Evaluating the effect of IMF lending to low-income countries
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Journal of Development Economics Vol. 61 Ž2000. 495–526 www.elsevier.comrlocatereconbase Evaluating the effect of IMF lending to low-income countries Louis Dicks-Mireaux ) , Mauro Mecagni, Susan Schadler International Monetary Fund, Policy DeÕelopment and ReÕiew Department, 700 19th Street, NW, Washington, DC 20431, USA Abstract The purpose of this paper is twofold: to apply to a group of low-income borrowers from the IMF, the most commonly used technique for measuring the independent effects on economic developments of IMF support; and to develop a minimum set of diagnostic tests for determining whether necessary conditions for using the methodology exist. The modified control-group methodology is used to measure the effect of IMF support on three key variables — output growth, inflation, and the external debtrservice ratio. The sample comprises adjustment programs begun during 1986–1991 supported by the IMF’s Enhanced Structural Adjustment Facility ŽESAF.. The distinguishing feature of the modified control- group approach is the estimation of a policy counterfactual — policies that would have been followed in the absence of IMF support against which to compare actual policies and resulting outcomes. Using this approach for the ESAF, the sample reveals statistically significant beneficial effects of IMF support on output growth and the debtrservice ratio but no effects on inflation. Diagnostic tests of these results, rarely if ever reported in the literature, are shown to be critical in interpreting the validity of the results of assessments of adjustment lending. For this sample, at least, the diagnostic tests cast doubt on the reliability of estimates of the effects of IMF-supported programs using panel data in a modified control-group model. The most obvious and manageable modifications to the ) Corresponding author. Tel.: q1-202-623-5699. E-mail address: ldicksmireaux@imf.org ŽL. Dicks-Mireaux.. 0304-3878r00r$ - see front matter q 2000 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S 0 3 0 4 - 3 8 7 8 Ž 0 0 . 0 0 0 6 6 - 3
496 L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 model do not overcome its basic weaknesses. q 2000 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: E65; F33 Keywords: International Monetary Fund; Conditionality; Stabilization programs 1. Introduction Evaluations of macroeconomic programs supported by international financial institutions ŽIFIs. do not all address the same question. Some look at the design of such programs to see if they represent ‘‘best practices’’ for correcting countries’ macroeconomic problems. Others examine whether programs are effectively im- plemented. Another question that has attracted attention recently is whether IFI support has significant independent effects; i.e., does it bring about developments significantly different from those that would have occurred in the absence of support from the IFI in question? This is a difficult question to address because it requires the construction of a counterfactual indicating what policies and outcomes would have been in the absence of IFI support. The independent effects are then calculated as the difference between outcomes that would have occurred in the absence of IFI support and actual outcomes. Since the mid-1980s, several papers have considered how to construct a counterfactual for such exercises and how to address other problems in identifying independent effects of IFI-supported programs. In particular, differentiating the effects of the counterfactual policies from exogenous developments, initial condi- tions and IFI support. The methodology that has been most widely applied was developed by Goldstein and Montiel Ž1986. by adapting techniques from the literature on labor training evaluation. Essentially, this technique, referred to as the General Evaluation Estimator ŽGEE. or modified control group, involves using policy reaction functions estimated for countries that did not have support from a particular IFI to approximate the counterfactual for countries that did have IFI backing for their program. 1 The GEE is a potentially powerful technique, although, as Goldstein and Montiel point out, it entails many restrictive assump- tions; e.g., it must be possible to characterize macroeconomic policy choices in a relatively simple reaction function based on quantifiable data, and it must be credible that the reaction functions estimated for countries that do not receive IFI support describe the counterfactual for countries that do receive such support. The purpose of this paper is both to apply the GEE methodology to data for low-income countries eligible for the IMF’s Enhanced Structural Adjustment 1 Applications of the GEE can be found in Greene Ž1989., Khan Ž1990., Faini et al. Ž1991., Corbo and Rojas Ž1992. and Conway Ž1994..
L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 497 Facility ŽESAF. 2 and to examine in greater detail than previous studies have done the conditions that must be met for the GEE to give robust results. To do this, we calculate the effects of ESAF-supported programs during the first 6 years of the facility’s existence Ž1986–1991. on three macroeconomic variables that are typi- cally the main objectives of the programs: output growth, inflation and, a key indicator of progress toward external viability, the external debtrservice ratio. We then perform several diagnostic tests to answer the question, ‘‘Are the restrictive assumptions underlying the standard GEE consistent with the sample?’’. Three main issues are addressed in these tests: does the single, relatively simple macroeconomic model used in applications of the GEE capture the interaction between macroeconomic policies and outcomes for a large number of countries over time; can a robust policy reaction function be estimated for periods when, and in countries where, IMF support is not in place; is it possible to address sample selection bias that is likely to characterize applications of the GEE to date? The results, like others for different data sets, point to significant positive effects of IMF-supported programs on growth and the debtrservice ratio. The diagnostic tests, however, cast doubt on the appropriateness of the restrictive assumptions underlying the GEE and accordingly about the reliability of the results. This finding raises questions about whether there are inherent problems in estimating GEE models with panel data. At a minimum, it strongly indicates that future applications of the GEE on other data sets need to incorporate standard diagnostic tests to ascertain whether the GEE methodology is valid for the sample under study. 2. Specification of the model The GEE is geared toward answering the question, ‘‘Did the involvement of the IMF through a lending arrangement significantly improve the outcomes for important macroeconomic variables relative to what they would have been in the absence of ESAF support?’’. To answer this question, the macroeconomic out- comes or target variables in countries are described as a function of: Ži. policies that would have been observed in the absence of an IMF-supported program; Žii. 2 The ESAF is the window through which the IMF can make highly concessional long-term loans available to low-income countries. This facility succeeded the Structural Adjustment Facility ŽSAF. which had similar characteristics but with somewhat less rigorous conditions on economic policies than the ESAF. During the period covered in this study, 74 countries were eligible for loans through the ESAF.
