Monetary policy and consumer prices: evidence from the Swiss franc unpegging - Alex Oktay

Page created by Kristen Floyd
 
CONTINUE READING
Oktay

 SJES SUBMISSION - JULY 2021 VERSION

Monetary policy and consumer prices: evidence
from the Swiss franc unpegging
Alex Oktay

   Abstract
   This paper uses a difference-in-differences strategy on the Swiss franc increase of January 2015 to quantify the
   one-year impact of a currency appreciation on the prices of goods and services for each category of the
   Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices. The results suggest a positive relationship between indirect exchange
   rates and prices with an average implied elasticity of 0.128 for all categories, such that a currency appreciation
   reduces prices. Oil, tourism, and durable goods are the most impacted sectors with some elasticities ranging
   from 0.649 to 1.111. The estimated transmission of importers price differentials to retail prices is 57%. Most
   services (excluding tourism) and fast-moving consumer goods are only slightly affected by the changes in
   exchange rate. The results confirm that the import share and foreign-currency invoicing share could be the
   main determinants of exchange rate elasticity, while also pointing towards expenditure switching as an
   important mechanism. The analysis outlines an important heterogeneity in how different goods and services
   react to exchange rate fluctuations following monetary policy changes.
   Keywords: Prices; Currency appreciation; Monetary policy; Short-term inflation; Exchange rates
   JEL Classification: E31; E52; F31

1 Introduction                                                           Swiss National Bank (SNB) decision to remove their
Exchange rate fluctuations can have a large impact                       exchange rate ceiling caused a large and unexpected
on prices. By shaping agents expectations about their                    appreciation of the domestic currency, which can be
currency, monetary policy is thus able to change short-                  studied as a shock on prices. A difference-in-differences
term prices and influence the domestic economy. How-                     (DID) estimation is carried by comparing prices of
ever, even if the general effect of exchange rate policies               each category of goods and services in Switzerland
on inflation is well-known, the specific results for each                with respect to the rest of Europe. The DID estimates
category of products have only started to be studied                     are then used to compute implied elasticities of prices
recently.                                                                to indirect exchange rate fluctuations.
  This paper estimates the impact of currency fluctu-                      Measuring the specific elasticity of each category of
ations on the prices of each type of goods and ser-                      products is crucial to understand the connection be-
vices using data from a 2015 monetary policy change                      tween exchange rate policies and inflation. A nega-
in Switzerland. Doing so allows to understand which                      tive relationship between a currency appreciation and
sectors, industries, services, and products are most im-
                                                                         prices has already been observed in empirical data
pacted by exchange rate policies. Such information
                                                                         across multiple countries (Bhattarai, 2011; Carranza
greatly benefit central banks policymaking by helping
                                                                         et al., 2009; Nguyen, 2012; Pindiriri, 2012; Umeora,
them plan how exchange rate interventions and policy
                                                                         2010). Despite the complexity of monetary transmis-
changes can affect specific groups of agents. Under-
                                                                         sion mechanisms, the most likely channel in this case
standing the specific effects of their policies on prices
becomes even more important given the prevalence of                      is for the appreciation to cause an increase in the pur-
price stability objectives in modern central banking                     chasing power of households together with a higher
(De Gregorio, 2012).                                                     demand for imports, leading to an overall negative
  The Swiss franc appreciation of 2015 provides a fit-                   domestic inflation (Leitemo and Söderström, 2008).
ting empirical framework to study these relations. The                   However, this general result lacks details on which
                                                                         types of goods and services are most impacted by this
Correspondence: alex.oktay@unil.ch
University of Lausanne, Lausanne, Switzerland
                                                                         negative relationship. While considering inflation as a
Full list of author information is available at the end of the article   whole works for inflation forecasting (Hubrich, 2005),
Oktay                                                                                                      Page 2 of 9

