JAPAN'S NORM DEFIANCE: THE CASE OF WHALING IN 2007
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
JAPAN’S NORM DEFIANCE: THE CASE OF WHALING IN 2007 GRO SLOTSVIK Abstract It is the argument of this paper that Japan’s defiance of international anti-whaling norms in 2007 can be explained by analysing the domestic and international factors shaping the state’s foreign policy-making. A study of Japan’s refusal to end its scientific whaling programme shows that this norm defiance was sustained by domestic factors. Simultaneously, the state’s decision not to leave the restricting International Whaling Commission, despite threats to do so, was based on international factors. The conflicting nature of the factors has left Japan in a peculiar state of norm defiance, where the state will not end whaling, and yet chose to stay in the IWC in 2007. Introduction In 2007, Japan declared its intention to start hunting the much-loved humpback whale, triggering international protests (Independent 19.11.07a; Times 19.11.07). Although Japan’s ‘scientific whaling’ had already endured heavy criticism, the country had until then focused on less well known and more abundant whales, such as the minke whale. The humpback whale has been seen as a more sociable and intelligent than the other great whales since at least the early 1900s (Risting 1922:34). 2007 thus formed yet another benchmark in Japan’s history of defying international anti-whaling norms (Stockwin 2008:237). The issue of whaling was first brought to my attention in 2007 through a project on Norwegian and Japanese international relations, where whaling was one of the common denominators. The case was interesting because Japan refused to end whaling in spite of international criticism, and I was intrigued to investigate why. Despite accusations of Japanese foreign policy simply being reactionary (Wolferen 1989; Schmiegelow and Schmiegelow 1990:559), I believe that Japan's foreign policy-making, presumably like most other states', consists of a mix of unit- and system-level factors. Few cases demonstrate this better than the case of whaling. Generally, Japanese foreign policy appears to follow that of international regimes. This makes it more difficult to distinguish between actual domestic foreign policy-making and the influence that the international regimes themselves have on POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
foreign policy-making processes. In the case of whaling, however, strong domestic unit-level factors battle with international system-level factors, leading to a situation in which Japan will not stop limited whaling, but will also not leave the international regime that constrains its whaling practice. My hypopaper is that Japan's norm defiance in the case of whaling is an example of a foreign policy-making process consisting of conflicting unit- and system-level factors. The questions arising from this hypopaper are, fundamentally, what these unit- and system-level factors are and how they interact to create Japan's whaling foreign policy. My assumption is that an analysis of the unit- and system-level factors will explain why Japan acts as it does in the case of whaling, i.e. why it continues limited whaling but does not leave the restricting International Whaling Commission (IWC). I believe the unit-level factors in the case of whaling correspond to domestic issues in Japanese foreign policy-making, and also to the question of why Japan will not stop whaling. Similarly, system-level factors correspond to the international aspect of Japan's foreign policy-making process, and also to the question of why Japan did not leave the IWC in 2007. The dichotomy between domestic (unit-level) and international (system-level) factors is not perfect, as the two levels clearly overlap and interact. However, the strong distinction has proved useful for an analysis of conflicting factors. In order to explain the issue of whaling in 2007, I will first give a short background to the whaling debate, before defining what the ‘norm defiance’ in this case constitutes. I will then present the analytical framework, and then move on to the questions of why Japan will not stop whaling and why Japan did not leave the IWC in 2007. The methodology of my analysis is based on applying a combination of theories on international regimes, domestic and foreign policy to my two research questions. The case of whaling is an ongoing debate, and I have chosen to use newspaper articles as sources for whaling debate events in 2007, and also for more recent developments. The first of the two main issues is the question of why Japan continues to defy the anti-whaling norm. By evaluating three different domestic explanations proposed on the subject, I will argue that all three, to varying degrees, interact to create the unit-level factor of Japan's foreign policy. The first explanation is that whaling acts as a ‘pressure vent’ for more important political matters; POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
whaling is seen as a way to assert Japan’s own politics, in a political climate where the state is usually forced to follow the United States’ lead. The second explanation focuses on the ‘culture argument’, which is often mentioned as part of the whaling debate in both media and scholarly debates. The argument focuses on the cultural importance of whaling –a view which the Japanese government champions – and generally sees the anti-whaling bloc's rhetoric and behaviour as a reason for why whaling has become such an important issue for the Japanese. The third explanation is the ‘security argument’, which focuses on the Japanese historical dependency on marine food resources, arguing that the whaling issue is perceived to be a resource security issue, rather than a minor political or cultural matter, by the Japanese. I will then move on to the second part of my paper, which explains why Japan did not leave the IWC in 2007, despite the fact that it appeared to be in the country’s interest to do so. I will first evaluate the legitimacy of 'scientific whaling', arguing that Japan's whaling policy is viewed as legitimate by the state itself due to the legality of research whaling. I will then analyse Japan's role in the International Whaling Commission, emphasizing the importance of the state's usual internationalist foreign policy approach in combination with regime theory. My argument is that various factors relating to the international whaling regime and Japan's international political approach interact to create the system-level factor of Japan's foreign policy in the case of whaling. Historical Background Whaling has been a contentious political issue since Dutch and British whalers started the commercial whale hunt in Europe in the 16th century, when whale stocks were still abundant (Risting 1922:71-73). In Japan, commercial whaling did not start fully until a few centuries later. By 1898, there were 11 whaling communities spread across Japan (Risting 1922:278). With the development of modern whaling methods came extensive worldwide commercial hunting; the larger whales could be hunted and processed at sea, with Great Britain and Norway at the head of a large commercial fleet (Wong 2001:90). POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