498 L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 exogenous external factors; Žiii. the existence or otherwise of an IMF-supported program; and Živ. unobservable random shocks: yi j s b o j q b jk x i k q a jh wi h q b jIMFd i q e i j , Ž 1. where yi j is the jth target variable in country i, x i k is a k-element vector of policy variables that would be observed in country i in the absence of IMF support, wi h is an h-element vector of exogenous external variables for each country i, d i is a dummy variable equal to 1 if an IMF program is in effect and zero otherwise, and e i j is a zero mean, fixed variance, serially uncorrelated error. For the jth target variable, b jk and a jh are kxl and hxl vectors, respectively, of fixed parameters. After postulating a rule for policies in the absence of an IMF-supported program Ž x i k ., the model is estimated using pooled cross-section and time-series data drawn from countries and periods in which IMF support was in place and those in which IMF support was absent. The aim is to get consistent estimates for b jIMF, the ‘‘independent effect’’ of IMF support on each target variable. If these are statistically significant at a reasonable confidence level, IMF support is found to have significant effects. Policies adopted in the absence of an IMF-supported program Ž x i k . are directly observable only for nonprogram periods, and thus, a key element of the GEE is the construction of a counterfactual for policies during programs. In Goldstein and Montiel Ž1986. and subsequent empirical applications, this counterfactual is based upon a policy reaction function that links changes in policy instruments to the deviation of the observed lagged value for each target from its desired value, yidj .3 Specifically, the policy reaction function is described by: D x i k sg k j yidj y yi jŽy1. q hi k , Ž 2. where yi j is a j-element vector of target variables, hi k is a zero mean, fixed variance, serially uncorrelated error term assumed to be uncorrelated with e i j , and D is the first difference operator.4 The kxj parameter matrix g k j indicates the extent to which policy instruments are adjusted in response to disequilibria in the target variables. 3 In the empirical exercise, we also experimented with other reaction functions. One, derived explicitly from an optimizing exercise, produced a final reduced form equation in which past policies do not enter Žsee Eq. 3.. A second included lagged values of exogenous influences wi hŽy 1. , which would be important, e.g., if lagged changes in export or import prices affected the current fiscal position. Both of these performed less well than Eq. 2 in estimation and are not, therefore, reported here. See Dicks-Mireaux et al. Ž1995. for a fuller discussion of selecting a reaction function. 4 The lack of mutual correlation between hi k and e i j implies that changes in policy instruments Ž D x i k . are not influenced by contemporaneous exogenous shocks to the target variables.
L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 499 Substituting Eq. 2 into Eq. 1 and subsuming yidj in the constant Ži.e., assuming yidj is invariant across countries and over time., we obtain: D yi j s b jo y Ž b jkg k j q 1 . yi jŽy1. q b jk x i kŽy1. q a jh wi h q b jIMFd i q Ž e i j q b jk hi k . . Ž 3. Eq. 3 constitutes the basic GEE reduced form model as applied in most earlier studies.5 Its operational usefulness depends on the validity of several restrictive assumptions, discussed in the remainder of this section.6 First, an important question for the empirical application is whether individual country behavior can be sensibly aggregated in a uniform model that is stable across countries and over time. Specifically, differing institutional characteristics Že.g., the degree of policy discipline inherent in specific exchange rate arrange- ments or the relationship with a major donor., changing political conditions, or varying severities of economic distress are likely to result in countries formulating policies with respect to different or changing objective functions, or subject to different or changing constraints. Another question is whether it is appropriate to assume that the policy reaction function of a program country, had it not received IMF support, is identical to that of a nonprogram country that did not seek IMF support. For example, the counterfactual for a country receiving IMF support may involve the imposition of trade or exchange restrictions, while countries that do not seek IMF support may constrain themselves to ‘‘IMF-type’’ policies; i.e., avoiding the use of trade or exchange restrictions. Second, the constant additive term b jIMFd i is meant to capture four separate channels through which IMF support could affect macroeconomic targets: Ži. changes in the state of confidence in the economy; Žii. changes in the desired value of targets, e.g., through structural reforms aimed at raising the rate of potential growth; Žiii. policies different from what they would have been in the absence of a program; and Živ. changes in the effectiveness of any given stance of policies. While an additive term in a reduced form equation like Eq. 3 can capture the first two of these channels, a more complex specification requiring the explicit estimation of the policy reaction functions is needed to capture the third and fourth channels of influence.7 The intuition is straightforward. Both the third and fourth channels involve effects that are proportional to the size of the difference between actual and counterfactual policies: strictly, therefore, they require the different sizes of effects of actual and counterfactual policies to be measured directly. In sum, a simple invariant additive term in the GEE may not do full justice to the 5 A potential source of bias in Eq. 3 because of nonzero correlation between the error terms and explanatory variables is ruled out by assuming a stochastic structure whereby shocks are transitory. 6 Some of these restrictive assumptions characterize other, especially cross-section, estimators. 7 See Dicks-Mireaux et al. Ž1995. and Goldstein and Montiel Ž1986. for a discussion of the specification needed to accurately capture these channels and the operational constraints in doing so.
