13 New Directions in Veto Bargaining: Message Legislation, Virtue Signaling, and Electoral Accountability
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
13 New Directions in Veto Bargaining: Message Legislation, Virtue Signaling, and Electoral Accountability Charles Cameron and Nathan Gibson Introduction much of the action, the sound and fury of daily politics, is quite mysterious and clearly In the years since the creation of separation- beyond the ambit of those simple frame- of-powers (SOP) models – aimed first at works. Examples include repeated fruitless courts,1 then at Congress,2 and finally at attempts to pass doomed bills, hopeless presidents3 – much has changed though vetoes, futile filibusters, lopsided cloture much remains the same. Needless to say, the votes, obviously doomed attempts at bicam- constitutionally mandated architecture of the eral legislating, hostage-taking via govern- American government hasn’t changed at all. ment shut-downs, manifestly impossible This architecture separates the three branches impeachment attempts, ostentatiously illegal and forces them to interact through a struc- executive orders and more. tured bargaining process of proposals and In this chapter we focus on the mysteri- vetoes. On the other hand, the coalition struc- ous, and we offer some suggestions on how ture of the political parties, the participants in to make the murky more transparent. politician selection and the media environ- We begin with a brief review of the clas- ment have all changed, arguably dramati- sic separation-of-powers (SOP) models, cally.4 The causal linkages remain disputed focusing on the veto bargaining version but but the net effects are striking and manifest noting easy extensions to the filibuster. We to all: elite partisan polarization, political emphasize the use of incomplete information rancor, congressional stasis, aggressive presi- models to study not just outcomes but pro- dential unilateralism, and puissant courts.5 In cess. We are terse because handy and more the new American politics, policy outcomes elaborate reviews are available elsewhere.6 are generally quite understandable using the Then, we note the rise of several puzzling classic SOP models, or so we assert. But empirical phenomena. These include bizarre BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 224 30/01/20 9:37 AM
New Directions in Veto Bargaining 225 vote margins on vetoed bills and during over- recruitment, fund-raising, participation in pri- ride attempts; similarly weird vote margins maries, campaigning and turnout.10 Without for filibustered bills and during cloture votes; the enthusiastic support of these individuals, and the useless re-passage, many times, of a member of Congress or president is in seri- virtually the same doomed legislation. (If ous electoral peril. Furthermore, the selector- space allowed, we would add more from the ate will be enthusiastic only about politicians laundry list above.) We trace much of these who, if circumstances permit, are willing to phenomena to a single cause: the desire of work hard to enact the base’s policy agenda. political agents to send credible signals to That programmatic agenda is, in contrast to political principals about their dedication the typically muddled and inchoate desires of and ideological fealty, using the policymak- less engaged citizens, usually quite definite ing procedures of the SOP system. In other in some particulars. Politicians’ seemingly words, they are variants on or consequences bizarre SOP manipulations, such as fruitlessly of what congressional scholar Frances Lee, repealing portions of the Affordable Care Act in a seminal contribution, called ‘message dozens of times in a legislatively hopeless legislation’ in the lawmaking context.7 We configuration, can be seen as rational efforts dub this phenomenon ‘virtue signaling’. to prove to their skeptical ‘boss’ that they Virtue signaling is closely related to, com- are indeed the type who will bring home the plementary of, but distinct from, blame game policy bacon should circumstances permit in politics. the future. And demanding such signaling is With one exception – Groseclose and actually rational for a boss who is doubtful McCarty’s prescient explication of ‘blame whether the agent possesses ‘true grit’. game vetoes’ – the first-generation SOP To illustrate these points, we sketch a sim- models did not accommodate, and say noth- ple model that embeds a stripped-down veto ing about, message-oriented manipulation of bargaining game within a simple account- the SOP system’s policymaking procedures.8 ability model (we do not undertake a genuine Instead, they assume serious policy-minded formal analysis here; our discussion is merely actors who pursue genuine policy goals by illustrative). We hope these notes-to-a-theory bargaining with one other in a straightfor- suggest the potential for a new direction for ward and serious way. Even the blame game separation-of-powers models. veto model, which takes a big step away from We conclude with some observations about this paradigm, does not fully capture the new whether the sound and fury of phony legislat- direction in American legislative politics. We ing actually makes a substantive difference assert, however, that if the SOP models are or is just meaningless political theater. Our suitably modified, then new veto bargaining, simple new-style SOP model suggests it does pivotal politics and related models can make make a difference. sense of the novel phenomena while retaining their broad accuracy about policy outcomes. The trick (in our view) is to move beyond the first-generation framework by Classical Veto Bargaining embedding the SOP games within what is Games now called an ‘accountability’ model of elec- tions.9 In other words: situate the SOP game The classical models feature bilateral bargain- in a larger model that features retrospective ing between a policy proposer, Congress, or C, voting or similar action by political princi- and a policy receiver, the President, P. Also pals. The principals we have in mind are the making an appearance is the veto over-ride high-information ‘base’ or ‘selectorate’, that player, O. This player is defined as the legisla- is, the individuals who are critical in candidate tor closest to the president for whom exactly BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 225 30/01/20 9:37 AM
