Enhancing digital diffusion productivity
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Enhancing digital diffusion for higher productivity growth in Spain By Aida Caldera Sánchez, Müge Adalet McGowan and Yosuke Jin Digitalisation is transforming the Spanish economy, changing the way firms operate, with positive implications for productivity. However, these changes are not evenly shared between high and low productivity firms, or small and large firms (Figure 1), which can help explain why aggregate productivity gains from digitalisation have been modest in Spain so far. Hence, Spain still has considerable scope to reap the benefits of the adoption of digital technologies and, perhaps more importantly, their effective use to produce new business models and products, as discussed in the 2021 Economic Survey of Spain (OECD, 2021; Jin, 2021). Figure 1. The adoption of digital technologies varies with firm size Percentage of firms which adopt each technology, 2019 Note: “Small firms” stands for small enterprises with 10-49 employees, while “Large firms” stands for large enterprises
with 250 employees and more. Source: OECD, ICT Access and Usage by Businesses (database). The pandemic has shown the benefits of a more digitalised economy (e-commerce, teleworking) and accelerated the pace of digital adoption, with the extent of teleworking and digital sales increasing in Spain during the last year. The Spanish Recovery, Resilience and Transformation Plan allocates 29% of funds to digitalisation, which will help Spain achieve its ambitious objectives laid out in its national digital strategy, “Digital Spain 2025”. In this context of the increasing importance of digitalisation in Spain, the Survey analyses the challenges and opportunities that digitalisation offers through three types of policies. First, good communications infrastructure is a prerequisite to adopt and use digital technologies. This is an area where Spain ranks relatively well in international perspective, with a high share of fibre in total fixed broadband subscriptions and a relatively widespread internet usage. The coverage of fibre networks in rural areas is also well above that in other European countries (46% vs. 21%). Nonetheless, the digital divide between urban and rural areas in Spain remains, even if it has narrowed recently. Barriers to “rights of way” – permission to install necessary equipment – are high in some regions and municipalities, and should be reduced to lower deployment costs. Second, there are complementary factors that are key to take full advantage of digitalisation. These include organisational capital and managerial skills, R&D and digital skills. There are important gaps in these areas in Spain. For example, business investment in intangible assets and R&D are relatively low. To boost innovation and reap the full benefits of digitalisation, the Survey recommends boosting partnerships between the public and the private sector, for example by enhancing the role of Technology Centres to increase cooperation between research institutes and SMEs,
which need to innovate and use digital technologies more. There is also ample room to develop ICT skills, especially for low-educated and older people (Figure 2). Reducing the mismatch between the skills employers need and the qualifications of jobseekers should be a priority. This would help in particular low productivity firms and low-skilled people, making the benefits of digitalisation shared by all. Targeting training to those with lower digital skills and shifting financial incentives for lifelong training at least partially to training programmes chosen by individuals rather than employers would help achieve these outcomes. Figure 2. There is room to develop digital skills Percentage of respondents claiming to have basic digital skills, 2019 Source: Eurostat, Digital skills (database). Finally, policies, which raise competitive pressures and sharpen incentives to better use digital technologies and better access to finance, can also enhance the diffusion of digital technologies. For example, the Survey recommends fostering the implementation of the Markey Unity Law to reduce regulatory differences across regions and facilitate the growth and entry of new firms and this way encourage the adoption of new technologies. It also recommends strengthening targeted support to new and high-potential firms through
public guarantee schemes. In addition to these policies, which facilitate the entry and expansion of innovative firms, it is also important to ensure the efficient exit of non-viable firms and restructuring of viable firms in temporary distress. An effective insolvency regime can help reduce the barriers and costs of firm restructuring or exit and facilitates technological experimentation. In this context, promoting out- of-court insolvency proceedings, especially for SMEs, is key. References: Jin, Y. (2021), “Enhancing digital diffusion for higher productivity growth in Spain”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1673, OECD Publishing, Paris. OECD (2021), OECD Economic Surveys: Spain 2021, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/79e92d88-en. A recipe for lower house prices By Volker Ziemann, OECD Economics Department https://www.oecd.org/housing/policy-toolkit/ Does housing need to become always more and more expensive
relative to other services, eating an ever-higher share of income? This situation puts a strain on household finances, making it complicated for people to move close to jobs and often generating macro-economic or financial risks. The economy’s capacity to meet the demand for housing and supply dwellings where they are demanded is crucial to avoid these excessive price and rent increases, contribute to macroeconomic stability and facilitate residential mobility. The OECD has recently launched a report entitled “Brick by Brick: Building Better Housing Policies” to help analysts and policymakers make better housing policies. At its core, one of its chapters focuses on the fundamental drivers of housing supply and demand and the relevance of housing policies to ensure affordable and quality housing for all. The empirical framework underlying the analysis builds on the famous stock-flow model for housing in which i) a positive (negative) shock to housing demand increases (decreases) house prices, ii) higher (lower) house prices boost (reduce) housing investment, and iii) higher (lower) supply of housing feeds back into house prices and partly offsets the initial demand shock. In this framework, demand and supply elasticities jointly determine how much of a change in demand feeds into prices and how much into construction. Figure 1. Stock-flow model of housing
These elasticities depend to a great extent on housing-related policies. Eliminating mortgage interest deduction, for instance, mitigates house prices increases amid demand pressures (lower demand elasticity). A high degree of decentralisation of land-use decisions is generally associated with more restrictive land-use policy settings consistent with the home-voter hypothesis (lower supply elasticity). Strict rental market regulation inhibits new construction by reducing the incentives to invest in rental housing (lower supply elasticity). These housing-related policies differ considerably across countries. Accordingly, expected benefits from moving towards best policy practices also vary across countries and policy tools. Figure 2 illustrates the expected reductions in house- price to income ratios.[1] Figure 2. Housing affects society and the economy in multiple ways
Note: Simulated change between 2020 and 2050 in the number of years over which cumulated average household disposable income equals the average price of a 100m2 dwelling (in years). Source: OECD (2021), Brick by Brick: Building Better Housing Policies, OECD Publishing. Residential construction is simulated to expand by more than 20% in Sweden if rent control becomes as flexible as in New Zealand, increasing the housing stock in 2050 by around 11%, which could reduce house prices in Sweden by around 1.5 years of disposable income for the typical 100m2 dwelling. Sweden, alongside the Netherlands, would also be the largest beneficiary in terms of housing affordability from eliminating mortgage interest deductibility. New Zealand, in turn, could boost affordability the most by streamlining the governance of land-use policies across levels of government. These examples illustrate the great potential of housing policy reforms. Many more are discussed in the report. A dedicated Policy Toolkit including an online Dashboard and Country Snapshots allows policymakers to compare their country’s housing outcomes and policies. Finally, a Policy Action Tool helps implement such reforms by anticipating synergies and trade-offs across various outcome dimensions.