it proves to be limited for other purposes such as eval-     country, I used the HICP, a collective effort by nations
uating the macroeconomic impact of the policies or           to standardize their observations of CPI to allow for
the persistence of inflation, which differ for each cate-    comparisons. The data are provided by the Statistical
gory of goods (Lunnemann and Mathä, 2004). As such,         Office of the European Union. There is currently no
general inflation underestimates the heterogeneity be-       scientific evidence of a bias in the HICP (Wynne and
tween different industries, regions and products, lead-      Rodriguez-Palenzuela, 2004).
ing to potential adverse effects if not considered in pol-     This dataset of prices was cleaned for easier anal-
icymaking.                                                   ysis and interpretation. For the purpose of my anal-
  Recent literature started to analyze the effect of ex-     ysis, I used monthly HICP panel data from January
change rates on specific prices. Breinlich et al. (2019)     2014 to December 2015 for 34 countries in the Eu-
studied import costs in the context of Brexit, which         ropean region[1] . Due to some data not being avail-
confirms the heterogeneity of products reaction based        able in some countries, I averaged all 33 countries (ex-
on their import share. One step further, Auer et al.         cluding Switzerland) in a single ”Euro-Average” vari-
(2021a) outlines the role of the invoice currency in         able weighted by their respective GDP. The dataset is
the elasticity of prices to exchange rates, with foreign-    originally separated in 468 multi-levels types of goods
invoiced goods being more affected by the fluctuations.      but has to be trimmed down to 76 (shown in table
Both of these papers provide convincing explanations         3) because multiple subcategories are not available
of price movements, together with estimates of import-
                                                             for Switzerland before 2015. Moreover, some subcat-
share (Breinlich et al., 2019, pp. 45–47) and invoice
                                                             egories must be removed due to a low frequency (usu-
currency (Auer et al., 2021a, pp. A10–A14) for vari-
                                                             ally quarterly and yearly). While this removes some
ous types of products. The purpose of this paper is to
                                                             precision in the analysis of which goods are most af-
contribute to this recent literature by providing esti-
                                                             fected by the shock, it does not create a bias in the
mates of the elasticity of prices on the exchange rate
                                                             results. The final input data is a panel dataframe of
for different categories of goods and services.
  My results outline the important differences in how        the prices of 76 types of goods and services, over two
various industries are affected by currency fluctuations     regions (Switzerland and Europe), on a monthly fre-
following changes in exchange rate policies. They show       quency from January 2014 to December 2015.
that liquid fuels (such as gasoline, kerosene, and diesel)
are the most impacted goods, with prices dropping af-        2.2 The Swiss franc appreciation of 2015
ter a currency appreciation. The tourism sector also         The SNB introduced an exchange rate ceiling on the
greatly relies on exchange rates, with holiday prod-         Swiss franc in 2011. This change of policy followed
ucts and services related to holidays and accommo-           how the currency came under much upward pressure
dation dwindling soon after the SNB announcement.            due to capital inflows resulting from the European
The last category to be actively impacted is small-          debt crisis. The commonly accepted safe haven posi-
sized durable goods (such as books), which prices suf-       tion of Switzerland (Baltensperger and Kugler, 2016)
fer from cross-border shopping and international on-         plays an important role in the appreciation pressure on
line delivery. Most categories of services (excluding        the Swiss franc, which tends to attract foreign capitals
tourism) and fast-moving consumer goods have much            following external crises and uncertainty (Ranaldo and
lower elasticities than these products. The full results     Söderlind, 2010). Consequently, the sovereign debt cri-
are presented in table 3.                                    sis that started in 2010 with the Greek budget deficits
  The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 intro-        led to much volatility that was anticipated to make
duces the data, empirical context, and identification        the Swiss franc appreciate. With interest rates already
strategy. Section 3 presents the results of the currency     close to the zero lower bound, the SNB decided to re-
appreciation on prices. In section 4 I discuss the re-       spond with foreign exchange interventions and to in-
sults in the context of monetary policymaking. Section       troduce an explicit ceiling on the EUR/CHF exchange
5 concludes.                                                 rate at CHF 1.2 per Euro to prevent a domestic ap-
                                                             preciation (Hui et al., 2016).
2 Methodology
2.1 Data                                                       List of countries: Belgium, Bulgaria, Czech Republic,
                                                             [1]

The analysis presented in this paper is based on the         Denmark, Germany, Estonia, Ireland, Greece, Spain,
Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices (HICP). The              France, Croatia, Italy, Cyprus, Latvia, Lithuania,
more widely known Consumer Price Index (CPI) pro-            Luxembourg, Hungary, Malta, Netherlands, Austria,
vides the perfect framework to analyze the price evo-        Poland, Portugal, Romania, Slovenia, Slovakia, Fin-
lution of a wide range of products and services. How-        land, Sweden, Iceland, Norway, Switzerland, United
ever, as its methodology often differs from country to       Kingdom, North Macedonia, Serbia, Turkey
Oktay                                                                                                               Page 3 of 9

