countries cannot be involve near stagnating prices in We consider 2 different time the rest of the euro area. With EA gap of close to horizons – 10 and 20 years –, adjusted through inflation at 3%, the adjustment is 20 percentage and 3 assumptions regarding the nominal obviously much easier for the rest points between the overall EA inflation exchange rate of the EA but inflation would be rate – 1%, 2% and 3% a close or above 4% in Germany. Germany and year –, for a total of 6 scenarios presented in Table 2. How do such scenarios compare with the rest of the Going into the details of the calculations, we take the historical records of inflation? Figure 3 euro area midpoint gaps from the IMF external report 2017 presented plots the 3-year moving average in Table 1, which implies a gap of close to 20 percentage inflation of the EA and its largest points between Germany and the rest of the euro area. 5 members. The 1% inflation scenario corresponds to the post- Note that the gap is slightly larger (21%) when considering crisis EA average inflation. In this period price adjustments Germany and the Netherlands together. 6 Table 2 presents the implied (average) price growth in Germany and the rest of the EA during the adjustment Figure 3 – 3-year moving average inflation (GDP price) 5 5 3. Desbordes et al (2017) show that cyclical factors explain more than half the explained adjustment of current account of EA countries over the 2008/2013 period. Focusing on Spain, Moral-Benito and Viani (2017) show that cyclical 4 4 factors explain almost 60% of the adjustment between 2008 and 2015. 4. We use the growth in GDP deflator as our measure for inflation. The GDP deflator depends on factor prices which are mainly domestic whereas 3 3 the consumer price inflation (CPI) also depends directly on foreign prices (including oil price) and exchange rates, volatile factors that enter the terms 2 2 of trade with weights varying across countries according to their openness and specialization. In the long run both measures converge. Note that the IMF’s REER are computed using CPI. 1 1 5. The 20 pp German REER gap with respect to the rest of the EA is computed as follows: (REER gap DE - weight DE*REER gap EA)/(1- weight DE)=(-15-0.3* (-1))/(1-0.3). Using an alternative methodology to compute equilibrium exchange 0 0 rates (behavioral equilibrium exchange rate), the CEPII’s EQCHANGE database 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 provides a similar order of magnitude (i.e. a 17 percentage points misalignment EA France Germany Italy Spain between Germany and the rest of the EA); see Couharde et al. (2017). 6. The Netherlands are less undervalued (12 pp vs 20 pp for Germany) but its Source: Eurostat weight (6% of EA GDP) adds to that of Germany (30% of EA GDP). 4 CEPII – Policy Brief No 21 – January 2018
Policy Brief occurred but were associated with low growth, with the inflation and unemployment involving that adjustment in a low exception of Germany which posted inflation environment is costly in terms GDP growth close to its (low) pre-crisis of economic activity. 8 record. During this period, inflation the current inflation The first episode saw Germany accumulate has been 1.7% on average in Germany pattern therefore a 14 percentage point inflation differential and 0.8% in the rest of the EA, which with respect to the EA between 1996 and corresponds to the 20 year adjustment involves: (i) an horizon of 2008 (see Figure 4).Germany appreciated scenario in Table 2. The current inflation adjustment of 20 years and since 2009, but at the pace observed pattern therefore involves: (i) an horizon (ii) a below 1% inflation in up to 2016 (0.4% per year) it would take of adjustment of 20 years and (ii) a below the rest of the EA 35 years to complete the adjustment. 1% inflation in the rest of the EA. Throughout all the internal devaluation To place such inflation targets in a broader period but the last 3 years (2006-2008) perspective, 1% corresponds to the pre-crisis German inflation Germany posted significantly low relative real growth. rate, and 1.7% corresponds to the French or average EA inflation pre-crisis. On the other side, an inflation close to 3%, as implied for Germany when EA inflation is set at 2%, Figure 4 – Inflation and growth differentials with respect to the EA in Spain and Germany while lower than the inflation recorded in Spain over the pre-crisis period, is obviously very challenging: it happened Germany in Germany only in the 1980s at a time when monetary 3 3 policy was independent, inflation in most other high income 2 2 countries was in the two digits and when the reunification took place (3.8% on average from 1989 to 1993). 1 1 0 0 4. 4. Past episodes of price adjustment in the euro area are associated -1 -1 with low growth -2 -2 We review here two episodes of significant price adjustments -3 -3 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 achieved between EA members since the inception of the euro. 7 We consider episodes when domestic inflation Spain GDP deflator differential GDP real growth diffential remained below that of the EA for at least six years. Most 3 3 of them entailed low growth, consistently with the Phillips curve that shows a negative relationship between the level of 2 2 1 1 7. Three other recent episodes involving EA countries appear less 0 0 representative. Finland depreciated vis-à-vis the EA from 2002 to 2006, cumulating a 7 pp inflation gap, while real GDP growth remained above -1 -1 that of the EA by 1 pp. The sectoral specialization may largely explain that episode: Nokia was booming in a sector experiencing a rapid price fall due to technological progress. Until 2003 Austria followed the German depreciation, -2 -2 but at a lesser pace (-0.6%/year versus -1.1%), which combined with the openness rate of this small economy may have helped preserving growth slightly above the EA. Ireland devaluation was very stark but relatively -3 -3 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 short, from 2007 to 2010; real growth fell in 2009 (with respect to the EA) and 2011, then strongly recovered from 2013 onwards. The Irish economy is also too specific (very high openness and specialization, major role of foreign GDP deflator