500 L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 range of potential program effects. In practice, the possibility of a more informa- tive decomposition of program effects that allows variation across countries requires a large sample and the ability to identify empirically a stable policy reaction function as examined in Section 4. Third, Eq. 3 contains only the most simple dynamics. The principal dynamic influence comes from the lagged target variable term in the policy reaction equation — policies are assumed to adjust to deviations of actual from desired values of the target variables in the preceding period. Lags in the effects of policies on target variables or inertial effects in the targets themselves are typically not considered.8 Indeed, in Eqs. 1–3, the stochastic terms e i j and hi k are assumed to be serially uncorrelated: all shocks are assumed to be transitory and to cause one-period changes in target variables that are fully reversed in the following period. This restrictive assumption requires that each target variable be stationary, but it also rules out a wide range of stationary stochastic processes for which the impact of temporary shocks persists over time.9 If, in fact, significant inertia exists; impos- ing full one-period reversion to mean will understate the positive effects of an IMF-supported program after a negative shock. Empirically, this issue could not be explored for ESAF countries because of the short sample time span. While a more general dynamic form can be easily specified, in practice, the data set for ESAF countries is not long enough to apply it meaningfully.10 3. Estimation procedures 3.1. The sample The model, as specified in Eq. 3, was estimated with data from 1986 to 1991 for 61 of the 74 countries ŽTable 1. eligible to use ESAF resources as of 1992 Žexclusions are noted below.. Nineteen of these countries had ESAF arrangements at some time during the sample period.11 The sample was restricted to ESAF-eligi- ble countries, rather than a larger set of developing countries: including only 8 Inertial effects may arise for a variety of reasons, such as backward-looking indexation, slowly adjusting expectations, staggered contracts, and transaction costs. 9 In the absence of stationarity, the concept of reversion to mean is not well-defined because the mean of the stochastic process is not time-invariant, and the series will tend to move continuously away from a given level as a result of past and current shocks. See Harvey Ž1981. and Priestley Ž1981.. 10 See Dicks-Mireaux et al. Ž1995. for a fuller discussion of the dynamic properties of the model and the full dynamic specification. 11 For these countries, program years are those when either a SAF or ESAF arrangement was in place. SAF arrangements typically had less stringent conditionality than ESAF arrangements. For most countries that had ESAF arrangements, however, prior SAF arrangements were used to establish commitment to adjustment and were close in nature to ESAF-supported programs.
L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 501 low-income countries reduced the scope for parameter instability owing to differ- ences in structural and institutional conditions between low-income countries and other developing countries. Even the sample restricted to ESAF-eligible countries is quite diverse. The program countries are dominated by heavily indebted African countries with a narrow range of exports and relatively simple market structures. The nonprogram countries are more diverse, including, in about equal proportions, indebted African countries and small Caribbean or Pacific island countries with close institutional and financial links to particular industrial countries. There are also a few South and Southeast Asian countries. For estimation, a number of data points are dropped from the full sample of ESAF-eligible countries.12 Some observations are excluded because of inadequate data owing to civil strife wAfghanistan Ž1990–1991. and Angola, Liberia, and Nicaragua Žall years.x; major discontinuities which could not be corrected wDjibouti, Sao Tome and Principe, and Zaire Žall years.x; extreme isolation wAlbania, Cambodia and Mongolia Žall years.x; or political discontinuities wDemocratic Republic of Yemen Ž1990–1991. and Yemen Arab Republic Ž1989–1991.x. Years in which countries had a SAF arrangement Žexcept when followed immediately by an ESAF arrangement., standby, or extended arrangement are omitted because they were considered invalid as nonprogram counterfactuals; this excludes Cote d’Ivoire, Philippines and, together with lack of data in 1991, Somalia, entirely from the sample.13 Even for the limited sample covered, the quality of data is poor. In many instances, the accuracy of the measures of macroeconomic variables, such as GDP, is likely to very weak. Also, ad hoc correction for breaks in the series was frequently needed. These fundamental weaknesses qualify the inferences or judge- ments that can be drawn from the data. 3.2. Definitions: targets, policies, exogenous influences and period of IMF support This study considers three target variables Ž yi j . that reflect the objectives of the ESAF: Ži. the growth rate of real GDP; Žii. consumer price inflation; and Žiii. one 12 As a result, the structure of the panel data is incomplete. Techniques for analyzing panel data in which missing observations are random or regular Žor ‘‘rotating’’. are not applicable because the sample data exclusions do not conform to either of these patterns. Instead, for estimation, the panel data are handled as a pooling of annual observations, with the number of program and nonprogram years varying from country to country. 13 In principle, years when countries had a SAF, standby, or extended arrangement could have been included as neither ESAF years nor nonprogram years, but rather as additional categories. In this case, the selection of the facility through which a country borrowed Žwith its attendant conditionality. would have had to be modeled as the outcome of strategic negotiations; see, e.g., Knight and Santaella Ž1994.. The correction for sample selection bias Ždiscussed below. would also have had to be differentiated for each facility.
502 L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 Table 1 Sample of countries and programrnonprogram years a Nonprogram Nonprogram years SAFrESAF Program years Nonprogram countries program countries years Afghanistan 1986r1987– Bangladesh 1986r1987– 1988r1989 1991r1992 Benin 1986–1988 Bolivia 1987–1991 Bhutan 1986–1991 Burundi 1986–1989, 1990 1991 Burkina Faso 1986–1991 Gambia, The 1986r1987– 1991r1992 1990r1991 Cape Verde 1986–1991 Ghana 1987–1991 Central African 1991 Guinea 1987–1991 1986 Republic Chad 1986, 1991 Guyana 1990–1991 1986–1989 China 1988–1991 Kenya 1988–1991 1986–1987 Comoros 1986–1990 Lesotho 1988r1989– 1986r1987– 1991r1992 1987r1988 Dominica 1990–1991 Madagascar 1987–1991 Dominican 1986–1990 Malawi 1988–1991 1986–1987 Republic Egypt 1989r1990 Mauritania 1986–1990 1991 Equatorial 1987–1988, Mozambique 1987–1991 1986 Guinea 1990–1991 Ethiopia 1986–1991 Niger 1987–1991 Grenada 1986–1991 Senegal 1986r1987– 1991r1992 Guinea 1986, 1988, Sri Lanka 1988–1991 1986–1987 Bissau 1991 Haiti 1985r1986, Tanzania 1987r1988– 1986r1987 1987r1988– 1991r1992 1988r1989, 1990r1991 Honduras 1986–1989 Togo 1988–1990 1991 India 1986r1987– Uganda 1987r1988– 1986r1987 1989r1990 1991r1992 Kiribati 1986–1991 Lao, PDR 1986–1988 Maldives 1986–1991 Mali 1987, 1991 Number of countries: 19 Myanmar 1986–1991 Number of annual program observations: 88 Nepal 1990r1991 Number of annual nonprogram observationsb : 20 Nigeria 1986, 1988, 1990 Pakistan 1986r1987– 1987r1988 Rwanda 1986–1990 St. Kitts and Nevis 1986–1991 St. Lucia 1986r1987– 1991r1992
L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 503 Table 1 Ž continued . Nonprogram Nonprogram SAFrESAF Program years Nonprogram countries years program countries years St. Vincent 1986–1991 Sierra Leone 1987r1988– 1990r1991 Solomon Islands 1986–1991 Sudan 1986–1991 Tonga 1986–1991 Vanuatu 1986–1991 Vietnam 1986–1991 Western Samoa 1986–1991 Yemen, AR 1986–1988 Yemen, PDR 1986–1989 Zambia 1988–1991 Zimbabwe 1986–1991 Number of countries: 42 Number of annual nonprogram observations:b 183 a Fiscal years tr t q1 were considered to correspond to calendar year t if the fiscal year started on or before July 1st. b Includes observations in which a SAF, ESAF, SBA or EFF arrangement was not in place. of the key measures by which the IMF measures progress toward external viability —the ratio of external debtrservice to exports. The last target is preferred to other indicators of the external position, such as the current account, the overall balance of payments, or the level of international reserves for several reasons.14 Most countries entered ESAF arrangements with large debt overhangs, and reducing the debtrservice ratio to manageable levels was the primary external objective of the program. For other external variables, however, even the direction of targeted and actual changes varied depending on initial conditions and prospects for attracting concessional inflows. Moreover, for nonprogram periods, developments in these other variables sometimes reflected the imposition of formal or informal trade and exchange restrictions rather than changes in the viability of the external position. Increases in reserves, probably the next most general indication of external sector developments, were at times associated with the accumulation of arrears. Also, a reserves target did not exist for many countries ŽCFA and ECCB members. that did not directly own international reserves. 14 The debtrservice ratio is not, however, an infallible indicator of progress toward external viability. For example, changes in this ratio may reflect only a temporary change in export prices.