  This ceiling was maintained until January 15, 2015,                and foreign economies for multiple years (Lleo and
when the SNB surprised the market by suddenly re-                    Ziemba, 2015). However, the results of Auer et al.
nouncing to maintain its peg. The underlying reason                  (2021a) point toward a one-year impact of the shock
for this can be traced back to the European Cen-                     on prices, which motivate the use of data from January
tral Bank (ECB) quantitative easing program, which                   2014 to December 2015 for this analysis. Doing so al-
made the peg too expensive to maintain as it required                lows one year before the shock for pre-trend analysis
large amounts of foreign reserves (Lleo and Ziemba,                  and one year after the shock to infer the pseudo-causal
2015). This decision came together with the imple-                   impact of the appreciation on prices.
mentation of negative interest rates, which questions
the zero lower bound position of Switzerland in 2011                 2.3 Identification strategy
(Berhold and Stadtmann, 2018). The market reacted                    A naive comparison of Swiss prices before and after
with a sudden appreciation of the Swiss franc, with                  the shock would produce biased results. Prices are af-
                                                                     fected by a variety of factors that make the identifi-
the EUR/CHF decreasing as low as 0.975 on the day
                                                                     cation of the unpegging shock impossible without a
of the announcement. The Swiss franc then depreci-
                                                                     counterfactual due to endogeneity, making the results
ated and stabilized at around 1.04 to 1.09 for the rest
                                                                     uninterpretable (Antonakis et al., 2010). For instance,
of the year, which represents approximately a 10% ap-
                                                                     oil prices depreciated largely in 2014-2015 due to for-
preciation in the medium term. This sudden reaction
                                                                     eign policy and financial changes (Baffes et al., 2015)
demonstrates how the SNB decision clearly surprised
                                                                     which makes it impossible to identify the portion of
the market, with no evidence of expectations for this
                                                                     price change attributable to the SNB announcement.
announcement (Mirkov et al., 2019).
                                                                     Moreover, as seen in figure 1, the shock came in a
                                                                     period of inflation for Europe due to the quantita-
  102 Prices                                                         tive easing program of the ECB. As such, computing
                                                                     only the slight negative inflation that was observed
                                                                     in Switzerland would underestimate the real negative
  101                                                                effect of the shock on prices, as it would fail to con-
                                                                     sider the inflation that would have happened otherwise
                                                                     in Switzerland as a spillover from the Euro inflation
  100
                                                                     (Falagiarda et al., 2015). Given how the United King-
                                                                     dom faced similar inflation as other countries despite
   99                                                                not using the euro, it is likely that the ECB inflation
        jan14       jul14        jan15         jul15                 spreads to Switzerland as well despite not using the
            United Kingdom   France      Denmark       Switzerland   same currency. Due to the wide range of factors im-
                                                                     pacting prices of various goods and services, control
 Figure 1 Inflation in selected countries. Notes: HICP all-items     variables would most likely not be able to significantly
 aggregate with prices normalized to January 2014. Dotted line
 at January 2015 level indicate the time of the SNB unpegging        decrease the bias (Clarke, 2005).
 announcement and ECB quantitative easing program                       This paper uses the difference-in-differences method-
                                                                     ology as a solution to endogeneity. By using the rest
                                                                     of Europe as a counterfactual to Switzerland, identi-
  The rest of Europe can be used as an imperfect coun-
                                                                     fication of the effect of the exchange rate policy on
terfactual for this shock. As a small exporting coun-                prices can be made. A necessary condition for this in-
try, Switzerland relies heavily on its exchange rate                 ference is for both Switzerland and Europe prices to
for economic growth, so that the shock had signifi-                  follow parallel paths before the shock (Abadie, 2005).
cant implications for the Swiss economy. On the other                This assumption is verified for general prices (figure
hand, Switzerland is only a small trading partner for                2), as well as for the most affected categories of goods
the whole of Europe, so that the overall continent                   (figure 3). Even if this assumption remains robust for
was only slightly impacted by these local fluctuations.              most of the 76 types of goods and services presented in
Even though there were some negative consequences                    table 3, a small number of them exhibit unpredictable
for CHF-denominated loans in foreign countries, espe-                non-parallel trends. This can mostly be explained by
cially regarding mortgages in Central and Eastern Eu-                their prices having a larger volatility, resulting in non-
rope (Vassileva, 2020), taking the Euro-average prices               significant p-values for the categories concerned. All in
makes these specific cases marginal.                                 all, the DID can be tested for the prices of all types of
  My analysis focuses on 24 months of data: one year                 goods and services (k) using the SNB announcement
before the shock and one year after. The announce-                   as the treatment with equation 1.
ment had many positive and negative financial effects
on different agents that are likely to impact the Swiss                 priceik = αk + βk CHik + γk tik + δk DIDik + ik (1)
Oktay                                                                                                                     Page 4 of 9

