Having Their Cake and Eating It Too - Business Profits, Taxes, and Investment in Canada: 1961 Through 2010
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
> April 2011 Having Their Cake and Eating It Too Business Profits, Taxes, and Investment in Canada: 1961 Through 2010 Jim Stanford
About the Author Jim Stanford is an economist with the Canadian Auto Workers and a CCPA Research Associate. He is also the author of Economics for Everyone, published by the Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives in 2008. Please make a donation... Help us continue to offer our publications free online. We make most of our publications available free on our website. Making a donation or taking out a membership will help us continue to provide people with access to our ideas and research free of charge. You can make a donation or become a member on-line at www.policyalternatives.ca. Or you can contact the National office at 613-563-1341 for more information. Suggested donation for this publication: $10 or what you can afford. isbn 978-1-926888-60-6 This report is available free of charge from the CCPA website at www.policyalternatives.ca. Printed copies may be ordered through the National Office for a $10 fee. 205-75 Albert Street, Ottawa, on k1p 5e7 tel 613-563-1341 fa x 613-233-1458 em ail ccpa@policyalternatives.ca www.policyalternatives.ca
Executive Summary This paper reviews longer-run empirical trends in The paper conducts an original econometric fixed non-residential capital spending by Cana- analysis of historical Canadian data on business dian businesses. Since the first of several rounds fixed non-residential investment, and confirms of business tax reforms and reductions was im- that tax rates have had no direct, statistically plemented in 1988, business investment has de- significant impact on investment. Moreover, clined by 1 full percentage point of GDP — even the indirect impact of tax rates on investment though after-tax business cash flow has increased (experienced via their enhancement of after-tax (in part as a direct result of the tax reforms) by 3 business cash flow) has become less important in to 4 percentage points of GDP. The proportion of recent years. Business investment is more sensi- after-tax cash flow which Canadian firms re-in- tive to GDP performance, interest rates, exchange vest in fixed non-residential capital has declined rates, and oil prices than to cash flow. from near 100 percent before the tax reforms, to In recent years, after adjusting for these less than 70 percent today. Since 2001, Canadian other investment determinants, only about 10 corporations have received a cumulative total percent of additional business cash flow has of $745 billion in after-tax cash flow which they been converted into incremental business in- have not re-invested into Canadian fixed non- vestment. Thus the proposed 3-point reduc- residential capital projects. This growing wedge tion in corporate tax rates would stimulate of excess corporate savings has translated into only about $600 million of new investment. several outcomes which have undermined the From a policy perspective, government would vibrancy of Canada’s recovery from the recent elicit ten times as much new investment by al- recession — including excess accumulation of locating the same amount of money directly to cash and short-term financial assets, a noted public infrastructure investment. In addition increase in the rate of payout of corporate divi- to the $6 billion in incremental public invest- dends, and a sustained reduction in leverage by ment directly financed by such spending, this non-financial corporations. strategy would also elicit $520 million in new private investment thanks to the positive im- Having Their C ake and Eating It too 3
pact of stronger GDP growth on business in- ing, the historical evidence suggests that busi- vestment. As a means of stimulating growth, ness tax cuts are both economically ineffective employment, and even private business spend- and distributionally regressive. 4 c anadian centre for polic y alternatives
Introduction Investment in fixed capital assets is a crucial driver Business fixed investment spending (consider- of economic growth, job-creation, technological ing both structures and machinery & equipment) change, and productivity growth (DeLong and declined by 24 percent in real terms from the Summers, 1991). In a capitalist economy such autumn of 2008 through the end of 2009. That as Canada’s, most investment is undertaken by decline was the worst since the Great Depression private businesses (although public investment of the 1930s (Cross, 2011), and was the steepest spending plays an important supplementary role decline in spending experienced in any sector of in capital accumulation). Hence the vibrancy Canada’s economy during the recession. and success of business investment spending is In the year since investment spending finally a central determinant of the overall state of the bottomed out, business capital spending has be- economy (Stanford, 2008, Chapter 12). When ag- gun to recover, but by end-2010 had still recouped gregate investment spending is high as a share well under one-half of the decline experienced of total GDP, economies tend to grow faster, ex- during the recession. The business sector is the perience faster productivity growth (Rao et al., only sector in Canada’s economy still spending 2003; Sharpe, 2006), and rapidly growing in- less in 2011 than in 2008 before the recession comes. This was true in Canada during the 1960s started. In contrast, consumer spending and and 1970s (when total national capital spending government spending have both increased sub- accounted for over 20 percent of GDP), and it is stantially (partly as a result of pro-active stim- true today in high-investment economies such ulus efforts by policy-makers, including lower as Korea, China, and Brazil. interest rates and discretionary fiscal policy). The downturn in investment spending by Ca- In short, business investment spending was nadian businesses following the global financial the major source of Canada’s recent downturn, crisis in 2008 was the most dramatic and impor- and the slowness of the recovery in business tant channel through which the effects of that spending is a key reason why Canada’s recovery crisis were “imported” into Canada, resulting from the recession is still uncertain, sluggish, in a sharp recession in our domestic economy. and incomplete. It is worth noting that this sharp Having Their C ake and Eating It too 5
