The social construction of scarcity. The case of water in

Page created by Hazel Contreras
 
CONTINUE READING
Ecological Economics 34 (2000) 233 – 245
                                                                                                  www.elsevier.com/locate/ecolecon

                                                    SPECIAL ISSUE

                SOCIAL PROCESSES OF ENVIRONMENTAL VALUATION

    The social construction of scarcity. The case of water in
                  Tenerife (Canary Islands)
  Federico Aguilera-Klink *,1, Eduardo Pérez-Moriana 2, Juan Sánchez-Garcı́a
  Department of Applied Economics, Uni6ersity of La Laguna, Campus Guajara, Camino La Hornera s/n, 38071 La Laguna,
                                              Tenerife, Canary Islands, Spain

Abstract

  Water has traditionally been considered a physically scarce resource in the Canary Islands. Paradoxically, one of
the reasons behind the conquest of the Islands in the 15th century was the existence of abundant water which allowed
sugar to be grown in Tenerife and Gran Canaria. This article aims to show that the water scarcity in Tenerife is not
physical or natural, but rather a socially constructed one, stemming from a set of social processes that reflect the
conflicts concerning the desirable kind of society and social order. These processes also consolidate the notion of
aquifer and water as a capital asset and commodity, as opposed to the notion of water as an ecosocial asset or
common property. The change in mentality with respect to water momentarily led to abundance, with availability
multiplying tenfold in less than a century and, at the same time, to the social construction of scarcity, given that the
groundwater aquifer was overexploited rapidly because successive changes in the institutional framework were
impeded which might have regulated water extraction. The overriding concern was to maintain private ownership of
water, even if this entailed eventual exhaustion. We study water shortage as the result of the articulation between the
natural system (aquifer) and the social system. © 2000 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Water management; Social scarcity; Environmental valuation

  
    The support of the funding received from DG XII of the European Commission under contract ENV4-CT96-0226 for the
project entitled ‘Social Processes for Environmental Valuation: Procedures and Institutions for Social Valuations of Natural Capital
in Environmental Conservation and Sustainability Policy (VALSE)’ is gratefully acknowledged, as are the helpful comments of
Martin O’Connor and the three journal referees.
  * Corresponding author. Tel.: + 34-922-317012/13; fax: +34-922-253742.
  E-mail address: faguiler@ull.es (F. Aguilera-Klink).
  1
    Second E-mail address: jusangar@ull.es.
  2
    Research assistant during the VALSE project.

0921-8009/00/$ - see front matter © 2000 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
PII: S 0 9 2 1 - 8 0 0 9 ( 0 0 ) 0 0 1 6 0 - 9
234                        F. Aguilera-Klink et al. / Ecological Economics 34 (2000) 233–245

1. Introduction                                               society understands and accepts as a socially ade-
                                                              quate solution.
   It is customary for social scientists to speak of             In the case of Tenerife we endeavour to show
natural resource shortage, which is self-evident if           that, as compared to the widespread and widely-
one acknowledges that we live in a finite world.              accepted notion of the physical scarcity of water,
For this reason, the approach we take seeks to                the notion of socially constructed scarcity is more
study and understand shortage not as a physical               relevant and has greater explanatory power. To
statistic or as a point of departure, but rather as           do so, we will examine the social processes that
the result of the articulation between the physical           have led to the creation of this type of scarcity. In
and social systems, i.e. an arrival point. This               the first part of the paper, we show the existence
articulation can be understood in terms of coevo-             of a constant social conflict over distribution,
lution (Norgaard, 1984), although it should be                arising out of the criteria used to appropriate and
noted that little mention has been made of the                then distribute surface water. These criteria fa-
fact that coevolution and coevolutionary develop-             voured in particular those with some degree of
ment are not the same thing. Whereas coevolution              power, who from the 18th century onwards took
can lead to a more artificial and vulnerable physi-           for themselves public and communal water, and
cal (and by extension social) system, coevolution-            went unpunished in the process. In the second
ary development would require constant and real               part we examine the process of the privatisation
institutional change, one that translates into a              and exploitation of groundwater. This was done
change in attitudes (thinking habits) and in con-             using the ‘catchment’ rule and at the expense of
ducts regarding the withdrawal, distribution and              rapid exhaustion of surface water, so much so
use of water which would enable the social system             that the documents from the 19th century speak
to be maintained and make it compatible with the              literally of drilling ‘fever’. Thirdly, we look at the
physical system.                                              uncontrolled drilling of underground aquifers, a
   Both options implicitly bring out the kind of              process carried out under the formal umbrella of
questions that need to be addressed if we are to              numerous Water Laws, which in practice merely
understand the articulation between the two sys-              sought to ensure that private ownership was
tems. More specifically, in the case of the subject           maintained. This was not always the result given
under discussion here (water), we need to examine             that more recognition was given to withdrawal
in greater depth, among other issues, the under-              rights than to the groundwater aquifer’s recharge
standing of the social processes related to the               and accumulation capacity. Although it is true
perception of the causes of scarcity; the forms of            that groundwater availability did increase enor-
participation in the determination of the criteria            mously, it was at the expense of a multiplication
and institutions for water appropriation and use;             of the number of drillings (many of which hardly
the distribution conflicts generated by the forego-           produced water), more expensive withdrawal
ing; knowledge of how the hydrologic cycle func-              (competitive rather than cooperative drilling, due
tions; the role of technologies which reduce water            to an intensification of the catchment rule) and
scarcity; and the capacity to evaluate the implicit           the continued depletion of the aquifer. Lastly, we
technological risks of said technologies (such as             examine the importance of the valuation of the
where desalination of brackish water from the sea             social processes which form the notions of water
allows more sea water to enter and deteriorate                and water scarcity in order to complete the water
aquifers), etc. These are questions related in part           valuation exercise.
to scientific and technological knowledge and
partly also to power, that is, the social conflict
between the values and interests at stake, how this           2. Tenerife water resources: the case study
conflict is addressed by society and how society,
in reaching a consensus, defines which problem is               Tenerife (Canary Islands) is a very mountain-
socially and politically relevant and, lastly, what           ous island of volcanic origin, with recent erup-
F. Aguilera-Klink et al. / Ecological Economics 34 (2000) 233–245                    235

