PRICE CONTROL IN FRANCHISED CHAINS: THE CASE OF MCDONALD'S DOLLAR MENU
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Price Control In Franchised Chains: The Case Of McDonald’s Dollar Menu∗ Itai Ater Oren Rigbi Tel Aviv University Ben-Gurion University ater@post.tau.ac.il origbi@bgu.ac.il February 9, 2010 Abstract We analyze price patterns at franchised and corporate-owned McDonald’s outlets in 1999 and 2006. We find that prices charged at franchised outlets were higher than those at corporate outlets and that the price differentials decreased substantially between 1999 and 2006 only for items with good substitutes in the Dollar Menu, which was introduced in 2002. In addition, price differentials were higher and the reduction was generally larger in outlets located near highways, where the incentive of franchisees to free-ride on McDonald’s reputation is greater. We offer two possible reasons why McDonald’s was able to induce franchisees to adopt the Dollar Menu. First, the 1997 U.S. Supreme Court Khan decision, which allowed chains to negotiate maximum prices with franchisees, improved McDonald’s bargaining power vis-à-vis franchisees. Second, the large advertising campaign that accom- panied the introduction of the Dollar Menu made it costly for franchisees not to adopt the Dollar Menu. JEL classification: L14; L22; L42; K21; M37; Keywords: Franchising; Free-Riding; Reputation; Advertising; Vertical Restraints ∗ We are thankful to Raphael Thomadsen for his comments and for kindly providing us with the 1999 data. Special thanks to Liran Einav for his guidance and support. We also received helpful comments from Ran Abramitzky, Tim Bresnahan, Peter Reiss, Assaf Eilat, David Genesove, Seema Jayachandran, Francine La- fontaine, Philip Leslie, Yaniv Yedid-Levi and participants at several universities. Ater gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Stanford Olin Law and Economics Program and the Haley and Shaw Fellowship. 1
1 Introduction “Our (corporate-owned restaurants) prices are probably, on average, 3% or 4% below our franchisees’ prices, bear in mind that we are required by law (not to).. and we never ever try to influence their (franchisees’) pricing.” 1 This paper examines price patterns in franchised and corporate-owned outlets and asks the question of how franchising chains affect prices set by franchisees. This question is particularly interesting in light of the 1997 U.S. Supreme Court State Oil Company v. Khan decision which practically allowed chains to dictate downstream prices. We use panel data to document changes in prices of several items at franchised and corporate-owned McDonald’s outlets between 1999 and 2006. We find that the price differen- tial, defined as the difference between the average price in franchised outlets and the average price in corporate-owned outlets, fell significantly only for some items. We argue that the changes in the price differentials occurred only in items that have good substitutes in the Dollar Menu which was introduced by McDonald’s in 2002. McDonald’s Dollar Menu is a collection of items that are being sold at both franchised and corporate-owned restaurants for one dollar each. Our findings suggest that the introduction of a cheap menu alternative could enhanced price uniformity across franchised and corporate-owned outlets and improved the chain’s control over downstream prices. The changes in the price differentials raise the question of why McDonald’s franchisees, who are not contractually required to, chose to adopt the Dollar Menu in 2002 and contin- ued to offer it thereafter. We offer two complementary explanations: first, we claim that the 1997 U.S. Supreme Court Khan decision improved McDonald’s bargaining power vis-à-vis franchisees thereby facilitating the introduction of the Dollar Menu. Thus, the conjecture is that franchisees, concerned that McDonald’s would dictate maximum prices, have agreed to adopt the Dollar Menu.2 Second, the large national advertising campaign that accompanied the introduction of the Dollar Menu also induced franchisees to adopt it. In particular, the suggested mechanism is that through advertising the chain informs consumers about the price 1 Matthew Paull, McDonald’s Corporation CFO at McDonald’s Earnings Conference Call, 01/24/06. See http : //seekingalpha.com for full transcript. 2 Note that franchising contracts typically last 20 years. This fact, nonetheless, could hinder immediate contractual changes. 2
they should expect. Franchisees trying to meeting consumers’ expectations consequently opt to adopt the chain’s desired price. More generally, franchisees’ profits may have increased fol- lowing the introduction of the Dollar Menu because it served as a coordinating instrument that improved price uniformity across McDonald’s outlets as well as the reputation of McDonald’s. We present evidence from one franchised outlet that supports this claim.3 The literature on franchising has postulated that outlets owned by a franchisee are more likely to face inelastic demand compared to outlets owned by the chain because franchisees may not entirely internalize the effect of their pricing decisions on the overall reputation of the chain.4 To explore this argument, we distinguish between outlets located near a highway with those located at a distance from a highway, assuming that outlets located near a highway face more inelastic demand (or serve fewer repeating customers). Consistent with this assertion, we find that in 1999 the price differentials at outlets located near highways were higher than the price differentials away from the highway. In 2006, after the introduction of the Dollar Menu, the distinct price differentials between highway and non-highway locations fell. Two basic features of the fast-food franchising industry make it suitable for exploring the ability of a chain to control downstream prices. First, a standard experience across fast- food chain outlets has been a basic ingredient of the fast-food industry’s success and growth over the last 50 years. Thus, it is natural to focus on chains’ efforts to achieve uniformity across outlets as well as to maintain and enhance their reputation. Second, McDonald’s, as many other chains, operate franchised as well as corporate-owned outlets. McDonald’s controls the prices in corporate-owned outlets, whereas franchisees set the prices at their independently owned outlets. This dual organizational structure offers a unique opportunity to test the ability of the chain to affect prices at franchised outlets by comparing the two types of outlets. Our paper contributes to three strands of the literature. The first is the literature on franchising which has explored how franchisees’ product quality and prices differ from the quality and prices in corporate-owned outlets.5 Other papers discussed the concerns of chains 3 In general, however, the effect of the introduction of low-priced items on a particular outlet profits is ambiguous. It could result in higher profits but could also be detrimental to outlets who face inelastic demand and tend to charge relatively high prices. 4 See, for example, Barron and Umbeck (1984) and Lafontaine (1995). 5 In general, the existing evidence, particularly in the fast food industry, shows that franchisees charge higher prices than corporate stores. See Lafontaine and Slade (1997) for a survey and also Kalnins (2003) and Graddy (1997). Evidence from the hotel industry in Texas (Vroom and Gimeno (2007), Conlin (2004)), however, suggests that franchised hotels charge lower prices than corporate-owned hotels. 3