226 The SAGE Handbook of Research Methods in Political Science and IR one third of the legislature has ideal points actors and incomplete information. In its either lower or higher than the over-ride play- simplest form, the sequence of play in TILI er’s, depending on whether the president’s bargaining is: ideal point p (defined momentarily) lies in the left or right portion of the policy space, respec- 1 C makes a proposal b (a ‘bill’) to change the tively. In some versions another player, the status quo or reversion policy q. filibuster pivot, appears as well. The filibuster 2 P accepts or vetoes the offer. If P accepts the offer, the final policy outcome x is the bill b, and pivot is defined similarly but only for the the game ends. Senate and using 40 members (the threshold 3 If P vetoes the offer, a vote on a motion to over-ride for cloture since 1975), most relevantly on the occurs. If O supports the motion, the bill is success- opposite side of the median from the President. ful and again x = b is the new policy. If O does not The policy space is typically assumed to be support the motion, the bill fails and x = q, so the one dimensional. So it is a policy evaluation status quo remains the policy in effect. space similar to the oft-used NOMINATE space in empirical studies of roll-call voting.11 Because the game features complete and A critical point in the policy space is the cur- perfect information, it is easily solved using rent policy, the status quo, denoted q. backward induction, thereby incorporating Each actor has a policy utility function the idea of forward-thinking strategically defined over the policy space, with a well- minded actors. The resulting subgame per- identified most preferred policy, the ideal fect equilibrium is unique, depending only point. Call these ideal policies c and p, for on the configuration of ideal points and the Congress and President respectively, and that location of the status quo. We will not go into of the veto override player o. Policies increas- any of the details since very clear expositions ing far from the ideal point have declining are readily available. However, several points value. An example of such a utility function are worth noting. The first three are substan- is the ‘tent’ utility function: tive; the last two are theoretical. First, the basic model reveals a promi- u( x , xi) = − | x − xi | nent advantage for Congress relative to the President. The presidential veto acts where xi is player i’s most-preferred policy as a check on congressional power, but (e.g., c, p, and o) and x is any policy in the Congress’s ability to force an unamendable policy space. offer on a president who can only say ‘yes’ This simple apparatus was first developed or ‘no’ (and who might not be able to make to study elections and voting.12 The SOP ‘no’ stick) gives a huge, constitutionally policy-making models take the apparatus in a entrenched power advantage to Congress. somewhat different direction, however. Second, given much policy disagreement between the legislature and the executive or across the parties, moving the status quo The Engine: the One-shot Take-it- usually requires supermajorities in the leg- islature. Given the Constitution’s veto over- or-Leave-it (TILI) Bargaining Game ride provisions and the Senate’s privileging The engine that makes the SOP models run is of the filibuster, this should hardly be a sur- the celebrated one-shot take-it-or-leave-it prise. But it is a point of major historical (TILI) bargaining game first analyzed by importance – almost every piece of impor- Romer and Rosenthal (1978). Most of the tant legislation in the post-World War II SOP models, including veto bargaining, just era was enacted through supermajorities.13 make changes to this model, for example, by It also implies that the American rules of the adding more moves, additional institutional policymaking game force narrow coalitions BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 226 30/01/20 9:37 AM
New Directions in Veto Bargaining 227 of extremists to compromise if they are to trials, no strikes. The reason is that the par- accomplish anything legislatively. Moderates ticipants understand perfectly what ultimate will see this as highly desirable normatively; adjustments will happen and therefore reach passionate extremists will see it as a bug, not agreements that obviate uselessly destructive a feature, of American government. conflict. In order to get actual vetoes, filibus- Third, (and related to the second point), ters, wars, trials, strikes, and so on, a model often no policy movement is possible: the sta- requires a degree of incomplete information. tus quo lies in the so-called gridlock region. In other words, some actor must lack knowl- In fact, the model and its variants supply the edge about an important variable, and this causal mechanisms behind the status quo bias ignorance or uncertainty leads to ‘mistakes’ so characteristic of American politics. We (more accurately, the rational calculations of all know that status quo bias exists because the actors lead one or both to insist on obdu- there are so many choke points in the policy rate actions that would not occur if everyone process. The models go beyond this cliché to knew everything). show exactly how the choke points work to This fundamental point about human create policy gridlock. interactions is often met with skepticism: do Fourth, because the core model is so sim- you mean to say the horrific slaughter in the ple and easy to analyze, the analysis is very trenches of World War I (for instance) was extendable. This is a lovely feature for the caused by a lack of information, not national- theoretically inclined. For example, one can ism, militarism, military technology, age-old add congressional committees with gate- hatreds, and so on and so on? Not exactly: keeping power;14 filibusters and cloture nationalism and so on may have been neces- votes;15 a powerful Speaker of the House sary for the conflict, in the same way that pol- with gate-keeping power;16 agencies that icy disagreement is necessary for a veto. But begin the game by setting a policy via regula- nationalism was not sufficient. It took nation- tion, so the model becomes a model of the alism plus incomplete information to pro- administrative state in action;17 presidents duce the tragic slaughter. Similarly, in SOP who move first via an executive order, so models, it takes policy disagreement plus the model illustrates presidential unilateral incomplete information to produce a veto, action;18 and more. With very simple tools a filibuster, an over-ride attempt, a cloture requiring minimal mathematical ability, one vote, a judicial strike-down of an executive can easily see how a great deal of national order, a congressional reversal of a judicial policymaking works. policy, and so on. The fifth point is subtle and deep and not There is a logical corollary: analysts who easy to grasp on first acquaintance. In com- want to study not just policy outcomes but plete information models of the kind we phenomena such as vetoes, filibusters, clo- have been discussing, policy typically moves ture votes and over-ride attempts need to quickly to its final resting place. There are use models that incorporate incomplete no vetoes, over-rides, filibusters or cloture information. votes along the path of play; policy just adjusts. If no movement is possible, noth- ing happens at all. In this sense, the modern Bilateral Bargaining Under analysis of vetoes and filibusters is similar Incomplete Information to modern analyses of wars, litigation and strikes. Complete information models of Early analysts of separation-of-powers poli- those phenomena predict changes in territo- tics moved to do just that. McCarty (1997), rial boundaries, cross-litigant payments and for example, studied how a president can use wages. But they also predict no wars, no vetoes to build a reputation across different BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 227 30/01/20 9:37 AM