504 L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 Three policy instruments Ž x i k . are considered: Ži. the deficit of the central government in relation to GDP; Žii. the growth of net domestic assets of the banking system ŽNDA.;15 and Žiii. the change in the nominal effective exchange rate ŽNEER.. Ideally, the vector of policy instruments would also include indica- tors of structural reforms and conditions and institutional arrangements Žsuch as flexible or fixed exchange rate regimes.. However, these variables cannot easily be objectively quantified or reduced to an index. The external environment indicators Ž wi h . comprise changes in the terms of trade and the growth of export markets.16 Whenever possible, the data were taken from documents for the Executive Board of the IMF. Several questions arise in defining the variable denoting the presence of an IMF-supported program Ž d i .. First, the distinction between program and nonpro- gram years is blurred when IMF support starts in the middle of the year. For this study, any year in which a SAFrESAF-supported program was in effect for 6 months or more was considered a program year. Even this rule, however, does not clearly delineate the period during which IMF support influenced policies and outcomes. Usually, substantive negotiations and policy actions occurred in antici- pation of IMF support in the year preceding the formal program. In some cases, the IMF influenced policies even after an ESAF arrangement. For example, The Gambia’s SAFrESAF arrangements stretched from FY1986 ŽJuly–June. to FY1990, but even in FY1991, the IMF monitored macroeconomic developments vis a` vis quantified targets agreed with the authorities. A second question is whether the influence of the IMF should be measured only through a 0–1 dummy Žone when the arrangement is in effect, zero when it is not. or also through the proportion of purchases made relative to total access under the arrangement as a measure of the completeness of implementation of agreed policies. Purchases are likely to be an imperfect indicator of implementation, however, because purchases in SAFrESAF-supported programs are scheduled at 6-month frequencies and waivers may be granted to permit purchases even when implementation slips. This study uses a binary, one-zero index of IMF involve- ment for the dummy variable Ž d i .: a period when a country has an agreed program with the IMF but fails to implement it or meet the targets is treated as a program year in which the effect of the IMF is low. Conway Ž1994. used both these approaches as well as the proportion of the year covered by the program as proxies 15 Although the controllable monetary policy instrument of the authorities is net domestic assets of the central bank, data on a comparable basis across countries were not available. 16 In principle, only one of market price and volume indicators should be used. In practice, the suitability of each varies among the countries: the terms of trade are relevant for small primary producers, but world market growth is relevant for large primary producers and countries with differentiated exports.
L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 505 for participation, but obtained similar estimates of the effects of IMF-supported programs for all three proxies. A third point to recognize is that estimates of IMF-supported programs will likely include the effects of parallel World Bank programs. As distinct from the IMF’s standby and extended facilities, SAFrESAF arrangements require explicit collaboration among country authorities, the World Bank and the IMF. 4. Results 4.1. The generalized eÕaluation estimator Estimation results were obtained for the basic GEE Eq. 3. Several modifica- tions of the basic specification were also estimated but produced worse results: apart from those involving richer specifications of the reaction function,17 two other efforts to reduce the restrictiveness of the basic GEE model were tried: Ži. country and time dummies were introduced to help account for some of the cross-country differences in economic structures and time-specific exogenous developments not captured in the terms of trade and market growth variables; and Žii. a correction procedure developed by Heckman Ž1979. Žexplained in detail in Appendix A. was tried to correct for possible sample selection bias. Regression estimates based on pooled time-series, cross-country data are prone to heteroschedasticity, and even after the inclusion of country-specific and time dummies in the estimated equations, regression residuals display this characteris- tic.18 Without information on the form of heteroschedasticity, however, the primary form of one weighting scheme over another is unknown. Therefore, the reported t-statistics were computed from heteroschedastic-consistent estimates of the standard errors based on White’s variance–covariance estimator that provides consistent estimates even when the exact form of heteroschedasticity is not known.19 Table 2 presents the preferred estimates from these exercises. These estimates exclude the time dummies mentioned above because their coefficients were generally not significant and had little effect on Žor worsened. the fit of the equations. The impact of IMF-supported programs is found to be sizeable and statistically significant with respect to growth Žat the 5% level. and the external debtrservice ratio Žat the 10% level., but not inflation. On average, growth rates are found to be more than 1 percentage point per annum higher during program 17 See footnote 3 and Dicks-Mireaux et al. Ž1995.. 18 Statistically significant values of the Breusch–Pagan test for heteroschedasticity ŽBreusch and Pagan, 1979. were observed in the estimated GEE equation for inflation Žat the 5% significance level. and the external debtrservice ratio Žat the 1% level.. 19 See White Ž1980..
