Federations, Confederations and Umbrella Organizations - Classification and Governance of Multi-Level Associations1
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Federations, Confederations and Umbrella Organizations – Classification and Governance of Multi-Level Associations1 Torbjörn Einarsson, Stockholm School of Economics, Sweden, ate@hhs.se Bidrag till: Företagsekonomisk ämneskonferens 2009, 11-12 nov Draft version, please do not quote without permission of the author. In this paper I address the issue of how to understand complex structures of interrelated associations as for example the International Federation of Red Cross and Red Crescent Societies (IFRC) or Fédération Internationale de Football Association (FIFA). The arguments take departure in part from Ahrne and Brunsson’s (2005; 2008) work on meta-organizations but I also adopt a perspective where several formally autonomous associations can be regarded as forming of a more or less coherent organization. These multi-level associations are sometimes denominated as federations, confederations or umbrella organizations often without any further description or definition. I show that it is neither unproblematic to delimit nor to classify these organizational structures and therefore propose five variables that could be studied in order to shed a light on those problems. I argue that a fruitful way of delimiting multi-level associations is by examining (A) the correspondence of organizational identities and (B) mutual dependence across associational levels. I further argue that classification of federations and confederations could be done by an examination of (C) the distribution of power within a multi-level association, (D) if the individual’s membership contract primarily connect him or her to the local association or to the whole multi-level association and (E) if the governance system is organized to represent the individuals or the local associations. Finally I demonstrate the benefits of such a classification by briefly discussing how some expected differences between the three identified types of multi-level association could affect the organizations’ formal governance systems as well as the material balance of power. Much of contemporary organizational theory have been developed in order to describe the function of or to handle problems in formal organizations consisting of either one single juridical entity or a group of companies where the parent company formally owns the others and is in charge over all activities in its subsidiaries. In such groups of companies the parent company owns subsidiaries and by virtue of its ownership the parent company has a formal 1 This paper has been written in the context of the larger Civil Society Research Program at the Center for Management and Organization at Stockholm School of Economics and I thank my colleagues for their comments on this and earlier texts. I would also like to thank Professor Göran Ahrne at Stockholm University for his most valuable comments on an early draft of this paper. 1
decision power regarding activities of its subsidiaries. An implicit assumption in much of this kind of research is that the members of the organization are individuals (Ahrne and Brunsson 2005). Ahrne and Brunsson (2005; 2008) added to this knowledge by distinguishing between organizations with individuals as members and organizations whose members are other organizations (meta-organizations). Their empirical examples include amongst others organizations as the Community of European Management Schools (CEMS), the Swedish Association of Industry, the European Union and the Swedish Floorball Association. They argued that differences due to the type of members an organization have will affect basic organizational theoretical issues as the creation and sustainment of organizations, conflicts in organizations and organizational change. There is however also a large and influential group of organizations in society that consists of combinations of meta-organizations and individual-based organizations (e.g. Salamon and Anheier 1997; Wijkström and Einarsson 2006). Empirical phenomenon that in spite of the fact that they are composed of a multitude of formal organizations in many cases is suitable to consider as coherent organizations. Two of the organizations Ahrne and Brunsson discusses, the Swedish Floorball Association and the European Union are by themselves examples of meta-organizations since they have either floorball associations or states as members. But it is also possible to see them as larger integrated entities. A citizen in a European state could be regarded as a citizen in the European Union and an individual member in a floorball association could be seen as a member in the Swedish Floorball Association. While Ahrne and Brunsson (2005; 2008) used these organizations as examples of meta-organizations I will in this paper use two other similarly structured organizations to illustrate that it often can be meaningful to deal with a meta-organization together with its member-organizations as one coherent organization. One of the empirical organizations I discuss in this paper hopefully illustrates this point more clearly. Most people would probably regard the Swedish Red Cross (SRC) as a large integrated organization and it may in many cases be reasonable standpoint. But formally SRC consists of more than 1 200 local associations alongside with the national association. The question is how we could know which of all these and surrounding associations it would make sense to bundle when we think about the SRC as a whole. One of the aspects that make this judgment difficult in this kind of organization is the reversed power structures. In a group company we would expect that the parent company would have all of the formal power. But 2
the highest decision-making body within the SRC, the national assembly, consists of representatives elected by the local associations (Swedish Red Cross 2009a). That is, the local associations are formally in control of the national association. These kinds of organizations have mainly figured in research about co-operatives and have often been denominated as federations or to a lesser extent as confederations. Implications of the reversed power structures have been discussed from various perspectives but the boundaries of the organizations have in most cases been taken for granted. Since one of my main points is that the boundaries often are unclear and depending on one’s point of view and purposes I will use the term multi-level associations. I will however further discuss some ideal typical characteristics of federative and confederative structures but my two case organizations will show that empirical organizations simultaneously may present both federative and confederative characteristics simultaneously. In order to better understand why it could be sensible to view multi-level associations as forming a coherent whole we can pose the question why multi-level associations appear in the first place. Ahrne and Brunsson (2005) suggests some possible reasons for organizations to join meta-organizations. It could be argued that it is more efficient