Carbon Markets and Beyond: G-24 Discussion Paper Series The Limited Role of Prices and Taxes in Climate and Development Policy - UNCTAD

Page created by Mario Curry
 
CONTINUE READING
UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE ON TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    G-24 Discussion Paper Series

  Carbon Markets and Beyond:
The Limited Role of Prices and Taxes
 in Climate and Development Policy
              Frank Ackerman

              No. 53, December 2008

                     UNITED NATIONS
G-24 Discussion Paper Series

Research papers for the Intergovernmental Group of Twenty-Four
      on International Monetary Affairs and Development

                         UNITED NATIONS
                   New York and Geneva, December 2008
Note

Symbols of United Nations documents are composed
of capital letters combined with figures. Mention of
such a symbol indicates a reference to a United Nations
document.

		                          *
                     *		           *

The views expressed in this Series are those of the
authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of
the UNCTAD secretariat. The designations employed
and the presentation of the material do not imply the
expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of
the Secretariat of the United Nations concerning the
legal status of any country, territory, city or area, or
of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its
frontiers or boundaries.

		                          *
                     *		           *

Material in this publication may be freely quoted;
acknowl­edgement, however, is requested (including
reference to the document number). It would be
appreciated if a copy of the publication containing
the quotation were sent to the Publications Assistant,
Division on Globalization and Development Strategies,
UNCTAD, Palais des Nations, CH-1211 Geneva 10.

           UNITED NATIONS PUBLICATION

             UNCTAD/GDS/MDP/G24/2008/4

             Copyright © United Nations, 2008
                    All rights reserved
Carbon Markets and Beyond: The Limited Role of Prices and Taxes in Climate and Development Policy   iii

                                        Preface

        The G-24 Discussion Paper Series is a collection of research papers prepared
   under the UNCTAD Project of Technical Support to the Intergovernmental Group of
   Twenty-Four on International Monetary Affairs and Development (G-24). The G-24 was
   established in 1971 with a view to increasing the analytical capacity and the negotiating
   strength of the developing countries in discussions and negotiations in the international
   financial institutions. The G-24 is the only formal developing-country grouping within
   the IMF and the World Bank. Its meetings are open to all developing countries.

        The G-24 Project, which is administered by UNCTAD’s Division on Globalization
   and Development Strategies, aims at enhancing the understanding of policy makers in
   developing countries of the complex issues in the international monetary and financial
   system, and at raising awareness outside developing countries of the need to introduce
   a development dimension into the discussion of international financial and institutional
   reform.

        The research papers are discussed among experts and policy makers at the meetings
   of the G-24 Technical Group, and provide inputs to the meetings of the G-24 Ministers
   and Deputies in their preparations for negotiations and discussions in the framework of
   the IMF’s International Monetary and Financial Committee (formerly Interim Committee)
   and the Joint IMF/IBRD Development Committee, as well as in other forums.

        The Project of Technical Support to the G-24 receives generous financial support
   from the International Development Research Centre of Canada and contributions from
   the countries participating in the meetings of the G-24.
Carbon Markets and Beyond:
 The Limited Role of Prices and Taxes
  in Climate and Development Policy
              Frank Ackerman

         Stockholm Environment Institute
               and Tufts University

      G-24 Discussion Paper No. 53
                December 2008
Carbon Markets and Beyond: The Limited Role of Prices and Taxes in Climate and Development Policy               vii

                                                Abstract

 The climate policy debate has advanced from science to economics, with a growing focus on creating
 carbon markets and getting the prices right. This is necessary but far from sufficient for an effective
 and equitable response to the climate challenge. While market-oriented forces such as the IMF and
 the World Bank have focused almost exclusively on carbon markets, others, such as the Human
 Development Report and the Stern Review, have emphasized the need for complementary, non-market
 climate initiatives to promote energy conservation and above all, to create and adopt new low-carbon
 technologies.

 The equity implications of market-based policies depend on the price elasticity of demand. When
 demand is elastic (i.e. the elasticity is large in absolute value), as in the case of industrial energy use,
 price incentives are quite effective and distributional impacts are minimized. On the other hand, when
 demand is inelastic (i.e. the price elasticity is close to zero), as in the case of transportation fuel use,
 price incentives are less effective, worsening income inequality but doing little to change in energy
 use and carbon emissions. Thus non-market policy instruments are particularly important in sectors
 with inelastic demand for energy, such as transportation.

 Price incentives alone cannot be relied on to spark the creation of new low-carbon technologies.
 Many technologies display “learning curve” effects, starting out with high unit costs and becoming
 cheaper as they are used more widely. Wind power, which is now commercially viable, only became
 affordable as a result of decades of government subsidies and research support. The same will be
 true of other low-carbon energy technologies, which will be needed for a sustainable solution to the
 climate problem.

 Policy debate has focused on the need for a globally harmonized price for carbon. This is not required
 by economic theory; in an unequal world, the logic of market economics implies that richer countries
 should, in effect, have a higher price for carbon. It appears likely, nonetheless, that a consistent global
 price will eventually be adopted. This will make the benefit of reducing carbon emissions loom larger in
 lower-income countries. As a result, a wider range of carbon-reducing technologies will be profitable
 in developing countries, creating opportunities for “leapfrogging” beyond the technologies in use in
 high-income countries – thereby helping to launch a new, green path to development.
Carbon Markets and Beyond: The Limited Role of Prices and Taxes in Climate and Development Policy                                                         ix

                                                                 Table of contents

				                                                                                                                                                           Page

Preface		 . ............................................................................................................................................. iii
Abstract		 . .............................................................................................................................................vii
       I. Introduction......................................................................................................................................1
      II. The state of the debate......................................................................................................................2
     III. What do carbon prices accomplish?.................................................................................................4
     IV. Where do new technologies come from?.........................................................................................6
      V. Carbon markets and developing countries.......................................................................................7
    VI. Conclusion........................................................................................................................................8
Notes			         ....................................................................................................................................................9
References ....................................................................................................................................................9
Carbon Markets and Beyond:
                       The Limited Role of Prices and Taxes
                        in Climate and Development Policy
                                                Frank Ackerman*