506 L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 Table 2 Estimates of the GEE a Target variable Real GDP growth rate Inflation rate External debtr service ratio Constant y6.619 Žy1.71. 10.248 Ž1.08. 22.258UU Ž3.98. Lagged y1.107UU Žy17.96. y0.764U Žy2.18. 0.022 Ž0.09. real GDP growth rate Lagged 0.0005 Ž0.13. y0.687UU Žy4.76. 0.027 Ž1.09. inflation rate Lagged 0.013 Ž0.74. 0.106Ž1.14. y0.376UU Žy3.09. external debtr service ratio Lagged y0.042 Žy1.37. y0.467 Žy1.31. 0.097 Ž0.76. fiscal balancer GDP Lagged 0.004 Ž1.82. y0.088 Žy1.47. y0.020 Žy1.78. net domestic asset growth Lagged y0.009 Žy1.03. 0.436U Ž2.12. 0.058 Ž1.05. percentage change in NEER Current 0.002 Ž0.21. y0.104 Žy0.78. y0.104UU Ž3.44. percentage change in terms of trade Current 0.090 Ž1.78. 0.293 Ž1.26. y0.059 Žy0.30. export market growth IMF program 1.374U Ž2.18. y3.330 Žy0.35. y5.552 Žy1.75. dummy R2 0.537 0.398 0.069 SEE 3.259 29.612 15.734 Number of 291 291 291 observations Breusch– 1.35 10.83U 23.71UU Pagan test for heteroschedasticity Jarque–Bera 26.57UU 28,231.00UU 7086.90UU test for normality of residuals a The regression estimates were obtained using an ordinary least squares procedure, with country- specific dummies included in the specification. Standard errors and t-statistics of coefficients are computed using White’s heteroschedasticity-consistent variance–covariance estimator. The figures in parentheses are t-statistics; R 2 is the adjusted coefficient of determination; SEE is the standard error of the regression. A single asterisk indicates statistical significance at the 5% level; two asterisks indicate statistical significance at the 1% level.
L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 507 periods than they would have been in the absence of an IMF-supported program. Debtrservice ratios are found on average to be more than 5 percentage points lower during program periods than they would have been in the absence of an IMF-supported program.20 On the other right-side variables, very few coefficients are significant at the 5% or 1% confidence level. The exceptions are own lagged levels of the target variables, which enter with coefficients significantly different from zero at the 1% level; the lagged level of the real GDP growth rate and the change in the nominal effective exchange rate Žwhich has an implausible positive sign. in the inflation equation; and the terms of trade in the debtrservice ratio equation.21 The lagged fiscal balance and lagged net domestic asset growth are not found to have a significant impact on the outcome of any target variable.22 4.2. EÕaluating the underlying assumptions of the GEE We now turn to examining the robustness of the results of the GEE estimates. Specifically, we go beyond the standard presentation of GEE results, which focuses on the estimates of b jIMF only, to examine whether the regression estimates are stable and unbiased — evidence that would support the underlying assumptions of the model. The tests reported, which should be standard in all presentations of GEE applications, cut to the core issue of this paper — are estimates of the effects of ESAF programs using panel data in the GEE framework meaningful? 4.2.1. The policy reaction function The first window on this issue is the policy reaction function. Identifying the coefficients and measuring the standard errors in the policy reaction function from 20 This effect on the debtrservice ratio is not attributable to the link between Paris and London Club agreements and IMF support, because the debtrservice ratio is measured before debt relief. The effect of stock of debt reduction operations associated with IMF-supported programs would be reflected in measures of the debtrservice ratio before debt relief in years subsequent to the debt reduction. However, in the sample of program countries considered in this study, no stock of debt operations linked to IMF-supported programs was undertaken. 21 It is possible that this link reflects the presence of export prices in both the terms of trade and debtrservice ratio. However, in light of the many other variables affecting these ratios, this seems unlikely. 22 The residuals of most of the estimated equations fail to pass the Jarque–Bera test for normality. The t-tests should, therefore, be interpreted cautiously as they may be sensitive to nonnormality in a fashion that is determined by the numerical value of the regressors. This cautionary note applies also to other regression diagnostic tests Žsee Jarque and Bera, 1987..
508 L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 the reduced form GEE are not possible nor is it necessary for obtaining estimates of the b jIMF terms.23 Nevertheless, obtaining estimates by directly estimating the counterfactual policy reaction functions with data from the Žobservable. nonpro- gram periods only, provides a means of evaluating the validity of the reaction functions for the sample over which they can be estimated. Direct estimates of the policy reaction function also allow one to test and correct for sample selection bias arising when unobservable factors that influence countries’ decisions to receive IMF support also influence their policy reactions.24 Regression estimates of the policy reaction functions ŽEq. 2. consistent with the basic GEE ŽEq. 3. are reported in Table 3.25 These estimates are poor in several respects. The R 2 statistics are negative or very close to zero; t-statistics for individual coefficients are insignificant Žexcept on the debtrservice ratio in the equation for the nominal effective exchange rate.; F-tests cannot reject the null joint hypothesis of zero slopes; and the regression residuals exhibit statistically significant heteroschedasticity and nonnormality. In short, these estimates provide a weak basis for deriving estimates of the unobservable counterfactual policies for program periods. The inverse Mills ratio ŽIMR. was included as a regressor in the policy reaction functions to correct for possible sample selection bias, following a two-step procedure proposed by Heckman Ž1979..26 Appendix A describes in detail and reports estimates of this procedure. However, the estimated coefficients of the IMR are statistically insignificant, suggesting that sample selection bias is not present. Sample selection bias may arise in estimates of the reduced form GEE ŽEq. 3. even when it is not present in the reaction function. This would occur if the choice of having a program depends on expectations of better performance in the target variable. To test for this, the IMR was included in the estimated reduced form 23 The g k j parameters cannot be identified from the single equation estimates because the number of structural parameters exceeds the number of reduced form coefficients. However, by pooling the parameter estimates from the three equations, the g k j parameters can be identified if policy instru- ments and macroeconomic targets are equal in number. When the number of instruments is less than that of targets, the g k j parameters cannot be identified, and when they exceed the number of targets, multiple solutions exist. It is not possible to measure the standard errors of the estimates. 24 Goldstein and Montiel Ž1986., Greene Ž1989. and Khan Ž1990. do not attempt to correct for this potential source of bias, but several studies of World Bank adjustment lending do Žsee World Bank, 1990; Faini et al., 1991; Corbo and Rojas, 1992.. 25 Country and time dummies were introduced in the policy reaction function, but most had coefficients insignificantly different from zero and had little effect on, or worsened, the overall fit of the equation Žreduced the R 2 . and therefore were not retained. 26 The IMR is a monotone decreasing function Žranging from 0 to `. of the probability that an observation is selected into the sample of nonprogram countries.