to co-operate in common matters and pool resources in order to achieve things that the individual organizations themselves could not do. The membership in a meta-organization might also affect the member’s social status at the same time as the membership is important for the member’s identity. Ahrne and Brunsson’s argument is however restricted to organizations’ membership in meta-organizations. They do not discuss how and why this structure might evolve into a larger whole. The traditional explanation often found in many multi-level associations’ jubilee publications is that the organization emerged locally among the grass-roots and that local associations later joined together in district and national associations in order to further their co-operation. This view can however be challenged, as for example by Skocpol et al (2000). They argue that adopting a similar structure as the political system of local, regional and national levels made it easier for the organizations to exert influence. Other non-political organizations then adapted to this already legitimate and well understood model of organizing (cf. DiMaggio and Powell 1983). Skocpol et al (2000) further argue that this multi-level structure also proved to be effective in order to spread the organizations through the country. National and regional units offered help and standards which made it easier for people to set up local units in new 3
locations. Olson (1971) also argues that multi-level organizations might be more effective in certain circumstances. Small local units could be used as an instrument for increasing people’s involvement through social incentives which are not available in larger settings. Both Ahrne and Brunsson’s arguments and the organizations’ own creational myths do explain why organizations choose to co-operate with each other through a common unit but they do not clarify under which conditions the member organizations along with the common unit forms some kind of a whole. Skocpol et al and Olson’s does almost the opposite. They explain that it under certain circumstances is wise to structure a larger organization in multiple layers of semi-autonomous organizations. I will in this paper attend to two basic problems concerning multi-level associations which in previous literature have not been properly addressed. The first question is how to delimit a multi-level association from other organizations which are connected through the bond of membership and through that essentially distinguish between meta-organizations and coherent multi-level associations. The second question is about how the great variety of organizational structures among multi-level associations could be understood and classified.2 The last section of the paper is dedicated to some aspects of governance in multi-level associations in order to show that analysis of the two above questions can help us to better understand empirical organizations. Sjöstrand (2000) point out the importance in distinguishing between three perspectives on organizations: organizations as theoretical constructs or ideal types, legal definitions of organizations and empirical expressions of organization. These three perspectives are at the same time separate and interrelated because the perspectives exert influence on each other. Legal rules affect how real organizations are structured, while empirical organizations is the 2 The scope of this paper is limited to multi-level associations where the “local” units consist of individual based associations. Part of the arguments in this paper should however probably also apply for other similar organizational structures too. The discussion of how to delimit a multi-level association could for example be applied to multi-level trade associations with firms as members. It would maybe also be interesting to assess if the power structures in such an organization bear more or less traits of a federation or a confederation even if the analysis must be somewhat adapted. 4
basis for theoretical constructs that in turn affect legal definitions. I will in this paper adopt two of these three perspectives. The two above mentioned questions will be discussed on a theoretical level and I will also make a couple of ideal typical descriptions of different forms of multi-level associations. In this I will use two empirical organizations in order to illustrate my arguments. The legal perspective will however be in the background. Finding and delimiting multi level-associations The basic organizational building block that link multi-level associations together is the membership. An individual (among other individuals) holds a membership in a local association which in turn (among other associations) holds a membership in a national association possibly with one or more layers of regional associations in between. When analyzing formal organizations the question of delimiting the organization is often a minor problem since boundaries are quite well defined. This might also in the case of multi- level associations at first sight be seen as a trivial question. It would for example be easy to say that the Swedish Red Cross simply is composed of the national association and the local associations. But the SRC in turn holds a membership in the International Federation of Red Cross and Red Crescent Societies (IFRC). Would it then be appropriate to see the all local Red Cross associations together with all national Red Cross societies as one gigantic organization? Is it then possible to identify other or better ways to delimit the organization than by tracing formal membership-ties among associations? Would it maybe be suitable to delimit the organization at the national level? It could possibly be argued that differences in for example language, culture and in the legal system regarding associations makes that kind of delimitation appropriate. We would in that case understand it as if every country has their own national Red Cross multi level-association which join together in the international umbrella-association IFRC. But even if using country boundaries would be appropriate it is however not always enough in order to make a clear distinction. The formal structures of the Swedish Football Association (SFA) resemble the structures of the SRC. Individuals hold memberships in local associations which in turn hold memberships in a national association. The national 5