I.    Introduction                                               technologies. A harmonized global price for carbon
                                                                 emissions is not essential as a matter of economic
                                                                 theory, but is nonetheless likely to be adopted. This
      The good news is that all major voices in the
                                                                 will make the opportunities and incentives for innova-
climate policy debate, including the Bretton Woods
                                                                 tion even greater in developing countries, creating the
institutions (the International Monetary Fund and the
                                                                 economic basis for leapfrogging beyond the technolo-
World Bank), are taking the problem seriously. Skep-
                                                                 gies adopted in high-income countries.
ticism about the science is no longer an option: the
world’s scientists have never been so unanimous, and
                                                                       More specifically, this paper argues that appro-
so ominous, in their projections of future perils.
                                                                 priate carbon prices and functioning carbon markets
                                                                 are necessary but not sufficient. It begins with a
     The bad news is that for too many participants in           review of recent publications on climate policy from
the debate, including the Bretton Woods institutions,            the IMF and the World Bank, contrasting them with
climate policy primarily consists of manipulating                other recent recommendations. It then examines the
markets and prices. If the only tool you have is                 expected impacts of a higher price of carbon, which
market liberalization, then every problem looks like             will be both inequitable and, in some respects, inef-
a question of getting the prices right. But setting a            fective if adopted alone. Turning to more positive
price for carbon emissions is only the beginning of              solutions, the nature of technology, particularly its
climate policy, not the end.                                     path dependence and learning curve effects, requires
                                                                 carefully designed public investments to launch a
     The message of this paper for developing                    climate-friendly development path. And the impacts
countries is that it is important to look beyond the             of carbon prices and markets on developing countries
technical debates over carbon markets. To address the            create both unique problems, such as proportionally
threat of climate change, it is necessary to charge a            greater economic burdens, and unique opportunities,
price for carbon emissions – and it is also necessary            in the proportionally greater incentive to innovate and
for governments to do much more, taking action to                establish a new leadership position in 21st century
support innovation and diffusion of new, low-carbon              technologies.

*     This work was carried out under the UNCTAD Project of Technical Assistance to the Intergovernmental Group of Twenty-Four
on International Monetary Affairs and Development with the aid of a grant from the International Development Research Centre of
Canada.
2                                        G-24 Discussion Paper Series, No. 53

II. The state of the debate                                 possible to achieve climate stabilization at moderate
                                                            total cost, considerable ingenuity and new policy
     The IMF simply assumes that climate policy             directions will be required; by themselves, price
consists of getting the (carbon) price right:               changes of pennies per gallon of gas are not enough
                                                            to achieve anything of importance.
     An effective mitigation policy must be based
     on setting a price path for the greenhouse gas              For the World Bank, the success of market based
     (GHG) emissions that drive climate change              policy is already obvious:
     (IMF, 2008, chapter 4: 2).
                                                                  The carbon market is the most visible result
      Although making an occasional nod to the im-                of early regulatory efforts to mitigate climate
portance of developments such as hybrid vehicles                  change … Its biggest success so far has been to
or energy efficiency,1 the IMF’s focus is almost en-              send market signals for the price of mitigating
                                                                  carbon emissions. This, in turn, has stimulated
tirely on market instruments. Adaptation to climate
                                                                  innovation and carbon abatement worldwide,
impacts will, the Fund notes, require large increases
                                                                  as motivated individuals, communities, com-
in infrastructure spending – but much more is said                panies and governments have cooperated
about market opportunities for hedging against                    to reduce emissions (Capoor and Ambrosi,
predictable short-term climate fluctuations, through              2008: 1).
weather derivatives and “cat” (catastrophic risk)
bonds. Mitigation, i.e. emissions reduction, is ad-         This success, according to the Bank, is based on
dressed primarily through detailed modelling of the         two major markets for carbon emissions, the EU’s
expected effects of carbon taxes or trading schemes.        Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) and the Clean
This modelling effort shows that the Organization           Development Mechanism (CDM) provisions of the
of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) will            Kyoto Protocol. They account for about US$ 50 bil-
be the biggest losers from a moderate carbon price,         lion and $13 billion, respectively, of the $64 billion
while global trading of emissions allowances will           in worldwide carbon market transactions in 2007
probably benefit China above all, due to that country’s     (Capoor and Ambrosi, 2008: 1). Both markets, as it
massive opportunities for comparatively low-cost            turns out, are works in progress: the ETS initially
emission reductions.                                        gave away virtually all emission allowances to ex-
                                                            isting emitters, rather than auctioning them – and
     The IMF analysis sets a target of a 60 per cent        set such a high cap that the price of allowances fell
reduction in carbon emissions, relative to 2002 levels,     embarrassingly close to zero. (Revisions to the ETS
by 2100, in order to stabilize CO2 concentrations           framework are addressing these design flaws for
at 550 parts per million (ppm). This is a signifi-          future years.) CDM has been beset by procedural
cant change from business-as-usual, although less           delays and complexity, imposing unduly burdensome
ambitious than the targets advocated by many govern-        start-up costs. A large majority of CDM funding to
ments and independent analysts; there is a growing          date has flowed to China, suggesting that CDM does
concern among climate scientists that 450 ppm or            not yet provide a truly global mechanism for financ-
even lower concentrations may be needed to avoid            ing emission reduction.
serious risks of catastrophic change. Yet in the IMF’s
view, the world can move slowly and still reach the              Meanwhile, research sponsored by the World
target comfortably:                                         Bank has demonstrated that there is substantial
                                                            variation in carbon emissions at the same level of
     Carbon-pricing policies … must establish a
                                                            development:
     time horizon for steadily rising carbon prices
     that people and businesses consider believable.              The ranking of countries by emissions intensity
     Increases in world carbon prices need not be                 [i.e., emissions/GDP ratio] … was not system-
     large – say a $0.01 initial increase in the price            atically related to GDP per capita … Emissions
     of a gallon of gasoline that rises by $0.02 every            per capita were positively but only moderately
     three years (IMF, 2008, chapter 4: 42).                      correlated with GDP per capita and showed no
                                                                  evidence of an eventual decline in emissions
Changes in carbon prices of this magnitude are                    per capita at higher per capita income (the
dwarfed by recent swings in the price of gasoline, a              Environmental Kuznets Curve phenomenon;
topic discussed in the next section. While it may be              Bacon and Bhattacharya, 2007: 2).
Carbon Markets and Beyond: The Limited Role of Prices and Taxes in Climate and Development Policy           3