  Where CHik is a dummy for Switzerland, tik is             and post-treatment general prices, as seen on figure 2,
a dummy for the post-treatment period (after Jan-           outlines how Europe faced inflation while Switzerland
uary 2015), and DID is the multiplication of the two        prices decreased. As such, a naive comparison of pre-
(DIDik ≡ CHik ∗ tik ), run for both Switzerland and         treatment and post-treatment prices in Switzerland
Europe (i).Under this regression, δ will thus measure       would underestimate the effect of the SNB decision,
the DID effect of the monetary appreciation on prices       as it misses the inflation that would have happened
for a specific category of goods or services k.             without the treatment, as seen elsewhere in Europe.
  Despite its benefits, the DID approach has some lim-
its and remains unusual in macroeconomics. Indeed,          Table 1 Difference-in-differences estimate of the Swiss franc
this econometric method is mostly studied in microe-        appreciation on Swiss general prices
conomic research due to its potential for causal in-                                             HICP All-Goods index
ference, even though some issues such as serial cor-          Intercept                                  101.06∗∗∗
relation often bias its results (Bertrand et al., 2004).                                                   (0.11)
Some studies have used the DID approach in the con-
                                                              Switzerland dummy                           −0.55∗∗∗
text of inflation and macroeconomic variables, either                                                      (0.16)
directly such as Takyi and Fosu (2019), or combined
with a vector autoregression approach such as Mishkin         Post-treatment                               0.47∗∗∗
and Schmidt-Hebbel (2007). The scarce usage of this                                                         (0.17)
methodology for such topics probably comes from the           Diff-in-Diff estimate                       −1.29∗∗∗
need to have a shock that is completely exogenous from                                                     (0.24)
the counterfactual, which is uncommon in macroeco-            Notes: DID regression following equation 1 on monthly general prices
nomic data and makes any identification strategy diffi-       (CPI aggregate), with Switzerland as the domestic country and Europe
                                                              (GDP-weighted average of all European countries) as the counterfac-
cult (Nakamura and Steinsson, 2018). In the case of the       tual. Respective prices are normalized to January 2015. Pre-treatment
Swiss franc unpegging, the shock certainly had some           from January 2014 to January 2015, post-treatment from February
                                                              2015 to December 2015. ∗ p
Oktay                                                                                                                     Page 5 of 9

tive relationship between a currency appreciation and                      on oil prices. This high elasticity can be traced back
inflation.                                                                 to the fact that Switzerland has to import all of its oil,
                                                                           which should result in a high proportion of foreign-
3.2 Most impacted goods                                                    denominated invoices. This result confirms the find-
A second analysis can be conducted on the specific                         ings of Auer et al. (2021a) that imports and invoice
prices of each category of goods and services. Equa-                       currencies are the largest determinant of the elasticity
tion 1 can be used to regress each of the 76 HICP                          of prices on exchange rates.
categories. The full results are presented through their                     Another heavily impacted industry is the travel and
implied elasticities in table 3. Most prices were affected                 tourism sector. This is true both for goods (such as
negatively by the currency appreciation, with only a                       package holiday, displayed in figure 3 and table 2) and
few non-significant positive ones. The three most im-                      services (such as holidays, accommodation, and restau-
pacted categories deserve a specific analysis in order                     rants displayed in table 3). While there are some sea-
to understand the common underlying factors to their                       sonality effects and a weaker parallel trend assump-
higher elasticity. Their regression results are presented                  tion, the exchange rate shock had a clear negative
in table 2.                                                                effect on this sector, with an estimated negative im-
Table 2 Difference-in-differences estimates of the Swiss franc             pact of -8.92% for package holidays. This result is in
appreciation on selected Swiss goods                                       line with current literature that a currency apprecia-
                                      Type of goods:                       tion has major negative effects for domestic tourism
                                                                           (Santana-Gallego et al., 2010), domestic airlines (Day,
                          Fuels         Holidays           Books
                                                                           1986; Forsyth and Dwyer, 2010), and on the inter-
  Intercept            123.19∗∗∗       103.05∗∗∗          98.63∗∗∗
                         (2.43)          (1.45)            (0.51)
                                                                           nal holiday market (Greenwood, 2007). While the re-
                                                                           sult partially confirms Auer et al. (2021a) intuition
  Switzerland            7.60∗∗          −0.36            2.01∗∗∗          due to foreign companies invoicing domestic services
  dummy                  (3.43)          (2.05)            (0.73)
                                                                           in foreign currencies, it also outlines the importance
  Post-treatment       −18.84∗∗∗          2.52             1.42∗           of expenditure switching as customers move to foreign
                        (3.58)           (2.15)            (0.76)          booking services and international travel rather than
  Diff-in-Diff         −11.20∗∗        −8.92∗∗∗          −6.54∗∗∗
                                                                           domestic agencies and internal travel.
  estimate              (5.07)          (3.03)            (1.07)             The last of the most impacted category were de-
  Notes: DID regressions following equation 1 on monthly liquid fuelds,    liverable consumer goods. This category is illustrated
  package holidays, and books prices with Switzerland as the domes-        through the example of books in figure 3 and table 2,
  tic country and Europe (GDP-weighted average of all European coun-
  tries) as the counterfactual. Respective prices are normalized to Jan-   as their price decreased by 6.54% due to the SNB an-
  uary 2015. Pre-treatment from January 2014 to January 2015, post-        nouncement. These types of goods reflect the ease of
  treatment from February 2015 to December 2015. ∗ p
Oktay                                                                                                                     Page 6 of 9

        a) Liquid fuels                            b) Package holidays                        c) Books
  100                                        120                                        105