association is also a member of international associations such as the Union of European Football Associations (UEFA) and the Fédération Internationale de Football Association (FIFA). So far we have the same type of problem as with delimiting the SRC. But the SFA also holds a membership in the Swedish Sports Confederation which gathers all Swedish sport federations. Since it could seem to be a little bit farfetched to bundle football players and horseback riders with swimmers and race-car drivers it is apparent that we must find another way to delimit the organization than just by the combination of formal membership ties and country borders. An even more obvious example of the problem of only using the membership connection in order to establish the scope of an organization is the SRC’s membership in the Swedish Fundraising Council (SFC). There are probably no one that would consider the SRC together with the SFC and its other members as the Church of Sweden and the Swedish Guide and Scout Council to be part of a larger meaningful whole. The two multi level-associations that I have used as examples could be illustrated as in figure 1. Both complexes stretch over several formal associations both within Sweden and internationally. SFA with its membership in the Swedish Sports Confederation and SRC’s membership in the Swedish Fundraising Council makes it clear that the seemingly easy solution to use country borders for delimiting the multi level-associations is not enough. IFRC UEFA International organizations Swedish Red Cross Swedish Fundraising Swedish Football Swedish Sports Council Association Confederation Local association Local association Domestic organizations Individual Individual member member Figure 1: The Swedish Red Cross and the Swedish Football Association and some of their memberships in other associations. 6
Two promising alternatives for delimiting multi-level associations are to analyze similarities of organizational identity and differences in mutual dependence among integral associations. (A) Does the organizational identity correspond between the organizational levels? Associational levels that share the same organizational identity could also be seen as belonging to the same multi level-association. One first strong indicator of shared identities between associational levels would be a shared name. Another indicator would be shared purposes and activities between associational levels. A third indicator is the intra-organizational understanding of the multi level-association’s boundaries. How far do the individual member’s identification with the multi-level association stretch and with the reversed perspective how far away in the associational chain do the associations acknowledge the individual members as a part of the organization? (B) Is there a mutual dependency between associational levels? Would it be possible for a meta-association and its member-associations to continue their activities without large modifications if any of the associational levels would disappear? If two associational levels are highly dependent on each other they could be regarded as belonging to the same multi level-association. If these two questions are answered affirmatively it should make sense to bundle the two analyzed associational levels into a more coherent organizational structure. The following step is to continue to make the same analysis at the next associational level. Two additional ways of assessing where it would be appropriate to delimit a multi level- association could be sought in analyzing the history of the associations and the power distribution among the associational levels. How and when have different parts of the multi level-association been created? Was it as in many of the organizational myths a number of local associations that together created a national association to further their co-operation or was the national association founded first and later on spread through formation of local associations in new locations? Regarding the power distribution it would seem to be natural to group associations that have real and not only formal possibilities of influencing each other. I will however not use any of these two latter alternatives ways for delimiting the multi level-associations in this paper since I think the two firstly stated is enough. I do also not have 7
sufficient empirical data on history and actual power distributions for the two example organizations. I will nonetheless return to discussing power distribution when I propose a classification scheme for multi level-associations. The Swedish Red Cross and the Swedish Football Association To exemplify the criterions of identity and mutual dependence I will apply them on the Swedish Red Cross and the Swedish Football Association. If we start by looking at the SRC and its integral associations we can see that both the national association and all the local associations share the same name. The national association is named “the Swedish Red Cross” while all local associations have names indicating the local community supplemented with “Red Cross”. Taking this one step further we also notice that the international federation, the IFRC, have “Red Cross” in its name. In addition to the shared name all these three levels of associations within the Red Cross also share the same basic purpose: to “prevent and alleviate human suffering” (International Federation of Red Cross and Red Crescent Societies 2007; Swedish Red Cross 2009a). The organizational identity across all these associational levels consequently seems to correspond quite well. Would this be more nuanced if we took into account voices from within the organizations? Wordings in an organization’s annual report ought to be seen as an official voice from the organization. The Swedish Red Cross reported that they 2008 had 253 448 individual members distributed among 1 235 local associations (Swedish Red Cross 2009b). This indicates that the national association thinks that it reaches from the individual through the local association to the Swedish Red Cross. IFRC in turn report that they in the same year had 186 Red Cross and Red Crescent societies around the world as members (International Federation of Red Cross and Red Crescent Societies 2009). IFRC does consequently not try to extend their reach further than to its immediate member-organizations. The dependence between local associations and the Swedish Red Cross seem to be relatively high. Even if it would be theoretically possible it is hard to imagine the local associations without the Swedish Red Cross or vice versa. It is also hard to see that IFRC could carry out activities to the same extent without the national organizations. The national organizations would however probably be able to carry on with most of their activities without IFRC. 8
This analysis show that all the associational levels from the local associations via the Swedish Red Cross to the IFRC are relatively tight coupled. The “Red Cross”-identity seems to be strong at all associational levels and the individual members in Sweden think that the IFRC are important to them. The organizational purpose is also the same on all these associational levels. I would however anyway choose to delimit the associational complex so that it is composed by the local associations and the Swedish Red Cross but not the IFRC. My two main reasons for that is the IFRC’s dissociation from the individual members and that the SRC seem to be less dependent on the IFRC than the national and local associations within Sweden are dependent on each other. The Swedish Fundraising Council is also left out since there is only a small shared identity as fundraising organizations, the purpose differs and the Swedish Fundraising Council would probably not consider the SRC’s individual members as part of the organization. What would a similar analysis of the Swedish Football Association tell us? In Sweden it is common that sports