downturn in business investment occurred pre- ping back from the immediate damaging effects cisely coincident with another round of reduc- of the recent crisis, to ascertain whether there is tions in federal corporate income taxes, which any longer-run empirical support for the claim were cut from 22.1 percent in 2007 (including that lower corporate taxes will elicit more busi- the former 1.1 percent federal surtax) to 18 per- ness investment. cent by 2010. In other words, whatever impact The paper is organized as follows. Section 1 this 4-point reduction in federal corporate in- reviews empirical data regarding the level and come taxes may have had (or not had) on busi- composition of business investment spending in ness investment, it was vastly overwhelmed by Canada, the evolution of corporate tax rates, and macroeconomic factors which proved far more the components of business cash flow. This sec- important in the determination of business in- tion indicates that business investment spend- vestment spending. ing has clearly declined in Canada (by several The issue of further federal corporate in- measures) in the quarter-century since succes- come tax reductions has become important in sive federal governments began reforming and the current federal election campaign. The Con- reducing corporate income taxes. Section 2 re- servative party promises to reduce the rate by an views published economic literature regarding additional one-sixth (from 18 percent last year the determinants of business fixed investment to 15 percent next year). Other parties favour spending, including several of those studies in- maintaining rates at 18 percent (which would voked during the present debate by the advocates require reversing the 1.5-point cut which was of further corporate tax cuts. Section 3 presents just implemented by the Conservatives three the results of original econometric research into months ago) or higher. the determinants of business investment spend- Advocates of the tax cut claim it will spark ing in Canada. These results confirm that corpo- increased business investment, thus generating rate tax rates have had no visible direct impact jobs and incomes for all Canadians — and po- on business investment, and that the indirect tentially generating more revenues for govern- impact on investment (experienced via higher ment (offsetting or even replacing the foregone corporate cash flow) is small and has become revenue from the tax cut). This claim seems at weaker over time. Canadian business investment odds with the very recent history of Canadian is influenced more importantly by GDP growth business investment spending, whereby business trends, interest rates, exchange rates, and oil spending has declined substantially, and stayed prices than by changes in corporate taxes. The lower than previous levels, despite a 4-point tax implications of these results suggest that govern- cut. The fact that tax reductions to business are ment should place more emphasis on stimulat- highly regressive in their distributional effects ing GDP growth (including through a continued (since most income on capital is received by the expansion of public investment); the effects of wealthiest segments of society) makes the Con- these expansionary measures (including their servative proposals all the more controversial “crowding-in” impact on private business spend- politically.1 ing) are more effective than attempting to elicit This paper will consider the claim of the tax cut more business investment via additional reduc- advocates from a longer-run perspective — step- tions in corporate taxes. 6 c anadian centre for polic y alternatives
section 1 Empirical Review of Business Cash Flow, Taxes, and Investment Statistics Canada provides several different (by this measure) between 16 and 18 percent of sources of data regarding business fixed capital GDP, declining by about 2 percentage points of spending: its annual surveys of public and pri- GDP after the 1980s. It has fluctuated between vate investment intentions and expenditures 14 and 16 percent of GDP since then. This is a (which provide the most sectoral detail regard- gross measure of investment, which includes ing investment across different industries), its the spending required to offset depreciation of quarterly national income and expenditure ac- existing capital assets. Investment is highly cy- counts (which detail how investment spending clical, rising and falling with the overall state of by businesses, and government, contributes to economic growth. the evolution of overall GDP), and its quarterly Figure 1 also highlights another important and annual surveys of business finances (based trend in Canadian investment, the growing im- on corporate financial reports). Due to differ- portance in recent years of the mining and pe- ences in methodology and definitions, there are troleum industries in total business investment. variations between the data reported from these These two sectors now account for around one- different sources and surveys. They do reveal a quarter of total direct investment spending.2 consistent overall finding, however: namely that Excluding these resource-oriented projects, to- the long-run rate of business investment spend- tal business investment spending in Canada is ing slowed in Canada beginning in the 1980s, and around 12 percent of GDP — and showed so sign has not rebounded since that time despite the of improvement during the 2000s (unlike petro- repeated episodes of corporate tax reform that leum and mining investment, which did grow have occurred since. For more details on how to during that decade in response to very high measure investment spending, see the Appendix. global commodity prices). Figure 1 illustrates data from Statistics Can- Given this slowdown in capital investment, ada’s annual investment intentions and expen- Canada’s overall economy has curiously become ditures survey. Through the initial postwar less capital-intensive in recent decades. Businesses decades, fixed investment spending fluctuated are spending less; moreover, the more rapid na- Having Their C ake and Eating It too 7
figure 1 Business Non-Residential Fixed Capital Spending 1961–2010 20% 18% 16% Percent of GDP 14% 12% 10% Total Excluding Mining and Petroleum 8% 6% 1961 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 source Author’s calculations from Statistics Canada CANSIM data. figure 2 Declining Capital Intensity in Canada’s Economy 1961–2010 140% $110,000 capital stock (left) 120% $100,000 Net Capital Stock (Percent GDP) 100% $90,000 Capital Per Worker ($2002) 80% $80,000 60% $70,000 40% $60,000 capital per worker (right) Total Excluding Mining and Petroleum 20% $50,000 0% $40,000 1961 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 source Author’s calculations from Statistics Canada CANSIM data. ture of technological change means that exist- ciation) has not kept up with the overall size of ing assets become outdated more quickly (and Canada’s economy. As illustrated by the top line hence depreciation charges are higher). As a re- in Figure 2, the business fixed capital stock has sult of both factors, the net capital stock (that declined from around 140 percent of GDP in the is, the stock of fixed capital assets after depre- early 1980s, to only about 100 percent at present.3 8 c anadian centre for polic y alternatives
