The Wages Crisis: REVISITED - Andrew Stewart Jim Stanford Tess Hardy - NationBuilder
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
the Wages Crisis: REVISITED This report updates and supplements analysis originally contained in the book, The Wages Crisis in Australia: What it is and what to do about it, edited by Andrew Stewart, Jim Stanford, and Tess Hardy, originally published by University of Adelaide Press in November 2018. That original book contained 20 contributions from a wide range of Australian labour policy scholars and practitioners, documenting the extent, con- sequence, causes, and potential policy responses to the unprecedented stagnation of average wages in Australia visible since 2013. This report updates both the data and policy implications in light of continued weakness in Australian wages since then. The full original book is available for free download from: www.adelaide.edu.au/press/titles/wages-crisis About the Authors Andrew Stewart is the John Bray Professor of Law at the University of Adelaide and a consultant with the law firm Piper Alderman. A pre-eminent expert on employ- ment law and workplace relations, he has co-authored recent books or reports on decent work for interns, digital platform work, and workplace cooperation. Jim Stanford is Economist and Director of the Centre for Future Work at the Australia Institute. He is also Honorary Professor of Political Economy at the Uni- versity of Sydney, and Harold Innis Industry Professor of Economics at McMaster University in Canada. Tess Hardy is an Associate Professor at Melbourne Law School, Co-Director of the Centre for Employment and Labour Relations Law and an Australian Research Council Discovery Early Career Researcher Fellow. The authors thank without implication Marilee Hou, Ashwini Ravindram, and Greg Jericho.
Contents Summary 4 1. Introduction: Wages, Consumers and Recovery 8 2. The Aims of this Report: Revisiting The Wages Crisis 11 3. Charting the Wages Crisis 13 3.1 Indicators of wage growth 13 3.2 Other measures of labour costs 18 3.3 Wages and labour market conditions 20 3.4 Industry-level perspectives 23 3.5 Wages, inflation and productivity 24 3.6 Wages and the COVID-19 pandemic 27 3.7 Australian wages in international comparison 30 3.8 Summary 31 4. How Fast Should Wages Grow? 33 5. Tax Cuts Cannot Replace Wage Gains 36 6. Policy and Regulatory Weaknesses 38 6.1 Collective bargaining 39 6.2 Statutory wage-fixing 43 6.3 Gender pay inequity 45 6.4 Government wage policies 46 6.5 Wage underpayments 49 6.6 Migrant workers 51 6.7 Fragmented business structures and organisational networks 53 6.8 Sham self-employment and freelancing 54 6.9 Other forms of precarious work 57 7. An Agenda for Reform 61 7.1 Ending wage suppression by government 62 7.2 Revitalising collective bargaining 63 7.3 Strengthening minimum wage regulation 64 7.4 Responding to business models that avoid or outsource employment responsibilities 65 7.5 Improving compliance with employment standards 67 7.6 A final word 68 References 70 3
Summary For several years, nominal This report reviews the scale, likely causes, and potential remedies for the continuing wage growth in Australia’s weakness in Australian wage determination. economy has been unusually The report is a sequel to a collection of weak. original research published four years ago: The Wages Crisis in Australia: What it is and Beginning in 2013, the traditional pace of what to do about it (Stewart, Stanford and wage increases decelerated by roughly half: Hardy 2018). from around 4% per year prior to 2013, to an average of around 2% since then. The nine This new report begins by providing a years since 2013 have thus represented the comprehensive empirical description of the weakest sustained period of wage growth in wages slowdown, confirming by several Australia’s postwar history. indicators that the slowdown has continued in the years since our 2018 book was Despite unprecedented disruptions in published – including through the Australia’s labour market during the unprecedented events of the COVID-19 COVID-19 pandemic, this weak trajectory in pandemic and its aftermath. This evidence wages growth still predominates. Even with suggests that the wages slowdown does not the unemployment rate falling to a multi- seem to be the result of changes in supply- decade low as the economy re-opened after and-demand balances in the labour market, COVID lockdowns, wage growth has which did not substantially differ between remained stubbornly slow. The the pre- and post-2013 periods. Instead, consequences of wage stagnation are felt in explanations for the slowdown are more numerous areas of the economy: including likely to be found in the evolution of certain household financial pressures, restrained structural, institutional, and policy variables consumer spending, slower government affecting wage determination. revenue growth, and a shift in national income distribution away from labour and The report then considers the dimensions of toward capital. a healthy or ‘normal’ pace of nominal wage 4
growth, suggesting that wages should grow there is no guarantee that the tribunal’s faster than 4% per year in the medium-term recent willingness to lift minimum rates in order to restore normal relationships to will continue. Much will depend on who inflation, productivity growth, and dis- is appointed as the President of the tribution of national income between labour Commission to replace Justice Iain and capital. Incremental changes in tax Ross, who is due to retire in January policy (such as those advanced in the most 2024. recent Commonwealth budget) cannot replace the loss of normal wage increases in • Gender pay inequity. There remains a household finances or macroeconomic persistent gap between male and female functioning. earnings, and there is little sign that the equal remuneration provisions in the The report then reviews a range of possible Fair Work Act can be used to raise factors that have likely contributed to the minimum wages in feminised industries. sustained wage slowdown in Australia since 2013. We focus in particular on the • Government wage policies. Governments at institutions and rules governing the labour all levels have been actively seeking to market, identifying nine distinct areas of restrain wage growth, and not just for policy and regulatory weakness: their own employees (through pay caps imposed on public servants). • Collective bargaining. Enterprise-level ne- Compensation in large segments of gotiation is meant to be the main way of broader public and non-government gaining a wage increase under the Fair services has also been depressed by Work Act 2009. As union member-ship government funding and procurement has declined, however, so too has bar- policies. The aged care sector provides gaining, to the point where only 11% of a clear example of how damaging those private sector employees are now cov- policies can be, with the Royal ered by a current (non-expired) enter- Commission into Aged Care Quality and prise agreement. Rather than