associations have more than one sport on their athletic program. Consequently, many football playing associations do not have “football” in their name. A common identity among football associations could consequently not be built on the name. Since one of the main activities of the football associations is to compete against each other the name of the association is instead a strong source of identification that distinguishes associations from each other. At the national and international levels the Football Association and UEFA share the keyword “football”. The Swedish Sports Confederation do however not have football in its name since it gather (nearly) all national sports associations in Sweden. The purpose of local football associations varies a lot partly because the local associations can have more than football on their athletic program. The purpose of the Swedish Football Association is stated as to “promote and manage the sport of football in Sweden and to represent it internationally” (Swedish Football Association 2009a) and UEFA should ”deal with all questions relating to European football” (Union of European Football Associations 2007). Consequently there are clear differences among these purposes ranging from playing the game, maybe among a limited number of other sports, to manage the sports and deal with all the questions relating to European football. But they all have football as at least one of its main interest or activities. The Swedish Sports Confederation on its part should “manage common concerns for the sports movement both nationally and internationally” (Swedish Sports Confederation 2005) in which football just become one of many different sports on the agenda. 9
In their annual report the Swedish Football Association seems to dissociate somewhat from the individual members when they report that they have 3 375 associations as members where more than one million individuals are members (Swedish Football Association 2009b). It could be interpreted that they consider the local associations more as their primary members instead of the individual members. The SFA do nevertheless mention the individuals in the same sentence whereas UEFA do not mention the individual members at all when they say that they are comprised of 53 national football associations (Union of European Football Associations 2009). The Swedish Sports Confederation reports that they primarily are constituted by 68 sports associations (Swedish Sports Confederation 2009). In a later passage of the text it is however stated that the sports movement have more than three million members. The dependence between local football associations and SFA seem to be considerably high. The tournaments and series in which the local associations play in are organized by SFA and its regional association and without local football associations SFA would not have any sport to promote. SFA is in its turn dependent on UEFA and FIFA for international tournaments but could probably continue all its national activities without help from the international associations. SFA and the local association would also probably be able to continue its activities without the Swedish Sports Confederation even if that would potentially involve a considerable loss of state grants. All this taken together I would draw the border around the local associations and the SFA. SFA seems to partly want to dissociate itself from the individuals but the mutual dependence between the associations and SFA and the similarities in their football-identity should however compensate for that. UEFA, FIFA and the Swedish Sports Confederation are left out due to the even lower degree of shared identity and mutual dependence. As the two examples of multi level-associations demonstrate, these kinds of organizations can be fairly different. The associational levels could be more tightly coupled together like the Swedish Red Cross in relation to the Swedish Football Association. Since we could expect that this kind of difference could result in variations in the functioning of the organizations we cannot stop with delimiting a multi level-association. We must also find a way to classify it in accordance to those differences. 10
Classification of multi-level associations Maybe the most interesting difference between different multi-level associations is the formal distribution and material balance of power. The distribution of power between different levels of a multi-level association is also in part dependent on a variable we already have discussed – the mutual dependence between associational levels. In Emerson’s (1962) words: “power resides implicitly in the other’s dependency”. The dependence of an actor upon another actor is proportional to the first actor’s motivational investment in inducements from the second actor and inversely proportional to the availability of those inducements from outside that particular relationship. One distinction that sometimes is made between various types of multi-level associations or other types of multi-level organizations and often is connected to the distribution of power is the distinction between federations and confederations. Any commonly accepted usage of the two terms does however not seem to exist and their usage would rather be attributed to political scientists than to organizational scientists. Most scholars seem to prefer one of the terms and let it denote all types of multi-level organizations. Crémer and Palfrey (1999) writes: A confederation is an institutional arrangement in which the policies of different districts are, at least in part, influenced by the preferences of voters from other districts in the confederation. In practice, this is usually accomplished through a complex array of overlapping jurisdictions, representative governments at different levels, and a legal system that allocates decision-making authority and responsibility across these different levels. This quite wide definition makes it clear that the theoretical ideal type of in this case a confederation could empirical be expressed in very different ways. Ahrne and Brunsson (2008) also argue that the terms federation and confederation in most cases are too vague and unclear so they chose not to use the terms at all. Despite the obvious vagueness of the terms federation and confederation I will use them in order to avoid the inevitable confusion with inventing new terms. I will however use the terms to denominate two ideal typical forms of multi-level associations which resides on different end on a floating scale. Empirical organizations will probably more or less show characteristics from both these ideal types. One scholar that does make a distinction between confederations and federations is Blankart (2007). He argues that a confederation is built on a two-level contract. The individuals hold memberships in and acknowledge the local association. The local association 11