L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 509 Table 3 Estimates of the policy reaction functiona Policy variable D Fiscal balancer D Net domestic D Percentage change GDP asset growth in NEER Constant 1.643 Ž0.67. y2.209 Žy0.11. y2.607 Žy0.35. Lagged real GDP growth rate 0.024 Ž0.19. y1.090 Žy1.11. y0.204 Žy0.69. Lagged inflation rate 0.006 Ž1.02. y0.081 Žy0.12. 0.017 Ž0.29. Lagged external debtr y0.0007 Žy0.04. y0.097 Žy0.40. y0.152U Žy2.22. service ratio IMRb y3.911 Žy0.65. 16.271 Ž0.24. 13.070 Ž0.76. R2 y0.013 y0.016 0.019 SEE 7.064 106.339 23.239 Number of observations 203 203 203 F-statistics Žzero slopes. 0.36 0.22 1.96 Breusch–Pagan test for 0.70 62.27UU 21.88UU heteroschedasticity Jarque–Bera test for 4875.06UU 17,986.30UU 495.36UU normality ofresiduals a The regression estimates were obtained from the sample of nonprogram observations using an ordinary least squares procedure. Standard errors and t-statistics of coefficients are computed using White’s heteroschedasticity-consistent variance–covariance estimator. The figures in parentheses are t-statistics; R 2 is the adjusted coefficient of determination; SEE is the standard error of the regression. A single asterisk indicates statistical significance of the 5% level; two asterisks indicate statistical significance at the 1% level. b Values of the IMR were computed using the estimated probit equation reported in Table 8. GEE. The estimated coefficients of the IMR were statistically insignificant, again suggesting the absence of sample selection bias Žsee also Appendix A..27 4.2.2. Significance and stability of the estimates A second window on the robustness of the GEE estimates is to test for the significance and stability of the parameter estimates. The question at issue is whether the GEE results reported here or in other studies are robust to changes in the size and composition of the sample. There are many ways to evaluate the regression estimates, and the approach taken here is not intended to be exhaustive. As measured by the R 2 statistics, the overall fit of the estimated equations is modest Žalmost nil for the external 27 The IMR was highly collinear with the indicator of the presence of an IMF-supported program Ž d i . in Eq. 3, and the statistically significant impact of a program on growth and the external debtrservice ratio was statistically insignificant. The coefficient estimates of the other regressors in the GEE were not significantly altered by the inclusion of the IMR. An alternative procedure using the predicted probability of undertaking a program as an instrument for d i in Eq. 3 did not significantly alter the coefficient of the other regressors. These results are not reported here, but are available from the authors.
510 L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 debtrservice ratio.. This, together with the evidence of heteroschedastic residuals Ževen after the inclusion of country and time dummies. and the large number of coefficients insignificantly different from zero or with counterintuitive signs, suggests the possibility of biased coefficient estimates due to misspecification. For instance, one potentially important omission is structural conditions and reforms that figured prominently in ESAF-supported programs. A second concern is the possibility of heterogeneity bias ŽHsiao, 1986..28 A third concern is the risk of invalid inferential statements, even in large samples ŽJarque and Bera, 1987. given that the regression residuals fail to pass the Jarque–Bera test for normality. The reliability of the parameter estimates is also revealed by the stability properties of the model. Many GEE applications investigate changes in the effectiveness of IFI support as measured by the b jIMF coefficients between two sub-periods of the sample used; Greene Ž1989. and Corbo and Rojas Ž1992. also report changes in estimates of the other coefficients of the reduced form GEE. Yet, in each study, the evidence of changes in point estimates of the b jIMF and other coefficients Žat times statistically significant. is not seen as an indication of instability in the underlying model. The best approach to exploring instability would be to estimate a varying parameters model in which estimated parameters are allowed to vary across countries 29 and over time and therefore, also between program and nonprogram periods.30 This general approach would nest tests of stability and uniformity restrictions within a less restrictive framework, e.g., taking into account het- eroschedastic errors in estimation and testing of coefficient variation; this property is particularly appealing in pooled cross-section, time-series data. However, such an approach requires a data set considerably larger than that available in this study: to explore inter-country instability, the number of data points for each country must exceed the number of regressors; and to explore instability between program and nonprogram periods, the number of data points for each country in each regime Žprogram and nonprogram. must exceed the number of regressors.31 For our sample Žwhich is small and has an unequal number of annual observations for each country., the stability of the individual parameters b jk and 28 The key problem in heterogeneity bias is that the imposition of identical parameters leads to an averaging of coefficients that differ greatly across countries Žor time. and therefore produces nonsensi- cal results. In effect, the assumption of a ‘‘representative country’’ that can be described by an average is not valid. 29 See Swamy Ž1970.. 30 See Hsiao Ž1986.. 31 Extending the sample, however, would have required dropping several countries owing to the lack of consistent data for earlier periods. Also, the number of additional useable observations Ži.e., years in which countries did not have a standby or extended arrangement in place. would have been a rather small proportion of the total.
