The Consequences of a Public Health Insurance Option: Evidence From Medicare Part D Prescription Drug Markets
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
The Consequences of a Public Health Insurance Option: Evidence From Medicare Part D Prescription Drug Markets Daniel P. Miller Clemson University Jungwon Yeo Singapore Management University∗ November 2011 Abstract Policy makers in the US have debated the merits of including a government spon- sored public health insurance option as a part of health care reform. Under the pro- posed legislation, the government would offer a basic coverage plan with premiums set at cost that competes against plans offered by private insurers. The government’s ability to negotiate favorable prices with health care providers and lack of profit taking could increase competition and perhaps crowd out a significant amount of private com- petition. We consider the existing Medicare Part D prescription drug market which resembles the new health insurance exchanges that will be coming online in 2014. We use data from the 2006-2009 Part D market to estimate a random coefficient discrete choice demand system and a supply side model for Part D plans. Using our estimates, we conduct policy counterfactuals that include a public option as proposed by leg- islators in the 2009 “Medicare Prescription Drug Coverage Improvement Act.” Our results indicate a small increase in competition if the government plan operates with a cost structure similar to private plans. But, if the government has up to a 25% cost advantage over private plans, perhaps achieved through a strong bargaining position with drug manufacturers, the government plan dominates the market and crowds out a significant fraction (25%) of private plans’ market share. There are consumer surplus gains; they increase in the size of the public option’s cost advantage. But, no matter the cost advantage, all total surplus gains are eliminated after factoring in the decline in insurer profits and the implicit subsidies in the Part D program. ∗ We thank Leemore Dafny, Amanda Kowalski, Greg Lewis, Claudio Lucarelli, Tom Mroz, Robert Town and seminar participants at Clemson, University of Georgia, and University of South Carolina for helpful comments. First Draft February 2011. Author correspondence: dmille7@clemson.edu and jwyeo@smu.edu.sg 1
1 Introduction In 2010 US legislators passed a major health insurance reform bill. A controversial provision that was ultimately struck from the bill is the “Community Health Insurance Option”1 , col- loquially known as a “Public Option.”2 When fully enacted in 2014, the reformed health care system will continue to rely on private health insurance markets, but under the “Commu- nity Option” the government would have offered a zero-profit basic coverage health insurance plan that sells alongside private plans. The legislation stipulates that the government plan compete on a level playing field with private plans. It will not be subsidized, is subject to the same regulations as private plans, has no special mandates on coverage, and negotiates provider fees without statutory mandate. There are pros and cons of a public option. Supporters advocate the benefits of more choice and increased competition. They also hope the government will further drive down cost by leveraging a strong negotiating position over fees with providers (physicians, hospi- tals, drug manufacturers). Critics argue that the public option could significantly crowd out private plan enrollment without any competitive benefits. Moreover, they are concerned that greater negotiating power will distort providers’ supply-side incentives: for example, phar- maceutical manufacturers incentives to develop new drugs (Lakdawalla and Sood, 2009). Although the plan is explicitly budget neutral, there are concerns that the public option could have an budgetary impact through other subsidies and tax-provisions tied to the re- form. To another set of critics, who believe that government provision of services is less cost-efficient than private provision, the government option would simply be a fringe plan that has little impact on competition. In this paper, we consider the existing Medicare Part D prescription drug insurance market—which closely resembles the reformed insurance markets—to quantitatively evaluate the competitive consequences of introducing a public option. As part of the 2003 “Medicare Modernization Act” (MMA), Medicare introduced “Part D,” that for the first time would cover prescription drugs. Unlike the original Medicare program, where the government is the sole insurer, Part D is a regulated insurance exchange. Senior citizens enroll in plans subsidized and regulated by the government, but sold by competing private insurers. The Part D market has never had a public option; we cannot conduct a retrospective 1 House of Representatives Bill H.R. 3590 Section 1323, struck from bill Sec 10104. 2 The language in an earlier bill proposal (H.R. 3962) proposed by Nancy Pelosi, used the term “Public Health Insurance Option,” which was was changed to “Community Health Insurance Option” in the passed bill. The descriptions in the two bills are nearly verbatim identical. The key difference is that in the passed legislation states may opt-out of the community option whereas in the earlier bill states could not opt-out. 2
program evaluation. Instead, we estimate an equilibrium supply/demand model for insurance plans and then conduct a policy counterfactual that recomputes the market equilibrium with the inclusion of a public option. We assess many competitive outcomes such as the effect on enrollment for the government plan and private plans, monthly premiums, consumer welfare, industry profits, and subsidies linked to the Part D program. Two stylized facts about Part D markets fuel the debate over a public option. On one hand, individuals have lots of choices. The typical enrollee can choose from over 40 plans offered by about 20 insurers. On the other hand, it is a concentrated industry. Between 2006 and 2009, the Herfindahl-Hirschman concentration index (HHI) for the average market is 2376, in the range the Department of Justice labels “moderately concentrated,” just shy of the “highly concentrated” threshold of 2500. At the national level, the two largest insurers (United Healthcare, and Humana) together have a 50% market share. Taking these two facts together, it’s not immediately obvious whether a public option would have a minor or major impact on competition. We model plans as differentiated products. Per regulation, private insurers must offer at least one plan meeting a basic, minimum coverage standard, but they are also allowed to offer enhanced plans with more generous coverage, the so-called “Cadillac” plans. Coverage characteristics such as deductibles, drug copays, and drug formularies (the list of covered drugs) differentiate plans. We use a flexible random coefficients discrete choice model of plan demand. Our model captures heterogeneity in consumer’s preferences for plans, driven by factors such as enrollees’ health status and idiosyncratic differences in enrollees’ drug regimens. We model the supply of plans as a Bertrand multiproduct firm oligopoly model. We pay particular attention to the rules regarding premium subsidies. They distort the residual de- mand elasticities faced by insurers and hence effect insurer markups. Moreover, the subsidies are the channel by which the public option impacts the government budget. Using data from 2006 to 2009 on aggregate plan enrollment, pricing, and plan character- istics, we estimate the model using the method in Berry (1994) and Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995) (BLP). To evaluate the consequences of introducing a public option, we recom- pute the model equilibrium under the counterfactual market structure that includes a public option. As in Petrin (2002), BLP models are tailored for counterfactuals that introduce new products. A public option for the Part D market has been under consideration long before the 2010 health insurance reform debates. Every session of congress since the MMA legislation passed 3