[1] Measured by the reduction, compared to the baseline of no policy-change, in the number of years over which cumulated average household disposable income equals the average price of a 100m2 dwelling. Monetary policy and housing markets: interactions and side effects By Ernest Gnan, Oesterreichische Nationalbank (OeNB) and the 1 European Money and Finance Forum. https://www.oecd.org/housing/policy-toolkit/ Monetary policy influences housing prices through the level of interest rates (cost of credit, discount rate, attractiveness vis-à-vis other investments). The housing market affects aggregate demand through construction activity and its influence on consumption (wealth and income effects). Housing booms and busts can threaten financial and macroeconomic stability, and thus ultimately also feed through to consumer price inflation. Central banks can thus not ignore housing
market developments. But monetary policy is too crude an instrument to target house prices. A new class of instruments – macroprudential policies – has been created and fills this gap since the Global Financial Crisis. Moreover, housing prices are substantially driven by structural housing policies which affect housing supply and demand. At the same time, including owner-occupied housing in the consumer price basket helps to adequately feed this important part of households’ expenditure into central banks’ reaction functions. While monetary policies worldwide have undoubtedly played a central role in containing the economic fallout from COVID-19, potential side effects, such as shooting up housing prices, and the proportionality of long-lasting unconventional monetary policy measures need to gain increasing attention as economies are bouncing back from the COVID crisis. Why should central banks pay attention to a specific sector such as the housing market? Central banks worldwide are mandated with ensuring price stability, subject to this (or in parallel with, as in the US Fed) also with supporting growth and employment. Their price stability objective is usually coined in terms of consumer price inflation. Monetary policy is a rather “crude” instrument, which affects aggregate demand broadly, and cannot usually be targeted towards developments in specific sectors. So, why should monetary policy care about developments in a specific sector such as the housing market? There are several channels in which housing is relevant for the transmission of monetary policy impulses such as changes in official interest rates or in bond market yields through QE. First, the level of short-term and long-term interest rates influences mortgage credit rates. So, it makes purchasing a home more (or less) affordable. Thus, demand for housing – and thus employment, aggregate demand and ultimately also consumer price inflation – rises (or falls). Mortgage loans make up 77% of euro area households’ total borrowing
(ECB, 2021). The growth of euro area mortgage loans continued its upward trend observed since 2016 to reach around 5% in nominal terms most recently. In 2019, in the EU and euro area gross value added in the construction sector made up 5.4% and 5%, respectively, of GDP, with a wide range of 1.7% to 7.4% across EU countries, though. Construction projects are typically financed to a substantial extent through credit. So, financing costs exert a potentially strong effect on construction activity. Figure 1. Housing makes up a major part of households’ lending and is an important economic sector Positive and negative wealth and income effects from house price rises Second, the value of an asset is influenced by the net present value of the stream of income from this asset. In the case of housing, this income can either be rental income or the implicit income from using the house (in the case of owner- occupied housing). If the discount rate falls (as implied by lower official interest rates), then the net present value of
a home rises. Looser monetary policy thus, ceteris paribus, raises real estate prices. This rise in housing prices can affect household consumption in various ways. First, it can entail that households feel richer and can take out an additional mortgage on their house, to finance other expenditures. In this case, we observe a positive wealth effect. Conversely, rising house prices can also imply that for instance young households need to spend a higher fraction of the disposable income on housing, leaving less for other consumption (see e.g. OECD, 2021). In this case, there would be a negative income effect from rising house prices. Whether the positive or negative wealth and income effects prevail, depends on the fraction of homeowners versus tenants and demographic factors. If, for instance homeowners benefiting from wealth increases have a lower propensity to consume than those just buying a home, the net effect on aggregate consumption will likely be negative. Similarly, rising rents (which are the likely consequence, with some lag and to a certain extent, depending on countries’ institutional and legal frameworks, of higher house prices) will benefit landlords, while tenants will have less of their income left for other consumption. Assuming that renters are wealthier and have a lower propensity to consume than tenants, then a rise in house prices and rents will on aggregate dampen consumption for non-housing goods. A very similar argument applies to households which take out a loan to finance their homes: higher house prices imply the need for a bigger loan, implying lower disposable household income after loan servicing. Thus, the wealth and income effects from residential price swings also imply substantial redistributive effects across individuals and demographic groups (see e.g. OECD, 2021). Figure 2. Real estate price developments in the euro area