       This finding should give rise to curiosity about         economy. They are not a sufficient condition.
the subtler economic and non-economic determinants              Governments have a critical role to play in
of emissions. It suggests that growth is not equally            setting regulatory standards and in supporting
good, or bad, for carbon emissions in all contexts.             low-carbon research, development and deploy-
                                                                ment (UNDP, 2007, Summary: 20, 21).
Therefore, merely speeding up or slowing down eco-
nomic growth may not be the most efficient policy;
                                                                 HDR calls for carbon markets to be accompa-
it is also important to understand what differentiates
                                                           nied by government incentives for renewable energy
high versus low emission countries at the same level
                                                           production, tightened standards for vehicle fuel ef-
of economic development. (The same question can
                                                           ficiency, expanded research on carbon capture and
be asked about states within the United States, which
                                                           storage technology, and increased technology transfer
differ in carbon emissions per capita by a ratio of
                                                           to developing countries.
more than six to one.)
                                                                One of the most detailed recent proposals is
      The World Bank’s overall approach to the issue
                                                           Nicholas Stern’s “global deal on climate change”
sounds multi-faceted, if somewhat abstract. A pro-
                                                           (Stern, 2008). Stern argues that climate stabilization
posed “strategic framework” (World Bank, 2008) for
                                                           requires cutting global emissions to half of the 1990
the Bank lists six “pillars,” of which three are focused
                                                           level by 2050, with continuing declines thereafter.
exclusively on market instruments,2 while three are
                                                           The 2050 target is so low – 2 tons per capita, not
more general or ambiguous.3 However, critics have
                                                           much above the level of emissions today in India,
claimed that reality falls short of the World Bank’s
                                                           and less than half of China’s current emissions – that
rhetoric. According to a report from the Institute for
                                                           there is virtually no room for any large country to be
Policy Studies (IPS), an NGO in Washington DC,
                                                           significantly above the average. Stern calls for bind-
the Bank’s $2 billion in carbon finance projects suf-
                                                           ing national reduction targets, to be adopted soon by
fer from an extreme lack of transparency, and have
                                                           developed countries and the fastest-growing middle-
resulted in very little confirmed reduction in carbon
                                                           income countries, and by all other countries by 2020.
emissions (Redman, 2008). Less than 10 per cent of
                                                           Stern envisions a carbon market, in the form of a
the funding has gone to renewable energy, while 75 per
                                                           global cap-and-trade system that allows developing
cent or more has gone to the coal, chemical, and iron
                                                           countries to sell emission rights, combined with ar-
and steel industries. In the sponge iron industry in
                                                           rangements for technology transfer, and large-scale
India, IPS reports that the incentives for carbon reduc-
                                                           government support for the development of new
tion have been generous enough to cause a perverse
                                                           technologies. In the words of his summary,
expansion of the relatively energy-inefficient industry,
in order to gain additional carbon reduction credits.           The world should aim for a liquid international
                                                                carbon market in order to allow for the most
      Other voices in the international debate have             effective, efficient and equitable emissions
recognized the greater urgency of the problem, and              reductions. In addition, non-price interventions
have set more detailed reduction targets, such as               are required to expand the global market for
80 per cent reduction in developed countries and                low-carbon technologies, support common
                                                                standards and promote cost-effective reduced
50 per cent worldwide by 2050, with even greater
                                                                deforestation (Stern, 2008: 3).
reductions required by 2100. Along with the urgency
of the issue, there has been a willingness to consider           In short, all major proposals for climate policy
a broader range of policy instruments. For the Human       include a substantial role for carbon markets and
Development Report (HDR):                                  prices, either in the form of taxes or cap-and-trade
                                                           systems. Yet while the Bretton Woods institutions,
     Setting ambitious targets for mitigation is
     an important first step. Translating targets          by their nature and by inclination, give primary
     into policies is politically more challenging.        emphasis to manipulation of prices and financing in
     The starting point: putting a price on carbon         carbon markets, others, such as Stern and the Human
     emissions … Carbon markets are a necessary            Development Report, see carbon markets as one part
     condition for the transition to a low-carbon          of a complex ensemble of policies.
4                                     G-24 Discussion Paper Series, No. 53

III. What do carbon prices accomplish?                    Table 1

                                                             Impacts of a 20 per cent increase in
     Discussion of carbon markets often highlights                     energy prices
the distinction between effects on prices and effects
on emissions. A cap-and-trade system causes a pre-                                     Price elasticity of demand
dictable, explicitly stated reduction in emissions, but                                 -1    -0.5    -0.2   -0.05
could lead to unpredictable or fluctuating prices. A
carbon tax does the opposite, causing a predictable,       Change in quantity
stable effect on prices, at the expense of an uncertain     (per cent)                -20     -10      -4      -1
reduction in emissions. Those who, like Stern, focus
on the need to achieve a specific level of emissions       Change in cost to
                                                            consumers (per cent)       -4      +8    +15     +19
reduction tend to prefer cap-and-trade markets; those
who worry more about economic disruption tend
to prefer the predictable prices achieved by carbon
taxes.