in 2003 proposed a public option. The proposals detail exactly how the public option would be introduced.3 The government would only offer a basic plan—no enhanced plans. The plan competes on a level playing field as if it were just another private plan. Like private plans, the public option would construct a drug formulary, set copay and coinsurance rates, and negotiate discounts with drug manufacturers. The negotiating rules are fully flexible; there are no statutory pricing directives set in law such as reference pricing and the government (and manufacturers for that matter) may exclude drugs from the formulary.4 Unlike private plans, it foregoes profits by setting monthly premiums at cost. Thus, the public option is explicitly budget neutral. But, its introduction will have an indirect effect on the government budget through the existing Part D subsidy rules. We construct the public option’s plan characteristics to match the basic benefit structure, and, as our baseline, assume that it sells at the marginal cost equal to that of the average private plan. We explore the possibility that the government could offer a more or less desirable plan by varying the plan’s cost. For instance, the government plan could have a low cost if it has the ability to negotiate deep discounts with drug manufacturers. We consider a case where the government plan has a 25% cost advantage, comparable to the drug discounts negotiated by Canadian provinces and the Veterans Affairs program.5 We also consider the case that the government has a cost disadvantage, representing either poor drug price negotiations or inefficient management. Our results show that if the government plan operates with a cost similar to the average private plan it becomes an average plan. It ranks as a top 10 to 15 plan (out of about 40) with a 1.4% market share. It gains most of its share by crowding out private plans’ share. There is little effect on premiums; private plans lower them by just a couple cents. Nationwide consumer surplus increases by about $78 million, which is offset by a decrease in industry profits of $53 million. The competitive effects are more pronounced if the government has a 25% cost advantage. The government plan is number 1 with a 8.6% market share. Basic plans–the closest in product space to the government plan—respond with slightly lower premiums, yet lose 15% of their enrollees. Enhanced plans are affected modestly, losing 3 The 2009 “Medicare Prescription Drug Coverage Improvement Act.” is the most explicit. 4 The proposed Pelosi bill (H.R. 3962) included reference pricing clauses, but the passed law H.R. 3590 does not. 5 Danzon and Furukawa (2008) constructs a price index comparing Canadian and American brand name drugs and finds 20% to 40% lower prices in Canada. The advocacy group, Families USA, compared Part D drug prices to the Veterans Affairs (VA) negotiated Federal Supply Schedule (FFS) prices for the top 20 drugs in 2007. They found the VA negotiates a median 58% lower price than the lowest price that a Part D plan negotiated. source: www.familiesusa.org/assets/pdfs/rhetoric-vs-reality.PDF (accessed 8/12/10). 4
about 4% of their enrollees. The different response by basic and enhanced plans is due to the estimated higher cross price elasticity amongst basic plans, than between basic and enhanced plans. Nationwide consumer surplus increases $565 million while industry profits fall $311 million. If the government has a 10% cost disadvantage, there is negligible competitive effect. Despite the government forgoing profits, this result follows because the market is already highly competitive and has low markups: estimated markups average just 7% to 9% over cost. If we factor in the subsidies in the Part D program, all total surplus gains are wiped out (regardless of the government plan’s cost advantage) because more enrollees are brought in to the highly subsidized Part D program from other options with lower subsidies. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2 we relate our work to the existing literature. Section 3 provides background and institutional details of the Medicare part D market. Section 4 introduces the demand and supply model. Section 5 describes the data. Section 6 reports our supply and demand estimates. Section 7 conducts the counterfactual exercise. Section 8 concludes. 2 Contribution to Existing Literature There is an emerging literature about the Medicare Part D prescription drug program. Much of this literature focuses on the behavioral economics of senior citizens choosing plans. In particular, the literature examines whether senior citizens rationally choose plans. Abaluck and Gruber (2009) use micro level consumer data on plan choices and drug expenditures and find that senior citizens don’t necessarily pick the plan that would minimize total out of pocket expenditures on premiums, deductibles, and copays. Enrollees tend to overvalue plan characteristics such as the monthly premium and deductible, when in fact there exists a plan with a higher deductible or premium that results in lower expected out of pocket expenditures, even after factoring risk consideration. In a series of work Heiss, McFadden, and Winter (2006, 2010), document cases of sub-optimal plan choice with regards to plan coverage and a penalty for late enrollment. They find people delay enrollment who, looking towards future years, would otherwise be better off enrolling despite a short term loss. Lucarelli, Prince, and Simon (2008) estimate a similar model to ours and run a counterfactual experiment that limits the number of plans insurers may offer. These papers suggest limiting plan choice could be welfare improving if enrollees are not fully rational or face high search costs. Our study differs in several dimensions. First, we consider an equilibrium model of the 5