tions (early this century). In spite of its small size              sea); horizontal rain, generated by trade-winds
(2034 km2), it has a wide variety of local climates                 in contact with vegetation (however, the true
which make for enormous variations in rainfall                      amount involved does not figure in the water
(from 100 mm on the south coast to over 900 mm                      balances because there is no precise evaluation
in the highest northern and northeastern parts)                     methodology); desalination of sea-water with
and the resulting difficulties in calculating the true              fossil energy; purification of urban waste water
amount that filters down to the aquifer. Indeed,                    for agricultural use.
experts from the Tenerife Water Council are just                “   The extraction of underground water. This is
now beginning to admit that the data used to                        done using wells and galleries (which are hori-
determine water balances are rather hazy as re-                     zontal, although slightly sloped to allow grav-
gards the levels of evapotranspiration and infiltra-                ity outlet of the water), or a combination of
tion, as can be seen in Table 1. In just 5 years, the               both, such as when a horizontal gallery is
calculations have had to be corrected by around                     constructed at the bottom of wells. To give an
50%. Doubts also surround the amount of water                       idea of the type of drilling, conventional gal-
withdrawn from the aquifer. The reason is that                      leries usually measure 3 km on average, but
private water owners are against the Canarian                       many are in fact over 5 km long. The most
government’s plans to fit meters to measure with-                   productive wells are between 170 and 300 m.
drawal directly and the authorities are not strong                  Tenerife is riddled with over a thousand hori-
enough to enforce a mandatory meter scheme.                         zontal galleries, totalling between them some
   Tenerife’s current hydrologic system is made up                  1620 km, and over 400 wells with a combined
of a groundwater aquifer which is the remains of                    depth of approximately 52 km.
a broader — surface and groundwater — system                    “   The distribution of water. The main feature of
that was ruined by constant overexploitation dur-                   the distribution networks, both agricultural
ing the last century and the present one. Usable                    and urban, is their extensive deterioration (with
recharge — the sum of natural infiltration plus                     some exceptions, such as the capital, Santa
irrigation returns less natural coastal underground                 Cruz de Tenerife), which causes considerable
run off — is less than the volume of withdrawals.                   water loss, in some cases over 50% of the
Hence, withdrawals more or less eat into reserves                   amount actually distributed.
and gradually lower the water table. The immedi-                “   Uses of water. Farming is the biggest consumer
ate result is a reduction in the volume of water                    of water, accounting for over 50% of the total
strikes (Tenerife Water Plan, 1993).                                (109.2 Hm3 in 1991). Agriculture is a vital
   In Tenerife, the following phases in the hydro-                  sector both in terms of its repercussions on the
logic ‘cycle’ can be discerned:                                     land and its cultural connotations. 46 000 Ha
“ Contributions to the aquifer. These include the                   are devoted to farming land, taken up for the
    following direct and indirect sources: vertical                 most part by irrigation crops for export (ba-
    rain (some of which filters down into the                       nana and tomatoes mainly). These crops ac-
    aquifer, some evaporates and some reaches the                   count for over 50% of cropland. Household use
                                                                    accounts for 30% (62.7 Hm3 in 1991), while
Table 1                                                             water consumption in the tourist areas is less
Water balance HM3/YRa
                                                                    than 10% of the total (14.1 Hm3) (Tenerife
Year                           1993              1998               Water Plan, 1993). While water consumption
                                                                    by the farm sector has been falling of late (due
Rain                            865                865              to the low financial return of farming com-
Evapotranspiration              606                480              pared to other activities and, secondly, the
Infiltration                    239                365
                                                                    introduction of water-saving technologies in
Runoff                           20                 20
                                                                    new irrigation systems), both household con-
  a
    Source: Tenerife Water Plan, 1993 and 1999 (personal            sumption (due to population growth) and that
communication).                                                     of the tourist areas (rise in the number of
236                              F. Aguilera-Klink et al. / Ecological Economics 34 (2000) 233–245