bolstering Safety recommending that wage worker power, the Morrison govern- increases should become an explicit ment’s 2020 ‘Omnibus Bill’ sought un- policy objective of aged care funding. successfully to weaken the better off overall test (BOOT), which protects em- • Wage underpayments. The underpayment ployees from being disadvantaged under of employees (or ‘wage theft’) has an enterprise agreement. A further become endemic, harming workers and proposal would allow employers to se- allowing unscrupulous employers to cure long-term ‘agreements’ on wages reap a competitive advantage. The for major projects without union or Omnibus Bill proposed in various ways worker consent. to strengthen the Fair Work Act’s compliance and enforcement frame- • Statutory wage-fixing. In recent years, the work. But the Morrison government annual wage reviews conducted by the dropped these reforms, despite strong Fair Work Commission have been one of support for them in the Senate. the very few ways for Australian workers to gain significant wage rises. • Migrant workers. The number of But the minimum wage ‘bite’ (its temporary migrant workers fell relationship to median earnings) re- dramatically during the pandemic, but mains at a historically low level. And will rebound in coming months as the 5
international border is reopened. changes in the economy. But there have Temporary visa holders remain been notable increases in the rates of extremely vulnerable to wage theft. both multiple job-holding and Little has been done to implement underemployment. And casual recommendations of the Migrant employment continues to be overused, Workers’ Taskforce that sought to with far too many workers in this address some of the significant drivers category performing work that is not in of this exploitation. reality temporary, irregular or uncertain. Far from addressing this • Fragmented business structures and problem of ‘permanent casual’ organisational models. Businesses have employment, the Morrison increasingly found ways to avoid government’s legislative reforms have directly employing workers, whether entrenched it. through subcontracting, labour hire or franchising. Such arrangements not In our conclusion to the 2018 book, we set only reduce the chances of workers out a five-point plan to address these being organised and engaging in various concerns. We remain convinced that meaningful collective bargaining, they important and sustainable improvements in can be used to create competition wage growth could be achieved through amongst suppliers that drives down focused, pragmatic action on each of these wages. The same can result from matters: government outsourcing. Little has been done to counter this trend by involving 1. End wage suppression by government lead firms in supply chain or network Governments at all levels should lift bargaining, or by imposing liability for artificial caps on public sector wages, underpayments beyond the employment support decent wage growth in sectors relationship. affected by public funding and procurement, and make lifting wages a • Sham self-employment and freelancing. The central goal of economic policy. proportion of workers who earn their primary income from supplying services 2. Revitalise collective bargaining as an independent contractor has been The rules for the making and approval fairly stable over the past two decades. of enterprise agreements, and for the But that may be about to change, with taking of protected industrial action, two landmark High Court decisions in should be simplified. But it should also February 2022 rewriting the rules on be harder for employers to block determining employment status. It genuine collective bargaining, by should now be much easier for addressing issues concerning organisations to draft contracts that unrepresentative voting cohorts and the present workers as being self-employed, termination of expired agreements. even if in reality there is little to suggest Consideration should be given to they have a business of their own. This allowing industry-level or supply-chain has obvious implications for attempts to bargaining in sectors or situations regulate the burgeoning ‘gig economy’. where there are practical constraints on enterprise-level negotiations. • Other forms of precarious work. Some Competition laws should be reformed to forms of insecure work have not grown enable self-employed workers to engage lately, or have fluctuated according to 6
in effective and meaningful collective 5. Improve compliance with employment bargaining. And governments, tribunals, standards unions and business groups should To help tackle the systemic actively promote a more cooperative underpayment of wages, there should be approach to workplace relations. increased funding for federal and State inspectorates and more severe 3. Strengthen minimum wage regulation sanctions, either in criminal or civil The Fair Work Commission should be form. To strengthen deterrence and empowered to set a ‘living wage’ target, improve compliance with employment and encouraged to place greater weight standards, there should be more on the needs of the low-paid when emphasis on enhancing detection reviewing minmum wages. It should mechanisms, increasing the use of also be required to to look for and administrative sanctions, incapacitating redress the undervaluation of work repeat or egregious wrongdoers, and traditionally or predominantly harnessing the resources and influence performed by women, without needing of key third parties, such as lead firms to identify male benchmarks or and unions. There must also be an comparators. accessible forum for the speedy recovery of backpay. 4. Respond to business models that avoid or outsource employment These proposals will no doubt spark responsibilities dialogue and debate among labour market To protect the integrity of minimum stakeholders, and will require further wage standards, there should be a research and elaboration. But as the statutory definition of employment. This research compiled in this report confirms, should presume anyone who agrees to the wages crisis is a pressing economic and supply their personal labour to be an social issue which demands action. These employee, unless there is clear evidence five initiatives – first advanced in our 2018 they have an independent business of book, but just as timely and important now their own. Lead businesses should also – would represent important steps toward be included in bargaining and held this goal. responsible for underpayments where they exert sufficient influence or control over subsidiary employers in a supply chain or business network. 7