market. Our focus is not only on consumer demand, but also the supply side of the market. We are able to analyze both sides of the market because we have enrollment data on the entire market, not just a selected sample of consumers. We also have the necessary data on the subsidy rules that allows us to correctly model and estimate the supply side. By analyzing all sides of the market, we can conduct a comprehensive welfare evaluation of consumers, insurers, and (as a subsidized market) the government’s budget. Second, we construct plan characteristics using highly detailed data on drug coverage for the the entire universe of prescription drugs for every plan. In short, we observe every financially relevant plan characteristic that consumers observe. Although the micro data available to Abaluck and Gruber (2009) allows them to estimate a richer demand system, we are nonetheless able to estimate a very flexible random coefficient demand system. It is robust to the possibility that enrollees overvalue certain characteristics thus ensuring we get unbiased estimates of demand elasticities and the supply-side. The US healthcare system has historically relied on the private provision of health insur- ance. But, when the government becomes a supplier, crowding out of private competition becomes a concern. Examples include Medicaid, (Cutler and Gruber, 1996), the Supplemen- tal Children’s Health Insurance Program, (Lo Sasso and Buchmueller, 2004), and Medicaid’s long-term care insurance (Brown and Finkelstein, 2008). These papers use both program evaluation and calibration techniques to measure crowd out effects using data from after the enactment of the government program. In contrast, our structural approach has predictive power that allows us to make pre-enactment forecasts, and we can evaluate welfare effects, not just market share outcomes. This is also one of the first papers to address the competitive consequences of proposals in the recent health care legislation. Others contributions include Dafny, Ho, and Varela (2010) that quantifies the benefits of switching from an employer based health insurance system (with a limited choice of plans) to an individual health insurance exchange (with broader choice) and Avraham, Dafny, and Schanzenbach (2009) that evaluate the impact of tort reform on insurance premiums. Our work is also related to the IO health literature about competition in insurance mar- kets. A recent example is the reduced form work in Dafny, Duggan, and Ramanarayanan (2009) that examines the effect of mergers on health insurance premiums. They find consoli- dation that results in much higher concentration only causes a modest increase in premiums. There are other papers using that use a structural approach including Dranove, Gron, and Mazzeo (2003); Ho (2009), who, respectively, estimate the competitive effects product differ- 6
entiation in insurance markets and the role of bargaining between insurers and health care providers. Our model is static on both the supply and demand side which brings up two qualifica- tions. On the supply side, we do not model plan’s entry and exit to determine if a government option would cause plans to exit. We cannot identify this effect in a meaningful way because there is no entry or exit by major firms in the data. Entry and exit only occurs on the extreme competitive fringe, and we believe ignoring this churn will have negligible effect on our results. Second, our model does not account for dynamic features of the demand for health insurance plans. Carlin and Town (2009) document strong persistence in demand for health insurance across time. Miller and Yeo (2011) estimate a dynamic demand system for Part D plans with switching costs. Finally, our work relates to the adverse selection literature, in particular Lustig (2010). We do not have micro level data that would allow us to correct for adverse selection, but we sign the potential bias in our estimates following the intuition in Lustig (2010). 3 Medicare Background Medicare is the United State’s entitlement program that provides health insurance to all people over age 65 and to some categories of disabled people. It started in 1965 and is funded by a payroll tax. The original Medicare programs (Part A and Part B) cover hospital and doctor services, but lack coverage for prescription drugs. Under Part A and Part B, there is only 1 insurance plan that is provided by the government. The government negotiates fees with hospitals and doctors according to rules mandated in legislation. Medicare reforms have introduced a privatization of insurance. In 1997, Part C, currently called Medicare Advantage (MA), created a health insurance exchange that gave Medicare beneficiaries the option to purchase plans offered by competing private insurers. MA plans set coverage levels and freely negotiate fees with providers. Medicare regulates coverage standards and provides subsidies. Enrollment in a MA plan is voluntary and substitutes for Part A and Part B coverage. As part of the legislation in the 2003 Medicare Modernization Act (MMA), Medicare introduced Part D to offer prescription drug coverage. Like Part C, Medicare beneficiaries choose from a menu of plans sold on an insurance exchange by competing private insurers. Part D plans set coverage levels and freely negotiate drug prices with manufacturers. Medi- care regulates coverage by setting a minimum standard, and subsidizes monthly premiums. 7
Insurers may offer enhanced coverage that exceeds the minimum standards, but the enhance- ments are not subsidized. Roughly speaking, the subsidy is 2/3 of the average premium set by the plans. In the model of the supply-side, we elaborate and formally model the subsidy rules. Medicare beneficiaries are penalized for not having drug coverage.6 They can obtain coverage from a Part D plan sold in the exchange, a group policy offered by a current employer or union, a group policy offered by a former employer or union as part of the Retiree Drug Subsidy Program (RDS), or another government program such as Veterans Affair insurance. The policies in the Part D market are sold as either stand-alone plans or bundled with a MA plan (MA+Part D). We only endogenize the market for stand-alone Part D plans, but we use enrollment data on MA+Part D plans and the RDS program to account for the subsidy rules in our supply-side estimates and counterfactuals. The duration of a Part D contract is one year, beginning January 1st. Once the contract begins, enrollees are not allowed to switch plans. In November and December there is an open enrollment period when enrollees are allowed to switch plans for the upcoming year. Plans cannot adjust premiums or make major changes to coverage characteristics throughout the year. Enrollees can only select plans offered in their geographic region which are drawn around state boundaries. Plans must charge a uniform premium to all enrollees in a region; they cannot engage in 3rd degree price discrimination based on health status or prior experience. Enrollees can access many channels to evaluate and select plans. Medicare publishes plan information online through its “Plan Finder” tool and in print forms distributed through the mail. Third parties, such as pharmacies and consumer advocacy groups offer assistance. Insurers are allowed to market their plans through many types of media. Enrollees sign-up by contacting Medicare or directly with the insurer. These are complicated financial contracts; these channels are intended to make the plan selection process as transparent as possible. Low income households are eligible for additional subsidies. All enrollees receive a pre- mium subsidy, but Medicare pays all premiums and drug copays/coinsurance for households below 100% of the poverty level. The low income subsidy gradually phases out up until 150% of the poverty level. Low income subsidy enrollees may choose any plan, but they receive less than 100% premium and copay subsidies for enhanced plans and basic plans with premiums above a market determined threshold. The lowest income households that 6 For every month a beneficiary lacks coverage, premiums increase by 1% for the rest of the person’s life. For example, delaying enrollment by 2 years, results in a 24% premium penalty. 8