Source: ECB (2021). Housing booms and busts threaten financial and macroeconomic stability There is a second reason why central banks carefully look at housing market developments, which has gained prominence in the Global Financial Crisis (GFC): housing market bubbles can trigger and fuel economic booms, which subsequently end up in deep busts. Monetary policy can fuel such housing booms by making credit very cheap, thus encouraging excessive leverage among households. Real estate booms can also, at a more structural level, entail that an excessive fraction of economic activity goes into construction (as was the case in several countries prior to the GFC). Once the housing bubble bursts, a deep financial crisis can be the result, which requires the central bank to take emergency measures to prevent a collapse of the financial system, but also to dampen the resulting recession and the accompanying excessive fall of consumer price inflation, way below the central bank’s target, potentially even into negative territory. Some economists thus argue that central banks should “lean against the wind” in the face of rising real estate prices. Even if the central bank might not target asset prices, leaning against the wind might be justified since it also helps to cushion excessive swings in consumer price inflation which may be triggered by real estate booms and busts. Others argue that such “preemptive”
monetary policy tightening entails high macroeconomic costs in terms of foregone employment and output. Monetary policy is, according to this view, too crude a tool to take real estate prices into account and should exclusively focus on consumer price inflation. Macroprudential policies as a new tool to address housing cycles This is why, notably after the GFC, a consensus has emerged that an additional set of instruments, “macroprudential rules”, should be applied to cool down overheating asset price developments, e.g. by raising loan-to-value ratios or loan service-to-income ratios applied by banks when they grant housing credits (see e.g. ESRB, 2021, ECB, 2021 and OECD, 2021). These new policies have been implemented around the world and experience is accumulating in their application. Note, however, that in practice the stylized notion of two totally separate tools for two clearly distinct economic goals – monetary policy to stabilize consumer price inflation, and macroprudential policies to prevent asset booms and busts – does not fully do justice to a far more complex reality. Including owner-occupied housing in consumer price inflation to better reflect households’ comprehensive cost of living developments in central banks’ reaction functions One way how home prices feed into the central bank’s reaction function is by including the cost of accommodation in the consumer price index. This is already the case for rents. By contrast, at least in most European countries, it is not yet the case for owner-occupied homes. This implies that the cost of housing for owner-occupiers (including e.g. young families buying a home) is neglected in the measurement of consumer prices and thus in the central bank’s reaction function; it also implies that house price bubbles risk to escape the central bank’s formal reaction function. Including owner- occupied housing is thus useful for improving the metrics used
to inform monetary policy. Side effects and proportionality of monetary expansion gain weight as economies bounce back from COVID Another way how asset price developments, including house prices, can enter the central bank’s reaction function is through explicit consideration of side effects and the proportionality of monetary policy measures. Not even the best medicine comes without side effects. To take the current situation of the COVID crisis, clearly central banks had to step in to contain damage to our economies. Central banks are aware of the “side effects” of these policies, such as rising stock prices but also, in many countries, further rising house prices. To contain the latter, e.g. the ECB explicitly excluded mortgage credit from eligibility for meeting banks’ lending benchmarks in order to benefit from preferential interest rates on the ECB’s Targeted Long-Term Refinancing Operations (TLTROs). As mentioned, asset price increases in general, and housing price rises more specifically, may also entail large wealth gains for those already owning these assets, implying large distributive effects. Stronglyexpansionary, unconventional monetary policies over long periods thus ultimately raise the question of proportionality. It is not straightforward how to weigh the benefits against the (potential) costs – there is substantial uncertainty and any decisions ultimately rely on careful judgement. What seems clear, though, is that as the duration of expansionary monetary policy measures extends and as signs of “ exuberance” in asset markets including residential real estate markets intensify, while the economy seems clearly back on track, the case for taking side effects and proportionality duly into account is becoming more urgent. References
ECB (2021). Financial Stability Review, May. ESRB (2021). Lower for longer – macroprudential policy issues arising from the low interest rate environment June 2021. Report by the Joint Task Force of ESRB Advisory Technical Committee (ATC), ESRB Advisory Scientific Committee (ASC), and ESCB Financial Stability Committee (FSC), June. Fell, J., and T. Shakir (2021). May 2021 Financial Stability Review. Presentation at SUERF-Baffi Bocconi Webinar, May 19, 2021. OECD (2021), Brick by Brick: Building Better Housing Policies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/b453b043-en. Housing policy strategies – what is best practice? by Arent Skjæveland, Deputy Director of the Economic Policy Department of Norway’s Ministry of Finance and Chairman of the Working Party No. 1 of the OECD’s Economic Policy Committee. https://www.oecd.org/housing/policy-toolkit/ The first phase of the horizontal housing project has been completed, resulting in a new OECD Toolkit for housing policy
that can guide national reform efforts. The toolkit complements the OECD housing policy strategy. The core importance of the housing market both for welfare and efficiency in our economies makes this toolkit highly relevant and timely. First, debt-driven housing market bubbles are at the root of many financial crises and may imply harsh and very long- lasting downturns. Let me take my own country as an example. The financial crisis in Norway in the late 1800s, the so- called Christiania crash (that was the name of the capital at that time), left deep scars. Not only among ordinary people who saw their fortunes evaporate, but also in the city’s physical landscape. Large parts of today’s city centre in Oslo were built during the housing market frenzy of the 1890s. When the housing market collapsed in 1899, most building activity came to a standstill that lasted for two decades, leaving the architecture of the 1890s as one of the city’s distinctive characteristics. It took 90-years for house prices, in real terms, to recover most of their losses. A new financial crisis was then approaching. The Norwegian banking crisis in the late 1980s is one of the worst financial crises in advanced economies in modern times according to
Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff. Real house prices declined by 40 percent and did not return to pre-crisis levels for more than 12 years. The impact of the crisis was harsh, as the number of unemployed tripled and the three largest banks in the country collapsed. In recent years, house prices have surged once again, fuelled in part by low interest rates at home and abroad. However, we really have a close eye on this. Much is done at the demand side with macroprudential regulations to contribute to more sustainable household debt at the supply side to reduce building cost. Certainly, a lesson both from our crises-experiences and similar crises in other countries is that the housing market is at the core of financial stability and far too important to be left at its own. Not only for financial stability, but also for a range of other aspects of the welfare of the population. To own the house you live in, is of great value to most people. Owning a house often gives a sense of safety and security. In Norway, 80 percent of households own the house they live in. A high level of home ownership is a typical pattern in most OECD countries, with an OECD average of about 68 percent. Housing is typically the largest asset in household balance sheets, as well as one of the largest spending items in household budgets. Housing market developments are therefore of great influence for the distribution of income and wealth. Housing is a fundamental driver of the accumulation and the distribution of wealth and debt within and across generations. This has a strong link to housing affordability. House prices across the OECD countries have raised to levels that may undermine housing affordability, particularly for low-income households, first-time buyers and in fast-growing urban areas. Access to affordable housing is crucial for achieving a number
of key policy objectives, including poverty and homelessness reduction, equality of opportunities and sustainable growth. What policy avenues to follow to achieve housing affordability are challenging. As an example: Tax subsidies to homeownership often favours insiders, as house prices are pushed upwards, making the step into the housing market for first-time buyers even more difficult. Housing is also important for productivity and the growth potential of our economies. A main channel is via the impact on the mobility of workers. The degree of geographical mobility has strong implications for the functioning of the labour market as it affects the job-matching process and use of human resources. This is of crucial importance when labour market developments between regions show an asymmetric development. In this respect, high transaction taxes on houses or difficult access to reasonably priced housing in other regions can trap workers in unemployment or low-productivity jobs, and workers can even end up falling out of the labour market. Such obstacles to worker mobility may have strong effects on economic efficiency. Another aspect of housing development is how it may affect environmental outcomes, including thorough interactions with urban land-use patterns, residential energy consumption and transport systems. Here there has been a complete change in many countries over the last decades. One might say that car use strongly influenced urban planning in the former millennium. Currently, public transport, less parking, more cycling, less cars in the city centres and better clustering of living areas are more at the forefront. Net zero emissions are the new keywords in urban planning and transport policy. Building land is a scarce resource in urban areas, and it is a strong tendency that big cities experience a stronger house price growth than more rural areas. When working on national house policy strategies, we have to address such differences between pressure areas and areas with less pressure.
Taking all this together – a multi-facetted housing policy strategy is needed. Such a strategy has to cut across many policy areas, including financial regulation, taxation, carbon footprint, urban land use regulation, transport policies, local public finance, social housing, welfare support, housing standards, rental regulation and the enforcement of competition in related activities as construction and real estate. To be successful making such national strategies, we need to learn from the each other. What is best practice? The new OECD Toolkit for housing policy and the OECD Housing Policy Strategy give many of the relevant answers. Further insights and policy implications can be found in the new OECD report Brick by Brick: Building Better Housing Policies. The accompanying online toolkit features a Dashboard of indicators covering outcomes and policy settings, Country Snapshots of the housing sector, and a Policy Action Tool that allows policymakers to anticipate synergies and trade-offs across various outcome dimensions before implementing housing reforms. How will rising shipping cost affect inflation in OECD countries? by Sophie Guilloux-Nefussi and Elena Rusticelli, OECD Economics Department How will rising shipping cost affect inflation in OECD countries? Extraordinary demand and supply factors have pushed up freight
prices Shipping cost rates have soared in recent months due to the conjunction of booming demand for consumer durables from Asia and supply-side bottlenecks created by sanitary restrictions in ports and terminals. These have slowed loading and unloading operations and crew changes. Prices of containerised freight started to rise in the second half of 2020 and rose further in the first quarter of 2021, when the average quarterly increase across the main indices of global shipping costs ranged between 30% and 65% (Figure 1). Figure 1: Container shipping prices are on the rise since mid-2020 On the demand side, the pandemic led to a global demand drop at the start of 2020, followed by a quick recovery at the end of the same year. Pent-up demand caused by lockdowns in the first half of 2020, shifts in consumption patterns towards durable goods, and government income support all strengthened demand for goods when transportation services were still limited.