1. Introduction: Wages, Consumers and Recovery For several years, by far the longest-lasting one-sided ‘miss’ in the history of Australian inflation targeting. Australia’s labour market has experienced unusually For all these reasons, concern over the unprecedented and sustained weakness of slow increases in wages. wage growth has been mounting for years. From traditional rates of wage growth of But that concern took on a new urgency as a around 4% per year (sometimes stronger), result of the COVID-19 pandemic, the that pace was cut roughly in half after 2013. subsequent recession, and then economic Nominal wage growth has averaged just recovery. When the economy began to over 2% per year in the nine years since reopen from the extraordinary initial then. This unusually slow pace of income lockdowns, the mantle of economic growth has sparked growing concern in leadership rested squarely on the shoulders several areas of economic policy. It has of the Australian consumer. Impatient to contributed to financial stress among spend after weeks of health restrictions, and households, and constrained consumer with wallets bulging with extra savings spending. It has weakened aggregate accumulated during the lockdowns, economic activity, and undermined the consumers burst from the gate when shops vitality of government revenue flows (from and restaurants opened again – sweeping income taxes and the GST). It has made it the whole national economy along on a giant difficult for monetary policy, led by the shopping spree. Retail sales grew 16% in Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA), to achieve May 2020 in a single month, and double- its target inflation rate. Indeed, from digit gains were maintained as the year went September 2014 through to June 2021, the on. By the end of 2020, total spending for year-over-year inflation rate fell below the the year was up more than 6% from 2019, RBA’s 2.5% target for 27 quarters in a row,1 despite the pandemic. Ironically, for the 1 From Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS), Consumer Price Index. 8
year as a whole, 2020 marked the best the total expansion in real GDP. Household growth in retail sales since 2007 – despite spending on new residences accounted for the unprecedented catastrophe of the another 15%.4 All told, consumers thus pandemic.2 carried 95% of the weight of post-COVID recovery. The resilience and exuberance of Australian consumers contrasted sharply with the Any mechanic knows that an engine can’t relative weakness of other major economic run well on one cylinder. The failure of engines, such as business investment, other critical drivers of economic growth exports, and even public services. (business investment, value-added exports, Continuing uncertainty kept business capital and government services and spending mired at postwar lows. Exports infrastructure) has produced a recovery that deteriorated in the face of global trade is still unbalanced and fragile. And even that disruptions, even as imports poured in to one cylinder, working as hard as it can, meet the booming demands of Australian needs fuel to keep working. Consumers consumers. The result was a big can’t ramp up purchases for long unless deterioration in the trade balance. Even they have growing real spending power to government expenditure on programs and pay the resulting bills. The initial burst of capital was relatively subdued. The huge post-lockdown consumer spending was deficits incurred during the pandemic were powered by pent-up demand, renewed mostly the result of transfer payments to optimism (interrupted by subsequent waves individuals and businesses, through of COVID), and discretionary savings.5 That programs like JobKeeper and the initial burst soon petered out, however, and Coronavirus Supplement to JobSeeker. In retail sales began to slow down. Pent-up contrast, spending on public sector delivery demand dissipated, lockdown savings were and employment grew only modestly, as did spent, and confidence was shaken by new public capital projects.3 COVID variants. Making matters worse, after years of historically slow growth in As a result, consumers accounted for the wages, employment incomes (for those lion’s share of economic growth as the Australians who kept their jobs) grew economy began to recover. In fact, through during the pandemic at the slowest pace yet. the first year of recovery from the initial In the face of all these headwinds, lockdowns (from the June quarter 2020, the Australia’s recovery stumbled. GDP low point of the recession, to the June declined again in the September quarter of quarter of 2021), increased household 2021, before regaining positive ground at the consumer spending accounted for 80% of end of the year.6 2 All data in this section calculated from ABS Retail Trade, Australia. 3Massive government transfer payments played a vital role in sustaining consumer confidence and spending through the pandemic. But the government sector’s own consumption and investment (which shows up directly in GDP) grew just 6% in real terms in the year after the initial lockdowns, compared to the 15% increase in household consumer spending over the same period (data calculated from ABS, Australian National Accounts, Table 2). 4Counting investment in dwellings and related transfer costs; calculations from ABS Australian National Accounts, Table 2. 5Paradoxically, personal savings in Australia increased sharply during the pandemic: partly because restrictions on activity prevented spending, and partly because large government transfer payments more than offset (in aggregate) the decline in employment income. Not all households, of course, increased their savings; many that experienced job loss and/or were excluded from income support programs experienced dis-saving through the pandemic. Data on household savings from ABS Australian National Accounts, Table 20. 6 ABS Australian National Accounts, Table 2. 9
However, the ongoing crisis in wages has suddenly and autonomously adjust to reflect now taken on a new and worrisome accelerating inflation. So years of stagnant dimension, as a result of the sudden nominal wage growth set the stage for the acceleration in consumer price inflation that present decline in real wages – a followed post-lockdown re-opening. This devastating development that will inflict has captured the attention and concern of tangible harm on most Australian households. working Australians and policy-makers alike. After seven straight years of falling For all these reasons, the long-lasting crisis below the RBA target, the rate of CPI in Australian wages has taken on a new inflation has surged since mid-2021, urgency, as the national economy grapples reaching 5.1% year-over-year by the March with the next stages of post-COVID quarter of 2022. There is no evidence that adjustment and recovery. With continued rising prices are the result of wage uncertainty in business investment and pressures. To the contrary, nominal wage exports, Australia’s continued post-COVID growth has remained subdued, in line with recovery will need sustained support from post-2013 rates of growth, despite a decline consumer spending – which, after all, in the official unemployment rate (which accounts for over half of total GDP. Even fell to 4% by March 2022). Rather, the surge prior to the present surge in inflation, in inflation clearly reflects unique factors, Australia needed stronger wage growth to largely external, related to the pandemic