in turn, as an organization, holds a membership in the central association. A federation is instead building on a direct contract between the individual members and the central association. The confederation is a treaty among more or less autonomous local associations while the federation is a treaty directly among individual members (cf. Blankart 2007). One implication of Blankart’s definition is that local associations keep their autonomy in a confederation whereas they become more or less integrated in a federation since the individual members are direct principals both over the local association and over the central association. The membership-relationship in confederations and federations could thus be illustrated as in figure 2. Central Central association association Memb. Membership Local association Local assoc. Memb. Individual member Individual member Figure 2: The membership in ideal typical confederations and federations. It is however not as simple as analyzing the nature of the membership contract in order to settle where in the multi-level association the power resides. Crémer and Palfrey (1999) studied implications of different structures of federalism by separating the dimensions of centralization and representation. Centralization indicate on what associational level the most important decisions are made while the dimension of representation distinguish different multi-level associations depending on if it is the individuals or the local associations that is represented in the central association’s governance system. If every local association would have one vote each it would clearly be the local association that is represented. If the votes are allocated among the local associations proportional to their numbers of individual members the system is more designed to represent the individual members. But this is seldom drawn to the extreme. Every local association 12
sends representatives that are elected by their members but the individual members do not have the possibility to vote for representatives in other local associations. The two questions about which associational level the individual’s membership contract is anchored in and of the structure of the governance system is often related to the question of but it is not necessary the same. There could also be many variants of these two ideal governance types. It is for example quite common with governance systems where the votes primarily are distributed according to the number of members while small local associations are guaranteed to have a fixed minimum number of votes. The two first variables (A and B) were used to determine boundaries for multi-level associations. In this second step, I argue that the most important variables to have in mind while trying to classify multi-level associations into confederations and federations are: (C) The formal distribution of power between local and central associations. (D) If the membership contract is between individual and local association or between individual and central association. (E) If it primarily are the individuals or the local associations that are represented in the central associations governance system. The ideal typical federation has a high degree of centralized power, an individual membership directly connected to the central association and the individual directly connected to the central association through the membership. In the ideal typical confederation the local associations are autonomous, most of the power is retained at the local level and the individual do primarily hold a membership in the local association. The ideal type of the federation as an organization with a direct relationship to the individual members is close to a fully integrated association. The ideal typical confederation with autonomous local associations in turn is close to umbrella organizations or meta- organizations with Ahrne and Brunsson’s (2005) words as already discussed. When turning to empirical organizations it is possible to find many types of organizations with characteristics mixed from both federations and confederations. Since the division between federations and confederations seem to be a floating scale I propose to place them on a one-dimensional scale that as in figure 3. 13
Multi-level associations Umbrella Integrated Confederation Federation organization association Figure 3: Ideal typical umbrella organizations, confederations and federations placed on a one-dimensional scale. Using the five questions (A-E) that I have posed in order to delimit and classifying different types of multi-level association it is now in table 1 possible to list some interesting characteristics of the ideal typical umbrella organization, confederation and federation. Umbrella organization Confederation Federation Semi-integrated multi-level Type of organization Meta-association Integrated multi-level association association Central association and local Umbrella organization and member- associations share at least one association probably share one Central association and local (A) Organizational dimension of their organizational dimension of their organizational associations share nearly the same identity identities but the local associations identities but the member-associations organizational identity. distinguish themselves from each distinguish themselves from each other. other. Central association needs local Umbrella organization may not need associations in order for its members for other things than funding Central and local associations need activities to be meaningful. Local (B) Mutual dependency and legitimacy. Member-associations each other for most of their associations need the central do not need the umbrella organization activities. association for many of their for most of their activities. activities. Local associations are formally Member-associations are formally principals of the central Local associations are formally (C) Formal distribution principals of the umbrella organization organization but are often in turn subordinated to the central of power and may be bound to follow certain bound to follow certain rules due association. rules due to the membership contract. to the membership contract. Local association holds Individual member holds Member-association holds membership (D) Membership contract membership in the central membership in the federation as a in the umbrella organization. association. whole. Delegates / votes distributed One member-association – one One local association – one (E) Representation primarily to represent the delegate / vote. delegate / vote. individual members. Table 1: Characteristics of ideal typical umbrella organizations, confederations and federations. Back to our empirical organizations Once again I will illustrate this theoretical discussion with the empirical multi-level associations of the Swedish Red Cross and the Swedish Football Association. The statutes of SRC state that it is the central association that decides the level of the membership fee 14