228 The SAGE Handbook of Research Methods in Political Science and IR policy arenas over time. This model affords a move or counter-move by Congress are one explanation for the well-known honey- signaling games.20 These games feature stra- moon effect in presidential–congressional tegic reputation-building and require more relations (Congress, knowing the freshman sophisticated modes of analysis than the sim- president is hungry to build a reputation for ple complete information models (one must toughness, is extremely accommodating – at model player beliefs simultaneously with first). player strategies, and the two must reinforce Cameron (2000) explored a model of one another). sequential veto bargaining. Here, Congress Many of the incomplete information bilat- and President go through multiple rounds eral bargaining models make rather precise of passing and vetoing the same bill, with empirical predictions about vetoes, over- Congress making concessions each time in rides and so on. Data from the mid-20th cen- an effort to produce an offer the President tury (or earlier) through to the 1980s or so will accept, and the President vetoing and re- strongly display the predicted patterns. As a vetoing in a gamble that Congress will return result, this analytical endeavor has often been with a better offer before bargaining breaks seen as a success for the empirical implica- down. Perhaps somewhat surprisingly, some tions of theoretical models (EITM) move- of the most consequential legislation of the ment in political science. Critically, however, 20th century emerged from this sequential some of the key predictions of the incom- bargaining process (e.g., welfare reform plete information bilateral bargaining models under Clinton). show signs of breaking down – a point we Cameron (2000) also offered a very simple return to below. model of over-ride attempts. Here, in the face of uncertainty about who the critical veto over-ride player will be at the actual moment Bargaining before an of the attempt, over-rides can occur, both Audience: Message Votes successful and unsuccessful. Essentially the same model could be used to study filibusters One of the early incomplete information and cloture voting. models stands out from the others, because it In a particularly clever model, Matthews is not a bilateral bargaining game. We refer to (1989) studied veto threats. Here, a veto Groseclose and McCarty’s blame game veto threat is a little like a bid in a poker game: the model (2001). This model involves three president opens with a ‘bid’ (a veto threat), intrinsically important players. Specifically, Congress may or may not adjust its next Congress and the President play a legislative ‘bid’ (a bill) and then the President ‘calls’ or game before an audience, a Voter. The ‘folds’ by vetoing or accepting.19 Cameron President and Congress understand each oth- et al. (2000) take this model to data, which er’s preferences perfectly, so there is no generally display the predicted empirical incomplete information at that point. But the patterns. Voter is somewhat uncertain about the All of these models feature bilateral bar- President’s preferences; therein lies the criti- gaining between the President and Congress cal incomplete information. The Voter’s with uncertainty about one of the player’s uncertainty creates the opportunity for preferences. In most cases, the uncer- Congress to set up a policymaking sequence tainty involves the president’s preferences, which, if observed by the Voter, will lead her although in the simple veto over-ride model to draw a relatively unfavorable inference the uncertainty is about the preferences of about the President’s preferences (even know- the over-ride player. Models in which the ing that Congress would like this to happen). unknown-preference President moves before And that is the whole point – not truly BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 228 30/01/20 9:37 AM
New Directions in Veto Bargaining 229 legislating, but play-acting legislating in order President George H. W. Bush immediately to cast blame on the other side. Indeed, the before the 1992 presidential election. Bush veto-bait bill may fail miserably in enactment had publicly opposed the bill and his veto was but still succeed as symbolic action. entirely predictable. Given the vote margins, The ideas in the Groseclose–McCarty a successful over-ride was clearly doomed. model should resonate with contemporary So from a serious legislating perspective, the scholars, for blame-game vetoes are closely bill was futile. The Democrats nonetheless related to what Frances Lee has called ‘mes- pressed ahead, and then used the failed bill as sage votes’. According to Lee (2016: 143–4), a signature electoral issue. Upon re-gaining message votes occur when the presidency, they quickly enacted family leave in 1993 and touted it as a flagship legis- A party brings to the floor an attractive-sounding lative accomplishment. Quintessential blame idea with the following characteristics: (1) its mem- game politics! bers support it; (2) the other party opposes it; and (3) it is not expected to become law. Former The general phenomenon of blame game Senator Olympia Snowe offers a more detailed politics, presciently explored by Groseclose explanation: ‘much of what occurs in Congress and McCarty in the specific context of veto today is what is often called “political messaging”. bargaining, has now become routine, at least Rather than putting forward a plausible, realistic in the opinion of astute observers such as solution to a problem, members on both sides offer legislation that is designed to make the Lee and candid participants such as Snowe. opposing side look bad on an issue and it is not In fact, a series of empirical anomalies in intended to ever actually pass.’ separation-of-power politics suggest the need for some fresh thinking. The Groseclose–McCarty model works out the logic of ‘make the opposing side look bad’ in the specific context of the presiden- tial veto.21 Empirical Anomalies An obvious question is, how frequently have blame game vetoes occurred? We take Recent years have seen congressional legisla- a look at some relevant data below. But tive behavior that is extremely difficult to Cameron (2000a) addressed this question reconcile with the classical SOP models. Let’s over the 20th century, using an admittedly look at some of the empirical anomalies. stringent set of criteria: the veto needed to be prominent, occur in the run-up to a presiden- tial election, and led to a hopeless over-ride What to Look for: Vote Margins at attempt (so the enactors should have known the Pivots and Policy Concessions that serious legislating was off the table). The historical data on vetoes during the 20th The first question, though, is this: where century uncovers relatively few blame game should we look for legislative anomalies? vetoes, according to these criteria (see ibid, The incomplete information bilateral Table 5.1). Most vetoes did not look like this. bargaining models assume a degree of uncer- To the extent that this is a fair test, the blame tainty about the preferences of a key player, game model does not look like a general but not a huge amount of incomplete infor- model of vetoes, at least over much of the mation. This has important implications for 20th century. However, the data reveal that vote margins at the pivots and for policy some vetoes were clearly blame game vetoes. concessions in re-passed bills. An example was the Family and Medical First, vote margins at the critical pivots Leave Act of 1991, passed by a Democratic should be close. To see the logic, suppose, Congress and presented to Republican for example, a bill is geared to beat a likely BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 229 30/01/20 9:37 AM
