Mathiness in the Theory of Economic Growth
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2015, 105(5): 89–93 http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20151066 Mathiness in the Theory of Economic Growth† By Paul M. Romer* Politics does not lead to a broadly shared con- politics when she waged her campaign against sensus. It has to yield a decision, whether or not capital and the aggregate production function. a consensus prevails. As a result, political insti- Academic politics, like any other type of pol- tutions create incentives for participants to exag- itics, is better served by words that are evocative gerate disagreements between factions. Words and ambiguous, but if an argument is transpar- that are evocative and ambiguous better serve ently political, economists interested in science factional interests than words that are analytical will simply ignore it. The style that I am calling and precise. mathiness lets academic politics masquerade Science is a process that does lead to a broadly as science. Like mathematical theory, mathi- shared consensus. It is arguably the only social ness uses a mixture of words and symbols, but process that does. Consensus forms around the- instead of making tight links, it leaves ample oretical and empirical statements that are true. room for slippage between statements in natu- Tight links between words from natural lan- ral versus formal language and between state- guage and symbols from the formal language of ments with theoretical as opposed to empirical mathematics encourage the use of words that are content. analytical and precise. Solow’s (1956) mathematical theory of For the last two decades, growth theory has growth mapped the word “capital” onto a vari- made no scientific progress toward a consensus. able in his mathematical equations, and onto The challenge is how to model the scale effects both data from national income accounts and introduced by nonrival ideas. Mobile telephony objects like machines or structures that some- is the update to the pin factory, the demonstra- one could observe directly. The tight connection tion that scale effects are too important to ignore. between the word and the equations gave the To accommodate them, many growth theorists word a precise meaning that facilitated equally have embraced monopolistic competition, but tight connections between theoretical and empir- an influential group of traditionalists continues ical claims. Gary Becker’s (1962) mathematical to support price taking with external increas- theory of wages gave the words “human capital” ing returns. The question posed here is why the the same precision and established the same two methods of science have failed to resolve the types of tight connection—between words and disagreement between these two groups. math and between theory and evidence. In this Economists usually stick to science. Robert case as well, the relevant evidence ranged from Solow (1956) was engaged in science when he aggregate data to formal microeconomic data to developed his mathematical theory of growth. direct observation. But they can get drawn into academic politics. In contrast, McGrattan and Prescott (2010) Joan Robinson (1956) was engaged in academic give a label—location—to their proposed new input in production, but the mathiness that they * Stern School of Business, New York University, 44 W. present does not provide the microeconomic 4th St, New York, NY 10012 (e-mail: promer@stern.nyu. foundation needed to give the label meaning. edu). An appendix with supporting materials is available The authors chose a word that had already from the author’s website, paulromer.net, and from the web- been given a precise meaning by mathemati- site for this article. Support for this work was provided by cal theories of product differentiation and eco- the Rockefeller Foundation. . † Go to http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20151066 to visit nomic geography, but their formal equations are the article page for additional materials and author disclo- completely different, so neither of those mean- sure statement. ings carries over. 89
90 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2015 The mathiness in their paper also offers lit- will be worth little, but cheap to produce, so it tle guidance about the connections between its might survive as entertainment. theoretical and empirical statements. The quan- Economists have a collective stake in flushing tity of location has no unit of measurement. The mathiness out into the open. We will make faster term does not refer to anything a person could scientific progress if we can continue to rely on observe. In a striking (but instructive) use of the clarity and precision that math brings to our slippage between theoretical and the empirical shared vocabulary, and if, in our analysis of data claims, the authors assert, with no explanation, and observations, we keep using and refining the that the national supply of location is propor- powerful abstractions that mathematical theory tional to the number of residents. This raises highlights—abstractions like physical capital, questions that the equations of the model do not human capital, and nonrivalry. address. If the dependency ratio and population increase, holding the number of working age I. Scale Effects adults and the supply of labor constant, what mechanism leads to an increase in output? In 1970, there were zero mobile phones. McGrattan and Prescott (2010) is one of sev- Today, there are more than 6 billion. This