validate the consumer spending that has and other global shocks. These include been the dominant source of economic disruptions in supply chains, shortages of recovery. Now, with accelerating post- some products (such as semiconductors and COVID inflation, workers need much higher building supplies), and huge increases in nominal wages just to stand still. energy prices following the Russian invasion In sum, the historic weakness in wages of Ukraine. The implications for wages, which has been experienced for almost a however, are dire: real wages (measured by the ratio of nominal wages to inflation) fell decade poses a fundamental threat to by over 2% in the year to March 2022, and Australia’s future economic and social are poised to fall further in the next year.7 success. Simply hoping that this crisis will somehow be automatically reversed – if About the only silver lining from the only unemployment falls a little bit lower, or previous decade’s gloomy wage trends had deficits are brought under control, or been that consumer price inflation, most business confidence strengthens, or inflation years, had been just as slow as, or even is wrestled back down – hasn’t worked for slower than wages – thus largely preserving nine long years. Confronting and repairing the real purchasing power of wages. With the wages crisis will require a more honest the post-COVID surge in inflation, this is no and direct approach: first, by acknowledging longer true. Real wages have begun to fall, that something has structurally changed in and quickly. And the failure of the labour market to produce any significant real wage Australia’s labour market and wage gains in the preceding nine years has made determination system to explain persistent that reduction in real living standards all the stagnation in wages, and then by designing more painful. Without proactive wage- and implementing strong and proactive boosting policies, there is little reason to policy measures aimed explicitly at getting believe that nominal wage growth will them growing again. 7Data in this section based on calculations from ABS Consumer Price Index, Wage Price Index, and Labour Force, Australia. 10
2. The Aims of this Report: Revisiting In 2018, five years into the weak, despite a lower unemployment rate and supposed labour ‘shortages’ arising in wages slowdown, we some industries, and repeated assurances by convened a workshop of government that stronger wage growth leading scholars and would naturally reappear thanks to the workings of an efficient labour market. Now employment relations the COVID-19 pandemic, in complex ways, practitioners, hosted by the has made matters worse. As the national Adelaide Law School. economy continues to recover, employers, trade unions, regulators, and policy-makers Some 20 contributions were presented confront an uncertain and challenging exploring the varied causes, consequences, employment relations landscape. We thus and possible solutions to the wages crisis. thought it timely and important to revisit the Arising from that workshop, we put together research we organised in the original Wages a compendium of that research, Crisis collection. How has the trajectory of supplemented by additional papers nominal and real wage growth changed commissioned afterwards. This work was since the original publication of that work? published by the University of Adelaide Is there reason to believe the wages crisis Press under the title The Wages Crisis in will solve itself? And what policy responses Australia: What it is and what to do about it, are most appropriate and promising, in and made available open-access on the order to restore normal wage benchmarks internet (Stewart, Stanford and Hardy and achieve a more desirable and 2018).8 sustainable income distribution in Four years later, the wages crisis is still with Australia’s economy? us. Wage growth has remained historically 8 See www.adelaide.edu.au/press/titles/wages-crisis. 11
To that end this report, The Wages Crisis: Section 6 revisits several of the policy Revisited, aims to update our findings from decisions and regulatory failures that were the 2018 workshop and book, and place them identified in the 2018 book as having in the context of Australia’s post-COVID contributed to the sustained slowdown in recovery. The report is organised as follows. wages. It considers what has happened (or Section 3 provides a comprehensive in many instances not happened) in relation empirical review of the course of Australia’s to collective bargaining, the setting of wages, including a detailed analysis of wage minimum wages, gender pay inequities, changes during the initial lockdowns and wage underpayments, and the treatment of subsequent recovery. It confirms that migrant workers. It also examines the nominal wages have demonstrated a weaker failure of governments to respond to the use structural tendency since 2013, growing of ‘fragmented’ business structures that consistently slower than would be expected distance workers from the businesses which given labour market conditions, inflation, ultimately profit from their labour, the monetary policy, and productivity trends. potential growth of ‘sham contracting’ This has produced stagnant (and now, arrangements that deprive workers of declining) real wages, consistent employment rights and protections, and disinflationary pressures, and a decline in other forms of precarious work, such as the labour’s share of GDP and total factor ‘permanent casual’ jobs which have become income. such an entrenched feature of Australia’s labour market. Section 4 considers appropriate benchmarks for normal expected wage growth, to set a Finally, in Section 7 we revisit and update broad context for future wage-boosting five key policy proposals that we outlined in policies. Section 5 queries whether the 2018 as having the potential to revitalise economic and distributional consequences wage growth to more normal and healthy of wage stagnation can be corrected by tax levels. We conclude by calling on all cuts, aimed at enhancing disposable income stakeholders in Australian employment within the constraint of flat pre-tax relations to place top priority on targeted, incomes. The evidence is clear: tax cuts proactive measures to strengthen wage cannot offset the damage done by sub-par growth, as Australia’s economy traverses wage growth. the next stages of its post-pandemic recovery. 12