over franchisees’ free-riding behavior and how chains try to mitigate this problem.6 Our panel data enables us to compare prices at franchised and corporate outlets before and after the introduction of the Dollar Menu and helps us to rule out alternative explanations for the empirical patterns found in the data.7 Furthermore, to the best of our knowledge, we are the first to provide evidence on franchisees’ free-riding behavior by comparing pricing decisions at highway and non-highway locations.8 Second, this paper contributes to the empirical literature on antitrust and vertical restraints. Imposing maximum resale price maintenance (RPM) was considered per-se illegal under the U.S. antitrust law before the 1997 U.S. Supreme Court decision in State Oil Company v. Khan which determined that maximum RPM should be examined under the rule of reason standard.9 Our findings indirectly shed light on a potential effect of this decision on the marketplace. Finally, we provide evidence on a new role for price advertising as a mechanism for alleviating organizational problems. Price advertising in franchised chains is unique because the advertising and the pricing decisions are determined by different decision makers. The chain is typically responsible for the content and scope of advertising, while the franchisees set prices.10 The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides information on McDonald’s Dollar Menu and describes the data used in the paper. The estimation results of the Dollar Menu’s effect on prices, the sales data analysis and the analysis exploring prices near a highway are presented in Section 3. In Section 4, we discuss our results and offer concluding remarks. 6 See, for example, Brickley and Dark (1987), Rubin (1978), Brickley (1999), Klein and Leffler (1981), La- fontaine and Shaw (2005) as well as the survey by Lafontaine and Slade (2005). 7 A closely related paper is Jin and Leslie (2009), who study the effect of an exogenous change in consumers’ information on restaurants’ incentives to maintain good hygienic quality. 8 We also find, unlike Brickley and Dark (1987), that McDonald’s corporate-owned restaurants are more likely to be located near highways, presumably to address potential free-riding behavior by franchisees. 9 For a detailed review of the legal history of maximum resale price restraints see Blair and Lafontaine (1999). 10 See Steiner (1973), Farris and Albion (1980) as well as Levy and Young (2004) for related arguments. 4
2 Dollar Menu and Data 2.1 McDonald’s Dollar Menu McDonald’s Dollar Menu is a collection of 6 to 8 menu items that are sold for one dollar each. The Dollar Menu accounts for 14% of McDonald’s sales in the U.S.11 and it represents 10%-15% of McDonald’s total advertising expenditure.12 The Dollar Menu was introduced nationwide in September 2002 following a six quarter-period of relatively poor sales performance. According to industry news reports, the Dollar Menu was an attempt to boost sluggish sales and cripple Burger King, McDonald’s main rival.13 The Dollar Menu usually includes two main dishes - a Double Cheeseburger and a McChicken sandwich, together with side dishes and desserts, such as Small Fries, Small Soft Drink, Side Salad, Apple Pie and Sundae.14 To promote the Dollar Menu introduction, McDonald’s added $20 million to its advertising budget in the last quarter of 2002. McDonald’s 2002 annual financial report explained the 2002 increase in expenses as follows: “The increase in 2002 was primarily due to ... higher advertising expenses in the U.S. primarily related to the introduction of the Dollar Menu.” Launching a large advertising campaign, such as the Dollar Menu campaign, requires the support of the majority of franchisees. The setting of actual prices, however, remains at the discretion of each franchisee. McDonald’s corporate officer was willing to say that franchisees are encouraged to adopt the Dollar Menu.15 11 According to McDonald’s CEO, Ralph Alavarez, Dow Jones Newswires, 10/19/07. 12 McDonald’s Earnings Conference Call, 01/24/06. See http : //seekingalpha.com for full transcript. 13 James Cantalupo, McDonald’s CEO at the time the Dollar Menu was introduced was cited saying: “We like to wear out our competitors with our price”, Business Week, 03/03/03. In addition, Mike Roberts, McDonald’s U.S. president, called the Dollar Menu introduction campaign the most important endeavor he has led, “I believe we can no longer afford to wait on incremental gains. We need radical movement now.”, Advertising Age, 9/2/2002. 14 According to the New-York Times, the Double Cheeseburger has become McDonald’s most ordered item since the Dollar Menu was introduced. New York Times, 04/19/2006. 15 Unlike McDonald’s, Burger King Corporation forced its franchisees to adopt the Value Meal when it was introduced in 2006. The United States Court of Appeals for the eleventh circuit (Burger King Corporation v. E-Z Eating (11th Cir. 2009)) confirmed recently Burger King’s right to impose maximum prices on its franchisees: “There is simply no question that Burger King Corporation had the power and authority under the Franchise Agreements to impose the Value Menu on its franchisees.” 5