230 The SAGE Handbook of Research Methods in Political Science and IR presidential veto with the veto over-ride A second anomaly can occur with re- player as the critical pivot. Then the roll call passed, previously failed legislation: no margin on passage in both chambers should concessions. (That is, for re-passage under be about two-thirds. If it is much higher, the same configuration of players.) Under the proposers have not been tough enough; the sequential veto bargaining model, re- they have conceded too much. If it is far shy passage of vetoed bills can occur, but the of two-thirds then the bill is a sitting duck, re-passed bill should contain a compromise doomed from day one, and the proposers are in the direction of the president, so either he wasting their time. The margin for the over- will sign it or the veto over-ride player will ride attempt should also be about two-thirds. support the bill. As a result, the cutting line Now, suppose the president himself is the between the yeas and nays in NOMINATE critical pivot (that is, the veto override player space should shift toward the president, and is more extreme than the president). Then the the aye margin should increase.22 Similar passage margin may be lower than two-thirds logic applies to bills that die from a filibus- but if the president does veto the bill, no ter in the Senate: if re-passed, they should over-ride attempt should follow, as the over- contain a compromise to the filibusterers ride is hopeless. If an over-ride attempt did so that either they will accept it or cloture occur (anomalously), the vote margin would will succeed. The same logic also applies to be well short of two-thirds. In short, unless bills that are enacted by one chamber dur- the president is moderate relative to the over- ing split-chamber divided government, but ride pivot, passage margins for vetoed bills then die in the other chamber (perhaps they should be about two-third yeas and one-third are never taken up). If the first chamber re- nays, over-ride attempts should not occur for passes the bill, it should contain concessions vetoed bills with narrow passage margins to the recalcitrant chamber. Cutting lines for and actual over-ride margins should be about the roll call vote in the enacting chamber two-thirds yeas and one-third nays. should shift in the direction of the recal- Similar ideas apply to filibusters. Suppose citrant chamber and vote margins should a bill is geared to beat a filibuster in the increase. Senate. Then a bill that is likely to provoke In sum, the place to look for legislative a filibuster should pass the Senate with about anomalies are: 1) lop-sided supermajori- 60 votes. If it passed with many more votes, ties or, conversely, very narrow enactment the filibuster is pointless since cloture will be votes for vetoed bills upon initial passage; easy, hence no filibuster should occur (and 2) veto over-ride margins far from two- the bill’s proponents conceded too much to thirds in one or both chambers; 3) enact- the opposition). If initially passed with a nar- ment votes for filibustered bills far from row majority, then cloture seems likely to fail 60–40 in the Senate; 4) cloture vote mar- and the bill should not have been passed in gins far from 60–40; and 5) re-passed pre- the first place – its authors should have con- viously failed bills in the same legislative ceded more, or just abandoned the effort. configuration that do not contain conces- Similarly, actual cloture votes should show sions from bill to bill. about 60 votes in favor of cloture. Lop-sided So, how many legislative anomalies have successful cloture votes should not occur occurred in recent decades? Has the rate of because the filibusterers should have known anomalies increased? Unfortunately, a com- they would fail; lop-sided failed cloture votes prehensive empirical analysis lies outside should not occur because the bill authors our writ here. However, we can present some should have known the bill was a sitting duck simple data and mini-case studies that sug- and either conceded more or given up the clo- gest anomalies now abound and have distinc- ture attempt. tive features. BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 230 30/01/20 9:37 AM
New Directions in Veto Bargaining 231 Veto Anomalies the Senate. Theory would predict something close to zero. It should also be noted that, of Table 13.1 presents some simple summary the 34 hopeless over-ride failures, six of these statistics on vetoes from 1975 to 2018. There over-ride attempts failed in the Senate after were 167 vetoes in that period, with about success in the House (so the House success half escaping an over-ride attempt. Of those was immaterial), while the other four hope- that were challenged (90), about 69% were less over-ride failures in the Senate occurred sustained (the over-ride attempt failed) while for vetoes where the House did not even 31% succeeded. Under traditional veto bar- attempt an over-ride (so they were truly hope- gaining models, we would expect that if a less failures). In sum, the number of hope- veto is challenged it should either succeed or less over-ride attempts was not large but this fail by a narrow margin. Otherwise, either the phenomenon has become a notable feature of president should not have vetoed it or veto politics. Congress should not have challenged it. What type of bills did Congress typically try Hence, a 70% failure rate for over-ride so hopelessly to over-ride? At least in recent attempts may raise an eyebrow; one might cases, the bills were highly visible, highly con- expect something closer to 50–50. In fact, tentious vehicles for partisan position-taking. Cameron (2000) reports a success rate of They are similar to the bills involved in the 45%, using earlier data (p. 56). Still, one frenetic, frenzied re-passage episodes dis- needs to look more closely at actual vote cussed momentarily; in fact, some of them are margins to identify anomalies. the same bills. So, for example, bills repeal- Table 13.2 takes a closer look at sustained ing parts of Obamacare and the Dodd–Frank vetoes, that is, failed over-ride attempts. It financial legislation both generated vetoes and focuses on hopeless over-ride attempts. In the hopeless over-ride failures in the Republican House, over half of the time that an over-ride Congresses facing President Obama. Hopeless attempt failed, it failed by at least 10% of the over-ride failures during the Bush administra- required votes (29 votes). In the Senate, some tion were generated by vetoed bills banning 10 of the 22 failed over-ride attempts failed waterboarding and establishing a timeline for by the comparable 10% margin (6 votes). withdrawing troops from Iraq. Hence, the “hopeless over-ride” rate among Some of the hopeless over-rides seem to the failures was 60% in the House and 45% in follow the script of Groseclose and McCarty’s Table 13.1 Summary statistics on vetoes: 1975–2018 Sustained1 62 37.1% Overridden 28 16.8% Unchallenged 77 46.1% Total vetoes 167 100% 1This counts two vetoes that were overridden in one chamber but unchallenged in the other, technically leading to an outcome where the veto was challenged but not overridden. Accordingly, we classified these as sustained but exclude them from the following analysis of sustained votes. Table 13.2 Hopeless over-ride attempts, 1975–2018 Sustained in House 40 Sustained in Senate 22 Failed by more than 10% 24 Failed by more than 10% 10 Percent not close 60% Percent not close 45% BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 231 30/01/20 9:37 AM