(Swedish Red Cross 2009a). This indicates that the individual’s membership primarily is connected to the central association even when the statutes further states that the member belongs to a local association. The membership also gives the individual possibilities to participate in activities within the whole SRC. That the membership contract is directly between the individual and the central association is further accentuated by the conceptions of the membership within the organization. The texts in the central association’s annual report present the individuals as the primary members while the local associations are units that the members are distributed over. The representation in the general assembly is a mix between a representation of individuals and of local associations. One delegate within each municipality is elected by the boards from the local associations. Municipalities in which the local associations have more than 3000 members are further entitled to one more delegate for every 3000 extra members (Swedish Red Cross 2009a). The local associations in a municipality are consequently entitled to at least one delegate but this can be adjusted upwards depending on how many individual members these local associations have. In SRC’s statutes it is stated that the local associations are formally subordinated to the national association’s board of directors notwithstanding that they are juridical entities separated from the national association (Swedish Red Cross 2009a). It is further stated that the national association’s board decides local associations’ name, residence, aim and the membership fee for all members. A new local association must be approved by the national association’s board and it cannot be dissolved without confirmation from the national association’s board. In the statutes of the Swedish Football Association it is clearly stated that it only is football associations that can apply for membership (Swedish Football Association 2009a). As already mentioned SFA also regard local associations as their primary members in official text as the annual report even if they also take the opportunity to say that the local associations altogether have more than one million individual members. The representation in the general assembly is also in SFA a mix between a representation of individuals and of local associations but even more complex than in SRC. Approximately one third of the votes are allocated to the local associations that play in the two highest male football series and the highest female football series. The rest of the votes are allocated to the districts, which the local associations control. A little bit more than half of these votes are distributed evenly to all districts while the rest are distributed according to how many licensed 15
players (not necessary the same as the number of members) there are in the district (Swedish Football Association 2009a). The SFA does not have any direct control over the local associations more than that the associations through the membership commit themselves to follow athletic rules stipulated by SFA and the Swedish Sports Confederation (Swedish Football Association 2009a). With all this in mind we could say that SRC have more federative characteristics while the SFA have more confederative characteristics. It should however be noted that it would be wise to conduct a more thorough empirical examination of the workings of the organizations’ governance system since the actual distribution of power could differ from what could be read in the organization’s statutes. This was a quick classification of our two identified multi-level associations. But what about the other related associations as the IFRC, UEFA, FIFA and the Swedish Sports Confederation? They would, in my terminology, be classified as umbrella organizations since they are meta-associations but not multi-level associations. But I want to once more call attention to the fact that the theoretical constructions of ideal typical federations, confederations and umbrella organizations should not be confused with the classification of empirical organizations. Real world organizations can be hard to classify in an unambiguous way and classifications could differ depending on the perspective and purpose of the person doing the classification. In a situation as a coordinated international disaster relief project would it maybe be sensible to regard the Swedish Red Cross together with the IFRC and other national Red Cross societies as one coherent multi-level association. Governance of multi-level associations In this last part of the paper I will shortly touch upon some governance aspects of multi- level associations in order to show that identifying the boundaries and characteristics of these types of organizations can help us to understand their inner workings. Soegaard (1994) argue that it is useful to distinguish between political and material balance of power where political power refer to the formal governance system with distribution of power and mode of representation while the material balance of power depend on the distribution of mutual dependence within the multi-level association. It is in practice however not possible to completely separate the formal governance system and the material balance of 16
power since they are interwoven. I will in this section start out from the formal governance system and from there wander more and more into the material balance of power. If we look back at the scale in figure 4 of ideal typical organizational forms ranging from umbrella organizations over confederations and federations to integrated associations I have up till now almost excluded the basic association from discussions. That is however not possible or desirable any more. Since all the discussed organizational forms ultimately consist of associations, their governance systems will also be built on the governance system of associations. The lack of legal regulation of non-profit associations in Sweden leads to a situation where it to a great deal is up to the individual members themselves to decide how they should set up their organization. Most Swedish associations have an annual meeting as their highest decision-making body. Probably the most common way is to let all members have the same amount of influence – one member – one vote and questions are settled with majority votes (Hemström 2002). This suggests that all individual members have equal opportunities to influence questions that are raised in the annual meeting including elections of representatives to the board and other functions in the association. In associations with large number of members it can be impractical or even impossible to carry through annual meetings where every member has the right to attend. The statutes may then prescribe rules for electing delegates that will represent the members on the annual meeting (Hemström 2002). The difference between a system where all members is allowed to attend the annual meeting and a system with delegates is illustrated in figure 4. Instead of directly be a part of the decision-making process the members elect delegates who is supposed to represent them at the annual meeting. The figure also indicates that the members often are divided in groups who have their own delegates. Such grouping is often made on geographical basis and the delegates could be assigned different numbers of votes depending on how many members they represent. 17