do not actively sign-up are randomly assigned by Medicare to a plan that qualifies for the full low income subsidy. A large fraction of the Medicare population, over 20%, receives a low income subsidy. 3.1 Plan Characteristics Plan’s are differentiated along several dimensions of coverage characteristics (deductibles, coinsurance/copay rates, drug formularies) and other non-pecuniary characteristics. The regulations set minimum standards for cost sharing rules. Under the minimum Part D benefit structure enrollees’ out of pocket expenses follow a 5 part tariff. Table 5 and figure 1 depict the benefit structure and the names of the 5 regions of the tariff schedule. Enrollees pay a premium regardless of their drug expenditures. For the first $250 of drug expenditures (deductible) they pay 100% of their expenditures, and then between $250 and $2250 they are in the initial coverage zone and pay 25% of their drug expenditures. Then, between $2250 and $5100 of expenditures they are in the donut hole and pay 100%. Beyond $5100, they are in the catastrophic range and pay 5%. These are the 2006 thresholds; to keep pace with drug price inflation and to keep the Part D program on budget, the thresholds have increased in later years. Plan’s classified as “basis” satisfy the minimum standard. They can use either coinsur- ance rates that cover a percentage of drug expenditures or copay rates denominated in fixed dollar amounts. For example, a plan may set a $30 copay for brand name drugs and $4 for generic drugs. Across all drugs on the formulary, copay rates must be approved by Medicare as being “Actuarially Equivalent” to a benefit structure using coinsurance rates. Plans with more generous coverage are classified as “Enhanced.” They typically offer more generous coverage by reducing the deductible and/or reducing out of pocket expenditures in the initial coverage and donut hole regions. The portion of premiums attributable to enhancements are not subsidized. On a drug-by-drug basis, plans have a lot of scope selecting drugs for their formulary and setting copay/coinsurance rates. The regulations require plans to cover at least two drugs from the major therapeutic classes. Within a class they can pick and choose which drugs to cover with a few exceptions for protected drugs, such as some cancer treatments, that must be included on the formulary. Plans can cover “elective” medications, such as prescription sleep medications, but that coverage is considered an enhancement and not subsidized. En- rollees receive coverage for any on-formulary drug, but there may be restrictions in the form 9
Figure 1: Part D Basic Benefit Structure 10
of quantity limits, prior authorizations, and step therapies.7 Off-formulary drugs are not covered; to purchase an off-formulary drug, an enrollee would have to pay full retail price or go through an appeals process with the plan. Plans do not have to set 25% cost sharing rates for every drug on the formulary. They set higher or lower copay/coinsurance rates by placing drugs on tiers. For example, the tiers might be ranked as preferred, non-preferred, specialty. Medicare must approve the tiers as being “actuarially equivalent.” Despite this requirement, we observe a lot variation at the aggregate level, particulary amongst the most popular drugs. Drug prices are determined through a bargaining process between insurers, manufac- turers, wholesalers, and pharmacies. Per regulation, plans are required to pass along all discounts and rebates to enrollees. Medicare monitors every drug transaction to ensure com- pliance. Negotiated prices matter for enrollees. Even if plans have identical cost sharing rules, an enrollee would have a stronger preference for the plan with lower negotiated drug prices. While the regulations ensure copay/coinsurance rates remain fixed, negotiated drugs prices fluctuate throughout the year. As shown in Duggan and Scott-Morton (2010), restrictive formularies, tiered copay/coinsurance rates, and bargaining were important considerations in the design of the Medicare Part D market. Plans contract with pharmacies to construct a pharmacy network. Contracts are not exclusive; pharmacies can accept many plans, and plans can have several pharmacies. Plans designate network pharmacies as either preferred, non-preferred, or mail-order. Drug prices and copay/coinsurance tiers may differ across pharmacies, and are usually, but not always, lower at preferred and mail-order pharmacies. There are other important non-pecuniary plan characteristics. As in Starc (2010), mar- keting and advertising activities influences consumer’s choices. As an example, the market leader United Healthcare pays royalties to AARP to market and endorse their plans. Hu- mana, the second largest Part D insurer, has a marketing arrangement with Walmart. While marketing increases an insurer’s visibility, it is also signals to enrollees that they are dealing with a sound and reputable company. Case in point, Medicare recently terminated the plans offered by a fringe insurer, Fox Insurance, citing several regulatory violations. Finally, ser- vice quality characteristics such as the accuracy and ease of understanding documentation, leniency in appeals procedures, and customer service also differentiate plans. 7 Prior authorization requires the plan’s approval before filling a prescription at the pharmacy. Step therapy routines requires enrollees to try another drug first, and if it is ineffective then the plan provides coverage. 11
4 Model We model the supply and demand system for plans using the discrete choice framework of Berry (1994); Berry et al. (1995). We separately introduce the demand and supply side. 4.1 Demand Every year t, a consumer, indexed by i, can enroll in one prescription drug plan. Con- sumers choose amongst the j = 1, . . . , Jmt differentiated plans offered in market m in year t. Markets are geographically separated by Medicare regions drawn around state borders. Residency requirements and the annual enrollment period admit a very clean market defini- tion; consumers cannot enroll in plans outside their region, nor switch plans within a year. They may also choose an outside option, j = 0. Following the convention in the demand estimation literature, we normalize the utility from the outside option to zero. The outside option includes going without drug coverage, enrolling in an MA+Part D plan, or getting it from another source, such as a current employer, another government program, or a Retiree Drug Subsidy program plan. Each year, enrollees pay a premium pjmt set by the plan. They derive utility from plan characteristics and income left over after paying the premium. Define the conditional indirect utility of person i choosing plan j in market m as: Ui (Xjmt , pjmt ) = −αi pjmt + X0jmt βi + ξjmt + ijmt (1) where Xjmt is a vector of observable plan characteristics, ξjmt represents an index of unobserv- able (to the econometrician) plan characteristics, and ijmt is a term capturing idiosyncratic differences in consumers’ preferences over plans. The terms αi , and βi are random coefficients that represent consumer i’s marginal utility over income and over product characteristics. The random coefficients are distributed iid normal across consumers and markets with mean ᾱ and β̄ and variance Σ. Consumers choose the plan yielding the highest conditional indirect utility in equation 1. After describing the supply-side model, we introduce our measures of plan characteristics in the data section and further discuss factors driving heterogeneity in preferences. 12