Table 2                                                             rural minority allowed it to control (nominate)
Water consumption in Tenerife, Projection 2000a
                                                                    political offices. However, for this ‘social order’ to
Consumption              Year 2000             Variation (%)        be maintained, social cohesion mechanisms (or
                                               1991–2000            cushioning) were needed, first and foremost
                                                                    among them common and public ownership of
                         Hm3     (%)                                water and land. Hence, although after the con-
                                                                    quest of the Canaries (15th century) the Spanish
Non used resources         2.6          1.21       −42.22
                                                                    Crown distributed and granted (for private use
Losses in water           11.1          5.16       −3.48            but without private ownership) water and land,
  transfers                                                         both with restrictions, a large proportion of these
Agricultural use          96.8         44.96       −11.36           waters and lands were common and public
                                                                    heritage.
Urban use                 69.6         32.33         11.00
                                                                       As is well known, although this property for-
Tourism use               23.4         10.87         65.96          mat allowed the Ancien Regime to be maintained,
                                                                    it satisfied neither rich nor poor. It curtailed the
Industrial use            11.8          5.48        122.64          possibilities of the former to open new mercantile
                                                                    activities and obtain greater profits — which were
Total                    215.3   10 000               3.86          restricted because of the limited availability of the
  a
                                                                    different types of property — and it imposed
      Source: Tenerife Water Plan (1993).
                                                                    difficult living conditions on the latter, in spite of
                                                                    the existence of this more common form of
   holidaymakers) have increased in recent years.                   ownership.
   The consumption levels forecast for the year                        It was against this backdrop that the ideas of
   2000 by Tenerife’s Water Plan point to a con-                    the Enlightenment gained ground. These may be
   siderable rise in urban and tourism use (Table                   summed up as the glorification of private interests
   2):                                                              as the sole motor and destiny of all economic
  The resident population in 1996 was some                          activity and the need for unrestricted competition
690 000, to which one has to add the 2 993 084                      by economic and social agents as the most ade-
tourists who between them spent over 25 million                     quate form of allocating resources to social neces-
nights on the island.                                               sities. The application of these ideas required
                                                                    institutional change, a break with the previous
                                                                    institutional framework, and necessitated also the
3. Appropriation and distribution of surface                        shaping of content for a new one which would
water. Social conflicts and the strengthening of                    allow free trade to enable the country to progress.
the idea of private property                                        Here ‘progress’ means using (for crops) the lands
                                                                    and waters not used commercially (common prop-
  For a proper understanding of the process of                      erty) or in the hands of the church, and at the
the social construction of scarcity, one first must                 same time making available to the State an impor-
outline the historical context to show how current                  tant source of finance for public spending. For its
values and interests have been shaped. The con-                     part, nature was viewed as a capital asset avail-
text which, without any doubt, has conditioned                      able for human exploitation (Harvey, 1996).
water problems in the Canaries was Spanish soci-                       In the case of the Canaries, in addition to the
ety of the end of the late 18th and early 19th                      above, it is important to note the corresponding
centuries, one which underwent a major process                      economic incentive of export crops, which since
of transformation from the Ancien Regime to                         the Conquest had been one of the basic pillars of
Capitalism. The Ancien Regime was a state                           the Canarian economy and society, and needed
regime — the monarchy — based on privilege                          new arable land and water for irrigation. Al-
and in which the economic power held by the rich                    though much land was disentailed, the economic
F. Aguilera-Klink et al. / Ecological Economics 34 (2000) 233–245                    237

and social results of the successive disentailments           less power to create opportunities for economic
(1836 and 1855) did not fulfil expectations (Ojeda,           activities through exploitation of land and water.
1977). Indeed, one could say that property be-                The results obtained, however, were a far cry
came more concentrated than before the process                from those initially sought because only the rich
and the situation of those who had neither water              were in a position to buy — or to take possession
nor land worsened considerably. The cushioning                of — water and land. Moreover, the situation
mechanism that existed in the form of common                  worsened for the majority due to the disappear-
property had been eliminated. Besides, the rapid              ance of common land and (surface) water which
collapse of some export crops in the Canaries                 they might have been able to use free of charge to
triggered the highest rate of emigration in the               improve their lot.
region’s history (1835 – 1855), with many heading                Among the disentailed lands, forest areas were
for Cuba and Puerto Rico. Although surface wa-                sold off fraudulently by means of deliberately
ter was initially allocated to the land on which it           false classification of the woods as uncultivated
fell, the challenging of the notion of property               land. This was the official response to the request
(both public and common) encouraged owners of                 of certain sectors of Canarian society (Royal Eco-
land without water for irrigation to seek a means             nomic Society of Friends of Las Palmas Area in
of obtaining it. Here, following Nieto (1968), we             1868) who asked that forests should not switch to
can distinguish two ways of appropriating surface             private hands in the disentailment process: ‘‘The
water.                                                        destruction of trees without replanting will kill the
   The first was to ask municipal governments                 forests, this natural heritage of the air, water, land
with surplus water — once urban supply has been               and spontaneous production. Destroying the
guaranteed — for a concession, with a volume                  forest destroys springs, humidity and fertility’’
similar to that of the surplus water. The problem             (quoted by Ojeda, 1977). In a way this perception
arose when these concessions were distorted by                reflects scientific knowledge of the environmental
those who obtained them and then claimed full                 functions performed by forests and also the need
ownership of the water granted. According to                  to protect these functions for the benefit of society
Nieto (1968), the mechanisms most commonly                    in general and not just for a few private owners.
used to generate this distortion were as follows:                Since both ways were insufficient to meet the
(a) ‘to convert the concession of surpluses of                growing agricultural needs arising out of the ex-
public water into private property encumbered                 pansion of agriculture at the end of the 19th
with an unavoidable obligation in favour of the               century, a third way commenced, one involving
neighbours’, which is then disputed and denied;               the private appropriation of groundwater.
(b) perversion of the original title ‘at the time of
its constitution by a real fiddling of concepts’; and
(c) perversion of the original title ‘as a conse-             4. Appropriation and distribution of groundwater.
quence, in conclusion, of a phenomenon of hy-                 From public and common property to ‘common
postasis’. The previous mechanisms led to the                 pool’
private appropriation of surface water usurping
the rights of use contained in the aforementioned                It should be noted that, as far back as 1873,
concessions.                                                  debate had already commenced among the En-
   The second was to buy at public auction disen-             lightened as to the consequences drilling for
tailed lands with a given volume of surface water             groundwater would have for surface water
allocation which was initially set according to               courses. In other words, concern arose for a better
crop water needs. The philosophy underlying Dis-              understanding of the hydrologic cycle. The reason
entailment was to challenge a social organisation             for this was that with the passing of the Mines
that was based on privilege and governed by the               Act of 1868, applications were being made for
power of large properties that barely created                 mineral extraction licences, even though the min-
‘commercial wealth’, and thus to allow those with             erals did not exist in the Canaries. The real aim
238                         F. Aguilera-Klink et al. / Ecological Economics 34 (2000) 233–245