   90                                        110
                                                                                        100

   80                                        100

                                                                                         95
   70                                         90

   60                                         80                                         90
     jan14       jul14    jan15   jul15         jan14      jul14     jan15     jul15       jan14     jul14    jan15     jul15
                                                         Euro−Zone       Switzerland

 Figure 3 Selected goods prices before and after the currency appreciation. Notes: prices normalized to January 2014. Dotted lines
 are the respective fitted values before and after the treatment for both Switzerland and the counterfactual

must play a role in their price reaction. An important                4 Implications for monetary policy
distinction between these goods and the books men-                    There is a strong link between prices and welfare which
tioned earlier are that the import process is managed                 central banks are aware of. Indeed, retail prices are
by corporate agents and importers rather than the con-                important components of household finance and wel-
sumer himself with cross-border and online shopping.                  fare (Massell, 1969; Turnovsky et al., 1980). While this
With the elasticity of books being 0.649 and the elas-                explains the price stability objective of many central
ticities of vehicles, electrical appliances, and furniture            banks, including the SNB, it also emphasizes the need
being 0.393, 0.334, and 0.38, one can infer that approx-              to analyze the effect of exchange rate policies on prices.
imately 57% of the price differential is reflected in the             As a result, understanding how goods and services re-
final consumer price if the importation is done by an                 act to policy changes proves to be critical for matters
importer rather than the consumer himself. This re-                   of economic inequality (Broda and Romalis, 2009).
sult is in line with the estimate of Auer et al. (2021a)                The results of this paper outline specific short-term
that 55% of the import price differential at the border               price instability resulting from exchange rate policy
is reflected at the retail level.                                     changes. Indeed, my analysis showed that the one-year
  Secondly, most fast-moving consumer goods (FMCG;                    price differential caused by a change of monetary pol-
such as food and beverages) reacted less than the aver-               icy follows a heterogeneous pattern between types of
age elasticity. The fact that the currency appreciation               goods. Even if the overall price level remained in an
only has a small effect on these products can be re-                  acceptable range following the Swiss Bank unpegging,
lated to the fact that many of them are produced and                  some goods such as liquid fuels, tourism products and
consumed locally, with only a small part relying on                   durable goods faced major price instability in the year
imports. This growing trend to consume local FMCG                     following the shock. As such, some industries and con-
goods can be linked to a preference for local foods dis-              sumers were affected much more heavily than others
played by many consumers (Meyerding et al., 2019).                    in the year following the policy change.
As a result, the import share and foreign-currency in-                  However, the price stability objective of many cen-
voicing share for these types of goods are low, which                 tral banks refers to time horizons larger than one year.
confirms the findings of Breinlich et al. (2019) and                  Defining the timeframes behind the usual short-term,
Auer et al. (2021a).                                                  medium-term, and long-term inflation jargon can be
  Lastly, it is interesting to note that most services                achieved by looking at specific central bank policies.
(excluding those linked to tourism such as hotels and                 The ECB currently considers a one-year horizon to
restaurants) are also affected below the overall aver-                be short, three to be medium, and above three to be
age, with elasticities ranging from 0.071 to 0.187. This              long (Stanislawska and Paloviita, 2021), which means
can be explained by the local nature of most services                 that only short-term inflation is analyzed in this paper.
(such as housing, personal care, and communication)                   While the SNB does not provide an exact horizon, the
that greatly reduces imports and expenditure switch-                  Federal Reserve of the United States publicly targets
ing. Once again, this result is in line with the afore-               medium-term inflation (Svensson, 2020). As a result,
mentioned studies.                                                    one can infer that the price stability objective of many
Oktay                                                                                                              Page 7 of 9