Similarly, the capital stock is barely keeping by businesses, and the cash flow which busi- up with the growth in Canada’s working popu- nesses generate from their existing operations. lation as a result of the investment slowdown. Data for both sources is obtained from Statis- Consider the capital-labour ratio as the total tics Canada’s quarterly income and expenditure net capital stock divided by the number of em- accounts (and hence differs somewhat from the ployed Canadians; this constitutes a measure of data pictured in Figures 1 and 2). Business fixed the total value of “tools” with which each Cana- non-residential spending fluctuated between 12 dian worker performs their duties (the two lower and 13 percent of GDP during the initial postwar lines on Figure 24). Economists consider this ra- decades, and then declined by about one point tio (and the value of machinery and equipment of GDP after the early 1980s. Initially, the after- assets, in particular) as a very important deter- tax cash flow of the business sector (equal to minant of productivity growth. The capital-la- before-tax profits, less direct taxes paid to gov- bour ratio grew rapidly in Canada in the initial ernment, plus capital consumption allowances5) postwar decades, but levelled off with the de- was broadly equivalent to business investment cline in business investment in the early 1980s. in non-residential fixed capital (also running at The overall ratio grew by 9.6 percent in the 20 12–13 percent of GDP). years between 1990 and 2010 (compared with a Over the past quarter-century, however, af- 25 percent increase in the two decades ending in ter-tax cash flow received by the business sec- 1980). Moreover, all of that modest growth was tor in Canada has grown substantially relative due to increased investment in the petroleum to Canada’s GDP. This reflects three different and mining sectors; excluding those sectors, the trends. First, the structural determinants of average capital-labour ratio in Canada is actu- business profitability have improved markedly ally lower than it was twenty years ago. This is in Canada — as a result of factors such as stag- an unexpected and worrying finding: given the nant labour compensation, declining unioniza- importance of innovation and technology in the tion, the privatization of formerly public assets, modern economy, we would expect the average and other policies implemented by successive Canadian worker (not just those in mines and tar business-friendly governments over this period. sands facilitites) to be utilizing more capital in Secondly, corporate tax rates have been reduced their daily work than two decades ago, not less. repeatedly and significantly (as will be reported Most business investment is financed from in more detail below). Finally, due to more rapid the internal funds which are generated by a com- technological change and the resulting faster ob- pany’s existing operations. A rapidly-growing solescence of capital, depreciation charges have company may turn to financial markets to raise grown relative to GDP. For all three reasons, af- additional funds for new investment (through ter-tax business cash flow has grown since the loans, bonds, or new equity issues). But the bulk mid-1980s by 3 to 4 percentage points of GDP. of most companies’ new investments (both to re- Since the mid-1980s, therefore, business in- place depreciating assets, and to add to the net vestment spending has declined, but business capital stock) is paid for from the funds gener- cash flow has increased. The result is a grow- ated by the company’s existing operations. ing gap between cash flow and business invest- In fact, cash flow generated by existing busi- ment, illustrated in Figure 3. That gap cumulates ness operations in Canada is now well in excess to very large sums of uninvested after-tax cor- of total business spending on non-residential porate cash flow: funds received by companies fixed capital. Figure 3 illustrates the comparison which have not been ploughed back into new between fixed non-residential capital spending expenditures on fixed non-residential capital in Having Their C ake and Eating It too 9
figure 3 Business Cash Flow and Business Investment 1961–2010 20% 18% Cash Flow Capital Spending 16% Percent of GDP 14% 12% 10% 8% 6% 1961 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 source Author’s calculations from Statistics Canada CANSIM data. Cash flow is after-tax, and equals before-tax profits less direct taxes plus capital consumption allowances, for all private and government business enterprises. Capital spending is non-residential fixed capital investment. figure 4 Business Cash Flow Reinvestment Rate 1961–2010 140% Share of Cash Flow Reinvested (Percent) 120% 100% 80% 60% 40% 1961 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 source Author’s calculations from Statistics Canada CANSIM data. Reinvestment rate equals business fixed non-residential capital spending as a proportion of after-tax cash flow (before-tax profits less direct taxes plus capital consumption allowances), for all private and government business enterprises. Canada.6 Since 2001 alone, this uninvested cash uninvested cash continued to flow into corpo- flow totals to almost $750 billion. Even during rate coffers: a cumulative total of $200 billion in the recession (which reduced sales and profits), uninvested cash flow was received by the busi- 10 c anadian centre for polic y alternatives
ness sector since the recession began in the third will be retained and the rate will fall further to quarter of 2008. 15 percent next year. The contrast between stagnant or declining At the same time, many provincial govern- business investment, and rising business cash- ments have also reduced their own statutory tax flow, can be summarized in Figure 4, which il- rates (often pressed by companies which threaten lustrates the aggregate re-investment rate of Ca- to relocate reported profits from one province nadian businesses. This is the share of after-tax to another to take advantage of interprovincial corporate cash flow that is indeed reinvested in tax differences). The combined federal-provin- new fixed non-residential capital investment. cial statutory rate has thus declined from almost This ratio hovered near 100 percent during the 50 percent in the early 1980s, to 29.5 percent in initial postwar decades (during which time it was 2010, and will fall to an estimated 25 percent if reasonable to conclude that businesses generally the Conservative promise and all provincial re- reinvested their full cash flow into the Canadian ductions are fully implemented. In other words, economy). After the late 1980s, however, it has combined federal-provincial statutory tax rates declined steadily, averaging below 70 percent will have been cut in half by 2013, compared to through the entire last decade (in both good the early 1980s. years and recessionary years). The evolution of corporate tax rates in Canada Canada has experienced several episodes is summarized in Figure 5. This graph illustrates of business tax reform over the past quarter- the reduction in the combined federal-provin- century. The first occurred in 1988, under the cial statutory rate from 1981 through 2010. The Conservative government of Brian Mulroney, graph is based on a comprehensive OECD da- when the federal statutory tax rate was reduced tabase (OECD, 2010) which begins only in 1981; from 36 percent to 28 percent (not including a consistent federal-provincial annual statutory tax 1.1 percent surtax). At the same time, however, rates are not available for prior years, but those numerous tax loopholes which reduced effective statutory tax rates did not significantly change business taxes were closed. The net impact on fi- during the initial postwar decades. nal taxes paid by business was therefore muted. Due to the impact of various deductions and Then, beginning in 2001 the Liberal government loopholes, the effective tax actually paid by cor- (of Prime Minister