Decisions and Decisions and election of the board election of the board M M M M D D D D M M M M M M M M M M Figure 4: Representative system in large associations. A governance system like the one to the right in figure 5 is to the structure similar to the governance system of a federation. The individual members are represented by delegates in the central association’s governance system. The structure of confederations’ and umbrella organizations’ governance system does also present resemblances to this. There is however important differences in what the delegates are supposed to represent. In the ideal typical umbrella organization or confederation decision-making is a two-level process. In the first step every local association decide which position they should have and in the second step the local associations’ voices are aggregated in the central association (cf. Blankart 2007). In the ideal typical federation or integrated association decision-making only require one step since the delegates directly represents the individual members. In associations and federations the delegates are supposed to represent the individual members and in confederations and umbrella organizations the delegates are supposed to represent the member-associations. This could be seen as a minor difference when the structure nevertheless in the end gives the power to the individual members but it does have consequences. First of all a delegate that strives for the best for an association would under certain circumstances make other decisions than a delegate that strives for the best of the association’s individual members. In some situations it may even be for the best of the individual members that the association is discontinued but a delegate representing the association itself could not take such a decision under normal circumstances. Another difference is due to differences in the distribution of votes. When delegates in integrated associations and federations represent individual members their votes usually are distributed to reflect this. Delegates that represent many individual members usually have more votes than delegates that represent few individual members. In ideal typical umbrella 18
organizations and confederations the member-associations’ delegates only have one vote each. This mean that every member-association have the same amount of influence independent on how large they are in terms of individual members, how resourceful they are or how much they contribute to the central association. Both these arrangements could potentially introduce problems. Member-associations with many individual members or that on other grounds think that they are more important could construe a governance system where member associations have one vote each, as unfair and illegitimate. And if the governance system would be altered to reflect this, small member- association´s could accuse the governance system to be undemocratic since the rule of one member – one vote is abandoned. A situation where some of the participants deem the decision processes as illegitimate easily lead to a situation where decisions are characterized of consensus. Controversial questions may not come to surface at all since it is clear beforehand that the results would not be accepted anyway (cf. Ahrne and Brunsson 2008). This problem should be less pronounced in federations since their membership contract link the individual directly to the central association. The local association will accordingly not be as strong power centers as in umbrella organizations or confederations. Another consequence of this kind of weaknesses in the formal governance system that Ahrne and Brunsson (2005) mention is that decisions concerning the member-associations’ activities often are implemented as directives instead of binding rules. Such decisions can also be implemented as rules a potential member-association must commit itself to in order to become a member. An example of that is the athletic rules every associational member of the Swedish Sports Confederation commits themselves to. Umbrella organizations’ and confederation’s preference for consensus is however not as pronounced in federations which are more like integrated associations in that sense. Since the delegates represent the individual members they could also directly pass resolutions both for the central association and for the local associations which would not be possible in umbrella organizations or confederations where the local associations enjoys more autonomy. One of the differences between the different type of associations and multi-level associations discussed in this paper is how dependent different parts of the organizational complexes are on each other. All associations of course depend on having members. But every association is not equally dependent on who the members are. Ahrne and Brunsson (2005) argue that individual-based associations often are not dependent on who the members 19
are. The individual members are consequently relatively replaceable. They further argue that meta-organizations or umbrella organizations in my words often are dependent on having the strongest potential member-organizations since their presence creates much of the meta- organization’s attraction. An umbrella organization needs members for funding and legitimacy simultaneously as strong members are necessary in order to recruit other members. The member-associations in turn do however often not need the umbrella organization in order to continue with its daily activities. They have use for the umbrella organization in certain ways but it its activities are not crucial for them. The fact that both the member-associations and the central association are organizations is in itself a potential source for conflict. Strong member-associations have often the possibility to compete with the central association and go about with the same type of activities if they are not pleased with how it is handled by the central association (cf. Ahrne and Brunsson 2005). Since the umbrella organization are more dependent on its member-association than the member-associations are on the umbrella organization the power could be expected to be located with the member-associations more than with the umbrella organization. Ahrne and Brunsson (2005) further argue that strong members also could create uncertainty of who really is in charge. Is it the leaders of the central associations or the leader of some strong member-associations that really runs the show? Some of this uncertainty has been solved in the Swedish Football Association where the associations in the highest series get more formal voting power than other member-associations. Member-associations consequently both have formal power over the umbrella organization and they get power in practice through the umbrella organization’s dependence on its member-associations. Something that could compensate for this unbalance of power is connected to why associations join umbrella organizations. Ahrne and Brunsson (2005) argue that that the decision for organizations to join meta-organizations sometimes are more related to expressing an organizational identity or to a logic of appropriateness. The logic would be that an organization as the Swedish Red Cross would become member of the umbrella organization the Swedish Fundraising Council because it seems to be the appropriate thing for a fundraising organization to do. If this would be the case then we could expect that the Swedish Red Cross would not interfere very much in the daily business of the Swedish Fundraising Council. 20