differential GDP real growth diffential multinationals, etc.) to be taken as illustrative for the rest of the EA. Before the Euro, France went through 6 years (1990-1995) of significant price Source: Eurostat adjustment vis-à-vis Germany. Following the reunification Germany posted relatively high inflation whereas France, had engaged in what was called “désinflation competitive”, lowered its inflation to 1.8%. The cumulated 9pp inflation differential during this period was associated with a 6pp GPD growth 8. The slope of the Phillips curve, i.e. the relationship between unemployment differential in favor of Germany. Growth has however been higher in the post and the level of inflation, is estimated at 0.2 by Blanchard (2016) and 0.7 by reunification Germany in years 1990 and 1991 only, so that on average France Chatelais et al (2015). On a sample of 9 euro zone countries, we find in a managed to keep the German growth pace during the rest of the period. panel setting including country and year fixed effects a slope of 0.45 (sum Having large trade partners accumulating current account deficits facilitates of the coefficients of unemployment level and unemployment change) on the or is a condition for rebalancing without recession. GDP deflator. CEPII – Policy Brief No 21 – January 2018 5
Some Unpleasant Euro Arithmetic The second episode is the Spanish recent adjustment the end, result in costly price adjustments in deficit countries, of 7 pp since 2009. It is still ongoing but it remains to be particularly in case of asymmetric adjustment. Surveillance seen if the internal devaluation mechanisms aim at preventing the can be maintained while relative creation of imbalances in the future. GDP, thanks to domestic demand, imbalances in real effective Given the legacy of the euro crisis; is no longer shrinking. Greece is exchange rates have not been they should also favors symmetric another illustration of costly internal corrected and, absent nominal a d j u s t m e n t b y b o t h s u r p l u s a n d devaluation (11 pp cumulated inflation gap since 2011; 25 pp for GDP, 32 if exchange rate adjustment, dindicators e f i c i t c o u n t r i e s . C u r r e n t l y, t h e of the Macroeconomic the drop in 2010 is taken into account). their correction requires price Imbalance Procedure (MIP) of the adjustments involving inflation European Commission are not only over 3% in surplus countries biased towards surplus when it 4. Conclusion comes to the current account (the thresholds are -4% but +6% of GDP This policy brief has shown that current account rebalancing on average over 3 years) but are also inconsistent with a within the euro area has been limited since 2010 because lasting rebalancing in terms of inflation. The MIP defines a the reduction in excessive current account deficits has been 9% threshold on the 3-year percentage change in nominal matched by increasing current account surpluses in the rest unit labor costs (ULC); since ULC equal the labor share of the euro area. Therefore, imbalances times the price deflator, the central medium in real effective exchange rates have term scenario consistent with the 2% not been corrected and, absent nominal given the legacy of the inflation target of the ECB already involves exchange rate adjustment, their correction euro crisis; they should an average 6% cumulated ULC growth requires price adjustments involving also favors symmetric over 3 years. The 9% threshold on ULC inflation over 3% in surplus countries (i.e. growth is therefore inconsistent with the Germany and the Netherlands) over a 10 adjustment by both over 3% inflation required in Germany for years period and at 2.7% on average over surplus and deficit rebalancing in a scenario with an average a 20 years period. countries euro area inflation of 2%. In the absence of fiscal transfers within a monetary union, excessive current account imbalances cumulate into net foreign assets imbalances and, in 6 CEPII – Policy Brief No 21 – January 2018
Policy Brief References Baldwin Richard, Francesco Giavazz (2015), “The Eurozone crisis: A Desbordes R., G.Koop and V. Vicard (2017), “Determinants of consensus view of the causes and a few possible solutions”, Vox-EU, the current account: Bayesian model averaging and panel data 07 September. poolability”,mimeo. Blanchard Olivier (2016), “The US Phillips Curve: Back to the 60s?”, IMF (2013), “External Balance Assessment (EBA) Methodology: PIIE Policy Brief PB16-1, January. Technical Background”, Prepared by Staff of the IMF’s Research Department, 25 June, (https://www.imf.org/external/np/res/eba/ Chatelais Nicolas, Annabelle De Gaye and Yannick Kalantzis (2015), pdf/080913.pdf). “Inflation basse en zone euro : rôle des prix d’imports et de l’atonie économique,” Rue de la Banque, No 6, May. Moral-Benito Enrique and Francesca Viani (2017), “An anatomy of the Spanish current account adjustment: the role of permanent and Couharde C., A.-L. Delatte, C. Grekou, V. Mignon and F. Morvillier transitory factors”, Bank of Spain. (2017), “Sur- et sous-évaluations de change en zone euro : vers une correction soutenable des déséquilibres ?”, La Lettre du CEPII, No 375, March 2017. About the authors Guillaume Gaulier is Senior Research Economist at the Banque de France and associate researcher at CEPII, guillaume.gaulier@banque-france.fr Vincent Vicard is economist at CEPII, vincent.vicard@cepii.fr Contact: vincent.vicard@cepii.fr CEPII (Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et CEPII Policy Brief CEPII d’Informations Internationales) is a French institute CEPII’s insights on international economic policy 20, avenue de Ségur TSA 10726 dedicated to producing independent, policy- CEPII – Paris – 2018 75334 Paris Cedex 07 No ISSN: 2270-258X oriented economic research helpful to understand All rights reserved. Opinions expressed in this +33 1 53 68 55 00 the international economic environment publication are those of the author(s) alone. and challenges in the areas of trade policy, www.cepii.fr Editorial Director: Sébastien Jean competitiveness, macroeconomics, international Managing Editor: Christophe Destais finance and growth. Production: Laure Boivin Press contact: presse@cepii.fr CEPII – Policy Brief No 21 – January 2018 7
You can also read