Jean Chrétien and Finance porations can vary significantly from the theo- Minister Paul Martin) implemented a further retical statutory rate. An approximate effective reduction in the statutory rate to 21 percent by tax rate can be estimated by dividing the sum 2004. This was of main benefit to the services of direct taxes paid by business, by the pre-tax sector of the economy, since the manufacturing profit base. To reflect the lag times in processing and resources sectors had earlier already been and submitting tax returns, we divide taxes paid paying tax at a favourable 21 percent rate. Now by the previous year’s before-tax profit.7 This ef- the overall tax system was supposedly more neu- fective tax rate is also illustrated in Figure 5. It tral than before the first reform in 1988. Finally, is almost always lower than the statutory rate. It following the election of a Conservative govern- is interesting to note that the effective tax rate ment under Stephen Harper, the statutory rate did not decline noticeably following the 1988 was cut again beginning in 2008, reaching 18 tax reform (which simultaneously reduced the percent by 2010. A further 1.5 percentage point rate and closed loopholes, apparently with lit- cut was introduced at the beginning of 2011, and tle net impact on taxes paid). The effective rate under the Conservative platform, that reduction did begin to decline following the Martin cuts of 2001, and then more steeply with the addi- Having Their C ake and Eating It too 11
figure 5 Business Tax Rates 1961–2010 60% Statutory Effective 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1961 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 source Author’s calculations from Statistics Canada CANSIM data, and OECD (2010). Table 1 Business Profits, Taxes, and Investment 1961–2010 Tax Rates Business Investment Business Profitability As Share As Share After- After-Tax Statutory Effective1 GDP Tax Cash Flow Before-Tax After-Tax Cash Flow2 Pre-Reform (1961–87) Approx. 50% 38.2% 12.7% 95.3% 11.4% 6.9% 13.4% Mulroney Reforms (1988–2000) 42.4% 38.1% 11.7% 89.2% 9.5% 5.7% 13.3% Martin Reforms (2001–07) 35.9% 29.3% 11.9% 68.4% 13.7% 9.2% 17.5% Harper Reforms (2008–10) 30.9% 26.5% 11.7% 69.7% 12.2% 8.3% 16.8% Change from Pre-Reform to Harper Years -19.1 points -11.6 points -1.0 point -25.7 points +0.9 points +1.4 points +3.4 points Source Author’s calculations from Statistics Canada CANSIM and OECD data, as described in text. Includes private and government business enterprises, fixed non-residential capital spending. 1 Effective tax rate is direct taxes on business profits as share of before-tax profits lagged one year. 2 After-tax cash flow equals before-tax profits less direct taxes plus capital consumption allowances. tional across-the-board rate cuts implemented and business capital spending are summarized by the Harper government. The Harper rate re- in Table 1. This table divides the full 50-year pe- ductions applied to a broader class of businesses riod under consideration into 4 sub-periods. The than either of the previous reforms, and hence initial postwar decades prior to the major Mul- translated more powerfully into a lower effec- roney reforms of 1988 constitute the first sub- tive tax rate.8 period. Then additional sub-periods are defined These longer-run developments in business according to coverage by each successive set of profits and cash flow, business income taxes, 12 c anadian centre for polic y alternatives
business tax reforms: the Mulroney, Martin, and centage point of GDP from the pre-reform years Harper reductions.9 to the Harper period.11 Thanks to lower effective Table 1 indicates the decline in average statu- taxes, after-tax profits increased by 1.5 percent tory and effective tax rates over each period. The points as a share of GDP. And larger deprecia- statutory rate fell significantly with each reform. tion allowances boosted after-tax cash flow even The effective tax rate only began to fall signifi- more substantially: by a cumulative total of some cantly with the Martin and then the Harper re- 3–4 points of GDP in the Harper era,12 compared ductions. Compared to the pre-reform era, the to the pre-reform era. average statutory rate during the Harper reform As noted, the gap between after-tax corpo- years (2008 through 2010) was 19 points lower, rate cash flow and business fixed non-residen- and the effective rate was 12 points lower.10 tial capital spending has given rise to a growing As indicated in the preceding figures, how- surplus of what we might call “excess corporate ever, business investment has actually declined saving.” Companies are taking in far more cash relative to the pre-reform period. Using quarterly flow than they allocate to new investments in national income and expenditure data, business Canada. This excess saving reduces expenditure non-residential fixed capital spending declined and purchasing power in the Canadian econo- by 1 full percentage point of GDP in the post-re- my, and is especially damaging during times of form period, compared to the pre-reform period. recession — when the economy needs all sec- The successive Martin and Harper rate reduc- tors to borrow and spend, rather than save and tions did not affect this performance. During accumulate. this period, however, after-tax cash flow went As indicated in Table 2, the cumulative dif- up. So measured as a share of available cash flow, ference between after-tax cash flow and fixed investment spending fell more dramatically, by non-residential investment spending by Cana- about 25 percentage points (from 95 percent of dian businesses has been $745 billion since 2001. cash flow before the reforms, to under 70 percent What have companies done with all that money? of cash flow during the Harper reform years). Money is fungible, of course, and can be allocated Table 1 also indicates the three components and re-allocated into various compartments, so of the increase in after-tax cash flow during this it is impossible to trace the uses of the actual dol- period. Before-tax profits grew by about 1 per- lars corresponding to a particular cash flow. We Table 2 Effective Distribution of Excess Corporate Cash Flow 2001–10 Total Uninvested After-Tax Cash Flow $744.9 billion Excess accumulation of cash and short-term financial assets1 $144.1 billion Excess dividend payouts2 $82.1 billion Reduction in debt3 $232.7 billion Net outflow of FDI $89.8 billion Other (share repurchases, mergers and acquisitions, etc.)4 $196.2 billion Source Author’s calculations from Statistics Canada CANSIM data. Excess cash flow is the cumulative difference between after-tax cash flow (before tax profits less direct taxes plus capital consumption allowances) and fixed non-residential capital spending by businesses, from 2001 through 2010. Includes private and government business enterprises, fixed non-residential capital spending. 1 Currency and short-term assets owned by non-financial corporations only, in excess of the average proportion of GDP that prevailed prior to 2001. 2 Increase in dividend payouts by businesses above the average share of GDP that prevailed prior to 2001. 3 Reduction in corporate debt (short-term, loans, and bonds) as share of total business assets, relative to the ratio recorded at end-2000, times the total value of corporate assets at the end of 2010. 4 Residual. Having Their C ake and Eating It too 13