2.2 Data We constructed our data from several sources. Our main data set is an original panel data set collected in July 1999 (Thomadsen (2005)) and July 2006 regarding the location, price menu, and outlet characteristics16 of all the hamburger outlets which are chain-affiliated in Santa Clara County, California.17 In addition, we also use data on the number of outlets operated in the Santa Clara County by the sandwich chains Subway and Quizno’s. All the outlets in Santa Clara County except one offer the Dollar Menu.18 In the empirical analysis, we examine price patterns at McDonald’s outlets while the data on the other chains are used to determine the competitive environment of an outlet. We collected the 2006 data by visiting all the outlets in the Santa Clara County and documenting the menu prices and characteristics of the outlet.19 Ownership data were obtained by cross-referencing several public records.20 Data on outlets are supplemented by zip code demographic data, including median household income, median rent contracts, population density, share of the population below the age of 18, fraction of males and blacks as well as a dine out spending potential index.21 In addition, we use sales and costs data from one McDonald’s franchised outlet which adopted the Dollar Menu. The sales data include prices, the quantities sold for each item and the number of cashier transactions in that outlet for all the months between June 2001 and June 2006. The number of cashier transactions is used as a measure of the number of customers patronizing the outlet in a particular month. The cost data correspond to the food and paper cost of each item for each month in 2007. Table 3 displays the number of corporate and franchised McDonald’s outlets in 1999 and in 2006 in the Santa Clara County, entry and exit patterns and ownership distribution of franchised outlets. The table illustrates that there were no major changes in the number of operating outlets as well as in the number of outlets operated by each franchisee. In 16 The observed outlet characteristics are: number of seats, the presence of a playground, the presence of a drive-thru, the availability of wireless service at the outlet and whether the outlet is located in a mall. 17 There are about 300 outlets and the chains are: Burger-King, Carl’s Jr., In-N-Out, Jack-in-the-Box, Mc- Donald’s and Wendy’s. 18 The only outlet that has not offered the Dollar Menu is a franchised outlet located in the Stanford Shopping Center. 19 Outlet locations were obtained from chains’ websites as well as from business locator services, such as Google Maps and Yahoo Local Maps. Prices were photographed (when permitted) and a subset of prices were copied when taking photographs was not possible. 20 For each outlet we observe whether it is franchised or corporate-owned and the owner’s identity. Ownership data were assembled from the Assessor Office and the Public Health Department in Santa Clara County. 21 Zip code demographics were obtained from the 2000 Census data and 2005 Community Sourcebook America. 6
Table 4 we compare descriptive demographic data and outlet characteristics between corporate and franchised outlets. Overall, the comparison suggests that franchised and corporate outlets are located in similar environments. One notable exception is that a corporate-owned outlet is more likely to be located near a highway. Presumably if the chain is concerned about free-riding behavior near highways, it may choose to locate corporate restaurants near highways. 3 Empirical Analysis We focus on changes in franchisee’s price differentials which we define as the difference between the average price at a franchised outlet and the average price at a corporate-owned outlet. We first examine the price differentials for all the meals that were offered in both 1999 and 2006 and then use the sales data to explain the price patterns we find. We then explore how the price differentials varied and changed across outlets located near a highway and at a distance from a highway. Finally, we examine how profits and revenues changed before and after the Dollar Menu was introduced. 3.1 Price Patterns Across Adopting Outlets 3.1.1 Descriptive Statistics Table 5 displays descriptive statistics of the Big-Mac meal price. As the table shows, the price differential for the Big-Mac meal decreased from 44 cents in 1999 to 23 cents in 2006. Also the standard deviation of the Big-Mac meal prices at corporate-owned and franchised outlets dropped from 26 cents and 29 cents in 1999 to 13 cents and 18 cents in 2006, respectively.22 We also present the kernel densities of the Big-Mac meal price in franchised and corporate-owned outlets in both time periods in Figure 2. The Figure illustrates how the Big-Mac meal price had increased from 1999 to 2006 and how the two price distributions approached each other over time. 22 The price differential for the Double Cheeseburger – a Dollar Menu item – was 8 cents in 1999 and in 2006 it dropped to zero in the outlets that adopted the Dollar Menu. 7
3.1.2 Regression Analysis We utilize the following SUR differences-in-differences specification to test the changes in prices between 1999 and 2006: ln(pjit ) = α+γ ∗D2006,it +δ ∗Df ranchised,it +η ∗D2006,it ∗Df ranchised,it +β ∗Xit +θ ∗Compit +jit (1) This specification examines changes in prices of meals that were offered in both 1999 and 2006. pjit is the price of meal j in outlet i in year t. D2006,it is a dummy variable equal to 1 for observations collected in 2006. Df ranchised,it is a dummy variable equal to 1 if outlet i was a franchised outlet in year t. Xit is a vector containing outlet i characteristics in year t including the number of seats, the existence of a drive-thru, the existence of a playground, whether the outlet is located in a mall and demographic variables of the zip code in which the outlet is located. The competition vector Compit consists of the number of a rival’s outlets operating in the vicinity of each McDonald’s outlet. The set of rivals includes the following chains: Burger- King, McDonald’s (divided into corporate-owned and franchised outlets), other hamburger chains as well as jointly Subway and Quizno’s.23 The inclusion of Subway and Quizno’s in the set of rivals potentially controls for health-conscious changes in the tastes of the population between 1999 and 2006. Table 6 presents the estimation results when the logarithm of the Big-Mac meal price is used as the dependent variable. We find that conditional on outlet characteristics and demographics, the price differential for the Big-Mac meal decreased by 9.3%, from 12.5% in 1999 to 3.2% in 2006. Other outlet and demographic characteristics are typically insignificant with the exception of the positive coefficient on the Subway and Quizno’s medium competitor variable as well as the negative coefficients on the number of close Burger- King restaurants, the number of close McDonald’s franchised outlets24 and the fraction of blacks in the population. Table 7 displays the results for the other meals and demonstrates two interesting patterns: for the Quarter Pounder and the Double Quarter Pounder meals, we find that the price differentials dropped significantly from 7.7% to 1.4% and 7.6% to 2.7%, 23 We present estimation results including three competition variables; close competitors, medium competitors and far competitors defined as the number of competitors an outlet has within 0.1 mile, 0.1-0.5 mile and 0.5-1 mile, respectively. We experimented with several other criteria for the level of competition (e.g. perimeters around each outlet) as well as with alternative ways to define the set of rivals. None of these modifications changed the main results. 24 Thomadsen (2007) also examined numerically how fast food prices change with the proximity of rivals. 8