On the supply side, multiple factors are compounding shipping delays. Vessels are currently used at almost full capacity and containers remain scarce. Congestion at ports, and lower productivity at terminals and inland depots have also led to bottlenecks. Distancing rules and reinforced hygiene standards have increased intervals between crew shifts. These have prolonged processing times at ports, hampered the return of containers to Asia and generated delays along the entire shipping chain. The March blockage in the Suez Canal also added to shipping disruption and tensions. This atypical situation is expected to persist for a few more months. Port congestion continues to be a big bottleneck in the United States, where all loading/unloading slots for cargoes from/to Asia are fully booked throughout the second quarter of 2021. The reopening of European economies is also impacting supply and demand. In this context, industry experts do not foresee any normalisation of prices before the end of 2021. Rising shipping costs could push up inflation temporarily in OECD countries To which extent will the observed rise in global shipping costs impact inflation across OECD countries? The empirical approach to answer this question proceeds in two steps: first, quantifying the pass-through of shipping costs to merchandise import price inflation, and, second, assessing the transmission of import price inflation to consumer price inflation. In the baseline scenario, shipping costs are assumed to rise by 50% in the first quarter of 2021 and to stabilise at the same level for the rest of the year, in line with the recent industry experts’ projections. However, the uncertainty around forthcoming container freight rates remains high and, therefore, two alternative scenarios are considered: one of anticipated normalisation in which shipping costs gradually
decline to a price level slightly higher than prior to the pandemic starting from the second half of 2021, and one of delayed normalisation in which the initial rise is followed by a further 10% increase in each of the three remaining quarters of 2021. Figure 2 – Effect of global shipping costs developments on OECD merchandise import prices and consumer prices In the first quarter, the observed rise in shipping costs is estimated to boost merchandise import price inflation (year- on-year) in OECD countries by 2.5 percentage points on average. After four quarters, depending on the scenario, the impact on merchandise import price inflation could still be between 0.6 to 3.5 percentage points (Figure 2, Panel A). Notwithstanding the swift reaction of import costs, the pass- through to consumer price inflation would be modest. The overall rise in CPI inflation would be by about 0.2 percentage points after four quarters, with no major divergence across the three scenarios (Figure 2, Panel B). Consumer price inflation would start to recede gradually thereafter and settle back over the following 2-year period, reflecting the large inertia in price adjustments of consumption goods. Given the relatively small portion of transport costs normally incorporated in final goods value, this result is not surprising2 and is in line with previous estimates available for the US economy (based on a different methodology).3
Arguably, the rise in ocean shipping costs could compound with other input costs pressures − due to global shortages in specific industries like semiconductors − and rising commodity prices to further push up inflation in the coming months. However, these cost-push pressures are expected to be temporary. Inflation expectations are well anchored and global spare capacity remains sizeable. As a result, a significant and sustained pick-up in underlying inflation is unlikely beyond a few quarters and monetary authorities should look through these transitory relative price shocks. References: ECB (2021), “What is driving the recent surge in shipping costs?”, Economic Bulletin, Issue 3 / 2021 – Box 1. Guilloux-Nefussi, S. and E. Rusticelli (forthcoming 2021), “Recent developments in input costs on global markets and their consequences on inflation in OECD countries”. Herriford, T., E. Johnson, N. Sly, and A. Lee Smith (2016), “How Does a Rise in International Shipping Costs Affect U.S. Inflation?,” Macro Bulletin, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. OECD (2021), “Rising container shipping costs could push up near-term inflation in OECD countries”, OECD Economic Outlook No 109 (Edition 2021/1), Chapter 1, Box 1.3. The Netherlands: Building a
stronger recovery By Daniela Glocker, OECD Economics Department The Netherlands is recovering from its largest economic contraction since the Second World War. Almost overnight, the COVID-19 outbreak restricted people’s daily lives. Work and education shifted to take place from home. Many businesses offering non-essential but close contact jobs could not easily adjust, leading to a reduction in working hours or number of employed. Travel, social interactions, shopping, cultural and leisure activities were restricted to hold back the spread of the virus. The Dutch government swiftly implemented a comprehensive support package, and extended and adjusted the measures several times in response to prolonged restrictions. These policies reduced uncertainty and protected people, businesses and jobs. In combination with structural and institutional strengths and a high level of digitalisation, the generous fiscal support helped the country to weather the COVID-19 crisis with limited economic damage compared to many OECD countries (Figure 1). Figure 1. The economy contracted less than elsewhere Real GDP, Index Q4 2019=100 Note: The pre-crisis growth path is based on the November 2019
OECD Economic Outlook projection, with linear extrapolation for 2022 based on trend growth in 2021. Source: OECD Economic Outlook 106 and 109 databases. The start of the vaccination campaign earlier this year marked the beginning of the end of the health emergency. As the Dutch roll up their sleeves, restrictions are progressively lifted, business and consumer confidence are improving, and the economy is set to recover gradually. The 2021 Economic Survey of the Netherlands foresees annual growth of 2.7% in 2021 and 3.7% in 2022, with GDP recovering the pre- crisis level at the beginning of 2022. Private consumption will drive the recovery as households can eat out, shop and enjoy many of the social, cultural and leisure possibilities that have been off-limits during the pandemic. Nevertheless, private consumption will be held back by households facing an increase in pension premiums and rising unemployment as the result of support measures being phased out. Uncertainties still abound. Quicker than expected vaccine roll out can contribute to faster economic growth, especially if returning confidence spurs people to spend some of the savings amassed during the pandemic. On the other hand, potential outbreaks of vaccine-resistant virus strains could postpone the recovery. Well-targeted fiscal support should remain in place in the short term to support the recovery, but the government should also plan forward and carefully weigh permanent spending increases against pressures emerging from population ageing and related health care expenditures. The 2021 Economic Survey of the Netherlands argues that coming out of the pandemic is an opportunity to build back stronger, fairer and greener, by addressing some long-standing structural challenges: In the Netherlands, a high share of workers are on non- standard contracts. This trend has increased over recent years, driven largely by lower labour costs for the self-employed and other non-standard workers than for