4.2 Supply We model the supply side by closely following the regulations in the Medicare Modernization Act of 2003. A set of F multiproduct insurers compete in a Bertrand-Nash fashion. In year t, each plan j offered in market m submits a bid bjmt to Medicare. Insurers submit separate bids in each market, even if the plans offered in different markets are otherwise similar. For each enrollee, the plan receives a monthly payment equal to its bid. Part of that payment is made by enrollees in the form of the premium pjmt , and the remainder is subsidized by the government. We model plan’s marginal costs mcjmt of enrolling a customer as a constant. As multiproduct firms that can offer plans in many regions, profits for firm f are given by, X X Πf t = Mmt (bjmt − mcjmt )sjmt (2) mt Jf mt where Mmt is the number of potential enrollees in market m and Jf mt indexes the set of plans offered by firm f in market m. The first order conditions with respect to a bid bjmt are given by, X ∂sr sjmt + (br − mcr ) =0 (3) r∈Jf t ∂bjmt for all plans across all markets. Notice, we are explicit about summing across all markets; because of the subsidy rule, the cross derivatives ∂b∂sjmt r 6= 0 if r is in a different market than j. The system of first order conditions can be inverted to solve for marginal cost, mct = bt + ∆−1 st (4) where ∆m is a matrix of own and cross price share derivatives appropriately defined for a ∂s ∂s multiproduct firm. It has elements, ∂bjj for own share derivatives along the diagonals; ∂brj as off diagonal terms if the same firm offers plans r and j, otherwise zero. The boldface terms, mcmt and bmt , are vectors of marginal costs and bids. Under the assumption that the market is in equilibrium, the inversion allows us to estimate marginal cost without any data on cost. We only need data on bids, market shares, and demand elasticity estimates from the demand model. Because the demand model is expressed in terms of premiums and the supply model, in terms of bids, we need to account for the subsidy rules. The regulation sets the rule for determining the size of the subsidy. The government 13
subsidizes a fixed proportion, λt , of the enrollment weighted average bid of all plans in the country (λt ≈ 65%). The enrollee pays the balance as its premium. Thus, each enrollee gets the same subsidy amount regardless of plan choice. Enrollees realize savings from choosing cheaper than average plans, or pay extra to pick one that is more expensive than average. The determination of the weighted average bid is complicated by the distinction between basic and enhanced plans. Only the portion of the bid attributable to basic coverage is included in calculation of the weighted average bid. The portion attributed to enhanced coverage is not subsidized. A bid bjmt separates into a basic component bbasic jmt , and enhanced enhanced component bjmt , bjmt = bbasic enhanced jmt + bjmt Plans choose bids but do have discretion allocating between the basic and enhanced compo- nent. The allocation is based on an actuarial calculation that takes into consideration the plan’s coverage characteristics. We assume a fixed ratio γjmt between the two components. benhanced jmt γjmt = bbasic jmt For example, γjmt is zero for basic plans and is larger for an enhanced plan that eliminates the deductible and provides donut hole coverage than for an enhanced plan that only eliminates the deductible. The formula to map a bid bjmt to a premium pjmt is: pjmt = bjmt − λt b̄t (5) The weighted average bid b̄t is based on bids of all stand-alone part D plans and select MA+part D plans in the entire nation. X b̄t = s̃jt−1 bbasic jt (6) jt The weights s̃jt−1 are based on the previous year’s enrollment Ejt−1 , Ejt−1 s̃jt−1 = P jt Ejt−1 The weight is zero for plans that are new entrants to the market. Premiums are bounded below at zero, but it has never been a binding constraint. In the first year, 2006, the weights were equal for all plans. The shift from a simple average to the weighted average method 14
was gradually phased in through 2008.8 4.3 Supply-Side with Adverse Selection Adverse selection may bias our marginal cost estimates. Marginal cost depends on the drug consumption (or risk profile) of a plan’s pool of enrollees; “sicker” consumers are more costly to enroll than “healthier” ones. Adverse selection occurs because a plan’s risk profile depends on its premium and coverage characteristics relative to competing plans. Adjusting bids shuffles the sorting of enrollee risk-profiles across plans. Our model’s constant marginal cost is implicitly invariant to the risk profile of the pool of enrollees and thus potentially misspecified. Medicare uses risk adjustment payments to combat adverse selection. They gather highly detailed enrollee demographic and health information from Medicare records9 to compensate plans that attract high risk pools. With perfect risk adjustments, our model of constant marginal cost is correctly specified; even with less than perfect risk adjustments, the bias is mitigated. See Fong and Schwarz (2009) and McAdams and Schwarz (2007) for further discussion. But, it has been documented that Medicare’s risk adjustments are not perfect (Lustig, 2010), and we believe adverse selection is a legitimate concern. Without individual level data we cannot account for adverse selection, and thus it is beyond the scope of this paper. Nonetheless, it is useful to understand how adverse selection would bias our marginal cost estimates. In the appendix, we expand our supply-side model and follow the intuition in Lustig (2010) to heuristically sign the bias for basic and enhanced plans. The bottom line is that our marginal cost estimates for basic plans may be overstated, and understated for enhanced plans. 4.4 Elasticities with Subsidy Distortion To perform the inversion that solves for marginal cost, it is necessary to express demand elasticities in terms of bids, not premiums. For ease of notation, we use a non-random coefficient specification to illustrate how the subsidy rule distorts insurer’s residual demand 8 The “Medicare Demonstration to Limit Annual Changes in Part D Premiums Due to Beneficiary Choice of Low-Cost Plans” act, passed in mid-2006, amended the original legislation to phase-in the weighted average bid calculation method. 9 Healthcare Effectiveness Data and Information Set (HEDIS) 15