was to drill for groundwater. Within a short space             tween the extractions. Waters that had been com-
of time, 1000 applications for licences were filed in          mon and public property were thus transformed
Gran Canaria, thus opening the debate on the                   into individual private property, but without
relationship between surface water and groundwa-               clearly-defined property rights (common pool)
ter, and also on the extension of existing rights over         since it was impossible to know: (a) whether the
surface water to groundwater. Documents of the                 drilling would hit water; (b) the volume of water
time speak literally of ‘water fever’ in describing            that could be withdrawn; and (c) the volume of
the situation. Behind this fever was a desire to               water that could be maintained over time. Hence
place Nature at man’s service and to use early                 the beginnings of an all out ‘race’ or fever for water
machinery to drill for groundwater. As a result, in            withdrawal. Within a few years a situation of
much disentailed land groundwater was appropri-                physical scarcity (there was little water to satisfy
ated, even though this represented a total lack of             the needs created by the new commercial export
regard for and usurpation of rights over surface               crops) was transformed into a situation of socially-
water.                                                         conditioned scarcity (explained by a given social
   It must be said that the extraction of groundwa-            behaviour in the models of water withdrawal,
ter did increase the volume of water available for             distribution and use).
agricultural uses and encouraged an increase in                   This activity led to the eventual creation of
farm activity, although in doing so it caused the              companies with capital to finance the purchase of
disappearance (drying up) of public sources and                expensive steam-driven drilling machinery, in turn
springs, i.e. of surface water. Thus, even if the              leading to better knowledge of the hydrogeological
‘economic’ result is positive for those who with-              workings of the aquifer. However, the social confl-
drew groundwater and sold it to farmers, legally               ict surrounding the legal appropriation of water —
speaking it is a second usurpation or ‘a real and              or the unpunished usurpation thereof — has per-
massive usurpation’ that entirely alters the owner-            sisted until the present day, mainly because people
ship of water — some of which was also the result              (a minority, it must be said) question how a
of usurpation, as we saw above — and the previ-                resource as badly needed as water could be owned
ous owners of surface water were displaced by the              privately, can generate an impressive business in-
new water owners (Nieto, 1968; 106). Another                   cluding speculation in the sale of water and, be-
result was that most of the island’s springs dried up          sides, be tax-free. Still, this conflict did not deter
and, although in the 18th century the entire popu-             (‘willingness to play’) many from putting their
lation usually had enough water, in fact they were             small savings (and frequently losing them, because
forced to buy it from the ‘new owners’.                        no water was found) in this new activity. There was
   Water became consolidated — out of necessity,               always the hope of finding a small water supply,
albeit in a very favourable ideological context (the           which would provide irrigation for a small plot and
Enlightenment) — as yet another commodity, and                 would earn a fee when sold. A clear social percep-
the search for and extraction of groundwater be-               tion existed that water owners were very powerful
came an important and risky (uncertain result)                 and that, in an essentially agricultural economy, if
activity at the end of the 19th and beginning of the           you did not have water and could not buy it,
20th century. Once most of the surface water                   emigration was the sole alternative.
courses had disappeared due to the spiralling                     Although the whole process was based on
increase in underground drilling, which was fa-                usurpation, one of the chief worries of the ‘new
voured by the privatising philosophy of Disentail-             owners’ was how to obtain legal recognition (legit-
ment, water became a private good and now had                  imacy) of the new property redefining the institu-
to be taken from underground. This property right              tional capital.3 They did not find it too difficult
was exercised only through extraction, applying
the catchment rule — i.e. if I don’t extract it,                 3
                                                                   Stock of rules and underlying human organizational skills
someone else will — because there was only one                 which coordinate human behaviour in its interaction with
aquifer and there was great interdependence be-                natural resources (Hanna, 1997).
F. Aguilera-Klink et al. / Ecological Economics 34 (2000) 233–245                    239