central banks refers to periods larger than one year, or     An important development to this analysis would
even larger than three years.                              be to analyze the persistence of sector-specific infla-
  Short-term instability of prices can sometimes be        tion after the one-year time frame to determine the
necessary to achieve long-term stability. In the case      mechanism of transition between short-term, medium-
of Switzerland, the SNB exchange rate policy change        term, and long-term inflation. Another development,
was probably conducted with long-term objectives in        which was already started by Auer et al. (2021b), is to
mind, knowing that short-term instability would fol-       analyze expenditure switching heterogeneity as a po-
low. Indeed, the peg required large amounts of foreign     tential complementary explanation for differences in
reserves, and the anticipated depreciation of the euro     price reaction, as hinted by my results on tourism.
due to the ECB new quantitative easing policy led          An additional analysis could be to use the same DID
to the unpegging choice of the SNB to avoid foreign        methodology across multiple Swiss franc shocks, in or-
reserves problems in the long run (Lleo and Ziemba,        der to understand if the same industries remain the
2015). Given the importance of foreign reserves for        most impacted ones across time in Switzerland. Fi-
small open economies, long-term stability could have       nally, replicating this empirical framework to shocks
been compromised without the exchange rate policy          in other countries to analyze spatial variations in the
change.                                                    inflation arising from exchange rate fluctuations. All of
  The results of this paper outline that specific short-   these elements would allow to better understand the
term instability should also be considered in mone-        monetary transmission mechanism in the context of
tary policymaking, with long-term objectives remain-       large changes in monetary policy, which is of impor-
ing the first target. With prices being slow to adjust     tance for central banks as well as for the general econ-
to monetary policies (Ireland, 2010) and the short-        omy where short-term fluctuations also have much of
term instability concerning only a restricted number       an impact on corporate and private budgets.
of sectors, these results do not suggest that central
banks should respond to these immediate fluctuations       Appendix
or abstain from changing monetary policy. Medium-          Table 3 Elasticities of prices to indirect exchange rates, implied
                                                           by difference-in-differences estimates
term price stability remains the most important goal of
inflation-targeting central banks, but changes of mon-      Type of goods                                     Elasticity
etary policy also need to take the short-term sector-
                                                            All-items HICP                                     0.128∗∗∗
specific fluctuations into consideration. More specifi-
                                                            Accommodation services                             0.495∗∗
cally, the petroleum industry, the tourism sector and
                                                            Actual rentals for housing                         0.154∗∗∗
the durable goods sector are expected to face more in-
                                                            Alcoholic beverages                                0.187∗∗∗
flation than others following policy-induced exchange
                                                            Audio-visual equipment                             0.508∗∗∗
rate fluctuations. Even though the general negative ef-     Beer                                               0.304∗∗∗
fect on an economy may be small, this result has large      Books                                              0.649∗∗∗
consequences on firms and customers in specific sec-        Bread and cereals                                    0.024
tors. Understanding who will be affected and quanti-        Carpets and other floor coverings                   −0.035
fying how the policy will impact their welfare should       Cleaning, repair and hire of clothing              0.118∗∗∗
thus be two important considerations of monetary pol-       Clothing                                            −0.478
icymaking, which are partially answered through this        Coffee, tea and cocoa                              0.296∗∗∗
paper and emerging literature.                              Communications                                     0.073∗∗
                                                            Cultural services                                  0.241∗∗∗
5 Conclusion                                                Education                                            0.041
Assessing whether inflation is general or specific, and     Electrical appliances                              0.334∗∗∗
whether the shock is transitory or permanent is not         Electricity, gas and other fuels                   0.495∗∗∗
an easy task for central banks, as perfectly isolating
the effect of a shock is close to impossible on macro-
level data. This paper, which manages to use some
degree of causal inference thanks to the difference-in-
differences methodology, shows that inflation impacted
some sectors much more heavily than others, outlining
the heterogeneity of prices and the need for central
banks to consider some industries more carefully than
others.
Oktay                                                                                                           Page 8 of 9