is the eral papers by traditionalists that use mathiness kind of development that a theory of growth to campaign for price-taking models of growth. should help us understand. The natural inference is that their use of mathi- Let q stand for individual consumption of ness signals a shift from science to academic mobile phone services. For a ∈ [0, 1], let politics, presumably because they were losing p = D(q) = q−a be the inverse individ- the scientific debate. If so, the paralysis and ual demand curve with all-other-goods as polarization in the theory of growth is not sign numeraire. Let Ndenote the number of people in of a problem with science. It is the expected out- the market. Once the design for a mobile phone come in politics. exists, let the inverse supply curve for an aggre- If mathiness were used infrequently to gate quantity Q = qNtake the form p = S(Q) slow convergence to a new scientific consen- = Qbfor b ∈ [0, ∞]. sus, it would do localized, temporary damage. If the price and quantity of mobile phones are Unfortunately, the market for lemons tells us determined by equating D(q) = m × S(Nq),so that as the quantity increases, mathiness could that m ≥ 1 captures any markup of price rela- do permanent damage because it takes costly tive to marginal cost, the surplus S created by the effort to distinguish mathiness from mathemat- discovery of mobile telephony takes the form ical theory. The market for mathematical theory can sur- a(1+b) S = C(a, b, m) × N a+b , _____ vive a few lemon articles filled with mathiness. Readers will put a small discount on any article with mathematical symbols, but will still find where C(a, b, m) is a messy algebraic expres- it worth their while to work through and verify sion. Surplus scales as N to a power between a that the formal arguments are correct, that the and 1. If b = 0,so that the supply curve for the connection between the symbols and the words devices is horizontal, surplus scales linearly in is tight, and that the theoretical concepts have N .If, in addition, a = __ 12 ,the expression for sur- implications for measurement and observation. plus simplifies to But after readers have been disappointed too often by mathiness that wastes their time, they S = _____ 2m − 1 N. will stop taking seriously any paper that contains 2 m mathematical symbols. In response, authors will stop doing the hard work that it takes to supply With these parameters, a tax or a monopoly real mathematical theory. If no one is putting in markup that increases m from 1to 2causes Sto the work to distinguish between mathiness and change by the factor 0.75. An increase in Nfrom mathematical theory, why not cut a few corners something like 102 people in a village to 1010 and take advantage of the slippage that mathi- people in a connected global market causes S to ness allows? The market for mathematical the- change by the factor 108. ory will collapse. Only mathiness will be left. It Effects this big tend to focus the mind.
VOL. 105 NO. 5 MATHINESS IN THE THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 91 II. The Fork in Growth Theory As many growth theorists followed trade theorists and explored aggregate models with The traditional way to include a scale effect monopolistic competition, the traditionalists was proposed by Marshall (1890). One writes who worked on models with a microeconomic the production of telephone services at each foundation maintained their commitment to price of a large number of firms in an industry as taking and adhered to the restriction of 0 percent g(X ) f (x), where the list x contains the inputs excludability of ideas required for Marshallian that the firm controls and the list X has inputs external increasing returns. Perhaps because of for the entire industry. One obvious problem unresolved questions about the extent of spill- with this approach is that it offers no basis for overs, attention turned to models of idea flows determining the extent is of the spillover bene- that require face-to-face interaction. Because fits from the term g(X ). Do they require face-to- incentives in these models motivate neither face interaction? Production in the same city, the discovery nor diffusion, agents exchange ideas same country, or anywhere? in the same way that gas molecules exchange If we split x = (a, z) into a nonrival input a energy—involuntarily, through random encoun- and rival inputs z , a standard replication argu- ters. Given the sharp limits imposed by the ment implies that f must be homogeneous of mathematics of their formal framework, it is no degree 1 in the rival inputs z. Euler’s theorem surprise that traditionalists were attracted to the then implies that the value of output equals the extra degrees of freedom that come from letting compensation paid to the rival inputs z .In a full the words slip free of the math. equilibrium analysis, anything that looks like producer surplus or “Marshallian rent” is in fact III. Examples of Mathiness part of the compensation paid to the rival inputs. It follows that there can be no nonrival input McGrattan and Prescott (2010) establish a that the firm can use yet exclude other firms loose links between a word with no meaning from using. Production for an individual firm and new mathematical results. The mathiness must take the form A f (z) where A is both non- in “Perfectly Competitive Innovation” (Boldrin rival and fully nonexcludable, hence a public and Levine 2008) takes the adjectives from good. the title of the paper, which have a well estab- I started by my work on growth