      This is, however, only one question about the       20 per cent increase in the price of energy at different
effects of carbon markets. A related question has         elasticities, as shown in table 1.
received too little attention: when carbon prices are
increased, by a tax or a trading system, how large is            At an elasticity of -1, the 20 per cent increase in
the (intended) effect on emissions, and how large is      price causes a 20 per cent drop in demand. Consum-
the (unintended) effect on income distribution?           ers purchase 80 per cent as much energy as before,
                                                          at 120 per cent of the former price per unit, so the
      Increased energy costs to consumers fall dispro-    total cost to consumers amounts to 96 per cent of
portionately on low-income groups; energy costs are       the former total. At this elasticity, most of the effect
a larger fraction of income for the poor. As incomes      is felt in the change in the quantity of energy (and
rise, total spending on energy also rises, but more       therefore emissions), while total consumer spending
slowly; thus the fraction of income spent on energy       is little affected.
decreases. The one major exception to this pattern
occurs in countries where some people cannot afford             In contrast, at an elasticity of -0.05, a 20 per cent
fossil fuels, and instead rely on traditional biomass     increase in price causes only a 1 per cent change in
fuels. Among the population that buys and depends         quantity. Consumers buy 99 per cent as much energy
on commercial fuels, energy price increases are           as before, at 120 per cent of the former price per unit,
regressive, taking proportionately more from lower-       for a total expenditure of 119 per cent of the earlier
income households.                                        cost. At this elasticity, there is almost no effect on
                                                          the quantity of energy and emissions, but a large ef-
      To summarize in advance the point of this sec-      fect on the total cost to consumers. The other values
tion, the effect of a carbon price increase depends       shown in the table have intermediate results between
on the price elasticity of demand for energy. A larger    these two extremes. Judged as a strategy to reduce
elasticity means that a price increase has more effect    energy consumption and the resulting emissions
on emissions and less effect on income distribution; a    with minimal burdens on consumers, energy price
smaller elasticity means that the same price increase     increases seem quite effective at an elasticity of -1,
has less effect on emissions, but does more to increase   but decidedly inferior at an elasticity of -0.05.
inequality.4 Since price elasticities are fairly small
for energy in general, and extraordinarily small for            What elasticity values are applicable in reality?
petroleum products in the short run, price incentives     Separate estimates have been developed for major
are a blunt and painful instrument for achieving lower    energy markets including industrial energy use,
emissions.                                                electricity, and transportation. The largest elasticities
                                                          are found in industry. Estimates from three research
     The price elasticity of demand is, by definition,    groups for 15 countries found the price elasticity for
the percentage change in demand that is caused by a       industrial energy demand to be between -0.77 and
one per cent change in price. Consider the effects of a   -0.88. The estimates for India and Brazil were not
Carbon Markets and Beyond: The Limited Role of Prices and Taxes in Climate and Development Policy           5

significantly different from those for the developed         automobile-dependent environment – including the
countries included in the studies (Roy et al., 2006).        great majority in the United States, large fractions
Industrial energy use, in other words, provides fertile      of many OECD countries, and increasing numbers
ground for the application of price incentives for           in fast-growing, middle-income countries – has little
emission reduction. Indeed, industry lowered its en-         control over the amount of driving required to go to
ergy use much farther and faster than any other sector       work, school, stores, and other essential services. So
in response to the oil price shocks of the 1970s.            in the short run, purchases of gasoline will be quite
                                                             insensitive to price.
      Household demand for electricity is much less
elastic than industrial energy use. Recent estimates               In the long run, as cars are replaced, high oil
for the United States have found a short-run price           prices stimulate the sale of smaller and more fuel-
elasticity of -0.20, and a long-run price elasticity         efficient vehicles, as began to happen in the United
of -0.32, broadly consistent with earlier research           States during the price spike of 2007–2008. This
(Bernstein and Griffin, 2006).5                              will eventually affect oil consumption, as the fleet of
                                                             cars on the road slowly becomes more fuel-efficient,
      This finding of a relatively small elasticity for      implying that the price elasticity will be greater in
electricity does not appear to be unique to the United       the long run than in the short run.
States; the estimated long-run elasticity for Taiwan
is -0.16, described as “reasonably close” to the es-         A comparative international analysis estimated oil
timates in “numerous other studies” (Holtedahl and           price elasticities for many countries for 1979–2000
Joutz, 2004: 216).                                           (Cooper, 2003). For the United States, it found a
                                                             short-run elasticity of -0.06 and a long-run elastic-
      In both industrial energy use and electricity gen-     ity of -0.46, broadly consistent with other published
eration, there are alternative fuels that yield the same     estimates. For the G7 group of industrial countries,
result with differing carbon emissions. An increased         short-run elasticities ranged from -0.024 to -0.071,
carbon price would cause a noticeable reduction in           and long-run elasticities from -0.18 to -0.57. Using
industrial energy demand (less so in household elec-         these estimates for the United States, a doubling of
tricity), and also a shift toward lower-carbon fuels         oil prices causes a 4 per cent reduction in demand
– such as replacing coal with natural gas.                   in the short run, and a 27 per cent reduction in the
                                                             long run.
       The picture is different in the transportation sec-
tor, where there is essentially only one fuel choice:              A study focused specifically on the United
almost all transportation uses petroleum fuels. (On          States gasoline consumption found that the short-run
a global basis, the available supply of biofuels is too      price elasticity in 2001–2006 was -0.034 to -0.077,
small to make a noticeable dent in the demand for            lower than estimates for earlier periods (Hughes
oil.) In the wake of the oil crises of the 1970s, most       et al., 2006). The data did not permit estimation of
countries and industries have cut back on oil use            a long-run elasticity. The authors speculated that
wherever possible; oil-fired electricity generation,         increasing suburbanization and decreased avail-
once relatively widespread, is now common only in            ability of mass transit have made it more difficult
OPEC countries. Today a majority of crude oil is used        for most households to reduce their automobile use
for transportation, and a portion of the remainder is        today. They concluded that changes in vehicle fuel
dedicated to non-fuel uses such as petrochemicals,           efficiency would be the key to future changes in the
where there are no close substitutes. The connection         United States gasoline consumption.
between petroleum and transportation is projected
to grow even tighter; an estimated two-thirds of                  Short-run price elasticities for gasoline and
the growth in oil demand through 2030 will be for            other transport fuels are close to zero; this is why the
transportation.6 Thus the oil/transport market is            2007–2008 surge in the price of oil did not cause an
almost disjoint from the market for other fuels and          immediate collapse in demand. (Many months later, a
end uses.                                                    global economic downturn led to lower incomes, oil
                                                             purchases and prices; that downturn was not solely,
     The lack of alternatives to oil means that in the       or even primarily, caused by the high price of oil.)
short run, price elasticity is close to zero for many        An increase in oil prices is primarily a burden on
consumers. A household that lives in a completely            consumers, and causes only a modest change in short-
6                                      G-24 Discussion Paper Series, No. 53