respectively. However, for the regressions of the Fillet-O-Fish, Chicken McNuggets 6 pc. and Chicken McNuggets 20 pc. we find the following statistically insignificant changes: 2.3% to 1.6%, 5.9% to 5.1% and 2.6% to 1.8%, respectively. Thus, the empirical evidence on the changes in the price differential for menu items is mixed: for some items the price differential fell, while for others it remained stable.25 3.2 Explaining the Variation in Price Changes across Items To explain the observed distinct patterns in different items, we now turn to analyzing the sales data. In Figure 3 we present a time series of the proportion of cashier transactions, interpreted as the percentage of customers who bought a particular item for the following meals: Big-Mac, Quarter Pounder, Chicken McNuggets 6 pc., Fillet-O-Fish as well as a combined measure of the Dollar Menu items; namely, Double Cheeseburger and the McChicken sandwich. Each item measure is normalized based on its own August 2002 sales – the month prior to the in- troduction of the Dollar Menu. The percentage of customers purchasing Double Cheeseburger skyrocketed from from 0.4% to 14.6% between August 2002 to March 2004. Also, the propor- tion of McChicken transactions increased from 11.17% to 21.44%.26 Over the same period of time the proportion of transactions in which the Big-Mac meal was sold dropped from 8.69% to 5.8%. On the other hand, meals with fairly stable share in the store transactions have not experienced a change in their price differential.27 For example, the proportion of transactions for the Fillet-O-Fish changed slightly from 3.89% to 3.84%. Overall, the Figure strongly sug- gests that the increase in sales of the Dollar Menu items is largely driven by customers who had substituted from the Big-Mac and the Quarter Pounder meals.28 25 The observed changes in prices between 1999 and 2006 may be driven by changes only in a subset of the outlets in our sample. To check whether price outliers drive our results, we perform the regression analysis excluding observations with the highest and lowest prices. We find that the results are unchanged. Furthermore, the results are almost identical if we only use data from outlets that operated in both time periods. 26 One explanation for this difference is the fact that the price of the McChicken sandwich has not changed, whereas the price of the double cheeseburger dropped by 50% following the introduction of the Dollar Menu. The prices of the Big Mac, Quarter Pounder and McNuggets 6pc. meals were the same with identical 3 price increments occurring between August 2002 and March 2007. The total price change was 30 cents, roughly 7%. The Fillet-O-Fish meal price also changed 3 times over the period by 30 cents, an overall increase of 8%. 27 Matthew Paull, McDonald’s CFO at the time the Dollar Menu was introduced, acknowledged in a conference call to analysts: “(The Dollar Menu) brought in a lot of customers who might not have otherwise visited us. (But) We have seen a small drop in sales of our signature sandwiches, things like the Big-Mac and the Quarter Pounder with Cheese. We’re not thrilled with that.” “Restaurant Business”, 01/28/03. 28 We also conducted a survey among 104 undergraduate students to explore the substitution patterns between the Chicken McNuggets meal, the Big-Mac meal and the Dollar Menu items. The survey itself and the results 9
Importantly, using panel data with observations from the same geographic area en- ables us to rule out alternative explanations which rely on time-invariant unobservable price determinants including unobservable factors affecting the decision where to locate corporate and franchised outlets. Furthermore, since the price differentials of only a subset of the items changed, a possible alternative explanation should be based on a change in unobservables af- fecting only this subset of items.29 A potential concern is that the ownership structure of franchised outlets changed between 1999 and 2006.30 As can be seen in Panel B of Table 3 there were no significant changes in the ownership structure. Accordingly, when we include the number of outlets owned by a franchisee our main results do not change. We also performed the same basic empirical analysis for Jack-in-the-Box, the only ham- burger chain in the Santa Clara County, apart from McDonald’s, which operates a mixture of corporate-owned and franchised outlets. We found that the price differential between fran- chised and corporate outlets for the Jumbo Jack meal, the signature dish of Jack-in-the-Box, has fallen significantly from 6% in 1999 to 1.3% in 2006. This finding is consistent with the introduction of Jack-in-the-Box Value Meal at the end of 2001. 3.3 Repeat Customers Analysis To shed light on a potential reason why franchisees set higher prices than corporate-owned restaurants, we analyze prices at franchised and corporate outlets located near and at a distance from a highway. Our interpretation is that franchised outlets located near highways cater to fewer repeat customers and face relatively inelastic demand. As such, these franchisees have an incentive to free-ride on the chain’s reputation by charging higher prices.31 Df ar−f rom−highway,i are presented in Appendix A: 82% of the respondents who chose the Big-Mac meal before the Dollar Menu was available switched to a Dollar Menu option after it was introduced to them. On the other hand, only 53% of the Chicken McNuggets choosers switched to a Dollar Menu option when it was available. We compare the mean of the two groups and reject the null hypothesis of mean equality at 1% confidence level. 29 Hence, for example, a change in outlets’ royalties paid to McDonald’s cannot explain the different pat- terns because an outlet’s royalties are determined based on a total outlet sales rather than on per item basis. Furthermore, conversations with franchisees confirm that in recent years there were no relevant changes in the contractual arrangement between franchisees and the chain or in the cost structure of franchisees. 30 A single franchisee owning several franchised outlets may internalize the positive demand externality and charge lower prices. Alternatively, a franchisee owning several outlets in the same geographical area may choose higher prices because of internalizing the business stealing effect. 31 The 2000 Bay Area Travel Survey, available at www.mtc.ca.gov, reports that 60% of trips on the 101 Highway, one of the two main highways in Santa Clara County, are not home-work trips. Brickley and Dark (1987), among others, previously used the distance from a highway as a proxy for repeat business. 10