using price lished, tight connection to existing mathemati- taking and external increasing returns, but cal results, and links them to a very different set switched to monopolistic competition because of mathematical results. In an initial period, the it allows for the possibility that ideas can be at innovator in their model is a monopolist, the sole least partially excludable. Partial excludability supplier of a newly developed good. The authors offers a much more precise way to think about force the monopolist to take a specific price for spillovers. Nonrivalry, which is logically inde- its own good as given by imposing price taking pendent, is the defining characteristic of an idea as an assumption about behavior. and the source of the scale effects that are cen- In addition to using words that do not align tral to any plausible explanation of recent expe- with their formal model, Boldrin and Levine rience with mobile telephony or more generally, (2008) make broad verbal claims that are discon- of the broad sweep of human history (Jones and nected from any formal analysis. For example, Romer 2010). they claim that the argument based on Euler’s In models that allow for partial excludability theorem does not apply because price equals of nonrival goods, ideas need not be treated as marginal cost only in the absence of capacity pure public goods. In these models, firms have constraints. Robert Lucas uses the same kind of an incentive to discover a new idea like a mobile untethered verbal claim to dismiss any role for phone (Romer 1990) or to encourage interna- books or blueprints in a model of ideas: “Some tional diffusion of such an idea once it exists knowledge can be ‘embodied’ in books, blue- (Romer 1994). In such models, one can ask why prints, machines, and other kinds of physical some valuable nonrival ideas diffuse much more capital, and we know how to introduce capital slowly than mobile telephony and how policy into a growth model, but we also know that can influence the rate of diffusion by changing doing so does not by itself provide an engine the incentives that firms face. of sustained growth.” (Lucas 2009, p.6). In
92 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2015 each case, well-known models show that these The mathiness here involves more than a verbal claims are false. Any two-sector growth nonstandard interpretation of the phrase “obser- model will show how Marshall’s style of partial vationally equivalent.” The underlying formal equilibrium analysis leads Boldrin and Levine result is that calculating the double limit in one astray. Any endogenous growth model with an order limβ→0 (limT→∞ g[β : B ⇒ P]) yields one expanding variety of capital goods or a ladder answer, γ, which is also the limiting growth rate of capital goods of improving quality serves as a in the P economy. However, calculating it in counter-example to the result that Lucas claims the other order, limT→∞ (limβ→0 g[β : B ⇒ P]), that we know. gives a different answer, 0. Lucas and Moll In Lucas and Moll (2014), the mathiness (2014) use the first calculation to justify their involves both words that are disconnected from claim about observational equivalence. An argu- the formal results and a mathematical model that ment that takes the math seriously would note is not well specified. The baseline model in their that the double limit does not exist and would paper relies on an assumption P that invokes a caution against trying to give an interpretation to distribution for the initial stock of knowledge the value calculated using one order or the other. across workers that is unbounded, with a fat Pareto tail. Given this assumption, Lucas and IV. A New Equilibrium in the Market for Moll show that the diffusion of knowledge from Mathematical Economics random encounters between workers generates a growth rate g[P](t)that converges to γ > 0as As is noted in an addendum, Lucas (2009) tgoes to infinity. contains a flaw in a proof. The proof requires that α Assumption P is hard to justify because it γ be less than 1 a fraction __ .The same page has an γ requires that at time zero, someone is already expression for γ,γ = α ____, and because α, γ, using every productive technology that will ever γ+δ be used at any future date. So the authors offer αγ is greater and δare all positive, it implies that __ “an alternative interpretation that we argue is than 1.Anyone who does math knows that it is observationally equivalent: knowledge at time 0 distressingly easy to make an oversight like this. is bounded but new knowledge arrives at arbi- It is not a sign of mathiness by the author. But trarily low frequency.” (Lucas and Moll 2014, the fact that this oversight was not picked up at p.11). In this alternative, there is a collection of the working paper stage or in the process leading economies that all start with an assumption B up to publication may tell us something about (for bounded initial knowledge.) By itself, this the new equilibrium in economics. Neither col- assumption implies that the growth rate goes leagues who read working papers, nor review- to zero as everyone learns all there is to know. ers, nor journal editors, are paying attention to However, new knowledge, drawn from a distri- the math. bution with a Pareto tail, is injected at the rate β, After reading their working paper, I told so a B economy eventually turns into a P econ- Lucas and Moll about the discontinuity in the omy. As the arrival rate β gets arbitrarily low, limit and the problem it posed for their claim an