regular employed. During the crisis, self-employed and other flexible workers on freelance or on-call contracts were more likely to lose their job as the job retention scheme mainly protected workers on permanent contracts. Temporary contracts are also used more frequently in hospitality and service sectors, which were hit hard by the COVID-19 crisis, in lower skilled occupations and among young workers. Although the government provided some income support for the self-employed, the crisis may have exacerbated income inequality. Implementing the Commission for the Regulation of Work recommendations is key to reducing labour market duality. More should also be done to reduce the gap in part-time work between women and men. People living in the Netherlands are exposed to the risk of local air pollution and to climate change risks such as floods, as large parts of the country are below sea level. People’s exposure to nitrogen emissions remains among the highest in the EU owing to high population density, high industrial and agricultural production and being home to Europe’s main seaport. A High Court ruling in 2019 stipulated a re- evaluation of permits for a range of nitrogen emitting activities, notably for construction and agriculture projects near natural preservation areas. The available nitrogen space for new developments remains limited, constraining new investment in infrastructure, buildings and agriculture. Greenhouse gas emissions are also high compared to the EU average, and a High Court ruling in 2019 mandated a 25% reduction compared to 1990 levels by the end of 2020. This prompted a reduction in coal power capacity and other measures. The 2020 target was just met, owing in part to the COVID-19 crisis that reduced economic activity and mobility. Long-run prosperity and people’s well-being hinge on the reduction of local air pollution and greenhouse gas emissions, which
requires concrete national-level actions, as well as enhanced regional and international cooperation. High debt and a high share of illiquid assets, mainly housing, held by households create macroeconomic and financial vulnerabilities. Household debt is at more than 200% of disposable income, among the highest in the OECD, mainly consisting of mortgages. Limited housing supply and favourable tax treatment for owner-occupied housing have contributed to soaring house prices. As a result, home-owners are not only better off compared to people not yet owning a house, i.e. often the young and people on non-standard work contracts, due to higher equity, but also compared to investors of other assets. A possible future correction in house prices is a risk to economic growth, as households who suffer large capital losses tend to cut back on consumption in order to continue servicing their debt. A more balanced housing market with affordable prices and a better functioning rental market would not only reduce inequality and macroeconomic risks but also boost growth. A coherent package of reforms is needed, including to the tax treatment of owner-occupied housing, spatial planning and rental regulations. As the Netherlands re-emerges from the shadows of the pandemic, and people and businesses are weaned off emergency support, it is not the time to return to the old ways. It is the time to build a new future. A future that is better. Better Housing For All: How
to Square the Circle by Volker Zieman, OECD Economics Department https://www.oecd.org/housing/policy-toolkit/ Housing is one of the most complex policy challenges of our time. There is, of course, the affordability issue and how to cope with the concentration of demand in supply-constrained areas. Yet, the functioning of housing markets also reflects other burning challenges of our lifetimes, including social cohesion, financial resilience, residential and intergenerational mobility or the ecological transition. Against this background, the OECD has launched a Housing Policy Toolkit to help policymakers address these intertwined challenges. The overarching theme is assessing the performance of housing markets across three main policy objectives: social inclusiveness, economic efficiency and environmental sustainability. Figure 1. Housing affects society and the economy in multiple ways
Making housing more inclusive Access to affordable housing – a basic human need and central driver of well-being – has become increasingly challenging for many households in OECD countries. Housing-related spending absorbs on average about one-third of household budgets, a share that has been rising over time. Over the past two decades, prices have risen by 60% more for homes than for goods and services on average across OECD countries. Low interest rates have helped households absorb part, but not all, of these higher prices. Seven of the 23 OECD countries for which the data are available have experienced real house prices in excess of 90%. Moreover, increasingly steep house prices gradients in urban areas make housing close to economic and cultural amenities unaffordable for most families. The resulting spatial segregation by income threatens social cohesion and undermines economic and ecological efficiency. Making housing more efficient The affordability challenge very much reflects the housing sector’s failure to raise supply where demand is strong, particularly in jobs-rich urban areas, which drives up house
prices and rents. This is due to geographical constraints but also regulatory restrictions in many cities, including land- use and zoning provisions. In some cases, regulations on tenant-landlord relations, introduced to alleviate the near- term burden of housing costs mainly for incumbent tenants, can discourage the supply of rental dwellings or push up rents, thereby undermining affordability over time. Moreover, housing has often been at the core of financial crises, but there is room for policy, especially prudential regulations, to smooth house price fluctuations and make the economy more resilient to housing shocks. Making housing more sustainable The transition to a carbon-neutral, clean economy poses a formidable challenge for a sector that accounts for 17% of global CO2 emissions and 37% of global fine particulate matter emissions. Progress in this area calls for lowering the carbon footprint of new constructions and improving the energy efficiency of the existing building stock. Almost two-thirds of countries worldwide still lack mandatory building energy codes. Frontloading efforts is critical as dwellings have a very long lifespan. Besides, energy poverty tends to compound the affordability challenge, as nearly 20% of low-income people in the OECD area experience difficulties heating their homes. Addressing challenges through concerted policy action Some policies can deliver progress across multiple objectives. This is the case, for example, of increasing government investment in social housing, alleviating restrictive regulations on land use and shifting housing taxation towards recurrent levies on immovable property. Other reforms may involve trade-offs, calling for compensatory measures to ensure balanced progress. For instance, more flexible regulations on landlord-tenant relations, including rent control, can encourage housing investment, reduce supply-