equals one if an outlet is located more than 0.25 miles from a highway exit and zero otherwise. Specifically, we employ the following SUR heterogenous difference-in-difference specification: ln(pjit ) =α + γ1 ∗ Df ar−f rom−highway,i + γ2 ∗ Df ranchised,it + γ3 ∗ D2006,it + γ4 ∗ Df ar−f rom−highway,i ∗ Df ranchised,it + γ5 ∗ Df ar−f rom−highway,i ∗ D2006,it + γ6 ∗ Df ranchised,it ∗ D2006,it + γ7 ∗ Df ar−f rom−highway,i ∗ Df ranchised,it ∗ D2006,it + β ∗ Xit + θ ∗ Compit + jit (2) The results for the three meals whose price differential were affected by the Dollar Menu are shown in Table 8. They are consistent with the argument that franchised outlets located near highways cater to fewer repeat customers and hence charge higher prices than franchised outlets located at a distance from a highway. The results may also suggest that the introduction of the Dollar Menu was particularly effective in reducing the price differentials of outlets that initially charged relatively high prices such as those located near a highway. For example, in 1999 the Big-Mac price differential near a highway was 15.2% (γ2 ) and in 2006 it fell to 4.5% (γ2 + γ6 ). At outlets located at a distance from a highway, the price differential in 1999 was only 11% (γ2 + γ4 ) and 2.8% (γ2 + γ4 + γ6 + γ7 ) in 2006.32 Finally, to examine pricing decisions when consumers can be characterized as having highly inelastic demand, we present in Appendix B price data from restaurants located at airports.33 We find that franchised and corporate-owned restaurants at airports set higher prices than the restaurants in the Santa Clara county, and that none of them adopted the Dollar Menu. Given that payments to the chain are determined as percentage of sales, the chain is probably better off charging very high prices at outlets facing highly inelastic demand. In particular, this would happen if the additional revenues generated at these locations offsets 32 One might suspect that the effect attributed to repeat business is driven by the higher costs that franchisees incur near a highway. McDonald’s corporation owns the premises of both franchised and corporate units. The royalties franchisees pay to the chain are typically determined based on the cohort of the contract rather than on a particular characteristics of an outlet location. Furthermore, McDonald’s franchisees and the chain purchase their inputs from the same certified suppliers and at equal terms. Therefore, higher costs near a highway are unlikely to explain the observed price differentials. 33 The airport data, however, include only post Dollar Menu prices. 11
the negative effect on its reputation due to these high prices.34 3.4 The Impact of the Dollar Menu on Revenues and Profits Though the paper focuses on prices at franchised and corporate-owned outlets, a related ques- tion is whether all or only a subset of franchisees benefited from the introduction of the Dollar Menu. If the Dollar Menu was instrumental in coordinating prices among McDonald’s outlets and in enhancing price uniformity then all franchisees may have increased their profits. Al- ternatively, the Dollar Menu may have been used to discipline astray franchisees, who would otherwise gain from their ability to free-ride on the reputation of the chain. In this case, some franchisees gain and others lose from the introduction of the Dollar Menu. The chain, unlike franchisees, attempts to maximize franchisees’ revenues because royalties are determined based on an outlet’s sales. To shed light on the effect of the Dollar Menu on revenues and profits, we utilize cost data from the a single franchised outlet. In Figure 4 we present a plot of the revenues and profits of 20 top selling items normalized to their August 2002 level.35 As can be seen in the Figure, the increase in outlet revenues were consistently higher than the respective profit change following the introduction of the Dollar Menu. For example, the revenues increased by 18% between August 2002 and June 2003, whereas profits have increased by only 11%. 4 Discussion and Concluding Remarks Economists and legal scholars devoted considerable effort to studying the relationship between vertically related firms, like franchisors and franchisees, and to highlighting potential conflicts regarding downstream prices. Historically, franchisees have set prices at their own outlets and the chain could determine prices only at corporate-owned outlets. When choosing prices at its corporate-owned units, the chain faces a tradeoff between maintaining the chain’s reputation for low prices and enhancing price uniformity and between the additional profits the chain could 34 Consistent with this view, when Burger King corporation introduced its Value Meal in 2006, it exempted franchised restaurants located in highly seasonal tourist destinations from offering the Dollar Menu, see Burger King Corporation v. E-Z Eating (11th Cir. 2009). 35 We observe monthly cost data for 2007 only. Thus, the cost data used to calculate profits are taken from a randomly selected month. For example, the unit cost of Big-Mac, Double CheeseBurger, 6 McNuggets, small coke and large fries are: 58, 50, 49, 9 and 28 cents, respectively. 12