can illustrate, however, some of the alternative This attribution of excess cash flow to vari- uses of cash which companies have undertaken ous end-uses is by its nature approximate, given during this era of excess corporate saving. Some the impossibility of tracing the flow of particular of these uses are reported in Table 2. money. It is undeniable, however, that corporate Companies have notably increased their stock- Canada has been consistently taking in far more pile of cash and short-term financial assets. Ac- after-tax cash flow — in part as a result of suc- cording to Statistics Canada’s national balance cessive reductions in corporate taxes — than it sheet data, these liquid holdings of non-finan- is reinvesting in Canadian capital spending. In cial businesses in Canada have increased nota- that context, accentuating that cash flow through bly as a share of GDP since 2001. That increase further tax reductions certainly seems like push- in cash holdings (measured relative to the pre- ing on a string. It is highly likely that these tax 2001 average ratio to GDP) is equivalent to $144 reductions would only add to the large sums of billion.13 Dividend payouts to shareholders have uninvested cash flow already being received by also increased (again measured as a share of GDP), Canadian businesses. relative to pre-2001 averages; this corresponds Finally, the apparent lack of correlation be- to an excess cumulative payout of dividends of tween the decline in business taxes (illustrated some $82 billion. Companies have substantially in Figure 5) and the stagnation or modest decline reduced their debt (short-term debt, loans, and in business investment (summarized in Figure bonds), relative to their total assets; this is known 3 and Table 1) can be visualized. Figures 6 and as business “deleveraging,” and it contributed 7 present scatter plots which compare business importantly to the contraction in credit condi- tax rates in each period (total federal-provin- tions which accompanied the recent recession. cial statutory rates in Figure 6, and effective The decline in business debt as a share of total rates in Figure 7, measured in both cases along assets since end-2000 is equivalent to $233 bil- the horizontal axis) with business non-residen- lion worth of debt repayment. On a net basis, tial fixed capital investment (as a share of GDP, foreign direct investment (FDI) has left Canada measured along the vertical axis).14 Each scat- over this period (despite the massive increases ter plot appears as a “cloud” of seemingly ran- in FDI associated with recent takeovers of Cana- domly distributed points, indicating the lack of dian resource properties). This outflow of capi- any meaningful correlation between business tal to foreign jurisdictions could be ascribed as taxes and business investment. Attempting to the end use of another $90 billion of the excess impose a linear relationship onto this cloud is savings. The remaining residual (just under $200 not particularly successful. Indeed, in the case billion) could be attributed to a range of oth- of statutory tax rates, there would seem to be er non-productive uses of corporate cash that a slight positive (upward-sloping) relationship are more difficult to measure, including share between tax rates and investment (contrary to buybacks (which have become common among expectations that higher taxes lead to lower in- companies generating more cash flow than they vestment); in contrast, there is a slight negative reinvest), acquisitions and takeovers (which re- relationship between effective tax rates and in- sult in a reduction of the equity base), and other vestment spending. Neither relationship, how- activities which may make sense for individual ever, is statistically significant.15 companies, but do not translate into real invest- ment in the Canadian economy. 14 c anadian centre for polic y alternatives
figure 6 Business Investment and Statutory Corporate Income Tax Rates 1981–2010 20% 18% Fixed Investments (Percent GDP) 16% 14% Linear Trend 12% 10% 8% 6% 25% 30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 55% Statutory CIT Rate (Percent) source Author’s calculations from Statistics Canada CANSIM data and OECD (2010). Investment is fixed non-residential capital investment by private and government business enterprises. figure 7 Business Investment and Effective Corporate Income Tax Rates 1961–2010 20% 18% Fixed Investments (Percent GDP) 16% 14% 12% Linear Trend 10% 8% 6% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% Effective CIT Rate (Percent) source Author’s calculations from Statistics Canada CANSIM data. Investment is fixed non-residential capital investment by private and government business enterprises. Having Their C ake and Eating It too 15
section 2 Review of Previous Economic Studies of Business Investment Given the importance of business investment composite measures of the cost of capital, and spending to overall economic performance in the relative cost of substitutes). a capitalist economy, economists have gener- In Keynesian or heterodox traditions, on the ated a vast literature on the determinants and other hand, business investment is understood effects of business investment. This literature more from the perspective of its aggregate mac- reflects varying theoretical perspectives of the roeconomic role. Important attention is paid to respective authors; Jorgenson (1971) and Chirinko the independent expectations and decisions of (1993) provided the classic surveys. In the mar- investing firms — what Keynes famously referred ket-oriented neoclassical tradition of econom- to as “animal spirits,” and what other heterodox ics, businesses are expected to accumulate an economists have interpreted as broad indicators optimal capital stock that reflects the varying of the inherent vibrancy and momentum of capi- productivity of different factors of production, tal accumulation. Relevant variables in this ap- relative factor prices, and the impact of tech- proach would include macroeconomic growth nological change on the technical parameters (reflecting the impact of multiplier and accel- of production. Investment is not limited by de- erator effects on capacity utilization, demand, mand conditions (since the economy is assumed and hence investment), interest rates (through to self-adjust at a supply-constrained equilibri- their impact on aggregate demand, in addition um), nor by corporate liquidity (since financial to as an indicator of relative factor prices), and markets are assumed to efficiently allocate sav- even social and institutional factors (such as in- ings to their most productive real investments). come distribution, investment stability, politi- In this view, measured flows of investment are cal-economy conditions, and other structural seen as a movement towards this idealized “op- issues). More recent “neo-Keynesian” models timal” stock of capital. Therefore, they are mod- (eg. Fazzari et al., 1988) place emphasis on the eled on the basis of the standard core variables liquidity constraints limiting investment by par- of Walrasian general equilibrium (in particular ticular firms that might arise from asymmetric factor supplies, relative factor prices, including information problems. Underpinning all these 16 c anadian centre for polic y alternatives