L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 511 b jIMF has to be examined by recursive regression methods.32 Two types of recursive exercises were done: in the first, the reduced form GEE was estimated recursively, starting with a baseline sample Žcomprising all nonprogram observa- tions plus one program observation. and then adding in program observations one at a time Žreported as ‘‘program recursions’’.; 33 in the second, the recursive procedure was carried out by starting with the full sample and then subtracting nonprogram observations one-by-one Žreported as ‘‘nonprogram recursions’’.. The share of estimates in the recursions that differ significantly from the pooled sample estimates or from zero indicates the sensitivity of the estimated parameters to variations in the sample.34 For the estimates of the effectiveness of IMF support — the b jIMF coefficients — four of the six recursive exercises Žtwo for each of the three equations; Figs. 1–6. produce numerous estimates of b jIMF that are significantly different from the whole sample estimates. In all the recursive exercises, estimates were frequently not significantly different from zero. Thus, the finding of significant effects of IMF support on growth and the debtrservice ratio cannot be considered robust to variations in the sample. For the coefficients on the lagged policy variables, the recursive exercises suggest that the full sample estimates of policy effects are relatively more robust ŽTables 4 and 5.. The general pattern is for lagged policy variables to have little effect on target variables. The stability of the policy reaction functions parameters Ž g k j . was tested in a simplified recursive exercise over the sample of nonprogram observations. The recursions began with an initial sample of 25 observations, and observations were added one by one.35 The results, reported in Tables 6 and 7, indicate that the coefficient estimates from the full sample of nonprogram observations are gener- ally robust across recursions, and Žexcept for the lagged external debtrservice ratio in the equation, the nominal effective exchange rate policy. are insignifi- 32 Stability is assessed in terms of the point estimates and standard errors of individual parameters. An alternative approach would be to conduct Chow or Wald tests for the joint stability of the coefficients of interest on the recursive estimates of the equations. However, this was not possible because the fitted equation does not meet the requirement of both tests that the set of regressors remains constant over recursive estimates: the country dummies, which entered with statistically significant coefficients, change across the recursions. 33 The additional program country observation was required to avoid singularity in the presence of the IMF dummy variable Ž d i .. 34 These recursive procedures consider only a small subset Žarbitrarily chosen. of all subsamples that could be drawn from the data set. Thus, the range of coefficient estimates reported in Tables 4–7 does not necessarily encompass global maximum and minimum values for all permutations of the sample. 35 The size of the initial block of observations was chosen so as to start with a reasonable number of degrees of freedom Ž20..
512 L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 Fig. 1. Recursive point estimates and confidence intervals for IMF program dummy variable Žreal GDP growth rates.. cantly different from zero. Sign reversals are not widespread and most of the estimates are neither significantly different from zero nor from the full sample estimate.
L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 Fig. 2. Recursive point estimates and confidence intervals for IMF program dummy variable Žreal GDP growth rates.. 513
514 L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 Fig. 3. Recursive point estimates and confidence intervals for IMF program dummy variable Žrate of inflation.. 4.2.3. Dynamics and initial conditions The empirical results call into question the adequacy of the simple dynamic specification of the GEE commonly used in the literature. Specifically, the product
L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 Fig. 4. Recursive point estimates and confidence intervals for IMF program dummy variable Žrate of inflation.. 515
516 L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 Fig. 5. Recursive point estimates and confidence intervals for IMF program dummy variable Žexternal debtrservice ratio.. of independent estimates of g k j from the policy reaction function for nonprogram periods and estimates of b jk from the GEE reduced form for each equation is close to zero. If this is true, the coefficient on the lagged target variables in the
L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 Fig. 6. Recursive point estimates and confidence intervals for IMF program dummy variable Žexternal debtrservice ratio.. 517
518 L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 Table 4 Share of statistically significant t-statistics at the 5% level in recursive estimates of the GEE a Target Lagged fiscal balancer Lagged NDA growth, Lagged NEER percent variable GDP, b 1 b2 Change, b 3 H o : b1 s 0 H o : b1 s H o : b2 s 0 H o : b2 s H o : b3 s 0 H o : b3 s full sample full sample full sample value value value D Real GDP growth rate Share in total 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 program year recursionsb Share in total 45.0 0.0 47.0 0.0 0.0 4.5 nonprogram year recursions c D Inflation rate Share in total 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 3.4 0.0 program year recursionsb Share in total 0.0 0.0 10.9 13.9 85.6 0.0 nonprogram year recursions c D External debtr serÕice ratio Share in total 0.0 36.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 program year recursionsb Share in total 54.0 49.5 57.4 0.0 0.0 2.5 nonprogram year recursions c a Excluding full sample estimates, the total number of recursive estimates was equal to 87 for program year observations, and to 202 for nonprogram year observations. b Recursive procedure starts with the baseline sample Žall nonprogram observations plus one program observation. and adds program observations one by one. c Recursive procedure starts with the entire sample and subtracts out one by one nonprogram observations. reduced form equation yŽ b jkg k j q 1.4 should be close to y1. But the data strongly reject this hypothesis, except in the growth equation.36 This finding, 36 The null hypothesis of an estimated coefficient equal to y1 on the lagged dependent variable is rejected at the 10% level for real GDP growth, 5% level for the inflation rate, and 1% level for the debtrservice ratio.
Table 5 Generalized evaluation estimates of policy parameters Ž b . a Target variable Policy variable L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 Lagged fiscal balancerGDP Lagged net domestic asset growth Lagged NEER Žpercentage change. b 1 y2 b1 b 1 q2 b 2 y2 b2 b 2 q2 b 3 y2 b3 b 3 q2 standard Ž t-statistics. standard standard Ž t-statistics. standard standard Ž t-statistics. standard errors errors errors errors errors errors D Real GDP growth rate Full sample y0.103 y0.042 Žy1.37. 0.019 0.0004 0.004 Ž1.82. 0.009 y0.027 y0.009 Ž1.03. 0.009 estimates Recursive estimates Ø Minimum y0.411 y0.180 Ž1.55. 0.051 y0.001 0.003 Ž1.46. 0.006 y0.055 y0.022 Žy1.30. 0.012 Ø Maximum y0.094 y0.033 Žy1.08. 0.028 y0.004 0.013 Ž1.51. 0.030 y0.005 0.010 Ž1.32. 0.026 D Inflation rate Full sample y1.181 y0.467 Žy1.31. 0.247 y0.207 y0.088 Žy1.47. 0.031 0.025 0.436U Ž2.12. 0.846 estimates Recursive estimates Ø Minimum y6.101 y2.592 Žy1.48. 0.917 y0.216 y0.116U Žy2.31. y0.015 y0.190 0.170 Ž0.95. 0.530 Ø Maximum y0.954 1.358 Ž1.17. 3.669 y0.032 0.162 Ž1.67. 0.356 0.193 0.873U Ž2.567. 1.553 D External debtr serÕice ratio Full sample y0.157 0.097 Ž0.76. 0.351 y0.043 y0.020 Žy1.78. 0.002 y0.052 0.058 Ž1.05. 0.168 estimates Recursive estimates Ø Minimum y0.291 y0.116 Žy1.33. y0.068 y0.041UU Žy2.99. y0.174 y0.057 Žy0.97. 0.060 Ø Maximum 1.095 1.790 Ž5.149.UU 2.486 y0.067 0.004 Ž0.11. 0.076 y0.018 0.128 Ž1.76. 0.275 a Standard errors and t-statistics are computed using White’s heteroschedasticity-consistent variance–covariance estimator. A single asterisk indicates 519 statistical significance at the 5% level; two asterisks indicate statistical significance at the 1% level.