generate from setting prices that would maximize local profits. Franchisees, who maximize their outlet profits net of royalties, probably assign a lower weight to the chain’s reputation than the chain does. Consequently, franchisees may set prices which are sub-optimal from the point of view of the chain thereby encouraging the chain to affect franchisees’ prices.36 The tension between upstream and downstream firms was brought in front of the U.S. Supreme Court in the matter of State Oil v. Khan. In its decision the Supreme Court37 allowed firms, which were previously prohibited, to set maximum prices at the downstream market. We exploit the introduction of McDonald’s Dollar Menu in 2002 to test changes in prices of several items sold at franchised and corporate-owned outlets. We find that the price differential, defined as the difference between the average price in franchised outlets and the average price in corporate-owned outlets, fell between 1999 and 2006 only for items that have good substitutes in the Dollar Menu. For example, the price differential of the Big-Mac meal decreased from 12.5% in 1999 to 3.2% in 2006, whereas the price differential of the Fillet-O- Fish remained stable over the same time period. We also show that the price differentials were larger at outlets located near highways and that the distinct price differentials between highway and non-highway locations fell in 2006. Thus, our paper offers a potential avenue through which the U.S. Supreme Court decision in State Oil Company v. Khan affected the marketplace, suggesting that the Supreme Court decision may have led franchisees (who are not contractually required) to adopt the Dollar Menu. Importantly, the improved control of the chain over prices set at its franchised outlets is not necessarily at the expense of franchisees and may actually result in higher profits for both the chain and its franchisees. We present evidence from one outlet that supports this view. 36 There are additional reasons why chains may be interested in influencing franchisees’ prices. First, to eliminate double marginalization. Second, to increase franchisees’ sales because chains extract their revenues as a percentage of the sales revenue rather than the profits of franchisees. See, however, Schmidt (1994) who argues that the chain can determine the combination of competition level and royalty that maximizes the vertical relationship profits. 37 Overruling Albercht v. Herald Company (1968), 390 U.S. 145. 13
References Barron, J. M. and Umbeck, J. R.: 1984, The effects of different contractual arrangements: The case of retail gasoline markets, Journal of Law and Economics 27(2), 313–328. Blair, R. D. and Lafontaine, F.: 1999, Will khan foster or hinder franchising? an economic analysis of maximum resale price maintenance, Journal of Public Policy and Marketing 18(1), 25–36. Brickley, J. A.: 1999, Incetive conflicts and contractual restraints: Evidence from franchising, Journal of Law and Economics 42(745-774). Brickley, J. A. and Dark, F. H.: 1987, The choice of organizational form: The case of franchis- ing, Journal of Financial Economics 18(2), 401–420. Conlin, M.: 2004, The effect of franchising on competition: An empirical analysis. Farris, P. W. and Albion, M. S.: 1980, The impact of advertising on the price of consumer products, Journal of Marketing 44, 17–35. Graddy, K.: 1997, do fast-food chains price discriminate on the race and income characteristics of an area, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 15(4), 391–401. Jin, G. and Leslie, P.: 2009, Reputational incentives for restaurant hygiene, American Eco- nomic Journal: Microeconomics 1(1), 237–267. Kalnins, A.: 2003, Hamburger prices and spatial econometrics, Journal of Economics & Man- agement Strategy 12, 591–616. Klein, B. and Leffler, K. B.: 1981, The role of market forces in assuring contractual perfor- mance, Journal of Political Economy 89(4), 615–641. Lafontaine, F.: 1995, Pricing decision in franchised chains: A look at the restaurant and fast-food industry, NBER Working Paper 5247 . Lafontaine, F. and Shaw, K. L.: 2005, Targeting managerial control: Evidence from franchising, RAND Journal of Economics 36(1), 131–150. 14
Lafontaine, F. and Slade, M.: 1997, Retail contracting: Theory and practice, Journal of Industrial Economics 45(1), 1–25. Lafontaine, F. and Slade, M.: 2005, Exclusive contracts and vertical restraints: Empirical evi- dence and public policy, Forthcoming, Handbook of Antitrust Economics, Paolo Buccirossi (ed.) Cambridge: MIT Press . Levy, D. and Young, A. T.: 2004, The real thing: Nominal price rigidity of the nickel coke, 1886-1959, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 36(4), 765–799. Rubin, P. H.: 1978, The theory of the firm and the structure of the franchise contract, Journal of Law and Economics 21, 223–233. Schmidt, T.: 1994, An analysis of intrabrand competition in the franchise industry, Review of Industrial Organization 9, 293–310. Steiner, R. L.: 1973, Does advertising lower consumer prices?, Journal of Marketing 37, 19–26. Thomadsen, R.: 2005, The effect of ownership structure on prices in geographically differenti- ated industries, RAND Journal of Economics 36(4), 908–929. Thomadsen, R.: 2007, Product positioning and competition: The role of location in the fast food industry, Marketing Science 26(6), 792–804. Vroom, G. and Gimeno, J.: 2007, Ownership form, managerial incentives, and the intensity of rivalry, Academy of Management Journal 50(4), 901–922. 15
A Survey Results The survey, aiming to find substitution patterns between McDonald’s items, was conducted among 104 undergraduate students at Stanford University in late April 2007.38 The survey and a summary of the responses are presented in Figure 1 and Table 1. Table 1: Survey Response Big Mac Chicken McNuggets Dbl. CheeseBurger McChicken Enlarged Dbl. CheeseBurger Enalrged McChicken Meal Meal Dollar Menu Meal Dollar Menu Meal Dollar Menu Meal Dollar Menu Meal Big Mac Meal 0.18 0 0.39 0.14 0.21 0.07 Chicken McNuggets 0 0.47 0.13 0.21 0.06 0.13 The Table contains a summary of the responses to the survey we conducted. The (i, j) entry of the table is the proportion of respondents that chose option j from the extended menu conditional on choosing option i from the base menu. Among the 56 respondents who chose Big-Mac meal as their first choice, 46 (82%) switched to a Dollar Menu option once it was offered to them. On the other hand, only 25 (53%) out of the 47 respondents who chose Chicken McNuggets switched to a Dollar Menu option. We perform group mean comparison tests and reject in 1% significance level the null hypothesis that the percentage of respondents who switch to Dollar Menu option is the same for respondents that choose Big-Mac meal and for those who choose Chicken McNuggets. We reject the null hypothesis even when we test for mean difference over respondents that visit McDonald’s at least few times a year. 38 We use prices from the only outlet in Santa Clara county that did not introduce the Dollar Menu to control for price changes in the Big-Mac meal and the Chicken McNuggets meal that occurred following the introduction of the Dollar Menu. 16