to pressure the country’s lawmakers and thus                            with natural springs, resulting from hanging
obtain the ‘acquired’ rights in the new laws affect-                    aquifers. Many of these became exhausted.
ing water (Water Act of 1866, Mines’ Act of 1868,                   “ Stage 2: 1910–1930. Galleries reach the aquifer
Water Act of 1879). Ultimately, once the heredi-                        core. Slight lowering of water table. The island
tary, individualistic concept of underground water                      becomes virtually dependent on groundwater.
was imposed, it led to permanent conflict over                      “ Stage 3: 1930–1945. Exploitation of aquifer
rights between landowners and water withdraw-                           core begins to affect volume of reserves. Water
ers, to the detriment of ‘the stable economic con-                      table lowered by over 100 m in areas with
tent of the property’ and the social use of the                         highest concentration of galleries.
water. In the middle of the present century this                    “ Stage 4: 1945–1965. Gallery system for
conflict (which was not an obstacle to the respec-                      groundwater extraction spreads throughout is-
tive private interests in the Canaries) made it                         land. 90% of current galleries opened by 1965.
necessary to draw up and apply regulations (1956                        Extracted volume reaches 7000 l/s, compared
Landed Property Law — Heredamientos) to ac-                             to 700 l/s for surface water in 19th century.
commodate the conflicting interests of landowners                       Sharp fall in water levels. Uppermost galleries
and water entrepreneurs. The accommodation                              begin to dry up.
also served to deter untrustworthy public law                       “ Stage 5: 1965–present day. Total extracted vol-
experts from exposing and denouncing the social                         ume reaches ceiling, and constant fall of over
consequences of the system, including the poten-                        2000 l/s seen over last two decades (Table 3).
tial for serious abuse on the part of the landown-                     The problem is that the institutional framework
ers and those withdrawing the water.                                regulating surface water use was done away with
                                                                    and replaced by one which, in practice, encour-
                                                                    ages open access to the aquifer. Moreover, to date
                                                                    the various Water Acts have merely brought for-
5. Uncontrolled drilling of the underground                         mal institutional change, but have not enriched
aquifer: application to the full of the catchment                   the institutional capital since they fail to acknowl-
rule                                                                edge the existence of coevolution or coevolution-
                                                                    ary development. Rather, they assume evolution
   Up until the end of the 19th century mining                      in the sense of a lack of real articulation between
fever dominated, with the following stages dis-                     the physical and social systems. The reason is that
cernible in the exploitation of the aquifer (Tener-                 although they regulate drillings (which required a
ife Water Plan, 1989):                                              public concession and had to be physically sepa-
“ Stage 1: 1850–1910. Extraction of groundwater                     rate in terms of space) and extractions, they main-
   begins, with 90% of galleries opened in areas                    tained free access because, in practice, no control
                                                                    is exercised over water withdrawals even today in
Table 3
Volume withdrawn (groundwater)a
                                                                    1999. Indeed, there are no public statistics show-
                                                                    ing how much is withdrawn by each well or
Year            Volume (l/s)            Total km drilled            gallery.
                                                                       In sum, throughout the history and manage-
1930            1500                    100                         ment of Tenerife’s aquifer the maintenance of a
1940            2000                    220
1950            4600                    480
                                                                    kind of institutional capital (and the ensuing in-
1960            5600                    830                         centives) has been assured and this has permitted
1965            7000                      1.040                     the transition from a situation of permanent po-
1970            6300                      1.180                     tential water availability (sustainable aquifer man-
1980            5200                      1.450                     agement) to one of scarcity which is socially
1990            4700                      1.550
1998            4250                      1.630                     determined in terms of aquifer depletion. The
                                                                    combination of entrepreneurial risk-taking, inno-
  a
      Source: Tenerife Water Council (personal communication).      vative technological development in the physical
240                             F. Aguilera-Klink et al. / Ecological Economics 34 (2000) 233–245

Table 4
Distribution of water ownership in La Isla Baja, Tenerife (1975)a

Amount of         Owners            Shares           Owners             Shares           Accumulated   Accumulated
shares            (%) (pi)          (%) (pi)         (%) (qi)           (%) (qi)         owners (%)    shares (%)

Less than 1        18                  8265            2.66               0.14             2.66          0.14
 1–2              165               183 155           24.41               3.19            27.07          3.33
 2–3              112               247 553           16.57               4.31            43.64          7.64
 3–4               87               288 414           12.87               5.02            56.51         12.66
 4–5               43               181 943            6.36               3.17            62.87         15.82
 5–10             117               800 742           17.31              13.93            80.18         29.75
10–15              51               605 178            7.54              10.53            87.72         40.28
15–20              32               557 119            4.73               9.69            92.46         49.98
20–25              10               225 334            1.48               3.92            93.93         53.90
25–30               8               216 958            1.18               3.77            95.12         57.67
30–50              18               658 116            2.66              11.45            97.78         69.12
50–100              9               590 917            1.33              10.28            99.11         79.40
More than 100       6                  1183.85         0.89              20.60           100.00        100.00
 S                676                  5747.544      100.00             100.00

  a
      Source: Aguilera and Nunn (1989).

capital used and increases in the level of ground-                  lem. In short, the major owners can be said to be
water output capacity led groundwater resources                     the holders of structural power.
from a stage of socially determined surplus (com-                      The history of Tenerife’s water has thus been,
plex water resource cycle) to one of full utilisation               to borrow from Hanna’s terminology, a move-
in a relatively short period of time (simplification                ment ‘‘from the stewardship needs of ecosystem
of such complexity) (Hanna, 1997). This situation                   sustainability to the growth phase of frontier de-
can be illustrated in the following terms: low or                   velopment; movement which has proceeded in the
no-control over the levels of extraction of natural                 presence of two powerful underlying tensions:
capital; high rate of application of physical capi-                 economy versus the environment and individual
tal; and relatively undeveloped institutional capi-                 versus the community’’. That movement has been
tal for sustainable path management.                                reinforced by a path dependence technology pro-
   The social legitimisation of this water appropri-                cess (drilling and pumping technologies in the first
ation process is currently defended on grounds                      phase, with desalination and water treatment
that equal opportunities now exist for everyone                     technologies added in the second) and an evolu-
and water ownership is divided up extensively.                      tion of property rights regimes, where those are
Although information in this respect is scant, a                    attained at the point of the resource capture and
sample obtained (Table 4) indicates that water                      where the decisions on resource use are made by
ownership is distributed very unequally, with a                     individuals who interact with other resource de-
handful of owners having much of the water and                      velopers only through the depletion effect of the
a large number of small owners having very little.                  aquifer (Goodstein, 1995; Hanna, 1997).
This unequal distribution has very important im-                       Physical evidence of the above-mentioned
plications for water control, since it indicates that               movement can be seen in Tables 5 and 6.
the handful of big owners have extensive powers                        The Tables show the evolution of the physical
to: (a) fix prices; (b) fix the rules of the game with              yield of the volume of groundwater over the
respect to withdrawal; (c) establish the distribu-                  period 1930–1998 and the percentage variation of
tion conditions; (d) guide any rule changes; (e)                    the number, physical returns, flows and drilled
break the rules with impunity; and (f) influence                    meters of galleries and wells during the period
the dominant social perception of the water prob-                   1973–1990 in Tenerife. We can see in Table 6
F. Aguilera-Klink et al. / Ecological Economics 34 (2000) 233–245                               241