232 The SAGE Handbook of Research Methods in Political Science and IR blame game vetoes. For instance, the water- massive rolls of vetoes have occurred only boarding episode can be seen as an attempt about once per decade. Table 13.3 provides a by the Democrats to demonstrate to the pub- brief overview of these vetoes. lic the inhumanity of the president and his At the time of writing, the most recent administration. However, in some cases there massive roll of a presidential veto involved are hints of another dynamic. Thus, reporting President Obama’s veto of the Justice in The Hill noted: ‘Republicans say they are Against Sponsors of Terrorism Act (JASTA). playing the long game with the [ACA] repeal This bill would have allowed private indi- vote, hoping it will give voters a glimpse of viduals to pursue legal action against for- how they would govern if they win back the eign companies in US courts, primarily in White House in November.’23 We will return response to the victims of the 9/11 terrorist to this point below. attack. President Obama veto message cited We have looked at hopeless over-ride foreign policy concerns.24 President Bush’s attempts; what about hopeless vetoes? How lone massive roll came from his veto of the frequently does the president get massively Water Resources Development Act of 2007. rolled after vetoing a bill? Given the hopeless Bush claimed the bill was too pork-ridden to quality of the veto, why did he veto it in the serve the nation’s interests.25 Finally, a bill first place? canceling Clinton’s line-item veto of military In the time period we study, the presi- construction projects was also overridden dent occasionally vetoed a bill with massive by large margins.26 As with Bush’s veto, the support, so that an over-ride was virtually concerns behind the veto seem primarily cen- certain. Of the 28 over-ridden vetoes dur- tered on pork.27 ing this time period, Congress overrode nine In each of these examples, the president of them by at least 10% in each chamber. Six had genuine policy concerns, but the veto – a of these massive rolls came during the first hopeless endeavor from the get-go – seems to 12 years of the data (during the Ford have been undertaken partly or primarily for and Reagan Administrations). Since then, position-taking. Perhaps the president wanted Table 13.3 Massive rolls of presidential vetoes, 1975–2018 Bill Number Bill Name Date of Veto House Vote Senate Vote Reason for Veto S.2040 Justice Against Sponsors of 9/23/16 348–77 97–1 International concerns Terrorism Act H.R.1495 Water Resources Development 11/2/07 361–54 79–14 Too much pork Act of 2007 H.R.2631 Line Item Veto Cancellation 11/13/97 347–69 78–20 Too much pork H.R.1 Water Quality Act 1/30/87 401–26 86–14 Too much spending and federal oversight H.R.2409 Health Research Extension Act 11/8/85 380–32 89–7 Too much red tape and bureaucracy H.R.6198 To amend the manufacturing 7/8/82 324–86 84–9 Free trade concerns clause of the Copyright Law H.R.7102 Veterans’ Administration 8/22/80 401–5 85–0 Spent money on VA physician Health-Care Amendments bonuses instead of helping veterans H.R.5901 Education Division and Related 7/25/75 379–41 88–12 Fiscal irresponsibility Agencies Appropriation Act H.R.4222 National School Lunch and 10/3/75 397–18 79–13 Fiscal irresponsibility/personal Child Nutrition Act responsibility BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 232 30/01/20 9:37 AM
New Directions in Veto Bargaining 233 to signal his frugality and good stewardship filibusters may have been fruitless efforts to a national audience (or, in Obama’s case, leading to a crushing cloture vote, but one an international one). Or, the president may cannot easily detect such filibusters using have wanted to highlight Congress’s fiscal positive cloture margins alone. imprudence, a sort of reverse blame-game Therefore, let us turn our focus to the left- veto. In all three of these examples, both hand tail: failed cloture motions. In the face chambers of Congress were controlled by the of incomplete information about the filibus- other party. ter pivot, one would expect some cloture motions to fail, but generally with margins close to zero. Yet one sees some eye-popping Filibuster Anomalies negative margins, some by 20 votes or more. Thus, some invincible filibusters provoked Discussion of the filibuster may seem some- completely hopeless cloture attempts. Votes what odd in an essay on veto bargaining, but like this are hard to reconcile with classical we argue that the anomalies are similar in SOP style models. both cases and likely to have a common Have futile cloture efforts increased over origin. Therefore, let us quickly examine time? Figure 13.2 address this question by ‘strange’ patterns in filibusters, focusing on examining the number of hopelessly failed cloture vote margins. cloture votes, votes failing by a 10% margin Figure 13.1 displays vote margins in or more (that is, six votes or more). The time all cloture votes in the 111th to 115th period is longer, from the 94th Congress to Congresses (2009–18). Recall that the the 115th, in order to provide more of a required quota for success was 60 votes in historic contrast (the critical cloture mar- this period; in the figure, a margin of 0 cor- gin was 60 votes over the entire period). As responds to 60 votes for cloture. The thin shown in the figure, there appears to be a vertical line shows the average margin in jump in the number of big failures starting these Congresses: about 7.3 votes (in the at the 104th Congress (1995–6). Using the 94th through 98th Congresses, the average benchmark of a 10% short-fall in votes, the margin was almost exactly 0). Two features average number of futile cloture votes was stand out in the figure. 10.1 in the 94th to 103rd Congresses; it was First, and most noticeable, is the very 23.5 in the 104th to 115th Congresses. Thus, long and rather flat right-hand tail, that is, the number of futile cloture votes doubled successful cloture votes. As shown, some beginning with the ‘Gingrich Revolution’ cloture votes succeeded with absolutely Congress after the 1994 mid-term elec- spectacular margins, suggesting that the fili- tion. We note that the percentage of futile buster in question was a hopeless endeavor. cloture votes (relative to all cloture votes) Unfortunately, this inference is clouded did not change much over this time period, by the changing vagaries of senatorial pro- though the number of such votes seemed to cedure. As explained by CRS experts: increase. ‘In recent times … Senate leadership has What were some examples of recent hope- increasingly made use of cloture as a nor- less cloture votes? In the most recent period, mal tool for managing the flow of business many deal with border security, sanctuary cit- on the floor, even when no evident filibuster ies, DACA and abortion – all highly visible has yet occurred.’28 Thus, cloture is now used and highly partisan issues. pre-emptively and as a device to restrict non- We have just scratched the surface of this germane amendments. This change in proce- material but clearly some filibuster and clo- dure probably accounts for some of the huge ture attempts look quite strange from a bilat- positive margins in cloture voting. Some eral bargaining perspective. BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 233 30/01/20 9:37 AM