run oil demand; its longer-term, beneficial effect is       of “learning curves” or “experience curves.” As a
to accelerate the transition to a more fuel-efficient       result, investment in start-up costs can determine
vehicle fleet.                                              which technologies are cost-effective in the future.
                                                            Technological change is path-dependent: the current
     Any plausible carbon policy would, in the near         suite of available choices depends on past policies
term, raise fossil fuel prices by less than the oil price   and actions, just as the available technological op-
increases of 2007–2008. While such a policy might           tions in the future will depend on our policies and
have an important effect on industrial energy use, it       actions today.
would presumably have less effect on transportation
than the recent surge in oil prices. Something more               The learning curve phenomenon is particularly
needs to be done, to reduce emissions on the scale          important when there is a benefit to standardization;
and timetable projected by Stern and others.                in such cases, an early market leader can become
                                                            “locked in,” whether or not it represents the ideal
                                                            technology (as occurred with the Windows operating
                                                            system and other Microsoft software for computers).8
IV. Where do new technologies come                          The current style of industrialization has been referred
    from?                                                   to as “carbon lock-in,” meaning that carbon-intensive
                                                            technologies gained an early lead at a time when
      Market-based incentives such as a carbon price        fossil fuels were cheap and concern about global
are much better at some objectives than others. Price       warming was not yet on the horizon (Unruh and
signals lead to efficient choices among existing            Carrillo-Hermosilla, 2006). Today, the economic ben-
alternatives; this is the great success of the market       efits of standardization and the low costs of imitating
economy. On the other hand, as noted in the previous        and replicating existing technology keep the world
section, carbon prices will generally make the dis-         locked into that same undesirable path.
tribution of income and resources more unequal. In
addition, carbon prices alone will not create the new             Research on learning curves has often found that
technologies needed to solve the climate crisis.            as the cumulative total production of a new product
                                                            increases, the unit cost declines at a predictable rate.
       The pure theory of competitive markets has           This is measured by the “progress ratio,” defined as
little to say about technical change. If, as in the text-   the change in unit cost per doubling of cumulative
book model, all commodities are bought and sold by          production. In a historic example from the early twen-
small, competitive firms, and all resources are used        tieth century, Ford’s Model T had a progress ratio of
to produce the maximum possible satisfaction for            85 per cent throughout its long production run: every
consumers, who has the incentive and the ability to         time the cumulative total production of Model Ts
invest in research? Yet new technologies do emerge,         doubled, the price per car dropped by an average of
and productivity grows over time. Conventional              15 per cent (Abernathy and Wayne, 1974).
economic models have often addressed this question
with the ad hoc assumption of a predictable, constant             New energy technologies often display strong
rate of technical change, unrelated to investment           learning-curve effects. Research on wind power has
choices or policy decisions. In climate modelling, this     found progress ratios as low as 80 per cent (i.e., cost
takes the form of an “autonomous energy efficiency          reductions as great as 20 per cent from doubling of
improvement” (AEEI) parameter.7 That assumption             production) (Junginger et al., 2005). While wind
has the unfortunate consequence of biasing results          power is now competitive in the marketplace under
toward waiting for new technology to appear: abate-         many conditions, this success was made possible by
ment will always be cheaper if it is done later, after      decades of US and European government investment
better technologies have “autonomously” made their          in research and development. Brazilian ethanol pro-
appearance.                                                 duction, another industry launched by government
                                                            policy, reportedly had a progress ratio of 71 per cent
      In reality, new technologies do not drop from the     from 1985 through 2002 (Goldemberg et al., 2004).
sky, independent of investments and public policies.
New technologies are created by conscious effort;                 With technological progress at these rates, it
they often start out expensive and become cheaper           is often the case that private enterprises only find it
over time, a process that is often described in terms       profitable to buy a new product after someone else
Carbon Markets and Beyond: The Limited Role of Prices and Taxes in Climate and Development Policy         7

has been buying it and bringing down the price for          Instead, the United States Government moved rapidly
ten or twenty years. Hence the role for public sec-         and succeeded in launching a suite of technologies
tor involvement: governments can and must choose            that now dominate private markets and shape mod-
the new technologies to support, especially when            ern life.
– as with climate policy – there is a clear need for
change. The market alone is not enough; without
public investment, no credible carbon price would
do an effective job of launching the crucial new re-        V.	Carbon markets and developing
newable and low-carbon technologies. On the other              countries
hand, with adequate public support, vast changes are
possible. A plausible model of energy development,                The discussion of learning curves, path depend-
incorporating learning curves, projects that solar          ence, and technological lock-in applies equally to
photovoltaics, now one of the most expensive ways           climate policy and technologies in developed and
to generate electricity, could be one of the cheapest       developing countries. However, the current discourse
options by 2100 (Rao et al., 2006).                         on carbon markets and climate policies has unique
                                                            implications for developing countries, posing obsta-
      This is not a unique characteristic of new energy     cles and creating opportunities that are not present in
technologies; rather, it is the norm in technological       higher-income countries.
change. The United States Government has funded
the development of numerous innovative weapon sys-                It has become commonplace to insist on the
tems, technologies that would not have automatically        need for a globally harmonized price of carbon. Price
appeared without government support. Most of them,          harmonization is thought to ensure efficiency in the
fortunately, have never been used. Along the way,           worldwide distribution of abatement effort: with
many other technologies have been developed, with           appropriate market institutions, investment in emis-
more peaceful applications to civilian life. In the words   sions reduction will flow to the countries (presumably
of a history of microelectronics (Morton, 1999),            developing countries) where the costs of reduction are
                                                            lowest. Fears about the effects of unharmonized car-
     The U.S. military initially purchased nearly           bon charges have slowed climate policy initiatives in
     the total production of transistors in the early
                                                            some high-income countries, and have prompted an
     1950’s, using them to make the new generation
     of communications, radar and improved avion-           unproductive and potentially protectionist discussion
     ics systems, command and control systems, as           of border tariff adjustments. This notion is mistaken
     well as for missiles and jet fighters…                 both in fact and in theory. Empirically, only a handful
                                                            of industries are so carbon-intensive that a difference
     The U.S. government acted as the major market
                                                            in carbon charges could lead them to move from one
     for integrated circuits in the early years… In
     1962 … the U.S. government, with extensive             country to another – and many of them have already
     research interests in space, defense, and other        moved to middle- and low-income countries.
     areas, purchased virtually 100 per cent of all
     integrated circuits manufactured in the United               In theory, remarkably enough, marginal abate-
     States.                                                ment costs do not have to be equal in every country in
                                                            order to achieve economic efficiency. Theorists who
      As with wind power, a few decades of generous         reach this conclusion generally rely on the unexam-
public support were sufficient to launch the micro-         ined assumption that the world income distribution
electronics industry as a success in the marketplace.       is equitable – or equivalently, that increases in per
And the list goes on and on: computers got their            capita consumption are equally urgent everywhere
start with military purchases; the Internet grew out        (Sheeran, 2006; Chichilnisky and Heal, 1994). In the
of ARPANET, a Defense Department-sponsored                  absence of that implausible assumption, it is more
network set up in the 1960s to connect military re-         efficient to carry out higher-cost abatement efforts in
searchers around the country.                               richer countries. That is, in an inequitable world, ef-
                                                            ficiency can be improved by imposing higher carbon
      None of these technologies appeared auto-             prices in richer countries.
matically; if the world had waited for autonomous
technical change or relied on getting the prices                 It seems unlikely, however, that the enthusiasm
right, microelectronics might never have happened.          for a consistent worldwide carbon price will be
8                                      G-24 Discussion Paper Series, No. 53