Figure 1: Survey Hi Students, We are running a study on individuals’ fast food preferences, and would highly appreciate your help in filling the short questionnaire below. Note that there are no right or wrong answers, your participation is voluntary. You enter a McDonald’s restaurant and need to choose among the following two available standard meals (each containing an entrée + medium fries + medium soda) A. Big Mac Meal ($4.59) B. Chicken McNuggets (6 piece) Meal ($4.29) 1. Which one of the four meals above would you choose? ___ The next time you enter a McDonald’s outlet you discover that McDonald’s introduced two new Dollar Menu Meal options. Dollar Menu Meal can be one of two options: - Dollar Menu Meal - one small entrée + medium fries + medium soda for $3.00 - Enlarged Dollar Menu Meal - two small entrées + medium fries + medium soda for $4.00 Therefore, you now have the following six options to choose from (two regular meals and four Dollar Menu Meals): A. Big Mac Meal ($4.59) B. Chicken McNuggets (6 piece) Meal ($4.29) C. Double Cheeseburger Dollar Menu Meal – Double Cheeseburger + medium fries + medium soda ($3.00) D. McChicken Dollar Menu Meal - McChicken + medium fries + medium soda ($3.00) E. Enlarged Double Cheeseburger Dollar Menu Meal – Two Double Cheeseburgers + one medium fries + one medium soda ($4.00) F. Enlarged McChicken Dollar Menu Meal – Two McChicken + one medium fries + one medium soda ($4.00) 2. Which option would you choose? ____ 3. In case your preferred option is not available, which other option would you choose instead? ______ 4. How often do you eat at McDonald’s or other fast food chains? 1. Once a week or more 2. Once a month or more 3. A few times a year 4. Hardly ever or never Answer: ____ Thank you for your cooperation! 17
B Airport Data We collected data from McDonald’s restaurants located in the 35 largest U.S. airports in September-October 2007. The data indicate whether each restaurant offers the Dollar Menu, prices of a Big-Mac meal and a Double CheeseBurger, ownership information as well as whether an airport employee discount is offered. We assume that restaurants located at airports serve highly inelastic demand.39 Two interrelated implications of facing highly inelastic demand are higher prices and lower incentive to offer the Dollar Menu. Note also that the chain may be better off charging high prices if the additional revenues generated more than offset the potential harm to its reputation. While 59 out of the 60 McDonald’s restaurants located in Santa Clara County offer the Dollar Menu, none of the 41 McDonald’s restaurants located at airports chooses to offer it. The average price (including tax) of a Double Cheeseburger at an airport restaurant is 1.95 dollar compared to an average price of 1.12 dollar at non-airport restaurants. Another suggestive evidence that airport restaurants have little incentive to induce repeat business is their usage of an airport employee discount. Nearly 90% of airport restaurants offer an airport employee discount. These discounts vary across outlets within an airport and typically depends on the price of the item.40 By screening airport employees as potential repeating customers that have more elastic demand, airport restaurants can charge passengers higher prices and not offer the Dollar Menu. Table 2 displays descriptive statistics of the prices charged at McDonald’s airport restaurants.41 39 The inelastic demand can be driven by fewer repeat customers, less competition and higher customer average income. For example, a survey of 1,900 departing passengers at Denver International Airport reports that, on average, passengers travel through the airport less than four times a year. The report is available at http : www.f lydenver.com/diabiz/bizops/documents/concesSurvey.pdf 40 The typical discount is calculated as a percentage share of the price, 5% - 10%, although some offer an absolute price discount. Some restaurants offer different discounts depending on the item price. 41 We also sampled few McDonald’s restaurants in Santa Clara County in September 2007 and verified that prices have not significantly changed since July 2006. 18
Table 2: Summary Statistics - Airport Restaurants Big‐Mac Meal Double Cheeseburger Corp. Fran. Corp. Fran. Mean 5.23 5.92 2.07 1.93 Std. 0.35 0.54 0.25 0.37 10th % 5.03 5.14 1.81 1.49 90th % 5.65 6.81 2.29 2.26 N 4 34 4 34 The Table presents descriptive statistics for the (with tax) nominal Big-Mac meal and the Double Cheeseburger prices in McDonald’s restaurants located in U.S. airports during September 2007. None of these restaurants offers the Dollar Menu. Prices are significantly higher at airport restaurants compared to non-airport restaurants as presented in Table 5 19
Table 3: Ownership Structure and Exit/Entry Patterns Panel A: Entry and Exit Patterns 1999 Exit Entry 2006 Corporate 26 4 0 22 Franchised 36 3 5 38 Panel B: Size of Franchisees 1999 2006 # Outlets/Franchisee # Franchisees # Outlets/Franchisee # Franchisees 11 1 8 1 6 1 7 1 3 2 5 1 1 13 3 1 2 1 1 13 Panel A presents entry and exit patterns of McDonald’s outlets in Santa Clara County, divided into franchised and corporate-owned outlets. In panel B we show the distributions of outlets owned by franchisees in 1999 and 2006. While changes in the number of outlets owned by each franchisee may lead to changes in their pricing decisions, the data suggest that there were no major changes in the ownership structure between 1999 and 2006. 20
Table 4: Ownership Structure and Outlet Characteristics Charactersitics Corporate Franchised t-Stat. Income (zipcode) 78910 73145 1.43 Rent (zipcode) 1204 1126 1.55 Dineout Index (zipode) 167 164 0.30 Population Density (1,000s/Sq. Mile) (zipode) 8.39 8.16 0.76 Proportion of Children (Up to Age 18) (zipode) 0.21 0.21 0.13 % Male (zipode) 0.51 0.51 0.95 % Black (zipode) 0.03 0.03 1.43 Drive Through 0.65 0.67 -0.11 # Seats 87 114 -0.86 Mall 0.04 0.05 -0.14 Playground 0.43 0.33 0.79 Distance from Highway (Mile) 0.57 0.89 -1.79 Far from Highway 0.65 0.77 -0.99 Close BK Competitors 0.14 0.03 1.69 Medium BK Competitors 0.14 0.26 -1.09 Far BK Competitors 0.36 0.28 0.57 Close MD Corp. Competitors 0.09 0.00 1.94 Medium MD Corp. Competitors 0.05 0.00 1.34 Far MD Corp. Competitors 0.09 0.00 1.94 Close MD Fran. Competitors 0.00 0.03 -0.75 Medium MD Fran. Competitors 0.00 0.08 -1.33 Far MD Fran. Competitors 0.00 0.23 -2.23 Close Other Burger Competitors 0.14 0.13 0.09 Medium Other Burger Competitors 0.50 0.38 0.67 Far Other Burger Competitors 0.64 0.77 -0.66 Close Sandwich Competitors 0.09 0.18 -0.93 Medium Sandwich Competitors 0.36 0.08 2.95 Far Sandwich Competitors 0.14 0.46 -2.19 The Table presents characteristics of franchised and corporate-owned outlets in 1999. For example, the average zipcode income where corporate outlets are located is $ 78,910, whereas it is $ 73,145 for franchised outlets. The average number of far – within 0.5-1 mile – Burger King competitors is 0.36 for corporate outlets and 0.28 for franchised outlets. We cannot reject the null hypothesis that the two types of ownership are located in the same environment (p-value=0.14). The right column shows the t-statistic obtained from testing the null hypothesis that franchised and corporate outlets face the same corresponding characteristic. Interestingly, the likelihood that a corporate outlet will be located closer to the highway is significantly higher. Presumably, the chain chooses to locate corporate outlets near highways to mitigate free-riding concerns by franchisees at these locations. 21