The history of modern whale management started with the creation of the International Convention for the Regulation of Whaling in 1946, and the establishment of the International Whaling Commission in 1948. By then, the world market's demand for whale products, particularly whale oil, had resulted in the serious depletion of whale stocks worldwide. The International Whaling Commission was created in order to “provide for the proper conservation of whale stocks and thus make possible the orderly development of the whaling industry” (www.iwcoffice.org), and as such was only intended to protect whales in order to enable continued whaling. However, by the 1960s, emerging environmental organisations began to see whales as particularly intelligent, sociable animals, which should not be killed under any circumstances (Douglas and Wildavsky 1982:129; Nadelmann 1990:517; Catalinac and Chan 2005:137). The US government in particular was then lobbied to end domestic whaling, which resulted in the proposal to end whaling at the 1972 UN Conference on the Human Environment in Stockholm (Nadelmann 1990:518). Although the groundwork was laid for a moratorium on the killing of whales, the International Whaling Commission’s Scientific Committee disagreed with the proposal, stating that a ban on all, including apparently abundant, whale stocks could be not justified on scientific grounds (Heazle 2006:9; Catalinac and Chan 2005:138; Wong 2001:97). Through extensive international lobbying by environmental groups and the United States (Oterhals 2005:12; Andresen 1989:109), the anti-whaling bloc eventually managed to secure the necessary three-fourths majority in 1982, thereby introducing what was meant to be a temporary blanket ban on the hunting of whales from 1986 (Stockwin 2008:237). According to the IWC charter, a member state may file a formal objection to proposals such as the moratorium, thus exempting itself from that particular proposal. Japan and Norway, amongst others, submitted their objections, but Japan later withdrew its objection. According to IWC regulations, Norway is therefore able to pursue commercial hunting legally, whereas Japan can only hunt whales legally as part of 'scientific whaling' (Gulland 1988; Catalinac and Chan 2005:142). When the Scientific Committee adopted a conservative new whale management scheme in 1992 (Kalland 2002:19), which would have allowed for sustainable commercial whaling of selected stocks, the anti-whaling bloc still refused to lift the moratorium (Catalinac and Chan 2005:141). In 2007, Japan was not the only country that conducted whaling in spite of Western POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
sentiments. Norway hunted whales for commercial purposes and Iceland engaged in both scientific and commercial whaling. Japan's whaling, however, differed from that of Iceland or Norway in that this norm defiance ran contrary to Japan's overall foreign policy approach. The moratorium was in 2007 still upheld by the countries with the toughest stances on the whaling issue, i.e. the United States, Great Britain, New Zealand and Australia, as well as the rest of the anti-whaling bloc. The Western states' reasons for protesting against whaling have grounds in domestic opinion. Although there are other threats to whales than whaling, such as destruction of habitat and noise pollution (Jenssen 1985:37), the history of whaling as a cause of near-extinction makes saving whales a convenient ‘moral’ cause for non-whaling nations. Arguing for a complete ban on whaling as the main part of the 'save the whale' campaign enables non-whaling policy-makers to attribute responsibility for certain whale stocks’ endangeredness elsewhere (Douglas and Wildavsky 1982:8; Heazle 2006:33). Particularly old whaling nations, such as the US and Great Britain, appeared to favour an aggressive stand on whaling (Wong 2001:91). Greenpeace International and the Sea Shepherd Conservation Society in particular stood out as the most confrontational anti-whaling NGOs in 2007. The anti-whaling bloc's motives are varied. Whereas the more extreme Sea Shepherd is an organisation devoted to "end (...) slaughter of wildlife in the world's oceans" (www.seashepherd.org/who-we-are), Greenpeace International works to conserve the environment generally (www.greenpeace.org/international/about). For the latter, whales appear to provide a useful symbol to rally behind, despite the fact that the whale stocks mainly targeted by the Japanese, the minke whale stocks, were not endangered even before the hunting ban was initiated (Danaher 2002:105). Although less aggressive than Sea Shepherd, Greenpeace activists have made it difficult for anyone without recommendations from approved institutions to be allowed into the Institute for Cetacean Research (Personal Communication 8 January 2009). The former appear to champion what Johansen (2005) terms the “Moby Dick syndrome”, in which the whale symbolises uncorrupted and innocent nature, in contrast to morally depraved and greedy mankind. The huge Japanese whaling factory ships have therefore provided a good target for environmental activists (Caron 1995:174). Norm Defiance The fact that Japan’s whaling is technically legal does not mean that it is not a norm defiance. POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
Using Dyer’s definition (1997:14), “norms are, ordinarily speaking, standards or measures (from the latin norma, a carpenter’s square or rule). More generally, a norm is a ‘standard or pattern or type considered representative of a group’ (Oxford English Dictionary). In the social or political context norms are (descriptively) standards of behaviour – of social and political action – and (prescriptively) reasons which dictate such action”. It is often difficult to determine whether those conforming to a norm do so because they believe in the norm, because norm adherence aligns with their own interests, or because they fear the consequences defying the norm would have (Nadelmann 1990:480). A ‘norm defiance' implies that one actor's beliefs or behaviour are deemed unacceptable according to another, authoritative actor's norms, but these norms are not necessarily official or written. In order to affect a norm defiance, the actors would have to exist within the same system and interact in some way. For whaling, the system in which the norm defiance takes place can either be seen as the International Whaling Commission, ‘international society’ or ‘world opinion’. Although some do not separate the three (Kingston 2004:214), the International Whaling Commission has 84 member states (www.iwcoffice.org), which still lacks a majority of the world's countries. Furthermore, it is difficult to argue that there exists a pro- or anti-whaling 'norm' within the Commission, as the moratorium is upheld, but the Scientific Committee never