3. Charting the Wages Crisis This section of the report index (WPI), calculated quarterly by the ABS. The WPI aims to provide a measure of provides a range of ‘pure’ wage inflation. By controlling for empirical data on the changes in the composition of employment slowdown in nominal wage (such as shifts in occupation, industry, or job status), it attempts to capture pure inflation growth that has been in wages (paid to a fixed basket of experienced in Australia illustrative workers). Because of this since 2013. methodology, the WPI may misportray trends in actual realised labour incomes. For By several different measures, nominal example, if the composition of employment wage trajectories experienced a structural is shifting toward lower-wage industries, break, shifting on a sustained basis to occupations, or job statuses (such as part- average annual growth rates about half the time, casual, and other forms of insecure typical pace experienced prior to 2013. The work), then the WPI is likely to overstate implications of this slowdown for other growth in realised labour incomes. On the related economic variables – including unit other hand, if job quality is improving (with labour costs, national income distribution, a shift toward higher-paid and more secure and inflation – are also described. roles), then the WPI will underestimate improvements in received labour compensation.9 3.1 Indicators of wage growth Figure 1 illustrates the trend in WPI growth The most commonly reported measure of (measured on a year-over-year basis, sea- wage growth in Australia is the wage price 9This methodological aspect of the WPI is important to keep in mind when analysing changes in wages during the COVID-19 pandemic, as described below. 13
sonally adjusted) since the turn of the cen- occurred around 2013. From 2000 through tury. Nominal wages (adjusted for employ- 2013, WPI growth averaged 3.7% per year. ment composition) grew at an average of Since then it has averaged 2.1% per year. 3.7% per year through the first years of the This bifurcation of wage trends is visible in 21st Century – and in some years faster than other indicators as well, as discussed further 4%. This pattern was interrupted by a sharp below. but temporary deceleration during the global financial crisis (GFC) of 2008–09, Figure 2. when wage growth slowed to 3%; but wages Wage growth by sector, 2000-2021 then quickly recovered to pre-crisis rates of increase. After 2013, however, wage growth slowed more dramatically and persistently. Year-over-year WPI increases fell to 2% by 2016–17. Nominal wage growth picked up slightly after that (reaching 2.35% by late 2018), but then declined sharply again dur- ing the COVID-19 pandemic and resulting recession. Wage growth fell to 1.36% year over year (and less than 1% on an annu- alised quarter-to-quarter basis) in mid-2020. After the initial reopening (inter- Source: Calculations from ABS Wage Price Index, Table 1 rupted by the Delta and Omicron waves), WPI growth recovered to its pre-pandemic WPI data is also available by industry and pace (just above 2%), but remained well be- sector. We consider industry-level trends low normal pre-2013 patterns. further below. Figure 2 compares wage trends in private sector and public sector Figure 1. workplaces. In general, nominal wage Wage price index, 2000-2021 growth was weaker in the private sector throughout the entire period since 2000, and the deceleration of private sector wage growth after 2013 clearly preceded a subsequent slowdown in public sector wages. This is consistent with the institutional and political reality of wage determination in public sector settings. Governments at all levels have pointed to weak wage trends in the private sector as justification for the imposition of wage caps and other forms of compensation restraint Source: Calculations from ABS Wage Price Index, Table 1 in public sector workplaces, as discussed below in section 6.4. By 2021, however, Figure 1 suggests a clear structural break in wages were growing even more slowly in the pattern of nominal wage growth that the public sector than in the private sector.10 10 A similar but temporary pattern was visible in 2012–13, when governments (grappling with deficits in the wake of the GFC) imposed wage restraint in public sector compensation – just as private sector wage growth was recovering from its previous but temporary downturn. See Henderson (2018) for more discussion of the impact of this post-GFC public sector wage restraint on the subsequent path of broader wage growth. 14
In addition to the WPI, several other 4.4%. That is faster than the average growth measures of wage growth are published by of the WPI over that same period (3.7%), the ABS, using different methodologies. indicating wage-boosting shifts in These measures more directly capture employment composition (toward higher- realised changes in labour incomes, since paying industries and better jobs) during they do not attempt to control for changes in that period, as well as strength in the composition of employment (as does the supplemental compensation (such as WPI). For example, the ABS series on overtime and bonus payments). The average weekly earnings (AWE) provides subsequent deceleration in average weekly semi-annual data on realised earnings by wages after 2013 was initially more severe industry, and for different categories of than the decline in the corresponding WPI workers and compensation. Trends in this measure. Growth in AWE fell to barely 1% series will reflect both ‘pure’ wage inflation, by 2015. This suggests that coincident with and the impact on wages of changes in the the slowdown in pure wage inflation after composition of employment (such as 2013, realised wage incomes were also increases or decreases in the proportion of suppressed by a shift toward part-time, part-time and casual employment). The casual, and lower-paid jobs. A partial year-over-year growth in AWE for all recovery in the growth of average weekly workers is illustrated in Figure 3. wages was experienced in 2018 and 2019, Figure 3. reflecting some incremental improvements Average weekly earnings, in average job quality. 2000-2021 Then, with the onset of the COVID-19 pandemic, average weekly wages suddenly jumped by over 5% (on a year-over-year basis). This was due to a shock in the composition of employment during the initial lockdowns. Because lower-paid part- time and casual workers bore a disproportionate share of job losses, the average wage for those who remained employed shifted upward.11 However, once the economy reopened and those lower- Source: Calculations from ABS Average Weekly Earnings (annual wage workers (in generally insecure jobs) averages) were rehired, the average weekly wage fell. The AWE series is more volatile than the Despite this volatility during the pandemic, WPI, in part because it reflects changes in the trend in AWE confirms the post-2013 employment composition, overtime structural shift in wage patterns. In fact, by earnings, bonuses, and other factors that are this measure that shift was more severe filtered from the WPI’s measure of narrow (with a 2.2 percentage point deceleration in wage inflation. But the trend in AWE is average annual wage growth) than similar to the bifurcated pattern evident in according to the WPI series (1.6 percentage the WPI series. From 2000 through 2013, points). AWE grew at an annual average rate of 11The impact of the COVID-19 pandemic on nominal and real wage growth will be considered in further detail below, and is also documented by Stanford (2021). 15