Table 5: Summary Statistics - Big-Mac Meal Price in Santa Clara County 1999 2006 Corp. Fran. Corp. Fran. Mean 3.33 3.77 4.69 4.92 Std. 0.26 0.29 0.13 0.18 10th % 3.24 3.46 4.54 4.65 90th % 3.46 4.11 4.87 5.09 t-stat. 6.01 4.91 The Table presents descriptive statistics for the (with tax) nominal Big-Mac meal prices that were collected in July 1999 and July 2006 from all McDonald’s outlets in Santa Clara County. Franchisee’s price differential, defined as the difference between the average price in franchised outlets and the average price in corporate outlets, decreased from 44 cents in 1999 to 23 cents in 2006. The standard deviation of the Big-Mac meal price dropped from 26 cents in 1999 to 13 cents in 2006 for corporate-owned outlets, and from 29 cents to 18 cents in franchised outlets. 22
Table 6: Franchisees’ Price Differential for the Big-Mac Meal - Full Estimation Results Dependent Variable: ln(Big Mac Meal) Dependent Variable: ln(Big Mac Meal) D_2006 0.343*** Close Other Sandwich 0.006 (0.016) (0.010) D_franchised 0.125*** Medium Other Sandwich 0.039*** (0.015) (0.014) D_franchised*D_2006 -0.093*** Far Other Sandwich -0.003 (0.017) (0.007) Close BK Competitors -0.070*** Drive Thru 0.016 (0.021) (0.012) Medium BK Competitors 0.008 # Seats -0.000 (0.014) (0.000) Far BK Competitors 0.008 Mall -0.028 (0.009) (0.052) Close MD Corporate 0.020 Playground -0.006 (0.028) (0.013) Medium MD Corporate 0.013 log(Median HH Income) -0.000 (0.020) (0.000) Far MD Corporate -0.001 log(Median Rent Contract) 0.000 (0.016) (0.000) Close MD Franchised -0.072*** Dineout Spending Index 0.001 (0.020) (0.000) Medium MD Franchised -0.019 Population Density -0.006 (0.034) (0.007) Far MD Franchised 0.032** % Children 0.088 (0.014) (0.250) Close Other Hamburger -0.002 % Male 0.479 (0.011) (0.408) Medium Other Hamburger -0.000 % Black -0.936* (0.009) (0.566) Far Other Hamburger 0.002 (0.007) R2 0.94 N 114 Standard errors in parentheses *** p
Table 7: Franchisees’ Price Differentials Dependent Variable ln(Double Quarter ln(Quarter Pounder ln(Fillet‐O‐Fish ln(McNuggets ln(McNuggets Pounder Meal) Meal) Meal) 6pc.) 20pc.) D_2006 0.255*** 0.091*** 0.246*** 0.209*** 0.126*** (0.013) (0.013) (0.011) (0.017) (0.010) D_franchised 0.076*** 0.077*** 0.023** 0.059*** 0.026*** (0.012) (0.012) (0.011) (0.011) (0.009) D_franchised*D_2006 ‐0.049*** ‐0.063*** ‐0.007 ‐0.008 ‐0.008 ( (0.014)) ((0.014)) ((0.013)) ((0.023)) ((0.011)) 24 R2 0.95 0.78 0.95 0.9 0.9 N 115 115 113 107 110 Standard errors in parentheses *** p
Table 8: Price Patterns Near and at a Distance from the Highway Dependent Variable ln(Big Mac ln(Double Quarter ln(Quarter Pounder Meal) Pounder Meal) Meal) D_far_from_highway (γ ) 0.049 0.041* 0.036* 1 (0.032) (0.021) (0.021) D_franchised (γ 2 ) 0.152*** 0.120*** 0.126*** (0.028) (0.014) (0.016) D_2006 (γ 3 ) 0.360*** 0.276*** 0.130*** (0.017) (0.013) (0.018) D_far_from_highway*D_franchised (γ 4 ) -0.042 -0.065*** -0.070*** (0.039) (0.024) (0.024) D_far_from_highway*D_2006 (γ 5 ) -0.028 -0.033 -0.060** (0.034) (0.026) (0.026) D_franchised*D_2006 (γ 6 ) -0.107*** -0.077*** -0.120*** (0.032) (0.018) (0.023) D_far_from_highway*D_franchised*D_2006 (γ 7 ) 0.025 0.048 0.087*** (0.044) (0.030) (0.031) R2 0.93 0.92 0.71 N 114 110 110 Standard errors in parentheses *** p
Figure 2: McDonald’s Big-Mac Meal Price Distributions McDonald’s 1999 Big−Mac Meal Price Distributions 0 .01 .02 .03 Density 300 350 400 450 500 550 Price Franchised Outlets Corporate Outlets McDonald’s 2006 Big−Mac Meal Price Distributions 0 .01 .02 .03 Density 300 350 400 450 500 550 Price Franchised Outlets Corporate Outlets The figure plots the kernel density of the Big-Mac meal price, estimated separately for franchised and corporate-owned outlets for the time periods 1999 and 2006. It is easily observable how the two price distributions approached each other from 1999 to 2006. 26
Figure 3: % of Transactions for Different Menu Items Sales Data − % of Transactions Index August 2002 = 100 % of Transactions 60 80 100 120 Jan−2002 Jan−2003 Jan−2004 Jan−2005 Jan−2006 Date 6 McNuggets Meal Fillet−O−Fish Meal BigMac Meal Quarter Pounder Meal % of Transactions 300 100 Jan−2002 Jan−2003 Jan−2004 Jan−2005 Jan−2006 Date Dollar Menu Main Items − Double Cheeseburger and McChicken The figure plots the smoothed time series of the percentage of transactions in which each of the items was purchased over the period of October 2001 - March 2006 in a single franchised outlet. The percentage of transactions for each item was normalized to 100 in August 2002. In the lower part of the figure, we display the percentage of transactions of the Dollar Menu items: the Double Cheeseburger and the McChicken. The percentages of transactions for the regular menu items are shown in the upper part of the figure. The Dollar Menu introduction date in September 2002 is marked by a thick vertical black line. The figure demonstrates two interesting patterns. First, the sales of the Dollar Menu as a percentage of the transactions tripled in the observed period. Second, the sales of the Big-Mac meal and the Quarter Pounder meal as percentage of the transactions dropped abruptly after the Dollar Menu introduction, whereas the percentage revenue figures of the Fillet-O-Fish meal and the McNuggets meal remained relatively stable. The value used as the bandwidth is 0.3. 27
Figure 4: Revenues and Profits Before and After the Dollar Menu Revenue and Profit Index August 2002 = 100 120 110 100 Jan−2001 Jan−2002 Jan−2003 Jan−2004 Jan−2005 Jan−2006 Date Revenue Profit The figure plots the smoothed time series of revenues and profits based on the 20 most selling items between June 2001 and June 2006 in a single franchised outlet. These measures were normalized to 100 in August 2002. The Figure shows that the Dollar Menu had a positive impact on both revenues and profits, though the effect on revenues is larger. The value used as the bandwidth is 0.3. 28
You can also read