dampened by these considerations. Climate analyses         the Chinese auto industry has shown that there is little
from the Bretton Woods institutions (see section II),      tendency toward leapfrogging beyond international
among many others, place a priority on establish-          standards; in fact, the United States auto companies,
ing a single global carbon market. Thus developing         left to themselves, have often allowed their Chinese
countries are likely to face a global carbon price,        plants to lag behind their home-country technologies
while their local prices for labour, land and other        (Gallagher, 2006). Stronger Chinese government
inputs remain far below the levels of higher-income        policies and initiatives would be required to achieve
countries. Carbon emissions, or the credits for avoid-     the potential for newer, cleaner vehicle technologies.
ing them, will account for a much larger fraction of       Even for a developing country with the extensive
the value of production in lower-income countries.         resources and potential of China, there is much that
The potential dissonance between expensive carbon          needs to be done to reach this new technological
and cheaper local inputs creates both an obstacle and      frontier.
an opportunity.
                                                                 To realize the opportunity created by a global
      The obstacle is that development may be              carbon price in low-cost economies, there will be a
distorted in the direction of activities that yield        need for research and development in appropriate,
marketable carbon reductions. Even undesirable             cutting-edge technologies for carbon reduction. As
activities may be promoted, such as the expansion of       with many of the new energy technologies that will
the sponge iron industry in India in order to generate     be needed around the world, decades of public invest-
carbon credits (as cited in section II). Safeguards        ment may be required before the developing-country
are needed to prevent “carbon-allowance-seeking”           technologies are successful in the marketplace. This
investments along these lines; in any global carbon        is one more reason why carbon prices are necessary,
market, it will be essential to verify that emissions      but not sufficient, for an equitable solution to the
are not newly created in order to profit by reducing       climate crisis.
them. The temptation to seek such bogus allowances,
unfortunately, is a natural consequence of a global
carbon price in a low-cost local economy.
                                                           VI.	Conclusion
      The positive side of the same pattern of prices
is that much deeper reductions in carbon emissions               Setting a price for carbon emissions is a valuable
will be economical in developing countries. In the         beginning, but not the end, of climate policy. Much
simplest terms, saving a ton of carbon is “worth”          more needs to be done to complement the new mar-
more hours of labour at a lower wage rate. So there        kets in carbon emissions, and to ensure an effective
may be a category of carbon-saving investments and         policy response to the threat of climate change.
technologies that are profitable only in developing
countries, where the tradeoff between carbon and                 Reliance on carbon price increases alone would
other inputs is more favourable to emission reduc-         be both ineffective and inequitable. For end uses with
tion. With appropriate public initiatives and financing    small price elasticities, such as residential electricity
for these technologies, developing countries could         and, above all, transportation, a higher fuel price leads
“leapfrog” beyond the patterns of energy use in            primarily to a less equal distribution of resources, not
higher-income countries, establishing a new frontier       to a reduction in carbon emissions. Other policies
for carbon reduction.                                      are needed to offset the equity impacts of higher fuel
                                                           costs, and to launch the new, low-carbon energy tech-
      The potential for leapfrogging beyond the cur-       nologies of the future. Because technology choice is
rent technology frontier has been much discussed,          path-dependent, with strong learning curve effects,
but is difficult to achieve. The classic example is in     public sector initiatives are essential to ensure that the
telephones, where developing countries can now skip        global economy follows a climate-friendly path.
the expensive development of universal land lines,
and go directly to cell phones. This is not, however, an        The next international agreement on climate
example of jumping to an entirely new technology; it       policy is likely to move toward a globally harmonized
became possible only after cell phones were invented       carbon price. This creates a unique opportunity for
and commercialized in developed countries (Unruh           developing countries, by making it cost-effective
and Carillo-Hermosilla, 2006). Likewise, research on       to spend more local resources on carbon reduction
Carbon Markets and Beyond: The Limited Role of Prices and Taxes in Climate and Development Policy                            9