234 The SAGE Handbook of Research Methods in Political Science and IR Figure 13.1 Passage margin of cloture votes, 2009–2018 Note: A vote margin of 0 corresponds to 60 votes for cloture. The right-hand tail of the figure captures successful cloture votes; the left-hand tail unsuccessful ones. Not every cloture motion resulted in a vote. The data exclude nominees consid- ered under a pure majority confirmation rule. Figure 13.2 Futile cloture votes, 1975–2018 Note: Shown are counts of dramatically failed cloture votes by Congress, using the benchmark of a 10% short-fall in votes. BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 234 30/01/20 9:38 AM
New Directions in Veto Bargaining 235 Frenetic Failed Legislation ‘shellacking’, in President Obama’s memora- ble phrase. Critically, the Republican gained One of the strangest recent phenomena in the control of the House of Representatives, while new legislative politics is what can be called the Democrats retained the Senate until the frenetic failed legislation. With frenetic failed 2014 election, when the Republicans estab- legislation, one or both chambers of Congress lished a narrow majority. The Democrats held repeatedly enact almost identical bills that all onto the presidency until the 2016 election. participants understand have no realistic The classic SOP models clearly indicate chance of becoming law. And they do not, that the Republicans had no realistic pros- until the legislative configuration changes. In pect of repealing the ACA in the 112th, the traditional SOP frameworks, this spastic 113th and 114th Congresses. In the first re-passage of doomed legislation makes two Congresses, the Democratic-controlled about as much sense as repeatedly slamming Senate would simply ignore House legisla- oneself in the face with a baseball bat: it is a tion. In the third Congress, Democratic fili- sign of madness. Yet, Congress has spent busters or presidential vetoes would surely significant time and resources on such bills kill Republican bills. These were the trans- in recent Congresses. In fact, it has become a parently obvious outcomes predicted by the signature activity of contemporary legislative models, and that is what transpired. politics. Accordingly, using the SOP models, one To be clear, frenetic failed legislation typi- might expect Republican legislators to focus cally occurs under divided government, where on other legislation that might actually have one chamber (typically the House) passes and a chance of enactment. Or, they might con- re-passes a bill (sometimes with minor vari- centrate their efforts on congressional over- ations) favored by the majority party in that sight, constituency service, fund-raising chamber but opposed by the other chamber and just plain electioneering. Nonetheless, and/or the president. The status quo clearly the Washington Post documented a total falls within the gridlock interval. That is, the of 54 total or partial repeals of the ACA in bill lacks the votes to overcome a filibuster or the first four years of Republican control.29 veto or both. In contrast to the sequential veto While these bills were far from identical, bargaining model, which envisions repeated attacking the existing law from a plethora of passage of a succession of modified bills in angles, they all had the exact same chance of a serious effort at policymaking, there is no becoming law: zero. effort at compromise. Instead, these repeated The ACA wasn’t the only Obama-era stat- efforts are characterized by their intransigent ute that Republicans repeatedly attempted and clearly infeasible nature. Let us look at a to repeal during this period. They also made few examples from recent periods of divided several efforts to undo the Dodd–Frank regu- government to illustrate. lations on the financial industry. For example, The most famous example of frenetic in 2013 alone, House Republicans passed HR failed legislation is of course the Republican 1256, HR 992, HR 2374 and HR 1105, all efforts to ‘repeal and replace’ the Affordable of which were intended to repeal aspects of Care Act. Recall that this landmark legisla- Dodd–Frank.30 None of these bills were con- tion was enacted by the 111th Congress after sidered by the Democratic Senate. a historic donnybrook and signed into law by It should be noted that Republicans held President Barack Obama in March 2010. The no monopoly on frenetic failed legislation. mid-term elections that November then saw Democrats found themselves in a simi- the electorate administer a brutal drubbing lar political configuration during the 109th to the Democrats, racking up some of the Congress, when they had a House major- largest losses since the Great Depression – a ity during the waning years of the Bush BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 235 30/01/20 9:38 AM
236 The SAGE Handbook of Research Methods in Political Science and IR administration. And they engaged in simi- majority to highlight the perfidy of the oppo- lar legislative behavior. In particular, House sition: ‘Look, everyone! We would have this Democrats repeatedly attempted to restrict wonderful legislation but for the intransi- activities in the Iraq war, such as through gence of these terrible people!’ So: throw the requiring troop withdrawals. As noted in bums out! CQ Weekly: ‘In July, for example, the House At the same time, much of the weirdness passed a bill (HR 2956) sponsored by Armed seems somewhat distinct from pure blame Services Chairman Ike Skelton, D-Mo., that game politics. For example, it may make would have required troop withdrawals. But sense to try and fail to pass a symbolically like about a half dozen other measures, it resonant bill once, in order to demonstrate went no further.’31 Furthermore, the accounts that the fault for failure lies with the opposi- make clear that House Democrats were fully tion. But why pass the same bill 60 times? aware of the futility of their efforts: How much more education in the vileness of the opposition does the public need, once After Republicans blocked an effort last week to the opposition is revealed to be bad via the require a withdrawal of U.S. troops from Iraq, Senate Democrats put the issue aside and are not first failure? If, as Senate Majority Leader expected to return to it until after the August Mitch McConnell liked to suggest, ‘There’s recess. House Democrats, however, plan to do no education in the second kick of a mule’, 33 their part to keep the subject alive this week, with how much is there in the 40th, 50th or 60th? war-related votes possible during committee