 Energy                                  0.41∗∗     Services - miscellaneous                                   0.117∗∗∗
 Equipment for sport and recreation     0.229∗∗∗    Services: communication                                    0.073∗∗
 Fish and seafood                       0.312∗∗∗    Services: housing                                          0.143∗∗∗
 Food (aggregated)                      0.105∗∗∗    Services: holidays and accommodation                       0.681∗∗∗
 Footwear                                −0.295     Services: recreation and personal care                     0.187∗∗∗
 Fruit                                  0.357∗∗     Services: transport                                          0.071
 Fuels and lubricants for transport       0.306     Solid fuels                                                0.675∗∗∗
 Furniture and furnishings               0.38∗∗∗    Spare parts and accessories for vehicles                   0.316∗∗∗
 Games, toys and hobbies                0.193∗∗∗    Spirits                                                    0.257∗∗∗
 Gardens, plants and flowers            0.181∗∗∗    Sugar, jam, honey and confectionery                         −0.08∗
 Garments                                −0.565     Telephone and telefax equipment                              0.115
 Glassware, tableware and utensils      0.118∗∗∗    Telephone and telefax services                               0.044
 Heat energy                             0.126∗     Tobacco                                                    0.185∗∗∗
 Household appliances                   0.499∗∗∗    Tools and equipment for house+garden                       0.192∗∗∗
 Household maintenance                  0.087∗∗∗    Vegetables                                                  0.456∗
 Household textiles                     0.254∗∗∗    Wine                                                       0.121∗∗∗
 Industrial goods                       0.205∗∗∗    Miscellaneous goods and services                           0.071∗∗
 Information processing equipment       0.234∗∗     Notes: DID regression following equation 1 on prices of each
 Insurance connected with transport     0.419∗∗∗    subcategory of the HICP, with Switzerland as the domestic
                                                    country and Europe (GDP-weighted average of all European
 Liquid fuels                           1.111∗∗     countries) as the counterfactual. Implied elasticities are cal-
 Maintenance and repair of dwelling     0.089∗∗∗    culated from equation 2 using the DID estimates. Respective
                                                    prices are normalized to January 2015. Pre-treatment from Jan-
 Meat                                     0.007     uary 2014 to January 2015, post-treatment from February 2015
 Medical products                       0.206∗∗∗    to December 2015. Some names have been shortened from the
                                                    HICP categories. Excludes categories for which monthly data
 Milk, cheese and eggs                   −0.022     is not fully available in 2014-2015 for Switzerland. ∗ p
Oktay                                                                                                                                         Page 9 of 9