agreed with its implementation (Catalinac and Chan 2005) and Japan's whaling is legal according to IWC regulations (Gulland 1988; Catalinac and Chan 2005:142). The matter is not much less complicated with regards to the 'world opinion' (Mandel 1980:114); Whales are a common resource (Kalland 1994) and thus belongs to 'everyone', but as Catalinac and Chan (2005) point out, the concept of a world opinion on this topic is a difficult one. Although international organisations certainly have an impact on people's opinions about whaling across national borders, their impact is difficult to assess. Therefore, I have chosen to focus on the ‘international society’ of states, paying particular attention to the US, Great Britain, New Zealand and Australia. Whenever I refer to 'Western' ideas or beliefs, the ‘West’ refers to these four. All of these generally share Japan's political ideals, and are seen as important to Japan's overall foreign policy aims. The countries have been identified as most anti-whaling because they openly object to whaling for ethical reasons, meaning that they object to the resumption of commercial and scientific whaling regardless of the abundance of whale stocks. The norm that Japan defies is the killing of whales in itself, rather than the potential use scientific whaling as a ‘guise’ (Kingston 2004:214) or irresponsible POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
management of whale stocks. Moreover, Japan's whaling foreign policy also defies the country's own foreign policy norms, which are deeply rooted in Japanese modern history. Ever since its defeat in the Second World War, Japan has undertaken a range of foreign policies designed to avoid provoking international society. Under Prime Minister Yoshida, the main policies of the state centred around not engaging in international affairs and instead focusing on developing Japan economically (Hook et al 2000:68). Due to the economic boom in the 1980s, Japan suddenly became an economic giant and was viewed as a potential threat to the other Western nations (Stockwin 2003:347; Midford 2003:334). Coupled with a lack of decisive reaction during the 1991 Gulf Crisis, this may explain the extent of criticism Japan received for its ‘chequebook diplomacy’, where the country was not seen to be pulling its weight internationally (Hughes 2004; Stockwin 2003:347). The embarrassment Japanese foreign policy-makers felt led to a change in the country's foreign policy, in which the state sought to engage more in international security matters, dispatching personnel for United Nations Peacekeeping Operations and focusing on the United Nations generally as a source of legitimacy in international society (Hook et al 2000:67). Japan remains uneasy about appearing aggressive, thereby trying to avoid stirring memories of the country's wartime behaviour. To this day the constitution only allows for 'Self-Defence Forces' rather than an 'army'. The United States has been Japan's main ally since the American post-war occupation of Japan, and still has military bases stationed on Japanese territory. Since the attacks on the World Trade Centre on September 11th 2001, Japan has been eager to show the US that it is worthy of its status as a 'special ally' (Hook et al 2000:36), but nevertheless refused to participate in the wars in Afghanistan and Iraq without a UN resolution (Hughes 2004). Japan's past as an aggressor has lead to a foreign policy focus on being seen as a responsible member of international society, relying on 'soft power' - defined here as "the ability to get what you want through attraction rather than coercion or payments" (Nye 2004:3) - in order to promote its policies. Soft power policies include supporting the UN, providing overseas development aid and promoting the Japanese 'peace constitution', which renounces the use of military force. According to Nye, a country's soft power is enhanced through the attractiveness of its culture, political ideals and policies that are seen as legitimate in the eyes of others), a country’s soft power is enhanced (Nye 2004:3). It is baffling, therefore, how much Japan's norm defiance in POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
the case of whaling differs from the state's usual foreign policy approach: it makes Japan appear aggressive towards an animal seen as particularly intelligent and sociable (Klinowska 1988), the image of whales as endangered makes Japan seem irresponsible, hunting whales runs contrary to 'world opinion' (Kingston 2004) and it openly defies US pressure to end whaling. Analytical Framework History and culture play a significant part in Japan's foreign policy-making, and I agree with Stockwin's (2008) argument that Japan's politics cannot be explained purely in realist or liberalist terms. Rather, the case of whaling demonstrates how factors both at the unit- and system-level interact to create a foreign policy that appears to contradict Japan's usual foreign policy approach (although not the usual foreign policy process). The analytical framework used for my research consists of a fairly wide variety of political theories. I see all the theories described as valid in general, and useful for this particular case study, but also too limited to explain the case of whaling on their own. My assumption is that the case of Japan's whaling foreign policy consists of both domestic and international factors, and that the whaling debate is essentially a state against state argument taking place within an international regime. This means that different theories will have to cover different areas of the whaling issue. I realise that the wide choice of theories necessarily hinders a deeper analysis of particular aspects of Japan's whaling foreign policy, e.g. bureaucratic politics, domestic and international factor interactions or regime patterns. I believe, however, that for a project of this length, which deals with an issue not yet widely discussed academically, a more holistic approach is better suited. Additionally, the theories used here focus on the state as the main actor in the international system. I disagree with Strange's argument that the state is no longer in ultimate political control over society and economy (1996:220). The state of Japan is clearly both the link between the whaling regime and domestic units (Smith 2005:32- 33), as well as the institution advocating Japanese society's and economy's interests. However, I do recognise that there will always be a range of actors in a debate such as this, many of which are international or non-governmental organizations (OECD 2003:47). One of the weaknesses of my analysis comes from the fact that, in order to focus on Japan's role in the whaling issue, I have chosen to exclude factors that are not essential to the Japanese foreign policy-making aspect of the debate. Therefore, the role of NGOs and international POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