Table 5                                                               and the new technologies for desalinating brack-
Extracted volume (groundwater)a
                                                                      ish water have had very damaging effects on the
Year                Physical yield (m3/day/km drilled)                aquifer, as evidenced in wells where previously
                                                                      exploitation would cease when the water quality
1930                1269                                              worsened as a result of intrusion by sea water
1940                 769                                              beyond certain limits (mainly the minimum qual-
1950                 811
                                                                      ity required for irrigation use) but which are now
1960                 571
1965                 569                                              being exploited again thanks to the new technolo-
1970                 452                                              gies that help perpetuate the damage to the
1980                 303                                              aquifer (one single well contaminated by sea water
1990                 257                                              intrusion can lead to the contamination of an
1998                 221
                                                                      entire and vast area). At present, the authorities
  a
      Source: Tenerife Water Council (personal communication).        require a detailed study and compliance with cer-
                                                                      tain minimum water quality conditions before
how the number of kilometres drilled has multi-                       they will grant a licence for a brackish water
plied. The consequence of this massive drilling has                   desalination installation at the bottom of a well.
been not just a fall in the yield of the galleries and                Very often, however, the authorities are unable to
                                                                      exercise control due to resistance by the well
wells, but also an alarming reduction in the
                                                                      owners. As a result, situations that are disastrous
aquifer (in some places clearly irreversible). Avail-
                                                                      for the aquifer are not avoided and wells are
able data on the evolution of underground extrac-
                                                                      being exploited which are totally contaminated by
tions of water, both in galleries and in wells, as
                                                                      sea water intrusion.
well as the evolution of the springs (a natural
indicator of the state of the aquifer in as much as
springs function as aquifer regulators) corrobo-
rate the above statements. It can be seen that, in                    6. Water perceptions and environmental valuation
the period observed, the choice made has been for                     as a social process
exploitation by wells. Given the state of the
aquifer this seems consistent as the coastal areas                       Given all the above, it seems to us very impor-
are the least affected by over-exploitation. The                      tant to emphasise — as has already been said —
reduction in the yields is seen, however, in both                     that the most common social perception of the
types of exploitation. It should be said also that                    problem of water is essentially linked to a gener-
advances in techniques (pumping and drilling)                         alised notion of physical scarcity, i.e. the belief

Table 6
Evolution of wells, galleries (number, drilled meters, flows and physical return), Tenerife, 1973–90a

                Wells                                                    Galleries

                1973           1980          1990          Var. 73–90    1973             1980           1990        Var. 73–90
                                                           (%)                                                       (%)

No                 291            370           437           50.17            986             1001           1047      6.19
Drilled         14 000         27 000        52 000          271.43      1 327 000        1 453 000      1 627 000     22.61
 meters
m3/day              78.624       133.661        134.784       71.43             548.640    487 555.2      445 824    −18.74

m3/day/drille     5616          4950           2592        −53.85                 0.413          0.336          0.274 −33.72
 d m.

  a
      Source: Rodrı́guez Brito, (1995); author’s own elaboration.
242                        F. Aguilera-Klink et al. / Ecological Economics 34 (2000) 233–245

that the water scarcity is due to ‘natural reasons’           potentially serious environmental impacts that
(for example, low rainfall), and not to the idea of           could lead to an increasingly artificial hydrologic
social scarcity, i.e. the scarcity has more to do             cycle, with ever-growing costs in terms of mainte-
with the application of a particular rationale that           nance, energy dependence, and the environment.
renders some conducts and some social processes               Which is why we consider these proposed solu-
‘legitimate’. In other words, our considerations              tions as ‘non-solutions’, in the sense that they do
would suggest that the problem of water (water                not involve coevolutionary development, nor are
valuation) can only be adequately understood by               they sustainable. Consequently, in order to be
studying the social processes responsible for said            able to speak of the social perception of water we
conduct and for the guidelines for extraction,                must first define what we mean when we speak of
distribution and use. Only then will we be in a               water.
position to understand why this social perception                The physical renewability of water can be im-
does or does not exist, and the different types of            paired by human behaviour in two ways: convert-
social perception that do exist. We cannot carry              ing what used to be renewable into something
out a water valuation from the perspective of                 exhaustible, either by extracting more water than
social processes without, at the same time, valuat-           is collected through precipitation; or by interfer-
ing the social processes behind the notion of water           ing in the workings of biochemical cycles through
and water scarcity. One could say that an under-              the various types of pollution, which would in-
standing of social processes is needed for water              clude global warming. Secondly, although the hy-
(environmental) valuation and an understanding                drologic cycle itself functions with renewable
of the environment (water) is needed for social               energy, most of the energy used thus far to repro-
process valuation.                                            duce the cycle artificially (mainly for sea water
   Even though water is turned into a commodity,              desalination) comes from fossil sources, which are
it has to be said that the social perception related          exhaustible. This not only considerably limits any
to water is actually multi-dimensional, condi-                attempt to generalise the use of desalination
tioned, fragmented and complex. Put another                   plants, but also poses the problem of the gas
way, it should first be clarified what is meant —             emissions from the burning of fossil fuels.
and what we mean — by social perception in the                   Any valuation made of the reserves or
case of water, because we may be referring to                 availability of a natural resource — water, in this
different things at one and the same time. We                 specific case — is meaningful only if related to
should not forget that water means different                  the technological and institutional structures of
things for different people, and the perception               the society in which the resource is found. Thus,
may be so different that everyone can point to a              in the case of groundwater, it seems clear that
different quality or aspect of water or of its cycle.         with water-wheel technology the availability of
Thus, an urban user who has been influenced by                water is limited by the wheel’s capacity and also
‘save water’ campaigns may have a perception of               by the rules or laws regulating withdrawal. Im-
the water problem in terms of physical scarcity,              provements in drilling and pumping technology,
but may not realise (or know) that urban distribu-            however, and changes in the laws regulating water
tion networks lose more than 50 percent of their              exploitation have made extraction of groundwater
water (Tenerife Water Plan, 1993). Nor will they              easier (even leading to over-exploitation of the
be aware that, until recently, in winter water was            aquifer) and have increased the availability of this
usually discharged into the sea so that the price             resource or have turned into a resource something
did not fall in the summer (Cruz, 1958) or that the           which was not a resource with other technology.
aquifer is deteriorating irreversibly (Braojos,               At present, the installation of desalination plants
1988). Moreover, it is difficult to understand that           now means that sea water can be considered a
the very techniques put forward as a solution to              resource that is always renewable as long as the
the alleged physical scarcity — such as desalina-             energy used in the desalination is renewable in
tion of sea water with fossil energy — will have              nature (wind and solar energy, for instance).
F. Aguilera-Klink et al. / Ecological Economics 34 (2000) 233–245                   243