in lower-cost economies. A global carbon price                       Chichilnisky G and Heal G (1994). Who Should Abate Carbon
will make it profitable for developing countries                           Emissions? An International Perspective. Economic Let-
                                                                           ters 44: 443–449.
to “leapfrog” beyond the technologies in place in                    Cooper JCB (2003). Price elasticity of demand for crude oil:
higher-income countries.                                                   estimates for 23 countries. OPEC Review 27(1): 1–8.
                                                                     David P (1985). Clio and the Economics of QWERTY. American
                                                                           Economic Review 75: 332–337.
                                                                     EIA (2007). International Energy Outlook. Energy Information
Notes                                                                      Administration, United States Department of Energy
                                                                           (DOE), Washington, DC.
                                                                     Gallagher KS (2006). Limits to leapfrogging in energy tech-
 1    E.g., “Energy-efficiency improvements are unlikely to                nologies? Evidence from the Chinese automobile industry.
      eliminate the need for carbon prices, but they would reduce          Energy Policy 34: 383–394.
      their level” (IMF, 2008, chapter 4: 40).                       Goldemberg J, Coelho ST, Nastari PM and Lucon O (2004).
 2    “Consolidating Efforts to Mobilize and Deliver Finance”,             Ethanol learning curve – the Brazilian experience. Biomass
      “Expanding the Bank’s Role in Developing New Mar-                    and Bioenergy 26: 301–304.
      kets” and “Tapping Private Sector Resources for Climate        Holtedahl P and Joutz FL (2004). Residential electricity demand
      Friendly Development”.                                               in Taiwan. Energy Economics 26: 201–224.
 3    “Scaling Up Operational Approaches to Integrating              Hughes JE, Knittel CR and Sperling D (2006). Evidence of a Shift
      Adaptation and Mitigation in Development Strategies”,                in the Short-Run Price Elasticity of Gasoline Demand.
      “Clarifying the Bank’s Role in Accelerating Technology               NBER Working Paper 12530.
      Development and Deployment” and “Stepping Up Policy            IMF (2008). World Economic Outlook: Housing and the Business
      Research, Knowledge Management and Capacity Build-                   Cycle. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
      ing”.                                                          Junginger M, Faaij A and Turkenburg WC (2005). Global experi-
 4    Price elasticities are, strictly speaking, negative numbers.         ence curves for wind farms. Energy Policy 33: 133–150.
      This discussion follows the common convention of refer-        Morton D (1999). The Electrical Century: What Difference Did
      ring to numbers farther from zero (or larger in absolute             Semiconductors and Microelectronics Make? Proceedings
      value) as “larger” elasticities; thus an elasticity of -1 is         of the IEEE 87(6): 1049–1052.
      “larger” than an elasticity of -0.5.                           OPEC (2007). World Oil Outlook 2007. Organization of the
 5    See also Reiss and White (2005) estimating a long-run                Petroleum Exporting Countries, Vienna, Austria.
      price elasticity for California households of -0.39, and       Rao S, Keppo I and Riahi K (2006). Importance of Technological
      commenting that high-quality past studies have generally             Change and Spillovers in Long-Term Climate Policy. En-
      yielded estimates between -0.15 and -0.35.                           ergy Journal, Special Issue on Endogenous Technological
 6    United States EIA (2007) says transportation will account            Change and the Economics of Atmospheric Stabilisation:
      for two-thirds of the growth in world oil use through 2030;          123–139.
      OPEC (2007) data implies that transport will absorb 62 per     Redman J (2008). World Bank: Climate Profiteer. Institute for
      cent of the growth in oil use.                                       Policy Studies, Washington, DC. 10 April.
 7    The model used by the IMF, in the analysis discussed in        Reiss PC and White MB (2005). Household Electricity Demand,
      section II above, assumes an AEEI of 0.5 per cent per year           Revisited, Review of Economic Studies 72: 853–883.
      (IMF, 2008, chapter 4: 46).                                    Roy J, Sanstad AH, Sathaye JA and Khaddaria R (2006). Sub-
 8    The classic references on technological lock-in include              stitution and price elasticity estimates using inter-country
      Paul David (1985) and Brian Arthur (1994).                           pooled data in a translog cost model. Energy Economics
                                                                           28: 706–719.
                                                                     Sheeran KA (2006). Who Should Abate Carbon Emissions?
                                                                           A Note. Environmental and Resource Economics 35:
References                                                                 89–98.
                                                                     Stern N (2008). Key Elements of a Global Deal on Climate
                                                                           Change. London School of Economics, London.
Abernathy WJ and Wayne K (1974). Limits of the Learning              UNDP (2007). Human Development Report 2007/2008. Fight-
      Curve. Harvard Business Review 52(4): 109–119.                       ing climate change: Human solidarity in a divided world.
Arthur B (1994). Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the             United Nations Development Programme, New York.
      Economy. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, MI.          Unruh GC and Carrillo-Hermosilla J (2006). Globalizing carbon
Bacon RW and Bhattacharya S (2007). Growth and CO2 Emis-                   lock-in. Energy Policy 34: 1185–1197.
      sions: How Do Different Countries Fare? World Bank En-         World Bank (2008). Towards a Strategic Framework on Climate
      vironment Department, World Bank, Washington, DC.                    Change and Development for the World Bank Group –
Bernstein MA and Griffin J (2006). Regional Differences in the             Concept and Issues Paper (Consultation Draft, March
      Price-Elasticity of Demand for Energy, RAND Corpora-                 2008). World Bank, Washington, DC.
      tion, Santa Monica, CA.
Capoor K and Ambrosi P (2008). State and Trends of the Carbon
      Market 2008. World Bank, Washington, DC.
10                                   G-24 Discussion Paper Series, No. 53

                                     G-24 Discussion Paper Series*
Research papers for the Intergovernmental Group of Twenty-Four on International Monetary Affairs and Development