References                                                                      Ireland, P. N. (2010). Monetary transmission mechanism. In Monetary
Abadie, A. (2005). Semiparametric difference-in-differences estimators.             economics, pages 216–223. Springer.
   The Review of Economic Studies, 72(1):1–19.                                  Khan, M. I. (2017). Falling oil prices: Causes, consequences and policy
Antonakis, J., Bendahan, S., Jacquart, P., and Lalive, R. (2010). On                implications. Journal of Petroleum Science and Engineering,
   making causal claims: A review and recommendations. The leadership               149:409–427.
   quarterly, 21(6):1086–1120.                                                  Leitemo, K. and Söderström, U. (2008). Robust monetary policy in a small
Auer, R., Burstein, A., and Lein, S. (2021a). Exchange rates and prices:            open economy. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,
   evidence from the 2015 swiss franc appreciation. American Economic               32(10):3218–3252.
   Review, 111(2):652–86.                                                       Lleo, S. and Ziemba, W. T. (2015). The swiss black swan bad scenario: Is
Auer, R., Burstein, A., Lein, S., and Vogel, J. (2021b). Unequal                    switzerland another casualty of the eurozone crisis? International
   expenditure switching: Evidence from switzerland. Working paper.                 Journal of Financial Studies, 3(3):351–380.
Baffes, J., Kose, M. A., Ohnsorge, F., and Stocker, M. (2015). The great        Lunnemann, P. and Mathä, T. Y. (2004). How persistent is disaggregate
   plunge in oil prices: Causes, consequences, and policy responses.                inflation? an analysis across eu 15 countries and hicp sub-indices.
   Technical report, World Bank Policy Research Note 15/01.                         Technical Report 415, European Central Bank.
Baggs, J., Fung, L., and Lapham, B. (2018). Exchange rates, cross-border        Massell, B. F. (1969). Price stabilization and welfare. The Quarterly
   travel, and retailers: Theory and empirics. Journal of International             Journal of Economics, 83(2):284–298.
   Economics, 115:59–79.                                                        Meyerding, S. G., Trajer, N., and Lehberger, M. (2019). What is local
Baltensperger, E. and Kugler, P. (2016). The historical origins of the safe         food? the case of consumer preferences for local food labeling of
   haven status of the swiss franc. Aussenwirtschaft, 67(2):1–30.                   tomatoes in germany. Journal of Cleaner Production, 207:30–43.
Berhold, K. and Stadtmann, G. (2018). Who put the holes in the swiss            Mirkov, N., Pozdeev, I., and Söderlind, P. (2019). Verbal interventions and
   cheese? currency crisis under appreciation pressure. Journal of Central          exchange rate policies: The case of swiss franc cap. Journal of
   Banking Theory and Practice, 7(1):43–57.                                         International Money and Finance, 93:42–54.
Bertrand, M., Duflo, E., and Mullainathan, S. (2004). How much should           Mishkin, F. S. and Schmidt-Hebbel, K. (2007). Does inflation targeting
   we trust differences-in-differences estimates? The Quarterly journal of          make a difference? Working Paper Series 12876, National Bureau of
   economics, 119(1):249–275.                                                       Economic Research.
Bhattarai, K. (2011). Impact of exchange rate and money supply on               Nakamura, E. and Steinsson, J. (2018). Identification in macroeconomics.
   growth, inflation and interest rates in the uk. International Journal of         The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(3):59–86.
   Monetary Economics and Finance, 4(4):355–371.                                Nguyen, T.-P. (2012). Exchange rate policy and the foreign exchange
Breinlich, H., Leromain, E., Novy, D., and Sampson, T. (2019). Exchange             market in Vietnam, 1985-2009. PhD thesis, Griffith University.
   rates and consumer prices: Evidence from brexit. Working paper, CEPR         Pindiriri, C. (2012). Monetary reforms and inflation dynamics in zimbabwe.
   Discussion Paper No. DP14176.                                                    International Research Journal of Finance and Economics, 90:207–222.
Broda, C. and Romalis, J. (2009). The welfare implications of rising price      Ranaldo, A. and Söderlind, P. (2010). Safe haven currencies. Review of
   dispersion. Working paper, University of Chicago.                                finance, 14(3):385–407.
Campbell, J. R. and Lapham, B. (2004). Real exchange rate fluctuations          Santana-Gallego, M., Ledesma-Rodrı́guez, F. J., and Pérez-Rodrı́guez, J. V.
   and the dynamics of retail trade industries on the us-canada border.             (2010). Exchange rate regimes and tourism. Tourism Economics,
   American Economic Review, 94(4):1194–1206.                                       16(1):25–43.
Carranza, L., Galdon-Sanchez, J. E., and Gomez-Biscarri, J. (2009).             Stanislawska, E. and Paloviita, M. (2021). Medium-vs. short-term
   Exchange rate and inflation dynamics in dollarized economies. Journal            consumer inflation expectations: evidence from a new euro area survey.
   of Development Economics, 89(1):98–108.                                          Bank of Finland Research Discussion Paper, 10.
Clarke, K. A. (2005). The phantom menace: Omitted variable bias in              Svensson, L. E. (2020). Monetary policy strategies for the federal reserve.
   econometric research. Conflict management and peace science,                     Working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research.
   22(4):341–352.                                                               Takyi, P. O. and Fosu, R. (2019). Inflation targeting monetary policy and
Day, A. E. (1986). Impact of exchange rates on air travel. International            macroeconomic performance: The case of middle-income countries.
   Journal of Hospitality Management, 5(3):115–119.                                 Applied Economics and Finance, 6:1–9.
De Gregorio, J. (2012). Price and financial stability in modern central         Turnovsky, S. J., Shalit, H., and Schmitz, A. (1980). Consumer’s surplus,
   banking. Economia, 13(1):1–11.                                                   price instability, and consumer welfare. Econometrica, pages 135–152.
Duch-Brown, N. and Martens, B. (2015). Barriers to cross-border                 Umeora, C. E. (2010). Effects of money supply and exchange rates on
   ecommerce in the eu digital single market. Technical report, Institute for       inflation in nigeria. Journal of Management and Corporate Governance,
   Prospective Technological Studies, Digital Economy Working Paper                 2.
   2015/07.                                                                     Vassileva, R. (2020). Monetary appreciation and foreign currency
Falagiarda, M., McQuade, P., and Tirpák, M. (2015). Spillovers from the            mortgages: Lessons from the 2015 swiss franc surge. European Review
   ecb’s non-standard monetary policies on non-euro area eu countries:              of Private Law, 28(1).
   evidence from an event-study analysis. ECB Working Paper 1869,               Wynne, M. A. and Rodriguez-Palenzuela, D. (2004). Measurement bias in
   European Central Bank.                                                           the hicp: what do we know and what do we need to know? Journal of
Forsyth, P. and Dwyer, L. (2010). Exchange rate changes and the cost                Economic Surveys, 18(1):79–112.
   competitiveness of international airlines: The aviation trade weighted
   index. Research in transportation economics, 26(1):12–17.
Gomez-Herrera, E., Martens, B., and Turlea, G. (2014). The drivers and
   impediments for cross-border e-commerce in the eu. Information
   Economics and Policy, 28:83–96.
Greenwood, C. (2007). How do currency exchange rates influence the price
   of holidays? Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management,
   6(4):272–273.
Hubrich, K. (2005). Forecasting euro area inflation: Does aggregating
   forecasts by hicp component improve forecast accuracy? International
   Journal of Forecasting, 21(1):119–136.
Hui, C.-H., Lo, C.-F., and Fong, T. P.-W. (2016). Swiss franc’s one-sided
   target zone during 2011–2015. International Review of Economics &
   Finance, 44:54–67.
Huntington, H. G. (2005). The economic consequences of higher crude oil
   prices. Energy modeling special report, 9.
You can also read