elasticities. The market share for plan j in region m in year t is given by: M sjmt = Pjmt 1 + k Mkmt where ! ! X bkmt Mjmt = exp −α bjmt − λt s̃kmt−1 + X0jmt β + ξjmt . k 1 + γjmt We substituted bids in for premiums using the subsidy rule given in equation 5. There are three relevant price elasticities given in equation 7: own price, cross price with a plan offered in the same market m, and cross price with a plan offered in a different market m0 .10 h i ∂sjmt bjmt λt ηjjmt = ∂bjmt sjmt = −αbjmt (1 − sjmt ) − 1+γjmt s̃jmt−1 (1 − s0mt ) h i ∂skmt bjmt ηkjmt = ∂bjmt skmt = −αbjmt −sjmt − 1+γλtjmt s̃jmt−1 (1 − s0mt ) (7) h i ∂skmt bjm0 t λt ηkjm0 t = ∂bjm0 t skmt = −αbjm t − 1+γ 0 s̃jm t−1 (1 − s0mt ) 0 0 jm t The second term inside the brackets captures the distortion in residual demand elasticities cause by the subsidy. The distortion makes own-price elasticities more inelastic and cross price elasticities larger relative to a market with no subsidy. The intuition is that when plan j in market m increases it’s bid, the subsidy increases for all plans across the nation. With a larger subsidy, inside goods become more attractive relative to the outside option. Insurers internalize the subsidy distortion and will have higher markups, more so for large national insurers with high enrollments (hence high weights s̃jmt−1 ) that offer plans in many markets. Also notice the subsidy distortion would be more severe if the subsidy fraction λt were higher or if Medicare subsidized the enhanced component of bids (γjmt =0 for enhanced plans). In our results, we quantify the impact of the subsidy rule on markups by comparing our estimated markups to estimates from a model where insurers treat the subsidy amount as lump sum. 5 Data We collected publicly available data from the Center for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) on plan level enrollment and bids for all stand alone part D plans offered since the the programs inception in 2006 through 2009. We also purchased detailed data on plan 10 Because the weights s̃jmt−1 are based on lagged enrollment, we could also calculate cross price elasticities across time. We don’t because our model is static. 16
characteristics from CMS. There are four files. The formulary file lists all drugs on a plan’s formulary, the beneficiary cost file describes cost sharing rules, the pharmacy network file lists all preferred and non-preferred pharmacies, and the pricing file reports average drug transaction prices for every drug and plan. The pricing file was first published in 2009, the other files are available in all years. Specifically, prices are the average transaction price net of all rebates for a 30 day supply filed at the plan’s preferred pharmacies in Q3 2009.11 They are used to calculate enrollee drug expenditures. It’s worth noting that enrollees may not know the exact drug price during the enrollment period because drug prices and rebates vary throughout the year, and prices reported by the ”Plan Finder” tool on Medicare’s website are not necessarily accurate.12 5.1 Enrollment and Premiums Across the four years and 39 regions, 75 insurers offer stand alone Part D plans. The market penetration of insurers is quite skewed; 18 national firms offer plans in all states,13 while 44 regional insurers offer plans in just one market. Insurers offer an average of 2.5 plans in a market, with most offering 1, 2, or 3 plans.14 At least one must be a basic plan. Enrollees have lots of choices. A typical enrollee can choose from over 40 plans offered by about 20 insurers. Table 6 shows the average number of insurers and plan offerings in a market. The entries are broken down by year and plan segment: Enhanced and Basic. Despite the large number of insurers, the Part D market is highly concentrated. Table 7 reports various measures of firm concentration (1-firm concentration, c1, 2-firm c2, 4-firm c4, and Herfindahl-Hirschman index) averaged across markets. The top firm (United Healthcare for most markets) commands an average 36% market share, while the top 4 firms, 73%. The 11 Plan’s report all transactions, called Prescription Drug Events (PDE) to CMS. A PDE includes in- formation on prices and all rebates/discounts with manufacturers, wholesalers, and pharmacies. Rebate information is proprietary, only the net price is available to researchers. Some pharmacies charge a dispens- ing fee, on the order of a couple dollars, that may or may not be included in the net drug price. Our data are based on PDE records. 12 Every two weeks plans are required to submit a separate pricing file to CMS that is used in the plan finder database. The database is not constructed from PDE records. If the plan never submits a price, the finder reports a price 30% below the average wholesale price for generic drugs, 10% below for brand name drugs. Even if a plans submits a price, it may not get updated every 2 weeks, so the prices can be outdated. Recently, Medicare began reporting survey results that ask enrollees to rate the accuracy of drug prices paid at the pharmacy compared to price reported on the plan finder. Many plans get very poor ratings. 13 excluding 5 markets for US territories with very small penetration 14 There are a few exceptions where insurers offer more than 3 plans, up to a maximum of 9. The most notable is in 2006 when United Healthcare, the market leader, offered 5 plans. Two of these plans were sponsored by Pacificare, which was acquired by United Healthcare. United Healthcare consolidated these 5 plans into 3 in 2007. 17
HHI averages 2376, which according to the Department of Justice guidelines falls into the “moderately concentrated” category.15 Overtime, the markets have become less concentrated but still fall into moderately concentrated levels. Table 8 reports national enrollment as a percentage of all eligible Medicare beneficiaries (≈ 42 million) and monthly premiums. The table divides shares into three categories: stand alone part D plans, bundled MA+Part D, and stand alone Medicare Advantage plans. Stand alone Part D enrollment has been stagnant since program inception in 2006, while monthly premiums have risen dramatically; average premiums rose about 30% between 2006 and 2009. Meanwhile, both stand alone MA and bundled MA+PartD, plans have experienced an increase in enrollment. Tables 9 reports enrollment and premium statistics separate by basic and enhanced plans. Basic plans attract about 3 times as many enrollees and charge 30% lower premiums as compared to enhanced plans. Table 10 reports more detailed summary statistics for both basic and enhanced plans at the market level. Note the large variation in premiums for both plan segments as well as the variation and skew in enrollment figures. The average basic plans enrolls 1% of Medicare beneficiaries, while the largest, upwards of 18%. The average enhanced plan has a smaller share, .4%, but the distribution also exhibits a large skew. Every year Medicare announces the official average bid amount b̄basic t and average pre- basic basic mium b̄t − λt b̄t . These figures, along with the calculated subsidy fraction λt , are reported in table 11.16 Table 12 reports summary statistics on plan bids. 5.2 Plan Characteristics Our primary plan characteristic variables measure the generosity of plans coverage. Our first variable is the deductible. The second and third are intended to measure the generosity of coverage in the initial coverage and donut hole regions. The challenge is taking our rich drug-level data and converting it into a meaningful plan-level characteristic. We construct price indices for the top 100 most popular drugs ranked by prescriptions 15 A market with a HHI between 1800 and 2500 is considered moderately concentrated. 16 The official average bid and average premium are reported by Medicare. We also observe the basic and enhanced component of the bid for all stand alone Part D plans. We do not have complete data on MA+Part D bids due to further complications in the rules for subsidizing MA+Part D plans. Instead, we use enrollment figures from MA+Part D plans and the subsidy formula (equation 6) to calculate an average basic bid for MA+Part D plans. Since MA+Part D plans are included in the outside option, the average bid is a sufficient statistic for us to properly calculate marginal cost and perform counterfactuals. Because of the phase-in of the weighted average bid method, we are missing data that would allow us to calculate marginal cost in 2006 through 2008. 18