approaches is the recognition that the economy entire economy, this research often focused on is rarely supply-constrained, but rather normally firm-level data; and rather than tracking invest- expands in response to demand-side conditions ment over longer periods of time, they often ze- (including purchasing power, credit creation, roed in on shorter, “before-and-after” snapshots and business and consumer expectations). This of the effects of specific policy changes. These creates complex two-way feedbacks between approaches are worth reviewing, but it should investment and growth, whereby investment always be kept in mind that they are driven by causes growth, which in turn elicits more in- the theoretical predisposition of their authors. vestment. These macroeconomic mechanisms Their hope is to empirically identify a strong are not analyzed within a neoclassical approach, coefficient on the cost of capital in an empirical which focuses on supply-side determinants, and study of investment behaviour; in their view this is mostly concerned with optimal allocation of would validate the neoclassical interpretation of factor supplies (rather than the growth trajec- investment as an adjustment toward an optimal tory of capital accumulation). Walrasian capital stock. The relevance of this ap- Another class of empirical studies of invest- proach to understanding tax policy, is that if the ment behaviour has emphasized the interactions cost of capital is seen to be the crucial determi- between the stock market and real business in- nant of investment, then policy measures to re- vestment, following on the insights of Tobin duce that cost (such as reductions in corporate (1969) regarding the contrast between the market taxes, which increase the net cost of capital by value of business assets (reflected in stock prices) siphoning off funds which would otherwise con- and the replacement cost of real capital. Numer- stitute a return to investment) should be effec- ous models have extended this approach, which tive in eliciting more investment (depending on can be interpreted through either a neoclassical the extent to which the tax reforms changed the cost-of-capital lens, or through a liquidity-con- cost of capital). 16 In contrast, cost-of-capital co- strained demand-side lens. efficients in aggregate macroeconometric studies In addition to these varying theoretical per- tend to be small or non-existent. This approach, spectives, there are many choices to be made in instead, points to the importance of growth, li- terms of empirical methodology: using econo- quidity, and other demand-side mechanisms.17 metric methods (grounded in historical data) or This vast literature cannot be reviewed here. mathematical simulations (including the general The main point to make in the context of the equilibrium simulations popular with analysts current debates over investment and tax policy in the Walrasian tradition), using aggregate or in Canada is that there is a huge variation in the firm-level data, and the precise specification of findings of different economic models of invest- variables and relationships. ment behaviour, depending on the perspective of For many years, writers in the neoclassical or the modeler and the precise methodology cho- Walrasian tradition were frustrated by the ap- sen. There is no consensus among economists parent non-significance of their hypothesized regarding the determinants of investment, nor explanatory variables (relative factor prices, and the impact of specific policy measures. Anyone the distorting impact of policy interventions like who claims that their perspective is supported taxes) in empirical studies of investment behav- by “the literature” or by a “consensus” among iour. This led many of them (pioneered by Jorgen- economists, is reflecting an unduly narrow inter- son) to experiment with new ways of empirically pretation of the diverse and inconclusive litera- modeling investment decisions. Rather than ana- ture that has actually been published regarding lyzing aggregate investment spending across an the determinants of investment spending. And Having Their C ake and Eating It too 17
in many cases there is no need to make a firm arithmetically, based on the proportional effect “either-or” choice between the competing theo- of lower taxes on after-tax cash flow and hence retical perspectives; a more flexible and eclectic on investment. However, as seen above, this is model would allow for a range of supply-side and clearly not true: the re-investment rate is vari- demand-side influences. The impact of capital- able, and has declined markedly over the last cost effects on investment spending (whether two decades. If the re-investment rate declines interpreted as the result of Walrasian-style flex- further, then by this methodology there could ibility in factor allocations, or as reflecting op- be no impact on investment. portunity cost or liquidity channels which are Following a neoclassical optimal capital stock not really consistent with the Walrasian model) approach, Chen and Mintz (2010, 2011) suggest can certainly be admitted, while still allowing that a 10 percent decline in the cost of capital will for the macroeconomic and demand-side factors lead to a 7 percent increase in the capital stock. which seem to predominate in the longer-run Allowing for several years of adjustment (the au- historical macroeconomic evidence.18 thors suggest at least seven), the 3-point tax rate In addition to this short introduction to the reduction, converted into a 2.5 point reduction many efforts by economists to understand the in the marginal effective tax rate, would eventu- determinants of business investment, this sec- ally generate $49 billion in increased capital ac- tion will also briefly review several specific stud- cumulation.20 In somewhat of a departure from ies that refer to Canadian investment experience. the neoclassical principles of this approach, this Some of these studies have been invoked by ad- new investment is also predicted to be associated vocates of further business tax cuts in Canada with the creation of 233,000 new jobs in Cana- as evidence that lower business taxes will lead da — which implies that employment in Canada to increased business investment. How do these is currently constrained by inadequate invest- studies conclude that lower taxes will generate ment, whereas Walrasian models are premised increased investment, despite the seeming lack on market-clearing outcomes in factor markets.21 of correlation between tax rates and business in- As with the CME report, this research provides vestment in recent Canadian economic history? no new empirical evidence to support the link A study by the Canadian Manufacturers and between tax cuts and investment; rather, the 0.7 Exporters (2010) suggests that a 1-percent re- elasticity estimate is supported only by second- duction in effective federal taxes will stimulate ary references, to Parsons (2008) in particular. a relatively modest 0.11% increase in investment The Chen-Mintz papers simply utilize this 0.7 spending. Consequently, the 17% reduction in elasticity in a numerical simulation to calculate effective federal taxes associated