Where this is not the case, desalination of sea                rarely mentioned. Indeed one can read that the
water would exacerbate the exhaustion of fossil                Canaries have been successfully resolving all such
resources and increase CO2 emissions.                          problems (Hoyos, 1997; Simpson and Ringskog,
   Just as with other environmental questions, per-            1997), and can now ‘‘offer our experience, our
ception is rendered difficult because, in the West-            knowledge and our techniques to help in the
ern world at least, most people live in the artificial         always difficult and stormy ‘sea’ of world water
environmental medium formed by cities, and as                  resources’’ (Alsina, 1997). In other words, official
‘‘most of the population reacts mainly with this               water policy is really a ‘‘symbolic policy of decon-
medium, which is increasingly interposed between               tamination’’, that is, a policy which has hindered
man and nature, the illusion is created that each              the social perception of the water problem and
time one is less dependent on it’’ (Sunkel, 1980;              therefore the capacity for ‘collective understand-
19). The perception at urban user level is thus                ing’ (Vatn and Bromley, 1993; 143).
very limited and fragmented, i.e. it refers almost
exclusively to the quality and continuity of tap
water, with no relation to the hydrologic cycle.               7. Conclusions
This perception is quite normal given that ‘‘in
economically developed countries, the emotional                   Access to water resources in the Canary Islands
relationship with water has been obscured because              has been a source of conflict for centuries. Since
of the smooth working of the institutions which                the 19th century, surface water, until then largely
make sure that the water supply is guaranteed; the             a public and common property resource, has been
availability of water just requires turning on the             transformed into an individual and privately
tap. In economically developed countries, how-                 owned resource, a commodity. Profit opportuni-
ever, when the control of water is in danger, the              ties opened by new export crops, which were
force of the emotional returns’’ (Brown and In-                curbed by the physical scarcity of surface water,
gram, 1987; 197–198). Moreover, not even the                   led to groundwater pumping and within a few
‘scientific body’ has one sole perception about                years caused the disappearance of most of the
groundwater and about how the aquifer works.                   surface water courses. In an agricultural society,
On the contrary, the debate, in its many facets                the need for water created a real ‘water rush’,
(legal, hydrogeological, economic, etc.) is open               leading within a short time to aquifer overex-
and on many occasions is confused, ambiguous                   ploitation and to (at times irreversible) damage.
and contradictory. One could say therefore that                As a result, the physical ‘surface water resource
groundwater can be viewed, according to Fun-                   scarcity’ condition was transformed into a socially
towicz and Ravetz (1993), as a problem character-              conditioned ‘groundwater resource scarcity’ (and
ised by uncertainty, conflict of values and                    aquifer depletion). In spite of the large numbers
interests, the importance of what is at stake and              of people involved in water withdrawal, water
by the urgency (the need for quality information)              ownership was concentrated in the hands of a few
of decision-making.                                            big owners, with the majority owning small quan-
   In the case of Tenerife, drilling, pumping, de-             tities only. The big water owners become a real
salination and water treatment technologies are                ‘structural power’, with the power to lay down the
now firmly entrenched and have secured the water               rules of the game (water laws), to change them
supply from the tap for any use, with no account               and even to violate them with impunity. In sum,
taken of aquifer sustainability management. Pol-               the power to make water decisions. Attempts to
icy has been nudging the choice of technology                  declare water a public good and to make coherent
along a non-sustainable track. The water problem               decisions to ensure (renewable) aquifer manage-
in the Canaries can be described as a case of                  ment have generated important social conflicts,
‘organised irresponsibility’, to use Beck’s term               particularly in the last decade, and resulted in the
(Beck, 1991). The appearance given is that every-              adoption in 1990 of the new Water Act 1990
thing is under control and water problems are                  which formally at least sets out the need for
244                        F. Aguilera-Klink et al. / Ecological Economics 34 (2000) 233–245