arbitrarily long period of time has to elapse about observational equivalence. They left their before the switch from B to P takes place. (See limit argument in the paper without noting the online Appendix for details.) the discontinuity and the Journal of Political For a given value of β > 0, let β : B ⇒ P Economy published it this way. This may reflect denote a specific economy from this collection. a judgment by the authors and the editors that at Any observation on the growth rate has to take least in the theory of growth, we are already in a place at a finite date T. If T is large enough, new equilibrium in which readers expect mathi- g[P](T )will be close to γ ,but g[β : B ⇒ P](T ) ness and accept it. will be arbitrarily close to 0 for an arbitrarily One final bit of evidence comes from Piketty low arrival rate β. This means that any set of and Zucman (2014), who cite a result from a observations on growth rates will show that the growth model: with a fixed saving rate, when the P economy is observably different from any growth rate falls by one-half, the ratio of wealth economy β : B ⇒ P with a low enough value to income doubles. They note that their formula of β.They are not observationally equivalent in W/Y = s/g assumes that national income any conventional sense. and the saving rate s are both measured net of
VOL. 105 NO. 5 MATHINESS IN THE THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 93 d epreciation. They observe that the formula has organized their look at history without access to be modified to W /Y = s/(g + δ), with a to the abstraction we know as capital? Where depreciation rate δ,when it is stated in terms of would we be now if Robert Solow’s math had the gross saving rate and gross national income. been swamped by Joan Robinson’s mathiness? From Krusell and Smith (2014), I learned more about this calculation. If the growth rate falls and the net saving rate remains constant, REFERENCES the gross saving rate has to increase. For exam- ple, with a fixed net saving rate of 1 0 percent Becker, Gary S. 1962. “Investment in Human and a depreciation rate of 3 percent,a reduction Capital: A Theoretical Analysis.” Journal of in the growth rate from 3 percent to 1 .5 percent Political Economy 70 (5): 9–49. implies an increase in the gross saving rate from Boldrin, Michele, and David K. Levine. 2008. 18 percent to 25 percent. This means that the “Perfectly Competitive Innovation.” Journal of expression s/(g + δ) increases by a factor 1 .33 Monetary Economics 55 (3): 435–53. because of the direct effect of the fall in g and by Jones, Charles I., and Paul M. Romer. 2010. “The a factor 1 .38because of the induced change in s . New Kaldor Facts: Ideas, Institutions, Popula- A third factor, equal to 1.09, arises because the tion, and Human Capital.” American Economic fall in galso increases the ratio of gross income Journal: Macroeconomics 2 (1): 224–45. to net income. These three factors, which when Krusell, Per, and Anthony A. Smith. 2014. multiplied equal 2, decompose the change in “Is Piketty’s Second Law of Capitalism W/Y calculated in net terms into equivalent Fundamental.” http://aida.wss.yale.edu/smith/ changes for a model with variables measured in piketty1.pdf (accessed March 31, 2015). gross terms. Lucas, Jr. Robert E. 2009. “Ideas and Growth.” Piketty and Zucman (2014) present their data Economica 76 (301): 1–19. and empirical analysis with admirable clarity Lucas, Jr., Robert E., and Benjamin Moll. 2014. and precision. In choosing to present the theory “Knowledge Growth and the Allocation of in less detail, they too may have responded to Time.” Journal of Political Economy 122 (1): the expectations in the new equilibrium: empir- 1–51. ical work is science; theory is entertainment. Marshall, Alfred. 1890. Principles of Economics. Presenting a model is like doing a card trick. London: Macmillan and Co. Everybody knows that there will be some sleight McGrattan, Ellen R., and Edward C. Prescott. of hand. There is no intent to deceive because 2010. “Technology Capital and the US Current no one takes it seriously. Perhaps our norms will Account.” American Economic Review 100 soon be like those in professional magic; it will (4): 1493–1522. be impolite, perhaps even an ethical breach, to Piketty, Thomas, and Gabriel Zucman. 2014. reveal how someone’s trick works. “Capital is Back: Wealth-Income Ratios in When I learned mathematical economics, a Rich Countries 1700–2010.” Quarterly Jour- different equilibrium prevailed. Not universally, nal of Economics 129 (3): 1255–1310. but much more so than today, when economic Robinson, Joan. 1956. Accumulation of Capital. theorists used math to explore abstractions, Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin. it was a point of pride to do so with clarity, Romer, Paul M. 1990. “Endogenous Technologi- precision, and rigor. Then too, a faction like cal Change.” Journal of Political Economy 98 Robinson’s that risked losing a battle might (5): S71–S102. resort to mathiness as a last-ditch defense, but Romer, Paul M. 1994. “New Goods, Old Theory, doing so carried a risk. Reputations suffered. and the Welfare Costs of Trade Restrictions.” If we have already reached the lemons market Journal of Development Economics 43: 5–38. equilibrium where only mathiness is on offer, Solow, Robert M. 1956. “A Contribution to the future generations of economists will suffer. Theory of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Jour- After all, how would Piketty and Zucman have nal of Economics 70 (1): 65–94.
You can also read