organizations apart from IWC, e.g. NAMMCO or CITES, in the general whaling management debate is largely ignored. Overall, my analytical framework for studying the domestic policy-making process is very much based on Putnam’s two-level game theory (1988) and Wendt's theories on macro- and micro-structures (1999). Wendt’s theories will also be applied, along with Haas’ (1993) and Hasenclever, Mayer and Rittberger’s regime theories, to the analysis of international factors shaping Japan’s foreign policy-making process. Micro-structures, according to Wendt, deal with unit- and interaction-level theories, and explain foreign policy, whereas macro-structures explain international politics. In the case of whaling, micro-structures concerns states’ beliefs about other states’ rationality, strategies and beliefs, none of which, according to Wendt (1999:159), actually need to be true. As long as states believe that others believe in the same institutions, conventions, norms and rules, their interaction will reinforce those beliefs (Wendt 1999:160). In the case of whaling, both pro- and anti-whaling nations adhere to the International Whaling Commission, although, as I will be arguing later, neither necessarily agrees with the regime's norms and rules. Putnam (1988) also argues for the importance of integration between domestic and international politics in foreign policy-making. The two- level game theory presupposes that domestic groups pressure the government into pursuing their particular interests, while the government (or particular parts of government) also mitigates for international pressure that may have adverse effects on domestic affairs (Putnam 1988:434). Putnam’s theory allows for the existence of a state against state debate, while not presupposing that states are necessarily unitary, rational actors. The whaling debate is a clear case of this; non-governmental organisations have a large say in foreign policy-making, emotions run high during and between IWC meetings, and whaling and non-whaling states alike choose to stay in an organisation that quite often runs contrary to their own interests. Using Haas’ and Hasenclever et al's theories on international regimes, it is obvious that "power-based" or realist theories of regimes (Hasenclever et al 2002:3) fail to explain Japan's whaling foreign policy, mainly because Japan remains in an organisation that conflicts with its own interests and defies the most powerful states within that organisation (Stockwin 2008:237; Hook et al 2000:38). Neoliberal or "interest-based" theories of regimes (Hasenclever et al 2002:4) do not really fit the case of whaling either, as actors do not appear to be rational or unaffected by the IWC's practices and norms. The cognitivist or "knowledge- based" theories of regimes (Haas 1993:170; Hasenclever et al 2002:5), however, seem to fit POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
the whaling debate fairly well, as it combines elements of traditional power theories and newer ideas about the importance of social norms. According to Hook et al (2000), constructivism emphasizes that no ‘one’ rationality exists among units within a regime. Mutual interaction between policy-making agents and political actors is argued to create patterns of behaviour, shaping expectations, norms and identities (Hook et al 2000:38). The emphasis on "role-playing" (Hasenclever et al 2002:5) echoes Wendt’s theories on micro- structures and the reinforcement of beliefs (1999:160), as well as complementing Krasner's theory about the organisation assuming a 'life of its own' (1983:357). The regime is then viewed as reciprocally affecting the states, creating a system where states are not in complete, 'rational' control of their own beliefs or behaviour (Krasner 1983:357). Thus, when an anti- whaling state accuses Japan of breaching whaling regulations, or Japan justifies scientific whaling according to IWC regulations, both play their roles according to a regime neither fully agrees with. The regime is nevertheless "affirmed" by the states' actions and then reaffirms their roles as part of the regime (Hasenclever et al 2002:20). Why will Japan not stop Whaling? Much of the literature on Japan's scientific whaling has, just like the research question for this section, been focused on why Japan will not give up whaling despite international criticism (Blok 2008; Danaher 2002; Catalinac and Chan 2005). Generally, explanations focus on whaling as a 'pressure vent', on cultural reasons or resource security issues. Despite a contradictory, apparently popular belief within the anti-whaling bloc, there is little evidence to point towards any significant economic gain from Japan’s scientific whaling or even their resumed commercial whaling (Catalinac and Chan 2005:144; Blok 2008:51; Times 10.05.07; 21.12.07). It may appear puzzling, then, that Japan should choose to pursue a foreign policy that causes international tension, with no real economic gain to compensate for this (Blok 2008:45). In order to explain the domestic part of Japan’s whaling foreign policy approach, I will therefore focus on the three theories of why Japan continues whaling. The underlying theme for all of these theories is that the whaling issue is no longer primarily about whales, but rather reflects larger issues within Japanese domestic and foreign policies (Blok 2008:48). POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
It is frequently argued that the Japanese domestic political game can be difficult to fully decipher (Wolferen 1989:5). Bureaucratic politics, factions and business play an important, yet often elusive, part in foreign policy making (Hook et al 2000:72; Wolferen 1989:5). Although a full analysis of the decision-making processes, domestic groups and bureaucratic wrangling that form part of the current whaling foreign policy is beyond the scope of my research, some insight into the background of Japan’s foreign policy-making is important. According to Putnam's two-level games theory (1988:434), the domestic coalitions that form in response to certain issues may, depending on their levels of influence in national and international politics, have significant implications for policy making. I assume that for the state, internal actors and external pressures shape both foreign policy and ideas of national interest (Hook et al 2000:38). In the case of whaling, the Fisheries Agency (FA), part of the Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries, holds much of the power with regards to government policy-making and responses (Catalinac and Chan 2005:146; Danaher 2002:109). The Ministry of Foreign Affairs (MOFA), meanwhile, tends to be left to defend these policies on the international scene (BBC News online 22.01.08; Blok 2008:45). The Fisheries Agency is also in charge of domestic pro-whaling events and has close ties to the Institute of Cetacean Research (ICR), which is responsible for scientific whaling, and pro- whaling organisations (Blok 2008:46; Danaher 2002:109). These in turn have strong links to groups within the Japanese Diet and the leading domestic parties, including the currently ruling Liberal Democratic Party (LDP), and the Democratic Party of Japan (DPJ) (Danaher 2002:109; Blok 2008:46). Finally, the fact that the whaling industry is considered part of the traditionally powerful fishing industry leads to an even stronger position for pro-whaling business within the government (Catalinac and Chan 2005:146; Danaher 2002:109). At the same time, the Japanese generally do not view whaling as an environmental issue, and few Japanese environmental NGOs campaign to end whaling (Danaher 2002:111). This should make it all the more difficult for the government to cater for international pressure, as there is little corresponding domestic interest in following international society’s lead (Putnam 1988:428; Miyaoka 1998:168; Danaher 2002:115). The theory certainly appears to be appropriate in the case of whaling, where the Ministry of Foreign Affairs can do little to counteract domestic pro-whaling forces. The 'Pressure Vent' Theory POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