sustainable management of the aquifer, and yet at             been determined; how technological risk, environ-
the same time acknowledges something which is                 mental hazards and possible future scarcities have
totally incompatible with this goal, namely, recog-           been addressed; the political choices behind the
nition of private ownership for the next 75. The              institutions and the forms of compromise in the
permissive implementation of the Act reflects an              social processes that have defined water environ-
implicit accord between water owners and certain              mental valuation in Tenerife.
politicians, whereby groundwater is the property                 Any serious option to confront the situation of
of the owners until it is exhausted, and the au-              ‘organised irresponsibility’ requires the opening of
thorities undertake to invest heavily in small                public discussion fora to facilitate the diffusion of
reservoirs to store the winter surpluses of rainfall,         information and to allow the re-creation of a
in waste water treatment and in sea water desali-             social perception which was lost some years ago.
nation. The prevailing approach now is that                   This would serve to build a collective understand-
aquifer management is outdated and what are                   ing of the problems associated with sustainable
important now are new technologies, particularly              management of the aquifer as well as the eco-
those for desalination. This approach has resulted            nomic, social and environmental implications of
in, on the one hand, a reinforcement of water                 maintaining the current situation.
owners’ power (‘water is ours’) and, on the other,
the search for technological ‘solutions’ to the
problems of social scarcity in order to avoid                 References
having to challenge water owners’ vested interests.
                                                              Aguilera, F., Nunn S., 1989. Problemas en la gestión del agua
It has resulted ultimately in a diminished social                subterránea. Arizona, Nuevo Méjico y Canarias. Universi-
perception of water problems. However, the so-                   dad de La Laguna, Secretariado de Publicaciones, La
called technological ‘solutions’ (sea and brackish               Laguna.
water desalination using fossil energy), although             Alsina, E., 1997. El modelo hidráulico en Canarias. Diario de
(temporarily) reducing social conflict over the wa-              Avisos (newspaper), 15 de junio de 1997, 6.
                                                              Beck, U., 1991. La irresponsabilidad organizada. In: Daly,
ter issue, generate new conflicts and risks —                    H.E., et al. (Eds.), Crisis Ecológica y Sociedad. Germania,
which are not perceived immediately — such as                    pp. 35 – 56.
increased atmospheric pollution and increased                 Braojos, J.J., 1988. Zonificación Hidrológica: Evolución de la
aquifer deterioration due to the rise in the pump-               superficie freática. Plan Hidrológico Insular de Tenerife.
                                                                 Santa Cruz de Tenerife.
ing of brackish water.
                                                              Brown, F.L., Ingram, H., 1987. The community value of
   With regard to the social perspective, a range of             water: implications for the rural poor in the southwest. J.
environmental valuation methods of a more or                     Southwest 29 (2), 179 – 202.
less experimental nature can be deployed, among               Cruz, T., 1958. Ensayos sobre economı́a canaria. CSIC, Insti-
them focus groups, citizen jury and multicriteria                tuto de Estudios Canarios, La Laguna, Tenerife.
                                                              Funtowicz, S., Ravetz, J., 1993. Epistemologı́a Polı́tica. Cien-
analysis, and can be used as a support tool in a
                                                                 cia con la gente. Centro Editor de América Latina, Buenos
decision-making process. In the case of ground-                  Aires.
water in Tenerife (Canary Islands), key decisions             Goodstein, E., 1995. The roots of environmental decline:
were already made some years ago. A proper                       property rights or path dependence? J. Econ. Iss. 29 (4),
understanding of the multi-dimensional evolution-                1029 – 1043.
                                                              Hanna, S., 1997. The new frontier of American fisheries
ary process at play in the Tenerife case has re-
                                                                 governance. Ecol. Econ. 20, 221 – 233.
quired an explanation of the historical context, to           Harvey, D., 1996. Justice, Nature and the Geography of
show how current values and interests have been                  Difference. Blackwell Publishers, Oxford.
shaped; how conflict identification and resolution            Hoyos, A., 1997. La utilización del agua subterránea en Ca-
with respect to the water resource have evolved;                 narias y su papel económico, social y de oportunidad. In
                                                                 Asociación Internacional de Hidrogeólogos Grupo Es-
the nature of the decisions concerning distribu-
                                                                 pañol. Las aguas subterráneas en la planificación hidrogeo-
tions of income resulting from the social processes              lógica en las Islas Canarias. Las Palmas de Gran Canaria.
of water; how access or non-access to environ-                Nieto, A., 1968. Aguas subterráneas, subsuelo árido y sub-
mental resources and services such as water has                  suelo hı́drico. In: Nieto, A. (Ed.), Estudios de derecho
F. Aguilera-Klink et al. / Ecological Economics 34 (2000) 233–245                               245

   administrativo especial canario, vol. 2. Cabildo Insular de     Sunkel, O., 1980. La interacción entre los estilos de desarrollo
   Tenerife, Aula de Cultura.                                         y el medio ambiente en América Latina. Revista de la
Norgaard, R., 1984. Coevolutionary development potential.             Cepal 12, 17 – 53.
   Land Econ. 60 (2), 160–173.                                     Tenerife Water Plan, 1989. Plan Hidrológico Insular. Avance:
Ojeda, J.J., 1977. La Desamortización en Canarias (1836–             Basespara el planeamiento hidrogeológico. Cabildo Insular
   1855). Cuadernos Canarios de Ciencias Sociales 3. CIES,            de Tenerife y Gobierno Autónomo de Canarias, Santa
   Las Palmas de Gran Canaria.                                        Cruz de Tenerife.
Rodrı́guez Brito, W., 1995. El agua en Canarias y el siglo         Tenerife Water Plan, 1993. Plan Hidrológico Insular. Cabildo
   XXI. Cabildo Insular de Gran Canaria, Las Palmas de                Insular de Tenerife y Gobierno Autónomo de Canarias,
   Gran Canaria.                                                      Santa Cruz de Tenerife.
Simpson, L., Ringskog, K., 1997. Water markets in the Amer-        Vatn, A., Bromley, D., 1993. Choices without prices without
   icas. The World Bank, Washington.                                  apologies. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 26, 129 – 148.

                                                             .
You can also read