demand mismatches and lower barriers to residential mobility, but they could also penalise vulnerable incumbent tenants. Similar intertemporal trade-offs apply to relief measures taken during the COVID-19 crisis. Further insights and policy implications can be found in the new OECD report Brick by Brick: Building Better Housing Policies. The accompanying online toolkit features a Dashboard of indicators covering outcomes and policy settings, Country Snapshots of the housing sector, and a Policy Action Tool that allows policymakers to anticipate synergies and trade-offs across various outcome dimensions before implementing housing reforms. The state of Housing: Trends and Challenges for the Future by Luiz de Mello, Director, Policy Studies, OECD Economics Department https://www.oecd.org/housing/policy-toolkit/ The OECD has just launched a Housing Policy Toolkit to help policymakers deal with current and emerging challenges in the area of housing, share their experience and identify good
practices. The Toolkit puts together evidence and analysis to inform policy choices and, ultimately, deliver better housing outcomes. The Toolkit recognises that housing policies and regulations need to be forward-looking and anticipate changes in people’s needs, preferences and behaviour, as well as “megatrends” that affect economies and societies. The COVID-19 crisis, along with digitalisation, climate change and population ageing, will most likely have durable, yet uncertain, effects on housing demand and supply, including both the residential and commercial market segments. Buildings, structures and dwellings have a long life span, and as a result today’s policy choices will affect performance for many years to come. To the extent possible, poliymakers also need to foresee and respond to technological changes that affect the construction, use and maintenance of structures. Starting with the COVID-19 crisis, the changes in preferences and behaviour triggered by the pandemic are likely to influence housing demand over the longer term. For example, if teleworking becomes more prevalent, housing demand may shift away from city centres towards peri-urban and rural areas, and from apartments to single-family dwellings. An associated relief on property prices in city centres would likely be accompanied by pressure elsewhere with an uncertain net effect on affordability, unless supply adjusts in tandem. And it is not only the supply of homes that would need to adjust but also that of urban amenities, transport infrastructure and social services. Teleworking will also have a bearing on the demand for office space, putting downward pressure on commercial property prices in central business districts. If the fear of infectious diseases lingers, there could also be an increase in demand for larger offices to allow for effective physical distancing. This could somewhat offset the downward trend in demand due to teleworking.
Where these shifting demand patterns lead to a hollowing-out of city centres, there will be increased risk of urban decay and a loss of dynamism in areas where productivity tends to be highest. Alternatively, changing attitudes and work practices may create new opportunities for social and economic transformation in metropolitan areas that could become increasingly polycentric. At the same time, as density gives way to sprawl, the environmental footprint of cities will need to be reassessed, with implications for policy aimed to improve the environmental sustainability of the world’s metropolitan areas. Digitalisation, beyond its effects through teleworking, also poses challenges. It affects the housing outlook in several ways and has considerable further transformative potential. For example, the expansion of digital platforms for short-time accommodation has put pressure on rental markets in many cities worldwide, a trend that may well continue when the tourism and hospitality industries recover from the COVID-19 crisis. It is also possible that the decline in short-term rentals during the pandemic turns out to be more durable than anticipated, freeing up rental housing for residents and hence making housing more affordable. Moreover, digitalisation is re-shaping the “high street” with attendant changes in commercial property demand as in-person shopping is replaced by on-line retail trade. This phenomenon adds to the downward pressure on demand for office space in city centres associated with more widespread teleworking. Where regulations allow it, flexibility to convert commercial property and office space for residential use would facilitate the reallocation of housing capital to evolving demand for different uses, potentially making housing more affordable. However, there is a risk that disaffection for city centres gives rise to housing segregation as the better-off move away. These trends would pose challenges for urban planning and the design of land-use and zoning regulations.
At the same time, digitalisation offers several options for technological change and innovation in construction and “smart” management of buildings, not least through artificial intelligence and the internet of things. Innovations in urban planning and management are already taking place and can improve the management of traffic, urban amenities and infrastructure, as well as the energy efficiency of buildings and cities at large. These developments can make cities more attractive. Digitalisation could indeed improve the matching of supply and demand for dwellings. The rise of digital showings of properties during the COVID-19 crisis is likely to remain at least in part permanent, allowing for a better filtering of costly physical visits and ultimately more and better matches. Yet another aspect of digitalisation is the scope for expanding fintech to offer a broader range of finance for investment in real estate. To the extent that these activities are regulated appropriately and financial stability is safeguarded, the entry of new participants in real estate markets can enhance competition, reduce borrowing costs and facilitate access to finance for those who currently struggle to do so. Investment in the energy efficiency of buildings can lower housing costs further as it reduces household spending on energy and improves their creditworthiness. Ultimately, more flexible housing finance could facilitate the adjustment of supply to changes in the demand for both residential and commercial property after the crisis, facilitating housing capital reallocation. A final consideration is related to population ageing and climate change, which will influencehousing policies in the years to come. Changes in demographics have highly asymmetric effects on housing markets. Falling demand in remote areas puts downward pressure on prices, at the same time as changing needs and preferences elsewhere require the retrofitting of buildings, a