The first theory, which argues that whaling is essentially a nationalist issue, presupposes that Japan’s pro-whaling foreign policy approach is a purposefully created approach; whaling is seen to act as a vent for international pressure and hurt national pride (Blok 2008:47-49; Times 10.05.07). The term nationalist used here refers to a point of view in which Japan is pitched against an (often unreasonable) outside world; whaling then becomes both a source of national pride (something that distinguishes us from them) and a 'pressure vent' for foreign demands (placed on us by them) (Shimazu 2006:184). Blok (2008:61) emphasizes the importance of the international ‘outsiders’ to maintain this mindset and shape domestic political responses. The “moral universe” (Danaher 2002:115) created becomes as uncompromising as that of the more extreme environmental NGOs. The unfairness of the anti-whalers with regards to scientific rationality, culture and national sovereignty only serves to strengthen the perceived moral capital of the pro-whalers (Danaher 2002:115; Blok 2008:41). The portrayal of whalers as almost savage, blood-thirsty or uncultured (Independent 19.09.07; Guardian 15.09.08) unifies the Japanese pro-whaling community. Without highly critical outsiders, this community might otherwise question the approach Japan has taken to this particular foreign policy (Blok 2008:47). Due to the saturation of Japanese society with newspapers and TV stations, the mass media has enormous potential in shaping Japan's policies (Hook et al 2000:61). As was the case in Norway in the 1980s (Claudi 1988:126), anti-whaling groups are portrayed as ‘eco-terrorists’ by the Japanese media (Guardian 28.02.07; BBC News online 22.01.08; Blok 2008:55). The ‘goodies and baddies’ picture this paints does little to ease negotiation processes and efforts to compromise on the whaling issue. Historically, Japan's foreign policy has tended to gravitate towards "the major power of the day" (Hook et al 2000:36), with the US being Japan's main ally since the end of the Second World War (Stockwin 2008:249). Coupled with this is Japan's internationalist foreign policy, in which the country seeks to be seen as a responsible member of the international community (Hook et al 2000:66). The bilateral relationship with the US in particular has put pressure on Japanese foreign policy-makers, as Japan relies heavily on the US for national security (Hook et al 2000:40). With regards to whaling, pressure from the US to retract Japan's objection to the moratorium played a significant role in ending Japanese commercial whaling (Wong 2001:110). The introduction of the 1973 Pelly Amendment and 1979 POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
Packwood-Magnuson Amendment allowed the US to pressurise nations not complying with the ban on commercial whaling, threatening Japan with a withdrawal of fishing rights in US waters. With the economically important fishing rights at stake, Japan withdrew its objection to the moratorium, but the US nevertheless banned Japanese fishing within the American economic zone a few years later (Wong 2001:111; BBC News online 16.05.07). The Cultural Theory The second theory, that whaling reflects a broader cultural issue, assumes that the pro- whaling bloc is actually driven by sincere convictions about Western ‘cultural imperialism’ and the need to counteract it (Blok 2008:44). Minke whale stocks are currently estimated to about 900,000 worldwide (Danaher 2002:118), so they are not in danger of extinction. Anti-whaling nations and groups have therefore generally turned to ethical, rather than scientific, reasons for why whales should not be hunted (Mirsky 2008; Kalland 1993). The Japanese decision in 2007 to hunt humpback whales was described as "terrible" (Times 27.12.07) and "simply a gratuitous extension of the wish to kill, like a fox in a henhouse killing everything in sight" (Independent 19.11.07). International reactions that are obviously based on Western cultural perceptions of whales and whaling appear to only make Japan more determined to continue its policy on whaling. The humpback hunt was abandoned, but Japan has continued campaigns to promote the cultural aspect of Japanese whaling. These address both the issue of coastal whaling for communities with long whaling traditions, and what is perceived to be Western eco- imperialism and hypocrisy (Kalland 2002:28; Ben-Ami 1997:15). Firstly, certain nations, including the US, argue for indigenous whaling at home, while simultaneously arguing against coastal whaling in Japan (Mandel 1980:109). The difference between 'aboriginal subsistence' whaling, which is allowed under IWC rules, and small-scale coastal whaling, which is not allowed for any country that has not filed an objection to the moratorium, is contentious (Blok 2008:54; Catalinac and Chan 2005:155). Japan has a very long history of whaling, and a tradition of fully utilising caught whales. By the beginning of the 19th century, it is estimated that there were around 30 whaling communities across Japan. The European history of whaling, meanwhile, is very much linked to acquiring whale oil and POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