No. 52    November 2008      C.P. Chandrasekhar       Global Liquidity and Financial Flows to Developing
                                                      Countries: New Trends in Emerging Markets and their
                                                      Implications
No. 51    September 2008     Ugo Panizza	             The External Debt Contentious Six Years after the
                                                      Monterrey Consensus
No. 50 July 2008             Stephany Griffith-Jones Enhancing the Role of Regional Development Banks
			                          with David Griffith-Jones
			                          and Dagmar Hertova
No. 49 December 2007         David Woodward           IMF Voting Reform: Need, Opportunity and Options
No. 48 November 2007         Sam LAIRD                Aid for Trade: Cool Aid or Kool-Aid
No. 47 October 2007          Jan Kregel	              IMF Contingency Financing for Middle-Income Countries
                                                      with Access to Private Capital Markets: An Assessment of
                                                      the Proposal to Create a Reserve Augmentation Line
No. 46    September 2007     José María Fanelli	      Regional Arrangements to Support Growth and Macro-
                                                      Policy Coordination in MERCOSUR
No. 45    April 2007         Sheila Page              The Potential Impact of the Aid for Trade Initiative
No. 44    March 2007         Injoo Sohn	              East Asia’s Counterweight Strategy: Asian Financial
                                                      Cooperation and Evolving International Monetary Order
No. 43 February 2007         Devesh Kapur and         Beyond the IMF
			                          Richard Webb
No. 42 November 2006         Mushtaq H. Khan          Governance and Anti-Corruption Reforms in Developing
                                                      Countries: Policies, Evidence and Ways Forward
No. 41 October 2006          Fernando Lorenzo         IMF Policies for Financial Crises Prevention in
			                          and Nelson Noya          Emerging Markets
No. 40 May 2006              Lucio Simpson            The Role of the IMF in Debt Restructurings: Lending Into
                                                      Arrears, Moral Hazard and Sustainability Concerns
No. 39 February 2006         Ricardo Gottschalk       East Asia’s Growing Demand for Primary Commodities
			                          and Daniela Prates       – Macroeconomic Challenges for Latin America
No. 38 November 2005         Yilmaz Akyüz             Reforming the IMF: Back to the Drawing Board
No. 37 April 2005            Colin I. Bradford, Jr.   Prioritizing Economic Growth: Enhancing
                                                      Macro­economic Policy Choice
No. 36    March 2005         Jomo K.S.                Malaysia’s September 1998 Controls: Background, Context,
                                                      Impacts, Comparisons, Implications, Lessons
No. 35    January 2005       Omotunde E.G. Johnson Country Ownership of Reform Programmes and the
                                                      Implications for Conditionality
No. 34   January 2005        Randall Dodd and         Up From Sin: A Portfolio Approach to Financial
       		                    Shari Spiegel            Salvation
No. 33   November 2004       Ilene Grabel             Trip Wires and Speed Bumps: Managing Financial
                                                      Risks and Reducing the Potential for Financial Crises in
                                                      Developing Economies
No. 32    October 2004       Jan Kregel               External Financing for Development and International
                                                      Financial Instability
No. 31 October 2004          Tim KESSLER and          Assessing the Risks in the Private Provision of
			                          Nancy Alexander          Essential Services
No. 30 June 2004             Andrew CORNFORD          Enron and Internationally Agreed Principles for Corpo-
                                                      rate Governance and the Financial Sector
No. 29    April 2004         Devesh Kapur             Remittances: The New Development Mantra?
No. 28    April 2004         Sanjaya Lall             Reinventing Industrial Strategy: The Role of Govern-
                                                      ment Policy in Building Industrial Competitiveness
Carbon Markets and Beyond: The Limited Role of Prices and Taxes in Climate and Development Policy                11

No. 27 March 2004               Gerald Epstein,                 Capital Management Techniques in Developing
			                             Ilene Grabel                    Countries: An Assessment of Experiences from the
			                             and Jomo, K.S.                  1990s and Lessons for the Future
No. 26 March 2004               Claudio M. Loser	               External Debt Sustainability: Guidelines for Low- and
                                                                Middle-income Countries
No. 25      January 2004        Irfan ul Haque                  Commodities under Neoliberalism: The Case of Cocoa
No. 24      December 2003       Aziz Ali MOHAMMED               Burden Sharing at the IMF
No. 23      November 2003       Mari Pangestu                   The Indonesian Bank Crisis and Restructuring: Lessons and
                                                                Implications for other Developing Countries
No. 22      August 2003         Ariel Buira	                    An Analysis of IMF Conditionality
No. 21      April 2003          Jim Levinsohn	                  The World Bank’s Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper Ap-
                                                                proach: Good Marketing or Good Policy?
No. 20      February 2003       Devesh KAPUR                    Do As I Say Not As I Do: A Critique of G-7 Proposals
                                                                on Reforming the Multilateral Development Banks
No. 19		    December 2002       Ravi Kanbur                     International Financial Institutions and International
                                                                Public Goods: Operational Implications for the World
                                                                Bank
No. 18      September 2002      Ajit SINGH                      Competition and Competition Policy in Emerging
                                                                Markets: International and Developmental Dimensions
No. 17 April 2002               F. López-de-Silanes             The Politics of Legal Reform
No. 16 January 2002             Gerardo Esquivel and            The Impact of G-3 Exchange Rate Volatility on
			                             Felipe Larraín B.               Developing Countries
No. 15 December 2001            Peter Evans and                 Organizational Reform and the Expansion
			                             Martha Finnemore                of the South’s Voice at the Fund
No. 14 September 2001           Charles Wyplosz                 How Risky is Financial Liberalization in the
                                                                Developing Countries?
No. 13 July 2001                José Antonio Ocampo             Recasting the International Financial Agenda
No. 12 July 2001                Yung Chul Park and              Reform of the International Financial System and
			                             Yunjong Wang	                   Institutions in Light of the Asian Financial Crisis
No. 11 April 2001               Aziz Ali Mohammed	              The Future Role of the International Monetary Fund
No. 10 March 2001               JOMO K.S.                       Growth After the Asian Crisis: What Remains of the East
                                                                Asian Model?
No. 9 February 2001             Gordon H. Hanson                Should Countries Promote Foreign Direct Investment?
No. 8 January 2001              Ilan Goldfajn and               Can Flexible Exchange Rates Still “Work” in
			                             Gino Olivares                   Financially Open Economies?
No. 7 December 2000             Andrew CORNFORD                 Commentary on the Financial Stability Forum’s Report of
                                                                the Working Group on Capital Flows
No. 6 August 2000               Devesh KAPUR and                Governance-related Conditionalities of the International
			                             Richard WEBB                    Financial Institutions
No. 5 June 2000                 Andrés Velasco                  Exchange-rate Policies for Developing Countries: What
                                                                Have We Learned? What Do We Still Not Know?
No. 4       June 2000           Katharina PISTOR                The Standardization of Law and Its Effect on Developing
                                                                Economies
No. 3       May 2000            Andrew CORNFORD                 The Basle Committee’s Proposals for Revised Capital
                                                                Standards: Rationale, Design and Possible Incidence
No. 2       May 2000            T. Ademola OYEJIDE              Interests and Options of Developing and Least-developed
                                                                Countries in a New Round of Multilateral Trade Negotia-
                                                                tions
No. 1       March 2000          Arvind PANAGARIYA               The Millennium Round and Developing Countries:
                                                                Negotiating Strategies and Areas of Benefits

*     G-24 Discussion Paper Series are available on the website at: www.unctad.org. Copies of G-24 Discussion Paper Series
may be obtained from the Publications Assistant, Macroeconomic and Development Policies Branch, Division on Globalization and
Development Strategies, United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), Palais des Nations, CH-1211 Geneva 10,
Switzerland; Fax (+41-22) 917.0274.
You can also read