with the pro- the expected change in investment if that esti- posed 3-point reduction (along with the final mate were valid. elimination of capital taxes) would generate an Let us then consider the paper for the federal increase of about 2% in business investment.19 Department of Finance by Parsons (2008), since This claim is based on the simple assumption it underpins the Chen-Mintz numerical simula- that the proportion of after-tax cash flow which tions, and differs from the CME and Chen-Mintz businesses reinvest in Canadian capital projects studies in that it actually analyzes Canadian em- remains roughly fixed over time; there is no em- pirical evidence regarding the impact of corporate pirical evidence reported to suggest that lower tax cuts on investment. Parsons utilizes sectoral business taxes have actually increased invest- data on business fixed investment from 43 man- ment spending in practice. Hence the impact ufacturing and service sector industries over the of lower taxes on investment can be estimated period from 1998 through 2004. Recall that the 18 c anadian centre for polic y alternatives
figure 8 Investment Indices by Sector 1997–2004, 2000=100 140 130 Resources Services Manufacturing 120 Real Investment (2000=100) 110 100 90 80 70 60 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 source Author’s calculations from Statistics Canada CANSIM data. Paul Martin tax cuts (reducing the statutory rate (measured as a proportion of the starting capital from 28 percent to 21 percent) were introduced stock) by 3 to 7 percent. Applied retroactively to beginning in 2001, and phased in by 2004 — but the post-2001 period, this should imply an in- those reforms did not benefit the manufacturing crease in the overall Canadian investment rate and resource sectors (which were already pay- (investment measured as a share of starting capi- ing taxes at a preferential 21 percent rate). Par- tal) of 10 to 25 percent (based on the Martin and sons’ so-called “natural experiment” thus con- Harper business tax cuts).24 sists of comparing investment behaviour in the There are obvious methodological issues with services industries (which did benefit from the Parsons’ approach. First, there may be many tax cuts) to manufacturing sectors (which did other factors which explain why investment di- not), as a way of imputing the effects of the tax verged between services and manufacturing in- cut. Importantly, he excludes resources indus- dustries over the short four-year post-tax-reform tries from his analysis,22 on questionable grounds period which he analyzed. 2001 was marked, of that investment in those sectors “is affected by course, by the terrible events of 9-11, followed by different factors than other industries.” Parsons the effective closing of the Canada-U.S. border, uses two different methodologies to estimate massive disruptions in the manufacturing sup- the impact of tax cuts, which produce two dif- ply chain, and then a short recession in the U.S. ferent estimates of the sensitivity of investment which reduced Canadian manufacturing exports with respect to tax cuts: ranging from 0.3 to 0.7.23 to our largest international customer. Beginning Parsons’ results can be interpreted as implying in 2002, then, world commodity prices began to that a 10 percent reduction in what he calls the rise substantially, pushing up the Canadian dol- “tax wedge” (resulting from lower corporate in- lar, and this caused further problems for Canada’s come taxes) would increase the investment rate manufacturing sector, as did the tribulations that Having Their C ake and Eating It too 19
were experienced in the North American auto ity of investment with respect to output, in or- industry beginning about the same time. Servic- der to curtail the macroeconomic multiplier and es, on the other hand, being oriented mostly to accelerator effects that typically dominate most the domestic market, did not experience simi- econometric results). Once these assumptions lar consequences from the U.S. recession or the were imposed on the model, then investment appreciating Canadian currency. Nominally, was seen to be more sensitive with respect to its Parsons attempts to take account of these ad- cost (including, presumably, the tax component ditional causal factors by including other vari- of that cost). However, their finding of an even ables in his regression (namely output growth in larger elasticity than Parsons (equal to almost 1) each sector and the relative price of capital), but is once again entirely contingent on the validity those variables were not significant and hence of the initial constraints imposed on the model were dropped from his model. Moreover, by ex- (namely that capital expands only proportion- cluding resources, Parsons excluded several sec- ately with output); without those constraints, the tors from his analysis where the tax rate did not data do not support the hypothesis that invest- decline — but where investment spending did ment is so sensitive to its user cost. increase (in response to rising global commod- A couple of international studies also make ity prices). Figure 8 illustrates the contrasting reference to Canadian experience. A recent re- trends in aggregate investment over the period port by several economists associated with the considered by Parsons, over the 1997–2004 pe- World Bank makes very strong predictions re- riod. Manufacturing investment fell (for rea- garding the impact of tax cuts on business invest- sons noted), and services investment grew, but ment (Djankov et al., 2008). After analyzing in resources investment grew even more strongly. firm-level data the impact of various tax reforms The Parsons elasticity is based on comparing in a number of countries, this study estimates investment trends between manufacturing and that a 10 percent reduction in effective business services only, without controlling adequately taxes leads to a 2.2 percentage point increase in for additional factors, and arbitrarily excluding investment measured as a share of GDP (a very a set of sectors (resources) whose experience did substantial increase in the investment share). The not mesh with the model. Little wonder, then, data reviewed in Section 1 above confirm clearly that the strong response of business investment that this result was not attained in Canada: the that Parsons posits between investment and tax investment rate fell, rather, despite a decrease in rates, based on an unduly narrow set of indus- effective tax rates of over one-quarter. Similarly, tries over a short period of history, is not visible Cummins et al. (1996) review the impact of spe- in data covering the broader Canadian economy cific tax reform instances in a range of countries, over longer periods of time. including Canada’s 1988 reform, using a model Another federal Department of Finance report that combines Tobin-style and neoclassical pre- (ab Iorwerth and Danforth, 2004) also attempts cepts. Among other findings, they find that in- to identify a stronger elasticity of investment with vestment spending in Canada is constrained by respect to its user cost in historical data on Ca- corporate cash flow, with a coefficient of 0.23 nadian business investment. In this research, the (ie. 23 cents of each dollar in incremental cash authors initially find no econometric evidence flow is translated into new business investment). that investment is sensitive to its user cost. But There are several other published studies of then they exogenously impose certain neoclas- Canadian investment behaviour which do not sical assumptions on their regression model (in directly touch on the related issues of cost-of- particular, the assumption of a unitary elastic- capital and business taxes, including Schaller 20 c anadian centre for polic y alternatives