con- Similarly, even in clear blame game politics sideration of the fiscal 2008 Defense spending bill and on the floor.32 such as the veto of the Family and Medical Leave Act, part of the signaling was not just If the multitudinous ACA repeals are a sign that President Bush was blocking family of legislative madness, the malady, unlike leave. The message was also, ‘we Democrats much in Washington today, is refreshingly are really in favor of this idea and can be bipartisan. trusted to deliver if handed the keys to the But perhaps there is a method in the mad- kingdom’. In other words, the message sent ness, a method outside the ambit of the clas- to the audience is not just ‘the other side is sical SOP models. horrible, so kick them out’ but also ‘our side is wonderful, so support us’. Virtue signaling seems as much at play as blame game. What is Going on? Blame Game Consequently, let’s briefly explore the pol- itics of virtue signaling. Versus Virtue Signaling Our admittedly cursory review of recent empirical evidence suggests that much legis- lating continues to follow the script of the Toward A Model of Message classical, incomplete information bilateral Legislation: Virtue Signaling bargaining models. For example, in and Accountability Figure 13.1 most cloture votes do fall near the 60-vote benchmark. As the same time, Let’s consider a model of message legisla- there appears to be a serious under-current of tion, legislation not intended for enactment something else going on. What is it? but instead constructed solely to send a mes- An obvious candidate is blame game poli- sage to outside observers. Many obvious tics. As suggested by Senator Snowe’s com- questions arise: who are the senders? Who ment, a phenomenon like forcing a futile are the receivers? What is the message? What cloture vote in the face of an invincible fili- gives the message meaning? What gives it buster may be an attempt by the chamber’s credibility? Why is strategic information BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 236 30/01/20 9:38 AM
New Directions in Veto Bargaining 237 transmission of this form advantageous to the McCarty already constructed an example of parties? Many answers to these questions are the former. possible and lead to different models. But Virtue signaling requires the receiver (the let’s sketch one set of answers, if only to sug- selectorate) to have incomplete informa- gest how to embed veto bargaining-style tion about the sender, the incumbent legis- models of SOP policymaking within an lator. This is in contrast to the blame-game accountability model of the electorate. We’ll approach, where the incomplete information focus on the dramatic, frenetic failed legisla- must be about the opposition (e.g., the oppo- tion of the ‘repeal and replace’ variety. sition president or party). So, here, the selec- First, let’s assume the senders are mem- torate is somewhat uncertain about the virtue bers of a party that controls one chamber of of the incumbent representative. To make Congress but does not control all the major matters concrete, suppose there are two types veto points in the legislative process. So, the of representatives: slackers (low virtue) and president may belong to the opposite party. zealots (high virtue).35 Slackers have no pol- Or, the other chamber may be controlled by icy convictions but just value holding office. the other party. Or, ‘our’ chamber may be the Zealots also value office but in addition they House while the other party controls the very value policy, and value it similarly to the constraining filibuster pivot in the Senate. selectorate. From the viewpoint of the policy- Let’s assume the status quo lies firmly in the minded selectorate, it doesn’t make much dif- gridlock region, so no enactment improving ference which type holds office when policy matters from the sender’s policy perspective is gridlocked. After all, no change is possible. is actually possible. But if policymaking becomes possible and is Let’s assume the receiver of the mes- costly of time and effort, then it may make a sage is the sender’s selectorate – the high- great deal of difference who holds office. For information, highly engaged portion of the on that happy day, the slacker won’t do much party whose money, time and enthusiasm work, but the zealot will toil like a Trojan is vital for re-election. With the support of in order to achieve the policy goal. Clearly, these hyper-engaged kingmakers, re-election from the viewpoint of the policy-oriented is almost assured (the district is a safe one). selectorate, it will be much better to be rep- But without it, the sender may well be ‘pri- resented by a zealot rather than a slacker on maried’ and out of office. This approach that future day. is particularly compatible with the UCLA How then can an incumbent zealot prove approach to parties, where parties are formed he is a zealot and worthy of re-election? A out of a coalition of policy-motivated groups non-starter is, issue a raft of campaign prom- which ‘insist on the nomination of candi- ises. Any promise a zealot could make, a dates with a demonstrated commitment to slacker could make as well. So, our model its program’,34 but can also fit with others in will not feature Downsian-style prospective which the political marketplace is less than campaign promises. Rather, it will incorpo- perfect. rate V.O. Key-style retrospective voting. The Two broad classes of messages are pos- selectorate will act in light of what has gone sible. The first (as discussed above) is the before, eliminating incumbents likely to be blame-game message: I will show you that slackers and retaining those likely to be zeal- the other side is terrible [so you should sup- ots. The point is to increase the chances of port me]. The second is the virtue-signaling having a zealot incumbent when policy win- message: I will show you that I am trustwor- dows open in the future.36 thy, your faithful agent, one of you [so you Let’s focus on one type of action the should support me]. Let’s consider the sec- incumbent can undertake: frenetic failed ond class of models, since Groseclose and legislation. So, pass, re-pass and continue BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 237 30/01/20 9:38 AM