Table 6 520 Sensitivity of estimates of policy reaction function parameters Žg . a Target variable Policy variable D Fiscal balancerGDP D Net domestic asset growth D NEER Žpercentage change . gy2 g gq2 gy2 g gq2 gy2 g gq2 standard Ž t-statistics. standard standard Ž t-statistics. standard standard Ž t-statistics. standard errors errors errors errors errors errors Lagged GDP growth rate Full sample y0.222 0.0024 Ž0.19 . 0.269 y3.063 y1.090 Žy1.11 . 0.882 y0.795 y0.204 Žy0.69 . 0.388 estimates Recursive estimates b Ø Minimum y0.712 y0.159 Žy0.57 . 0.394 y2.793 y1.181 Žy1.46 . 0.431 y1.861 y0.685 Žy1.16 . 0.491 Ø Maximum y0.205 0.156 Ž0.86 . 0.516 y1.184 0.149 Ž0.22 . 1.482 y0.355 0.510 Ž1.18 . 1.375 Lagged inflation rate Full sample y0.005 0.006 Ž1.02 . 0.016 y1.474 y0.081 Žy0.12 . 1.312 y0.097 y0.017 Ž0.29 . 0.131 estimates Recursive estimates b Ø Minimum y1.196 y0.448 Žy1.20 . 0.300 y2.636 y1.398U Žy2.26 . y0.160 y0.768 y0.439UU Žy2.67 . y0.110 Ø Maximum y0.148 0.104 Ž0.82 . 0.356 y0.851 0.504 Ž0.74 . 1.861 0.192 0.511UU Ž3.20. 0.830 Lagged external debt r serÕice ratio Full sample y0.041 y0.0007 Žy0.04 . 0.039 y0.584 y0.097 Žy0.40 . 0.389 y0.289 y0.152 U Žy2.22 . y0.015 estimates Recursive estimates b Ø Minimum y0.102 y0.029 Žy0.79 . y1.300 y0.691U Žy2.27 . y0.708 y0.397 U Žy2.55 . y0.085 Ø Maximum y0.127 0.075 Ž0.74 . 0.277 y0.222 0.277 Ž1.11 . 0.775 y0.065 0.211 Ž1.53 . 0.487 a L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 Standard errors and t-statistics are completed using White’s heteroschedasticity-consistent variance–covariance estimator. A single asterisk indicates statistical significance at the 5% level; two asterisks indicate statistical significance at the 1% level. b Recursive least squares estimates obtained by adding observations one-by-one to an initial sample of 25 nonprogram years Žcorresponding to a minimum of 20 degrees of freedom ..
L. Dicks-Mireaux et al.r Journal of DeÕelopment Economics 61 (2000) 495–526 521 Table 7 Share of statistically significant t-statistics at the 5% level in recursive estimates of the policy reaction functiona Žin %. Policy D Fiscal balancer D Net domestic D NEER percentage variable GDP assets growth change H o: g s0 H o: g s H o: g s0 H o: g s H o: g s0 H o: g s full sample full sample full sample value value value Lagged GDP 0.0 Ž0.0. 0.0 Ž0.0. 0.0 Ž0.0. 0.0 Ž3.4. 0.0 Ž0.0. 0.0 Ž0.6. growth rate Lagged 39.3 Ž57.9. 0.0 Ž38.8. 0.6 Ž3.4. 9.0 Ž9.6. 3.4 Ž7.3. 2.8 Ž7.3. inflation rate Lagged 0.0 Ž0.0. 0.0 Ž0.0. 9.0 Ž14.0. 0.0 Ž7.9. 70.8 Ž73.6. 5.6 Ž14.0. external debtr service ratio a Excluding full nonprogram sample estimates, the total number of recursive estimates was equal to 178 for nonprogram years observations. Shares of statistically significant t-statistics at the 10% level are reported in parentheses. together with the fact that the reduced form coefficients for the lagged target variables are significantly different from zero, calls into question the GEE assumption that all shocks to target variables are fully reversed within one period. Indeed, if the reaction function parameters cannot account for the statistical significance of the lagged target variable, partial inertial effects in the target variables may explain why initial conditions do influence subsequent macroeco- nomic performance. However, the logical consequence of interpreting the coeffi- cients of the lagged target variable as reflecting inertial effects is that all other coefficient estimates should also be interpreted in light of a richer dynamic specification. In this case, the b jIMF estimates cannot be interpreted as the full contemporaneous effect of IMF support in a given period. 5. Conclusions With respect to the central objectives of this paper — to use the GEE framework to identify the independent effects of ESAF support during 1986–1991 on key macroeconomic variables and to assess whether the assumptions underly- ing the GEE are applicable to the ESAF-eligible countries — conclusions can be summarized as follows. For output growth and the debtrservice ratio, sizable beneficial effects that are statistically significantly different from zero are identi- fied.37 The effects on inflation are not significantly different from zero. These 37 For the external debtrservice ratio, statistical significance was at the 10% level.
You can also read