filled.17 Our first price index reflects the out of pocket cost for an enrollee to fill a 30 day supply for a basket of the 100 drugs when they are in the initial coverage zone. Our second price index reflects out of pocket costs in the donut hole. The basket of drugs evenly weights each drug (1/100th). While there may be drug-by-drug idiosyncratic variation in a plan’s out of pocket prescription drug cost, this measure captures a plan’s average cost across drugs. Constructing out of pocket costs is straightforward for drugs covered by a copay. For drugs covered by coinsurance, it is necessary to know the price of the drug. We use the 2009 pricing file. For off-formulary drugs, enrollees do not receive coverage, therefore the out of pocket cost is the full retail price. We set the retail price to the average price in the region.18 We do not construct a price index for the catastrophic region because there is virtually no variation across plans.19 There are three sources of variation in the price indices: copay and coinsurance rates, negotiated drug prices, and formulary composition. Table 14 reports statistics on out of pocket price indices for the top 100 drugs and separate indices for brand and generic. Most of the variation in the donut hole is between enhanced plans that fill the donut hole and basic plans with no coverage. There is more variation in the initial coverage zone than in the donut hole. The source of this variation comes from differences in copay rates. Comparing brand and generic drugs, the variation is larger for brand name drugs. Its also interesting to note trends across time. Average donut hole prices remain steady, while out of pocket prices in the initial coverage zone fall across years. Figure 3 shows a histogram of negotiated prices for all drugs in 2009. To compare across drugs, we record prices as percent deviations from the drug’s average price. Notice there is a lot of price dispersion; it contributes to the variation in our price indices. To give a sense of magnitude, 10% of drugs are priced 25% below the average, and 10% are priced 15% above average. The dispersion is quite remarkable considering these are perfectly homogenous 17 CMS published a report ranking the top 100 drugs by number of prescriptions filled by Part D enrollees in 2006. Rankings by cost are quite different. For example, the generic drug FUROSEMIDE is number 1 by prescriptions filled and 98 by cost. 18 Since the base price includes rebates and discounts, we are probably understating retail prices by using negotiated prices. We use the average national price in rare cases where a region price does not exists. For the years 2006 to 2008 we construct the price indices in the same manner using 2009 prices. For plans that did not exists in 2009, we use average regional prices. Drug prices, coinsurance rates, and copays differ across preferred, non-preferred, and mail order pharmacies. All of our calculations are based on preferred pharmacies. 19 The Part D regulations do not allow plans to use a tiered copay/coinsurance structure in the catastrophic region. Out of pocket payments are capped at $5 per prescription or 5% of drug cost. There is little variation across plans. Moreover, few enrollees, only 8% in 2006 reached the final tier, and of that group, they are over-represented by the low income subsidy enrollees who pay zero in the catastrophic region. 19
products. We measure formulary comprehensiveness by counting the number of top 100 drugs in- cluded on a formulary. We also break this list down by brand and generic medication; there are 42 brand name medications and 58 generic. Table 13 reports statistics on formulary comprehensive. On average plans cover most of the drugs (more than 90%), but there is significant variation that appears to have grown over the years, indicating the plans are more differentiated now than in 2006. There is little difference between enhanced and basic plans. Insurers typically share formularies for their plans. Across all four years and regions there are 6679 plans and 400 formularies. Th only intended to illustrate a source of variation in the price index; we do not includes these drug counts as a separate plan characteristic. Across the universe of Part D drugs, over 5400, there is a lot of idiosyncratic variation in formularies. Figure 2 depicts a snapshot of formularies in 2009. Gaps in the formularies show that less comprehensive formularies are not strict subsets of more comprehensive formularies. With so many non-overlapping formularies, each enrollee is likely to find a plan tailored his individual drug regimen. This suggests enrollees sacrifice very little in terms of choice when plans use formulary restrictions as a bargaining chip with drug manufacturers. From our data on pharmacy networks, we construct a measure of network coverage by counting the number of in-region network pharmacies per eligible Medicare beneficiary in the region. We group preferred and non-preferred pharmacies because many plans do not make a distinction. 5.3 Basic vs Enhanced Plan Characteristics Figures 4, 5, and 6 display side-by-side histograms of coverage characteristics for basic and enhanced plans in 2009. They illustrate the relative location in characteristic space for the two categories. The differences are relevant because they drive the substitution patterns in our counterfactual that introduces a basic government option. The plans are highly differentiated with respect to the monthly deductible. Most basic plans have the maximum deductible ($295 in 2009), while most enhanced plans have a $0 deductible. No systematic difference emerges in the histograms for the price index in the initial coverage zone, but there are differences in the donut hole price index. Almost no basic plans have a price index below 100, while about 50% of the enhanced plans fall below the $100 thresholds. The price index is lower for these enhanced plans because they provide some coverage in the donut hole. 20