bones (Epstein 2004:318). In 1908, the Japanese Whaling Association was set up for the purpose of developing whaling and protecting whale stocks, creating one of the world's first concession arrangements in 1909 in order to control and limit whaling (Tønnessen 1969:174- 214). This controlled, small-scale form of whaling, termed coastal whaling, has little in common with the notorious commercial whaling of the first half of the 20th century. Hunting generally takes place within entire communities, often fishing villages, with long traditions of sustainable resource management (Jonsgård 1992:26; Epstein 2004:318; Danaher 2002:113). The rather dismal history of commercial whaling in general, however, may explain why the term sets off alarm bells for some, who fear that allowing Japan to resume coastal whaling will once again lead down the path to depletion (www.greenpeace.org; Independent 19.11.07). However, the defence for a continued ban on whaling on the basis of a Japanese lack of cultural traditions for whaling, does not sit well with the Japanese government. Japan’s whaling foreign policy is very much linked to eventually opening up for small-scale coastal whaling for four communities with long whaling traditions: Taiji, Abashiri, Ayukawa and Wada (ICR 2008b:11-14; Guardian 24.06.01; Catalinac and Chan 2005:142;155; Blok 2008:54). The apparent hypocrisy of allowing one culture to whale, whilst deeming another unfit to do so, accounts for part of the Japanese unwillingness to follow its usual foreign policy norms of international compliance (BBC News online 06.02.09; Johansen 2005). The second reason why Japan reacts badly to what is perceived to be a new form of Western imperialism, is the different perception of whales (Blok 2008:48; Catalinac and Chan 2005:148). The Western notion of whales as sacrosanct animals clashes with Japanese ideas about whales being an animal like any other. According to Danaher (2002:10), the 'apparent paradoxes' deriving from the co-existence of a whale-watching industry and whale-hunting industry are possibly due to the traditional Japanese Buddhist notions of respect for nature. Johansen (2005), meanwhile, argues that sustainable management of nature's resources in Norway is built on both Christian and humanistic sets of values. Epstein, on the other hand, argues that this notion of animals may stem from these particular types of small coastal societies, as whaling cultures share similar ethnographic profiles. This lifestyle is contrasted with the essentially urban dwellers of the anti-whaling movement, who generally have little contact with animals (Epstein 2004:318). According to Kalland, Western ideas about whales have gradually mutated into a "super whale", which combines the most striking qualities of various types of whales into a single sacrosanct creature (Kalland 2002; 1993; Kalland and POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
Moeran 1992). The notions of the "super whale" originally stem from articles purporting the supreme intelligence and social skills of the whale (D'Amato and Chopra 1991). As a result, assumptions about whales in general, such as the idea that whales are the marine equivalent of man (Day 2006:7; Wong 2001:91) - “at least as sociable as elephants and probably a lot smarter” (Mirsky 2008:39) - makes Japan’s foreign policy appear "uncivilized" (Catalinac and Chan 2005:133) and “barbaric in the extreme” (Independent 19.11.07). Japan, however, does not share the notion that whales have special rights (Catalinac and Chan 2005:146), and the pressure from foreign NGOs to give up what has formed part of Japanese culture for centuries, without any scientific grounds for doing so, is perceived as Western cultural imperialism (Catalinac and Chan 2005:148). Whaling then forms part of a foreign policy seeking to challenge the status of the anti-whaling norm as universal, where continuing to eat whale meat becomes a matter of fundamental human and sovereign rights (Blok 2008:48; Danaher 2002:118; Johansen 2005). The Resource Security Theory Although, as previously stated, there is little to gain economically from hunting whales (Blok 2008:45), whaling is nevertheless a Japanese resource security issue. Whaling has been seen as belonging to fishing rather than land hunting for decades (Tønnessen 1969:95), and is still dealt with as a marine resource under the Fisheries Agency (Danaher 2002:107; Blok 2008:58). Part of the reason why Japan will not stop whaling lies in the uncertainty about what, and how much, whales actually eat; whereas some view the notion of minke whales eating large quantities of economically important fish as contentious (Huseby 2005:9; Guardian 19.06.06; Times 10.05.07), current Japanese and Norwegian reports of whales' stomach content, as well as reports dating back to the 1800s, disagree (Jonsgård 1992: 23-24; 71; Danaher 2002:112; ICR 2008a; 2008b). According to the Institute of Cetacean, “the whaling issue is a problem over food between man and whales” (ICR 2008a:11). For Japanese foreign policy-makers, what is true in this case matters less, perhaps, than that the ICR's beliefs may be true. Japan is fiercely protective of its marine resources (Danaher 2002:106), and the whaling issue tends to be placed into the wider context of resource security in general (Blok 2008:58; Danaher 2002:107). As an island nation with few natural resources, securing both food and other resources has been high on the state agenda for decades (Stockwin 2008: 264; Wong 2002: 112; Catalinac and Chan 2005:145; Danaher POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
2002:107). Quoting a pro-whaling advocate cited in Blok (2008:58), whaling "is a tip of a very huge iceberg" consisting of fisheries and other natural resources. According to Article 117 of the 1982 United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea, whales are considered exploitable resources which may be used in a sustainable manner, either in countries' exclusive economic zones or on the high seas. What appears to worry Japanese policy-makers is the impact that a never-ending moratorium on the apparently sustainable hunting of whales might have on other resources, resource regimes and the principle of sustainable management of resources (Danaher 2002: 107; Catalinac and Chan 2005:145; Times 21.12.07). Japan's fisheries in particular are seen as threatened by the changing ethical norms towards marine resource management. Two percent of the world's population are Japanese, but the country accounts for eight percent of global fisheries resource consumption (Catalinac and Chan 2005:145). Any threat to the continued use of marine resources is therefore a very serious one, which the Fisheries Agency is keen to counteract through Japan's foreign policy. Why Japan Will Not Stop Whaling The research question relating to the unit-level factors of Japan's foreign policy concerns why Japan will not stop whaling. I believe that when combined, the three domestic factors described above answer this question. The 'pressure vent' theory appears to be most favoured by the British media; it pictures Japan and the Japanese as unreasonable and intolerant, and as such makes most sense to the anti-whaling bloc. It also, ironically, resembles the Japanese view of anti-whalers according to the same theory. This theory is certainly most useful for states wishing to depict Japan as an environmental laggard in a political game where the cost- free action of 'saving the whale' scores green points at home (Kalland 2002:21-31; Wong 2001:91; Guardian 29.11.07). The whaling issue is, however, not cost-free for the Japanese, and the weakness of the theory lies in the fact that it is seen as an innocent pressure-vent for more important issues. I believe Japan's whaling foreign policy generates far too much international criticism to simply be a form of political retaliation (Danaher 2002:110). There does, admittedly, appear to be an almost nationalist element to Japan's whaling policy, but this is perhaps not surprising considering the harsh, sometimes borderline racist, anti-whaling attacks on Japan (Johansen 2005; Guardian 29.11.07; Hammond 1997:xviii). Certainly, personal opinions offered by officials at the Institute of Marine Research in Bergen and the Fisheries Agency in Tokyo indicated that the anti-whaling criticism was partially racially POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