The mutual dependence among associational levels are however higher in confederations than in umbrella organizations. Local associations are more dependent of the central association for some of their core activities. Without the Swedish Football Association the Swedish football associations would not have any tournaments to play in or they would have to coordinate tournaments among themselves. This dependence on the central association will also result in more material power residing at the central association. In federations the mutual dependence is even higher and the local associations are highly dependent on the central association both for most of its activities and for its identity which gives the central association even more power. The local association would be something completely different if it would be able to leave the federation. The central association has also often formal power over its local associations as in the Swedish Red Cross where the statutes state that local associations are formally subordinated to the central association’s board of directors. Concluding remarks Associations join together and form a central association in order to get some kind of advantage out of the co-operation with other similar associations. This advantage often comes from economies of scale in some area. It could for example be easier to influence the political system if you have more individual members to support your cause (Hvenmark 2008). The benefit with forming a central association over merging the local associations is that every local association gets to keep some of its autonomy. These benefits of scales of economies and preserved autonomy do however not come without any drawbacks. Decisions in umbrella organizations can often only be made in unanimity with following efficiency problems. This could in part be solved by changing the distribution of power in favor for the central association as in confederations and especially federations but that also mean that the local associations must sacrifice more of their autonomy. What could we say if we allowed ourselves to speculate in which conditions that favor specific types of multi-level associations? This too is a multi-level problem. Crémer and Palfrey (1999) argue that it from a moderate individual’s point of view would be desirable with a higher degree of centralization as in a federation. Individual with extreme opinions in 21
turn would favor more autonomy for local associations as in umbrella organizations or confederations since it is easier to get one’s way in a smaller setting. If we instead analyze the possibilities of having a long term stable governance system where most individuals will accept decisions we could use the distribution of preferences in and across local associations. A federation would according to Blankart (2007) from that perspective be suitable if individual members’ preferences are similarly structured across local associations and a confederation is more appropriate when individuals’ preferences vary more between than within local associations. On an organizational level local associations with large number of members would prefer a governance system where the individuals are represented as in federations since that would give the local association more influence. Small local association would be expected to prefer a representative system where every local association gets the same amount of votes since that in practice gives their members more power at the expense of members in larger local associations. It is accordingly not trivial to say under which circumstances an associational complex would be best of in the form of autonomous member-associations in an umbrella organization, as a confederation, as a federation or in the form of a larger fully integrated association. Neither is it trivial to delimit and classify such associational complexes. But I have however in this paper demonstrated that there are important differences between the four discussed forms of associational complexes which nevertheless make it fruitful to employ such a classification scheme. 22
References Ahrne, Göran and Nils Brunsson. 2005. "Organizations and meta-organizations." Scandinavian Journal of Management 21:429-449. —. 2008. Meta-organizations. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Blankart, Charles B. 2007. "The European Union: confederation, federation or association of compound states? A Hayekian approach to the theory of constitutions." Constitutional Political Economy 18:99-106. Crémer, Jacques and Thomas R. Palfrey. 1999. "Political Confederation." The American Political Science Review 93:69-83. DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell. 1983. "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields." American Sociological Review 48:147-160. Emerson, Richard M. 1962. "Power-Dependence Relations." American Sociological Review 27:31-41. Hemström, Carl. 2002. Bolag - föreningar - stiftelser : en introduktion. Stockholm: Norstedts juridik. Hvenmark, Johan. 2008. Reconsidering Membership. A Study of Individual Members' Formal Affiliation with Democratically Governed Federations. Stockholm: Ekonomiska Forskningsinstitutet vid Handelshögskolan i Stockholm (EFI). International Federation of Red Cross and Red Crescent Societies. 2007. "Statutory texts of the International Federation of Red Cross and Red Crescent Societies." —. 2009. "Independent Auditors' Report. Financial Statements 2008." Olson, Mancur. 1971. The logic of collective action : public goods and the theory of groups. New York: Shocken books. Salamon, Lester M. and Helmut K. Anheier. 1997. Defining the nonprofit sector : a cross- national analysis. Manchester: Manchester Univ. Press. Sjöstrand, Sven-Erik. 2000. "The Organization of Nonprofit Activities." Voluntas: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations 11:199-216. Skocpol, Theda, Marshall Ganz, and Ziad Munson. 2000. "A Nation of Organizers: The Institutional Origins of Civic Voluntarism in the United States." The American Political Science Review 94:527-546. Soegaard, Villy. 1994. "Power-Dependence Relations in Federative Organizations." Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 65:103-126. Swedish Football Association. 2009a. "Stadgar." —. 2009b. "Årsredovisning 2008." Swedish Red Cross. 2009a. "Stadgar för Föreningen Röda Korset gällande från 2009-01-01." —. 2009b. "Årsredovisning 2008." Swedish Sports Confederation. 2005. "RF:s Stadgar. I lydelse efter RF-stämman 2005." —. 2009. "Verksamhetsberättelse med årsredovisningar 2008." Union of European Football Associations. 2007. "Statutes Edition June 2007." —. 2009. "About UEFA." Wijkström, Filip and Torbjörn Einarsson. 2006. Från nationalstat till näringsliv? : det civila samhällets organisationsliv i förändring. Stockholm: Ekonomiska Forskningsinstitutet vid Handelshögskolan i Stockholm (EFI). 23
You can also read