reconfiguration of living spaces and investment in adapted urban infrastructure. The implications of population ageing for policy go beyond housing and include urban planning and regional development considerations. Climate change raises the risk of natural disasters and capital depletion in coastal areas exposed to rising sea levels, just to cite a few. It influences construction patterns and the use of materials in buildings, calling for innovation to improve energy efficiency in response to changing weather conditions. It also has a bearing on the design, maintenance and upgrade of urban infrastructure. The attendant economic (private and public) costs need to be taken into account and pose challenges for urban planning and regional development, as well as disaster risk management and insurance. Success on all these fronts will require appropriate policies, building on solid evidence, good practices and mutual learning. The OECD Housing Policy Toolkit can help. References: For further reading, see Brick by Brick: Building Better Housing Policies The Tortoise and the Hare: The Race Between Vaccine Rollout and New COVID
Variants by David Turner, Balázs Égert, Yvan Guillemette and Jarmila Botev, OECD Economics Department Variants of the virus causing COVID-19, notably the so-called ‘UK variant’, account for a large part of the resurgence of infections in many OECD countries since the latter part of 2020. Seasonal effects also drive fluctuations in virus incidence. More recently, vaccination has been very effective at curbing COVID-19 infections, substituting for lockdown policies at much lower costs to the economy. Those are among the main findings of a recent Economics Department Working Paper – The Tortoise and the Hare: The Race Between Vaccine Rollout and New COVID Variants – an update to a previous version of the study published last year. The study relates country-level daily reproduction numbers for OECD countries to several potential explanatory factors, including containment policies, public-health policies, seasonal conditions, the prevalence of variants, vaccination rates as well as proxies for spontaneous behavioural changes and natural immunity, all at once within the same framework. It also relates containment policies to the OECD weekly GDP tracker to study their effects on economic activity. Some new variants of the virus are estimated to be able to boost the effective reproduction number by up to 50%. Seasonal effects are also found to increase the effective reproduction number in fall/winter, in some countries by up to 25% relative to summer. The rapidity of these adverse shocks represent a major challenge to policy-makers because they can coincide and take full effect over a matter of a few months. The two effects together can potentially boost reproduction numbers by up to 90%. Thankfully, vaccination is found to powerfully reduce the
spread of the virus. The estimated effects can be stated in intervention-equivalent terms (see figure). Fully vaccinating… 7% of the population is equivalent to either complete school closure, requiring people not to leave the house with minimal exceptions, or banning all public gatherings; 15% of the population is equivalent to closing down all- but-essential workplaces; 20% of the population is equivalent to closing down all- but-essential workplaces as well as public transport; 50% of the population is equivalent to simultaneously applying all of the above restrictions as well as closing all international borders. And, of course, vaccination does not have the damaging effects on economic activity that lockdown policies have, rather it boosts activity by enabling lockdown policies to be eased. The study’s results are used to examine a few scenarios that differ in the presence of COVID variants and the speed of vaccination. In a baseline scenario without variants nor vaccines, stringent containment policies are needed to keep the reproduction number below 1, and the situation is nevertheless precarious in that many factors, including seasonal influences, have the potential to push the reproduction number above 1 and so lead to a surge in infections.
Another scenario assumes that the UK variant becomes predominant, leading to an increase in transmissibility of the virus by 35%. It shows that with only 13% of the population fully vaccinated (which corresponds to the OECD median in mid- May), the reproduction number remains above 1. Policy-makers then face difficult choices about which containment policies to tighten further. For instance, schools might need to remain closed full time, which would be just sufficient to keep the reproduction number below 1. A more optimistic scenario illustrates how quick vaccine rollout not only avoids the need to tighten containment polices despite the presence of the UK variant, but enables those in place to be progressively relaxed. For example, with 40% of the population fully vaccinated (which is close to the shares in the United States and United Kingdom at end-May), there is no need for any stay-at-home requirements or workplace closure and restrictions on gatherings can start to be relaxed, which has the added benefit of raising GDP by 4% relative to the baseline scenario. Together, the scenarios suggest that a rapid rollout of vaccinations is needed to compensate for the pressure from more infectious variants and avoid a cycle of stop-and-go mitigation policies. For those countries now going into summer, it is also important that policy-makers are not lulled into a false sense of security by the temporary decline in reproduction numbers due to seasonal factors, as in the summer of 2020. Failure to vaccinate a sufficient share of the population could then lead to a resurgence of the virus in the winter as seasonal factors reverse. Further reading Turner, D., B. Égert, Y. Guillemette and J. Botev (2021), “The Tortoise and the Hare: The Race Between Vaccine Rollout and New COVID Variants”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1672, Paris, OECD Publishing.
América Latina tras el COVID-19: cómo impulsar una recuperación tan deseada Jens Arnold, Aida Caldera-Sánchez, Paula Garda, Alberto González Pandiella, Alvaro S. Pereira. Departamento de Economía, OCDE América Latina es una de las regiones más golpeadas por el COVID-19 y tendrá una recuperación más lenta. La región ha concentrado cerca de 1 millón de muertes, o un tercio del total de muertes por COVID-19 en el mundo. En términos económicos también es la región que más se ha visto afectada en mundo con una caída del PIB de alrededor de 7% en 2020, comparado con 5% de media en la OCDE. Esto es debido a las características estructurales de la región: sistemas sanitarios y redes de seguridad social débiles, grandes sectores informales, fuerte dependencia del turismo, gran proporción del empleo en ocupaciones no compatibles con el trabajo a distancia, y un margen limitado para el apoyo fiscal. Hacia adelante la OCDE prevé que el crecimiento de seis grandes economías de la región, que abarcan alrededor del 85% del PIB de América Latina, sea del 4.9% en 2021, y un 2.8% en 2022 (Tabla). La recuperación de la actividad económica se ha frenado a inicios del 2021, frente a las nuevas medidas de contención en la mayoría de los países de la región, y se retomará a medida que avanzan los procesos de vacunación y mejora la situación sanitaria. Pero la recuperación será gradual, sin recuperar el terreno perdido en el PIB per-cápita ni siquiera en 2022 (Gráfico 1). Existe una alta incertidumbre en torno a la evolución de la
You can also read