238 The SAGE Handbook of Research Methods in Political Science and IR re-passing virtually the same bill in the face equilibrium is quite attractive for the incum- of an unbeatable veto, an invincible filibus- bent politician regardless of type; after all, ter or just plain disregard from the opposite he doesn’t have to do much policy work in chamber. The resulting sequence of play is: period 1 and yet gets re-elected. But it is not so good for the voter, because when the 1 Nature selects the incumbent legislator’s type policy window opens in the second period he (slacker or zealot), which is private information may find himself saddled with a slacker as for the incumbent. representative, resulting in a missed legisla- 2 The incumbent engages in a futile legislative tive opportunity. interaction with, say, the President, fruitlessly passing and re-passing the same bill with multi- The second, and more interesting, equi- ple vetoes and re-vetoes. Enactments are costly librium is a separating equilibrium.37 Here, of time and effort that could profitably be spent in period 1 incumbent slackers and zealots elsewhere. behave in very different ways. The zealot 3 When either the president accepts a bill or the engages in frantic frenetic failed legislating, incumbent desists with fruitless legislating, play- fruitlessly passing and re-passing the same ers receive period 1 payoffs. bill over and over and over. The slacker does 4 The voter then retains or fires the incumbent. nothing because imitating the furious action If the voter fires the incumbent, nature selects of the zealot would be too costly of effort. the type of the new representative. Nature also The zealot’s policy-mindedness creates a selects a new president so that policy windows wedge between him and the slacker that open. 5 The representative (either new or retained) allows this separation to occur – but only at engages in a legislative interaction with the new high levels of effort, hence the need to do a lot President. of futile policymaking. The voter then fires a 6 Based on the outcome of the legislative interac- revealed slacker and retains a revealed zealot. tion, players receive second period pay-offs. In the second period, when policy windows open, a zealot works hard to legislate and a Comparison of this sequence with that of the slacker doesn’t. This equilibrium is much simple TILI game indicates a much more worse for the legislator: a period 1 slacker complex game. It features two periods, not gets fired, and a period 1 zealot must slave one; incomplete information (held by the away at phony legislating in order to retain voter about the incumbent’s preferences), not his job. But this equilibrium is much better complete information; voter beliefs about the for the voter because it boosts the chance of incumbent’s preferences; costly signaling by having a valuable zealot in place when policy the incumbent in period 1; retrospective windows open. voting by the voter; and, finally, serious poli- We have only sketched an analysis of mes- cymaking in the second period. Still, as a sage legislation and virtue signaling. But costly signaling game, it is not hard to ana- we hope we have at least suggested that the lyze using modern techniques. idea is worth pursuing, and that the politics We assert without proof that the virtue of virtue signaling is distinct from but com- signaling game has two generic equilibria. In plementary to the politics of the blame game. the first, a pooling equilibrium, both a slacker Carefully elaborating the theory of virtue legislator and a zealot legislator behave the signaling may enable some parsing of the same way in period 1: they do nothing. And, difference between the two and lead empiri- in this ‘incumbency advantage’ equilibrium, cal work in new directions, for example the the voter re-elects the incumbent despite the effect of message votes on fund raising, pri- dearth of effort. Then, in the second period, mary challenges and citizen voting – all new a zealot legislator engages in fruitful leg- directions for SOP-style models. In addition, islating while a slacker does nothing. This further theoretical development might well BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 238 30/01/20 9:38 AM
New Directions in Veto Bargaining 239 tackle the question: why the rise in message fairly subtle one. The separating equilibrium legislation? The new media environment, in our proto-model involves considerable partisan polarization of elites, the rise of information transmission between the send- groups such as the Tea Party on the right and ing congressperson and the constituent. The “the opposition” on the left, partisan sorting constituent learns something about the con- geographically and across the parties, and the gressperson and – critically – then uses the increase in competition to control the gov- information in choosing either to support or ernment are probably all implicated. But how oppose the incumbent. The result is an ideo- exactly? In a related way, in the context of the logical filter applied to incumbents, resulting virtue signaling model one might ask, across over time in greater retention of representa- different issues, when should we expect the tives who are zealous in pursuit of the selector- pooling equilibrium to prevail, and when the ate’s ideological goals. The result is not quite separating equilibrium (the difficult question the same thing as ideological polarization per of equilibrium selection)? se. But because the key constituents who fol- low and respond to the political theater tend to be high-information ideologically consist- ent extremists, the net effect is to build a more Does Bargaining Before an extreme legislature over time. In essence, there Audience Make a Difference? is an enhanced feedback loop between incum- bent position taking and constituent response, We have suggested ways to modify classical leading to a legislature responsive to relatively SOP models, such as the veto bargaining extreme blocks within the electorate. Or so the models, in order to better capture the new model suggests. An obvious question is: is this American legislative politics. The new poli- actually happening? tics on which we have focused results from There is another element, outside our blame game politics but also (we suggest) sketch model, but of potential importance and from politicians’ virtue signaling to an atten- concern. In the pooling equilibrium, zealous tive audience of ideological extremists. But incumbents who face gridlock don’t under- is modifying the classical models to incorpo- take any policymaking effort since it won’t rate message legislation really worth the accomplish anything substantively and they effort? After all, the classic SOP models will get re-elected anyway. But in fact, case more or less get it right with respect to policy studies show zealous policy-minded con- outcomes: when they say policy windows are gressmen doing a lot of policy work during shut, relatively little is enacted. When they down periods. In particular, congressional identity the key veto players, they are gener- policy entrepreneurs hone their legislative ally correct. And when they suggest the proposals and lay the foundation for future political evaluation needed for enactment – legislative coalitions. For instance, Senator that is, the spatial position of viable legislation Bill Bradley spent years working on tax in something like NOMINATE space – reform before policy windows opened creat- usually they are close to the mark. So, one ing the opportunity for a big policy innova- may well ask, does all the noisy action atten- tion.38 Similarly, famed policy entrepreneur dant on message legislation actually make a Representative Henry Waxman labored long substantive difference? Or does the sound and hard, often for years, to build carefully and fury signify nothing? crafted bills well aimed at specific health Our sketch model of message legisla- policy problems.39 The result was (arguably) tion and virtue signal suggests that the poli- high quality bills ready to go, when the grid- tics of bargaining before an audience does lock region narrowed and legislative opportu- make a difference for outcomes, though a nity presented itself. BK-SAGE-CURINI_FRANZESE-190202-V1_Chp13.indd 239 30/01/20 9:38 AM
You can also read