(1993), Landon and Smith (2006), Christensen der to find that result. And many studies of the and Dib (2008), Kalyvitis (2006), Faroque and Mi- Canadian data find that other investment deter- nor (2003), and Aivazian et al. (2005). The over- minants (ranging from macroeconomic growth all literature on Canadian investment behaviour, to corporate liquidity to accelerator effects) are therefore, is as eclectic and inconclusive as the the crucial determinants of investment spend- international literature. While some studies con- ing. At any rate, it is certainly not reasonable to clude that user costs of capital (and, by extension, claim that the notion that business tax cuts will corporate tax rates) are significant determinants stimulate significant investment expenditure is of business investment, these studies typically supported by any kind of consensus in the eco- rely on the imposition of strong prior theoretical nomic literature. or empirical assumptions and exclusions in or- Having Their C ake and Eating It too 21
section 3 Econometric Analysis of Business Investment and Business Tax Rates In order to cast some independent light on the taneity problems. For every specification con- significance (or not) of business taxation in the sidered below, the regressions were conducted determination of business investment, this sec- for the entire sample period (1961 through 2010, tion will use econometric techniques to analyze before adjusting for the impact of lagged varia- the actual historical data regarding Canadian bles on sample size), and then separately for the business investment spending and its potential pre-reform and post-reform periods (before and determinants. Econometric regressions were after the first quarter of 1988), in order to test for conducted on quarterly data regarding busi- structural shifts in relationships in the wake of ness fixed non-residential investment spending the successive tax reforms. (as a share of GDP), and a range of its potential We first tested directly for the significance of determinants. Some of the explanatory vari- corporate tax rates by performing simple single- ables are non-stationary, and hence the regres- variable regressions of the investment share on sions are performed in first-differenced form both statutory and effective tax rates. Effective (all variables are stationary in first differences). tax rates are based on national income accounts With quarterly data, independent variables can data and hence are available in quarterly form. exhibit unpredictable lag patterns in their re- In contrast, our data on statutory tax rates is lationship to the dependent variable. We adopt annual; these rates were thus applied to all four an agnostic approach to capturing these lag pat- quarters in each calendar year. terns, by including lags of 1, 2, 4, and 8 periods Table 3 summarizes the findings of these in initial specifications, and then excluding the simple regressions.25 As was hinted by the weak lags which were least significant. For those ex- relationships visible in the scatter plots above planatory variables which could be considered (Figures 6 and 7), there is no robust evidence of truly exogenous (such as statutory taxes and a direct relationship between tax rates and busi- the oil price), current values are also included ness investment. The effective tax rate was not in the tests; otherwise, we use only lags of the significant in any of the three regressions (total independent variables in order to avoid simul- sample, pre-reform, and post-reform). The statu- 22 c anadian centre for polic y alternatives
Table 3 Tests for Significance of Tax Variables in Regressions of Business Fixed Non-Residential Investment Full Sample Period Pre-Reform Post-Reform (1961:1–2010:4) (1961:1–1987:4) (1988:1–2010:4) Simple Regressions Effective tax rate None None None Statutory tax rate None None 10% level (negative) Multiple Regressions (Fully-Specified Model1) Effective tax rate 5% level (positive) None None Statutory tax rate None None 10% level (positive) Source Author’s calculations based on Statistics Canada CANSIM and OECD data, as described in text. Dependent variable is first difference of business fixed non-residential capital spending as share of GDP. Full regression results available from author. 1 Coefficients of fully specified model are reported in Table 4. tory rate was weakly significant (at the 10% level) Fazzari et al., 1988, and by Schaller, 1993, in with the expected negative sign in the full sample a Canadian context). period, but not in either of the truncated samples. • Real interest rates (equal to prime This single-variable approach can miss the corporate lending rates less the year- potential impact of tax rates on investment over-year growth in consumer prices in spending, however, since it excludes the other Canada). Interest rates affect business major determinants of business investment. So investment via opportunity cost effects we also test for the significance of the tax vari- (symbolizing returns that could be ables (both statutory and effective) within the captured via purely financial investments), context of a fully-specified investment equation. and cost-of-capital channels. Based on previous econometric studies of busi- • Oil prices (U.S. average price expressed in ness investment, we considered the following Canadian dollars). Given the importance explanatory variables in these regressions (all of energy-related projects in Canada’s included in first-difference form): overall investment, oil prices may have • The rate of growth of real GDP (measured an independent impact on investment as the change in the log of real GDP). In spending. a demand-constrained macroeconomic • The exchange rate can impact system, business capital spending will investment spending in complex and depend importantly on the growth path contradictory ways, by affecting the cost of output and sales. Stronger growth of imported capital equipment, the cost generates additional investment (the so- competitiveness of Canadian investment called “accelerator” effect) via impacts on locations, and through other channels capacity utilization and expected sales (Landon and Smith, 2007). potential. • Relative prices of capital goods (measured • After-tax business cash flow (measured by the ratio of the chained deflator for non- as a share of GDP). This variable captures residential fixed capital spending to the both incentive effects (higher after-tax chained deflator for GDP as a whole). Some profits eliciting more investment), and the economists have theorized (such as Tevlin potential impact of liquidity constraints and Whalen, 2003) that the decreasing on business investment (as investigated by cost of some types of capital equipment Having Their C ake and Eating It too 23
You can also read