Another useful measure of wage trends can annual average rate of 4%. Again, this is be derived from the ABS’s quarterly faster than the average growth in the WPI national income statistics. In the course of during this period, reflecting the impact of measuring GDP by income, the ABS tallies wage-boosting changes in employment total labour compensation accruing to composition (excluded by design from the employees. This can be compared to the WPI). A shortlived slowdown in average number of employees working each quarter compensation per employee during the GFC to generate a measure of average was quickly reversed, and compensation compensation per worker.12 This series rebounded during the subsequent two years shows even more dramatic fluctuations, due at a robust rate (over 5%). Growth in to changes in its various (separately average compensation then fell sharply after measured) components (see Figure 4). Since 2013, to just 2% on average from 2013 it portrays aggregate employee through 2021. A spike in compensation compensation for all jobs, it captures the growth in the initial COVID lockdowns (for impact of changes in employment similar compositional reasons as described composition and job quality (similar to the above for AWE) was quickly reversed as the series on AWE). A shift toward more part- economy reopened. Again, this series time employment, for example, obviously confirms that nominal compensation growth reduces compensation per employee – both for Australian employees was halved after because of the fewer hours worked by part- 2013: from 4% per year in 2000–2013, to 2% timers, and the lower hourly wages paid. per year since then. Figure 4. Workers covered by a collective agreement Average labour compensation fared better during the post-2013 wage per employee, 2000-2021 slowdown,13 although a lasting deceleration of wage growth is also clearly visible in negotiated wage increases. Figure 5 illustrates annualised average wage increases (AAWI) in federally-registered enterprise agreements.14 The black line shows the average across all current enterprise agreements (that is, those which have neither expired nor been terminated); the red line shows the average in newly approved agreements. Since 2013 average Source: Calculations from ABS National Accounts, Table 24 wage gains in newly approved deals usually (annual averages) fell below the average for all current Over the 2000–2013 period, nominal agreements, hence pulling down the overall compensation per employee increased at an AAWI (as newly approved agreements, with 12This series, appropriately, considers only waged employees, not self-employed workers whose income is accounted for in GDP statistics as mixed income. 13As discussed below in section 6.1, the share of workers covered by a current enterprise agreement has declined rapidly since 2013, and the erosion of collective bargaining has certainly been an important factor in the overall wage slowdown. Kylon (2018) discussed this issue in our initial collection. 14Figure 5 excludes non-quantifiable wage provisions (such as those tied to CPI or minimum wage changes) and enterprise agreements regulated by State governments (primarily State-level public service agreements in States other than Victoria). 16
Figure 5. enterprise agreements have fared somewhat Wage gains in enterprise agreements, better – but there, too, average wage growth 2000-2021 is slipping steadily. Table 1 summarises the broad averages for these four wage indicators across the two sub-periods of our analysis. The ABS initiated its WPI series in 1997, and hence it does not permit a longer-term view of the evolution of wage trends. However, other ABS series are available over longer time periods, and they confirm that the sustained post-2013 slowdown in nominal Source: Attorney-General’s Department, Trends in Federal wage growth has been historically unique. Enterprise Bargaining (federally registered agreements only) For example, AWE data is available in various formats dating back to 1949.15 From lower wage increments, gradually replace that point through 1990, AWE in Australia older expired agreements). From average grew at an average annual rate of almost 9% wage gains of 4% in the latter 2000s, wage – and even faster during the 1970s (13% per increases in enterprise agreements have year). In 1992, in the wake of a painful slowly flattened, reaching 2.6% in 2020 and recession and deliberate wage restraint 2021. As with the WPI, negotiated wage measures, annual wage growth temporarily gains have generally been slightly stronger for public Table 1. sector deals (which now Indicators of wage growth, Australia, 2020-2021 account for over one-third of 2000-2013 2013-2021 Change all enterprise agreement- (%/yr) (%/yr) (%pts) covered workers in WPI 3.65% 2.11% -1.54% Australia). In 2020 and 2021, AWE 4.36% 2.17% -2.19% however, public sector wage gains fell below private sector Compensation per employee 4.03% 2.03% -2.00% trends due to wage caps and Average wage gains in 3.87% 3.01% -0.86% other restraints imposed by enterprise agreements federal, State and Territory Source: Calculations from ABS Wage Price Index, Average Weekly Earnings, and National governments. Accounts; Attorney-General’s Department, Trends in Federal Enterprise Bargaining According to all four of these indicators, slowed to below 1% – but wages quickly therefore, Australia experienced a marked rebounded as the economy recovered, deceleration of nominal wage growth that recovering to 4% by 1994. The ABS’s began around 2013. From average annual average compensation per employee rates of around 4% (and sometimes higher), measure extends back to 1978. From 1978 wage growth fell by about half: to around 2% through 2000 that indicator of on average since 2013. Workers covered by compensation grew at an annual average 15A composite historical series on average weekly earnings can be assembled from several overlapping sources, including the ABS Average Weekly Earnings series (which dates back to 1994, with a series break in 2012); previous ABS series 6302.0, 6304.0, and 6350.0; and historical data from the RBA (1997). 17