motivated (Personal communication 19 August 2008; 7 January 2009). If criticism of Japan's foreign policy appeared more rational, i.e. written in less anthropomorphic or inflammatory terms (Johansen 2005), the nationalist element might very well disappear. The culture theory, meanwhile, appears more plausible. Although critics point to the limited whaling and eating of whale meat in Japanese society today (Independent 19.11.07b), a culture does not need to be national to be worthy of protection. Indeed, the opposite appears to be the case for "aboriginal" or "subsistence" whaling communities, such as the Alaskan Eskimo hunting of endangered bowhead whales (BBC News online 29.05.07). The fierceness of the attack on Japan's whaling culture, which has historical roots nationwide, has made the whaling issue one of culture and sovereignty, and the culture argument thus deeply influences the Japanese whaling foreign policy. The idea that some communities are 'indigenous enough' to continue whaling, whereas some should be 'modern' and refrain from whaling (Kalland 2002:28; Johansen 2005), makes little sense to the Japanese (Times 02.06.07). I believe this domestic factor will continue to influence Japanese foreign policy for the foreseeable future, unless the anti-whaling bloc in the IWC finally concedes and allows small-scale coastal whaling for Japanese whalers. It may be useful, in this case, to think of whaling as an issue of "societal security", a term borrowed from Buzan's (1991:19-20) five security agenda sectors: military, economic, political, societal and ecological security. Societal security concerns a state's identity and the “ability of a society to maintain its traditional patterns of language, culture, religion, and national identity and customs” (Smith 2005:33-34). If anti-whaling states were willing to consider the issue of whaling as more than a mere nationalist agenda issue, the dialogue between the two blocs might become more fruitful. As is the case for the other two domestic factors, the resource security argument argues that whaling forms part of a much larger issue in Japanese domestic politics. The importance to Japan of securing marine resources should not be underestimated. Although whaling may appear to have little in common with fishing to an outsider, the value of something depends principally on how the actor perceives it and the situation the actor is in (Baldwin 1997:19). Interests are, as Katzenstein points out, defined by actors who respond to particular cultural factors (Katzenstein 1996:17-32). Japan's geographical and historical position with regards to resource security should therefore be taken into account by those who claim that whaling is no longer needed. Being perceived as a resource security issue by the Japanese automatically POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
lends whaling importance, and there is little to indicate that it will be removed from that agenda in the foreseeable future. Seeing the whaling issue as part of Japan's resource and societal security agenda may enable the more compromise-orientated anti-whaling states to realise why the country refuses to give up the hunt even in the face of international protest. With less international pressure, there will be less to unify against and the Japanese may be equally willing to compromise (Blok 2008:61; Danaher 2002:115). Why did Japan not leave the IWC in 2007? Having dealt with the unit-level or domestic part of Japan’s foreign policy making process, I will now move on to explain the system-level or international part of the country's whaling foreign policy. The research question for this section concerns why Japan did not simply leave the IWC in 2007, end its scientific whaling programme and resume commercial whaling: the latter does after all appear to be the ultimate goal of Japan's scientific whaling (Blok 2008:51). Part of the criticism of the country's whaling policies focuses on scientific whaling as a 'guise' (Mirsky 2008:40) or 'loophole' (Huseby 2005:59; BBC News online 06.02.09; Times 10.05.07; 21.12.07). Therefore, a resumption of commercial whaling would possibly lead to the Japanese being seen as more honest about their reasons for whaling. There are, however, two problems associated with a return to commercial whaling. Firstly, there is issue of the legality of scientific whaling, and secondly, the problems associated with leaving the International Whaling Commission. Scientific Whaling Firstly, scientific whaling is not illegal, and is therefore a legitimate policy from a Japanese point of view. Under Article VIII, the International Convention for the Regulation of Whaling (ICRW) allows member states to grant permits to conduct lethal scientific whaling, and the IWC allows hunting of whales for scientific purposes in whale sanctuaries (Butterworth 1992:332; Danaher 2002:107). ICRW regulations also state that "any whales taken under these special permits shall so far as practicable be processed and the proceeds be dealt with in accordance with directions issued by the Governments" (iwcoffice.org). Japan's sale of whale meat does not run contrary to whaling regulations, with government officials arguing that the sale of whale meat partially funds the research programme (Huseby 2005:57; Catalinac and Chan 2005:143; Danaher 2002:109). The research is openly conducted, the Fisheries Agency POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
appears eager to explain the methods, findings and rationale behind Japan's scientific research and the materials from the research are published in both English and Japanese (ICR 2008a; 2008b). Legally speaking, then, scientific whaling is perfectly legitimate. That scientific whaling is actually a guise for commercial whaling is more contentious; certainly, the aim of scientific whaling is to show that a return to regulated commercial whaling is feasible (Danaher 2002:105; Blok 2008:51). Norway conducted similar research on the north-eastern Atlantic minke whale stock before resuming commercial whaling, in order to prove the viability of sustainable resource management (Jonsgård 1992:17). As has already been stated, however, Japan gains little economically from whaling, with evidence to suggest that Japanese government subsidies of scientific research have consisted of approximately 900 million yen (5.7 million Euro) annually since 1987 (Blok 2008:51; Danaher 2002:109). Furthermore, a scientific approach to the issue of whaling is viewed as legitimate foreign policy by the Japanese due to the standing of science. Science in general is viewed as an important factor