5.4 Heterogeneity in Preferences: Random Coefficients Our most flexible demand specification includes random coefficients on the monthly premium, deductible, and out of pocket price indices. As in a typical demand system, the random coefficient αi captures heterogeneity in consumers’ marginal utility over income, driven by differences in income and price sensitivity. Two other factors affect the distribution of αi : the low income subsidy and late enrollment penalty. The low income subsidy truncates αi . For example, it is zero for those receiving a 100% subsidy and half of what it would otherwise be for an individual receiving a 50% subsidy. For an enrollee subject to the late enrollment, penalty—1% per month not enrolled— αi increases in proportion to the duration of late enrollment. Combined, the low income subsidy and late enrollment penalty increase the variance on the distribution of αi . They may also skew the distribution, but we lack data on these populations to estimate higher order moments of the distribution. Heterogeneity in preferences for the deductible and out of pocket price indices are driven by heterogeneity in enrollee’s health status and risk aversion. All enrollees (weakly) prefer a lower deductible, but “Healthy” enrollees have a relatively low (in magnitude) marginal utility with respect to the deductible because their drug expenditures are unlikely to exceed the deductible. “Sick” enrollees have a higher marginal utility because they would expect to spend through the deductible with certainty. By the same reasoning, health status affects preferences over out of pocket prices in the initial coverage and donut hole regions. It’s worth noting, enrollees care not only about the cost sharing rates in the marginal tier of the tariff schedule they fall into (deductible, initial coverage, donut hole, or catastrophic), but also tiers they surpassed. Marginal utility only diminishes for the higher tiers that they are unlikely to enter. More risk averse enrollees place a higher preference on the deductible and price indices. Like the premium, the low income subsidy truncates the distributions towards zero. We use a parsimonious Normal distribution over the random coefficients with a block diagonal covariance matrix. However, this distribution may not be appropriate for three reasons. First, in a model of demand for drugs with a kinked tariff schedule, the distribution of drug expenditures will exhibit bunching and gaps around the kinks (Marsh, 2010). In our model of plan demand, this translate into gaps and mass points in the distribution of random coefficients. Second, we would expect correlation in the random coefficients across the tiers of the tariff schedule because they all relate to expenditures of money. For a risk neutral enrollee, a dollar spent on the premium is worth exactly the same as an (expected) dollar spent in the later tiers. This implies an enrollee’s marginal utility over characteristics 21
monotonically decreases moving down the tariff schedule. The premium should have the highest coefficient because it is paid with certainty, and the donut hole should have the lowest coefficient since it is not necessarily reached with certainty. Third, if consumers are risk averse, a risk premium is built into their preferences which further complicates the correlation structure of random coefficients. The distribution over the marginal tier that an enrollee enters matters for the risk premium. For example, a consumer that exceeds the deductible with certainty places a risk premium on the coefficient in later tiers and no risk premium on the deductible coefficient. For estimation, we experimented with specifications that accommodate these three qualifications (correlation in random coefficients, discrete type models (Berry and Jia, 2010), and mixtures models with Normal and discrete distributions) but could not obtain sensible results. In principle these richer models may be identified with aggregate data (?), but accessing consumer level data, as in Abaluck and Gruber (2009), would help with identification. We leave this as future work. Nonetheless, the focus of this paper is on the the supply-side for which the demand model is a means to obtain reasonable price elasticity estimates. With our more parsimonious random coefficient model, we estimate sensible elasticities and ameliorate the standard criticisms of non-random coefficient discrete choice models. 5.5 Heterogeneity in Preferences: Idiosyncratic Preferences The idiosyncratic logit error terms, ij , reflect unobserved heterogeneity in preferences that are not otherwise captured by random coefficients. There are several reasons we believe they should enter our demand specification. Drug purchasing patterns are likely the primary source of idiosyncratic preferences. Enrollees have stronger preferences for plans that cover their specific drug regimen at low out of pocket prices. Thus, drug-by-drug idiosyncratic dif- ferences in formulary composition and copay/coinsurance rates generate idiosyncratic pref- erences. Figure 2 illustrates idiosyncratic differences in formulary composition; a similar visual representation of copay/coinsurance rates shows the same pattern. Marketing activ- ities and pharmacy networks may also contribute to idiosyncratic preferences. Using the examples from before, AARP members might have stronger preferences for AARP endorsed plans, and Walmart customers might prefer plans that contract with Walmart. It is also worth noting low income subsidy enrollees who accept random assignment to plans. Their behavior can be rationalized in our model by attributing the random assignment to draws from the distribution of ij . 22
? and Berry and Pakes (2007) have critiqued this model because the dimensionality of ij increases as products are added. The added term ensures consumers benefit from the introduction of a public option, even if it has a high premium, undesirable average characteristics, and there is no competitive response by existing plans. We justify the extra ij term for the government plan by assuming its formulary and copay/coinsurance rates will exhibit the same sort of idiosyncratic differences found amongst the privately offered plans. These difference are a likely outcome because the legislation permits the government to bargain with drug manufacturers using restrictive formularies and tiered copays, just like private plans. 6 Estimation In this section, we report our demand and supply-side marginal cost estimates. Our most flexible demand specification includes random coefficients on the monthly pre- mium, deductible, and out of pocket price indices. We also report estimates for non-random coefficients specifications estimated by OLS and IV, and a more parsimonious random coef- ficient specifications. We include formulary fixed effects. They control for unobserved differences in the mean quality of formularies that would otherwise be difficult to measure with a few observable coverage characteristics. Formulary fixed effects have two advantages. First, they capture the desirability of the entire formulary, not just the top 100 drugs that are included in the out of pocket price indices. Second, without fixed effects, the price index variables may be correlated with mean unobserved quality in ξ. Specifically, the price index could be high because the formulary composition includes many high-cost, high quality drugs. Formulary fixed effects purge this correlation. The remaining characteristics in ξ reflect marketing activities and service characteristics. We use the instruments proposed in BLP to instrument for the endogenous premium variable: the sum of the other exogenous observable product characteristics offered by rival firms and by the firm’s other plans. It is necessary to justify the validity of the instruments: that is, the exogeneity of the characteristics. The price index variables are exogenous for several reasons. First, the benefit design is regulated by Medicare, not chosen by plans. Second, the underlying drug prices are set by pharmaceutical manufacturers, not insurers. Part D enrollment may affect insurers’ bargaining power in drug price negotiations which brings into question the validity of the instruments. In defense, enrollment does not change 23
You can also read