rate of 6.2%. Both these longer-term series is volatile, driven mostly by empirical series confirm therefore that the significantly changes in estimated post-2013 wage slowdown has been by far productivity (which itself is a ratio of the most severe and sustained in the entire separate estimates of total output and total postwar era. employment). Nominal unit labour costs are a useful measure of the underlying inflationary 3.2 Other measures of labour pressure arising from labour costs (which costs are the most important single cost of In addition to the four direct measures of production in most industries, and in the wage compensation reviewed above, other economy as a whole). In general, nominal indicators further confirm the sustained unit labour costs should increase at deceleration of wage growth and labour approximately the same pace as the Reserve costs after 2013. The ABS national accounts Bank’s inflation target (2.5%), thus system reports changes in nominal labour providing an underlying foundation for costs for employers (including inflation at the desired pace. In the first superannuation and other employment- portion of Figure 6, covering the 2000–13 related expenses), adjusted for changes in period, nominal unit labour costs grew at an the productivity of workers. This ratio is average pace very close to target inflation defined as the unit labour cost, and indicates (2.8% per year). That fell within the RBA’s how labour costs are changing relative to target band.16 Not coincidentally, overall the value of output. It is thus an important CPI inflation in this period followed a indicator of the impact of wage changes on similar trend, with consumer prices also overall production costs, prices, and factor rising 2.8% per year on average. After the income shares. Figure 6 illustrates the year- post-2013 deceleration in nominal wage over-year growth in nominal unit labour growth, however, nominal unit labour costs costs, as reported quarterly by the ABS. The slowed to less than half that pace: rising at just 1.3% per year, barely half of the RBA’s Figure 6. inflation target and well below its band. CPI Nominal unit labour cost, inflation in Australia also fell below the 2000-2021 RBA’s target range for most of this period, averaging 1.8% per year from 2013 through 2021. The RBA has indicated that the unusually slow growth of wages and nominal labour costs has been a major barrier to its efforts to achieve the desired 2.5% inflation target (Lowe 2018). Figure 6 reveals the sharp fluctuations in nominal unit labour costs that were experienced during the COVID-19 pandemic. Initially unit labour costs fell Source: Calculations from ABS National Accounts, Table 42 (annual averages) dramatically – in large part due to the effect 16The RBA tries to keep inflation within one-half percentage point either direction of its 2.5% target – in other words, between 2% and 3% per year. 18
of powerful wage subsidies (through the As indicated in Figure 7, real unit labour JobKeeper program) offered by government costs have declined steadily through most of to encourage employers to retain employees the last two decades. Even before the who were not needed in light of health deceleration in nominal wages after 2013, restrictions on many businesses. Nominal real wages were already increasing more unit costs then bounced back rapidly with slowly than real labour productivity. Real economic reopening and the cancellation of unit labour costs flattened for several years those subsidies. Considered over the whole after the GFC in 2008–09 – mostly because period of the pandemic, however, nominal of a reduction in productivity growth unit labour costs have increased at the following the 2009 economic slowdown. But restrained, pre-pandemic pace. They grew real unit labour costs declined again in the at an annual average rate of 1.75% from the latter half of the 2010s, and even further end of 2019 through the end of 2021 – still during the COVID-19 crisis. Real unit labour below the RBA’s target band. There is no costs first dropped steeply during the initial evidence in the pattern of nominal unit COVID lockdowns (reduced again by labour costs, therefore, that the current JobKeeper subsidies), and then partially surge in consumer prices can be attributed rebounded as the economy reopened. By the to labour costs – which have clearly lagged, end of 2021 they had settled at a level not led, the acceleration of inflation. significantly below their pre-pandemic starting point.18 By late 2021 real unit labour Another perspective on labour costs is costs were 10% lower than at the turn of the provided by ABS data on real unit labour century. This continues a longer-run decline costs. This series adjusts both wages and in real unit labour costs (and labour’s share productivity for changes in prices, and thus of total output) that dates back to the 1970s. provides an indicator of both inflation pressures and distributional trends. If real Figure 7. wages are growing more slowly than real Real unit labour cost, 2000-2021 labour productivity on average, then real unit labour costs will decline. This implies a decline in the labour share of total output.17 That creates economic space for increased profits, even without changes in the rate of inflation. Similarly, if real wages grow faster than real labour productivity, then real unit labour costs increase, labour’s share of total output increases, and firms may feel pressure to increase prices (to protect profit margins). Source: ABS National Accounts, Table 42 17Indeed, when measured in percentage terms (rather than as an index, as in Figure 7), real unit labour cost is equivalent to the labour share of output. 18 The sharp swings in both nominal and real unit labour costs during the pandemic also reflected big changes in recorded labour productivity. Apparent labour productivity increased significantly during the lockdowns (because a disproportionate share of job losses were initially experienced in low-productivity service industries like retail and hospitality), and then declined as economic activity recovered after re-opening (see ABS Australian National Accounts, Table 24). That produced an initial decline in both nominal and real labour costs, reversed when the economy re-opened. 19
If real labour productivity is growing faster The labour share then declined again with than real wages (and hence real unit labour the COVID-19 pandemic and resulting costs are declining), this implies an erosion recession: partly because labour in the share of total national output received compensation weakened (due to reduced in the form of labour compensation employment), and partly because corporate (including wages, salaries, superannuation, profits increased strongly during the and other forms of compensation). This is pandemic. The labour share hit post-war confirmed by separate ABS data on the record lows during the pandemic. distribution of national income between factors of production. It shows a sustained redistribution of income away from labour toward capital. As illustrated in Figure 8, 3.3 Wages and labour market labour’s share of total factor income in the conditions economy19 has declined markedly since the Evolving wage trends are commonly mid-1970s, falling by about 12 percentage attributed to changes in supply and demand points of the total (from 62% to just 50% by conditions in the labour market. If there is 2021). not enough labour demand arising from employers, and willing workers are unable Figure 8. to find work, then wages will supposedly Labour share of factor income, moderate to facilitate a better balance 1975-2021 between supply and demand. The reverse should be true if labour demand is strong and unemployment is low. This conventional understanding views the labour market as essentially similar to markets for other commodities: competitive forces should cause price adjustments (in this case, changes to the price of labour) that push the market toward equilibrium. Unfortunately, however, conventional Source: ABS National Accounts, Table 24 supply-and-demand analysis does not shed much