in Japan, and a scientific approach appears to be the most reasonable way to counteract claims that all whales are special and endangered animals in need of complete protection (Wong 2001:112; Catalinac and Chan 2005:145; Danaher 2002:106). If Japanese whaling policies can be proven to follow rational and reasonable, this contrasts favourably with the 'emotional' approach taken by Western anti-whaling states and also renders useless any arguments about the non-viability of well-managed whaling. Leaving the International Whaling Commission Secondly, a return to commercial whaling would be problematic due to IWC regulations. Japan's scientific hunt is legal, but a resumption of commercial coastal whaling would be in breach of international whaling regulations. The only viable option, then, would be for Japan to leave the IWC, in which case any whaling would be conducted according to the country's own guidelines. However, this would be a fairly radical turn for Japan’s foreign policy. Japan's initial compliance with the moratorium was greatly influenced by US pressure. Japan's continued compliance, however, must be viewed in the context of the effects that adhering to regimes has on a state's foreign policy approach, in combination Japan's search for international legitimacy and responsibility (Wong 2001:117-119; Catalinac and Chan 2005:135; Danaher 2002:116). POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
According to an official at the Fisheries Agency in Tokyo, the IWC is the 'proper' institution for whaling related activities, and Japan would like to continue cooperation as far as possible (Personal communication 8 January). This statement mirrors Japan's search for international legitimacy and Krasner, Hasenclever et al and Haas' theories on the importance of regimes. The international environment of the whaling regime has changed radically since Japan joined the IWC, and Japan's decision to stay in the organisation may be explained partially as 'habit' (Krasner 1983:360). "Role-playing" in the IWC (Hasenclever et al 1997:5) may mean that Japan is not in complete, 'rational' control of its own political behaviour. When Japan justifies whaling according to IWC regulations, it plays its role within the regime and aligns its foreign policy approach according to a regime the country no longer really agrees with. The "role-playing" means that the regime is nevertheless "affirmed" by the state's actions and then reaffirms its role as part of the IWC regime (Hasenclever et al 1997:20; Catalinac and Chan 2005:150). Wendt argues that macro-structures, in this case the whaling regime, are both acted upon and acts upon states (Wendt 1999:155), in this case the state of Japan. The whaling regime should then "generate macro-level patterns in individual behaviour" (Wendt 1999:161). Put simply, this means keeping Japan within the ICW because 'that's the way it is'. The principles, norms, rules and decision-making processes in the IWC appear to have led to at least some degree of "regime autonomy" (Krasner 1983:359), although regime theory alone may not be adequate to explain Japan's approach to the whaling regime. As mentioned in the analytical framework, "power-based" or realist theories and "interest-based" or neoliberal theories of regimes (Hasenclever et al 1997:3-4) are difficult to apply to the case of whaling in 2007. "Interest-based" or neoliberal explanations of regimes -what Haas terms institutionalist or "bargaining patterns" explanations (Haas 1993:83) - are difficult to apply to whaling because interest-based theory assumes that actors are rational (Hasenclever et al 1997:4). Looking at the whaling regime in 2007, this is clearly not the case, although the theory may be applicable to the initial creation of the IWC. At the beginning of the modern whaling regime in the 1940s, the measures taken to curb whaling reflected the parties that were least enthusiastic about cutting the whale quotas. Members were united by their common interests, but unwilling to commit to drastic measures (Haas 1993:183; Catalinac and Chan 2005:134). POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
"Power-based" or realist explanations of regimes are difficult to apply to the whaling regime because neglecting the influence of non-state actors, and similarly neglecting the potential for international influence based on non-material forces (Haas 1993:169-170), would mean ignoring important aspects of the whaling regime. Non-governmental environmental groups such as Greenpeace, for instance, appear to influence international opinion greatly, even though this particular study is too short to include the role of NGOs. In addition, the Japanese reliance on soft power (Nye 2004:3) as a political tool means that there must at least be a belief among Japanese foreign policy-makers that non-material forces are useful for gaining international influence: this belief, in turn, influences policy-making. The realist approach, which Haas refers to as the "Follow-the-Leader" theory, could be argued to be applicable to the start of the moratorium, albeit if the role of non-state actors was still ignored to some extent. "Follow-the-Leader" assumes that collective behaviour within the regime is shaped by the strongest country, which then presses less powerful states to accommodate its own preferences by forcing them to modify their policies (Haas 1993:181). The United States' efforts to pressure Japan to withdraw its objection to the moratorium would be the obvious case of this. Additionally, the role of non-state actors, such as anti-whaling environmental organisations, was at this point more or less confined to lobbying through states, which would support the theory's assumption that states are the main actors. Although the "power-based" and "interest-based" approaches to regimes may be able to at least partially explain why states would adhere to the international whaling regime in the past, neither one can adequately explain why Japan chose to remain in the IWC in 2007. Iceland was able to return to commercial whaling by leaving the whaling regime. In order to understand why Japan, despite their wish to resume commercial whaling, nevertheless chose to stay in the IWC, a theory that is more sensitive to historical context than the abovementioned is required. Japan’s reliance on soft power (Nye 2004:3) as a means for gaining international influence, and the country’s quest for recognition of its role in international society makes it harder for Japan to leave an international organisation. This alone would mean that both “power-based” and “interest-based” theories are difficult to apply in order to understand Japan’s behaviour, because these do not, unlike cognitivist theory, treat actors as “reflective organisms” (Haas 1993:170). The cognitivist idea that state’s interests are often unclear and that the international system is more indeterminate than “power-based” and “interest-based” theories assume, is particularly clear in the case of whaling in 2007. POLIS Student Journal Vol.1 (1)
You can also read