light on the visible deceleration in The labour share of total factor income wage growth in Australia that occurred after depends not only on trends in wages, but 2013. Broad macroeconomic and labour also on returns to other factors – most market conditions did not differ notably profits on capital. The decline in significantly across the two periods profitability of some Australian industries considered in our analysis. Yes, Australia following the 2014 downturn in global experienced a significant recession (its first commodity prices temporarily boosted the in three decades) in 2020 during the labour share in subsequent years. That was COVID-19 pandemic. But the employment reversed as corporate profits recovered. recovery after the lockdowns ended was 19 Factor income equals the sum of income received by factors of production (labour and capital). It equals GDP less indirect taxes net of subsidies on production and imports. Capital income includes operating surpluses for incorporated businesses, and a share of the mixed income of unincorporated businesses (held to reflect return to proprietors’ capital, rather than their work). 20
swift. And Australia had also experienced a Curve relationship was imperfect, and major slowdown and near-recession during explained only a small portion of wage the previous period (namely, the 2008–09 growth. Even when unemployment was GFC), with negative but temporary effects high, for example, nominal wage growth on wage growth. On average, never fell below 3%. macroeconomic indicators differ little between the two periods defined above. Figure 9. Average unemployment was only slightly Wage growth and unemployment, higher across the 2013–2021 period (5.7%) 2000-2021 than in the preceding dozen years (5.4%).20 It seems doubtful that the historic deceleration in wages after 2013 can be blamed on a change in supply and demand balances in the labour market. The case for a structural shift in wage determination patterns after 2013 is strengthened by an analysis of the relationship between nominal wage growth and unemployment. In the conventional ‘Phillips Curve’ understanding, there should Source: Calculations from ABS Wage Price Index, Table 1, and be a predictable negative relationship Labour Force, Table 1 between the two: lower unemployment leads to faster nominal wage growth, and vice After 2013, however, this Phillips Curve versa. Monetary policy is informed by this shifted downward (so that wage growth was understanding, with the goal (in an inflation lower at all levels of unemployment) and targeting regime) being to keep lost all of its explanatory power (as unemployment at or above a rate (the Non- indicated by the red line of Figure 9). In Accelerating Inflation Rate of fact, were it not for a single observation Unemployment, or NAIRU) consistent with associated with COVID lockdowns (2020), stable inflation at or near the central bank’s the relationship between wage growth and target.21 Comparing unemployment rates unemployment has been perversely positive and wage inflation (measured by yearly since 2013: in other words, lower average WPI growth) in the 2000–2012 unemployment was generally associated period indicates a modest Phillips-type with slower wage growth during this period. relationship (indicated by the blue line in So while reducing unemployment remains a Figure 9). Wage growth was somewhat vital economic and social priority, this stronger in the latter 2000s (up until the evidence suggests that Australians cannot GFC), when unemployment was at or below rely on tightening labour markets alone to 5%. Wage growth was somewhat lower in solve the wages crisis. More direct most years when the unemployment rate measures are necessary to strengthen wage exceeded 6% (particularly in the early growth, regardless of prevailing 2000s). Even before 2013, this Phillips unemployment levels. 20 Calculations from ABS Labour Force, Australia. 21See Richardson (2019) for a theoretical and empirical critique of the conventional NAIRU model as practiced in Australia. 21
Some researchers (such as Lewis 2017, 3%. But after 2013 the curve shifts Eslake 2021, and Jericho 2022a) have downward (so that wage growth is suggested that the traditional unemployment significantly slower for any given utilisation rate is no longer an accurate indicator of the rate than in the earlier period), and loses true state of overall labour market slack. much of its predictive power.22 Changes in working arrangements have produced other pools of underutilised We believe the longer-term increase in labour that are not captured in the underemployment in Australia is indeed conventional unemployment rate – such as relevant to the slowdown in wage growth, individuals who are employed but working albeit for reasons that differ from the fewer hours than preferred (known as conventional conception of underemployment). The ABS generates a underemployment as an indicator of supply- broader alternative measure of demand imbalance. Most underemployment underutilisation which includes both is experienced by individuals in non- unemployment and underemployment. It is standard and generally quite insecure work plotted against annual WPI growth in Figure arrangements: including casual jobs, part- 10. time roles, and precarious forms of self- employment (especially unincorporated Figure 10. own-account small businesses, in which the Wage growth and underutilisation, proprietor has no employees). Few 2000-2021 individuals in conventional full-time permanent positions report they would like to work more hours (hence being considered underemployed), and they account for only a small share of total underemployment. In this context, underemployment may be more relevant as an indicator of employment precarity, rather than supply-demand imbalance; this conclusion is reinforced by the fact that underemployment has increased steadily over recent decades, largely regardless of Source: Calculations from ABS Wage Price Index, Table 1, and Labour Force, Table 22 the cyclical condition of the macroeconomy.23 Workers in casual, part- This figure also suggests a structural break time, and other non-standard positions are in wage determination after 2013. Until then, typically anxious to work more hours, but a stronger negative relationship between they face continuing insecurity in their wage growth and underutilisation is visible employment tenure; this undermines their – although even at the highest bargaining power in seeking higher wages. underutilisation experienced before 2013 In this context, even the weak relationship (over 13%) wage growth never fell below between underutilisation and wage growth 22Again, the outlying observation for 2020 (when underutilisation was very high due to JobKeeper subsidies and other measures which kept workers on the payroll even with sharp reductions in hours worked) imparts much of the apparent Phillips-type trend to the data during the post-2013 period. 23 Figure 21, in section 6.9 of this report, illustrates this secular rise in underemployment. 22
You can also read