THE CASE for GROWTH CENTERS - How to spread tech innovation across America - ROBERT D. ATKINSON, MARK MURO, and JACOB WHITON - Governor Tom Wolf
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
THE CASE for GROWTH CENTERS How to spread tech innovation across America ROBERT D. ATKINSON, MARK MURO, and JACOB WHITON December 2019
Table of contents Executive summary 3 1. Introduction 10 2. The entrenched geography of America’s innovation 16 industries 3. The costs of hyperconcentration 25 4. Why markets alone won’t solve the problem 32 5. Why place-based intervention is essential—and how it can 42 succeed 6. Countering regional divergence through growth centers 47 7. Spreading tech hubs across America: A proposal 52 8. Candidates to be America’s next top innovation hubs 62 9. Addressing objections and concerns 67 10. Conclusion 71 References 72 Endnotes 75 Appendix A 85 Appendix B 88 Appendix C 90 Acknowledgements 92
Executive summary I t has become clear that while the future are they likely to. Instead, these deeply seated of America’s economy lies in its high-tech dynamics appear ready to exacerbate the current innovation sector, that same sector has divides. widened the nation’s regional divides—a fact that became starkly apparent with the 2016 This is why the nation needs a major push presidential election. WRFRXQWHUWKHVHG\QDPLFV6SHFLoFDOO\WKH nation needs—as one initiative among others—a Dependent on intense agglomerations of highly massive federal effort to transform a short list skilled workers and based on winner-take-most of “heartland” metro areas with compelling network economies, the innovation sector has strengths into self-sustaining “growth centers” JHQHUDWHGVLJQLoFDQWWHFKQRORJ\JDLQVDQG WKDWZLOOEHQHoWHQWLUHUHJLRQV wealth but has also helped spawn a growing gap between the nation’s dynamic “superstar” The present paper, therefore, proposes that metropolitan areas and most everywhere else. Congress assemble and award to a select set of metropolitan areas a major package of federal Neither market forces nor bottom-up economic innovation inputs and supports that would help development efforts have closed this gap, nor those areas accelerate transformative innovation- THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 3
sector scale-up. Along these lines, we envision enhancing nature of the regional economics Congress establishing a rigorous competitive market. process by which the most promising eight to 10 potential growth centers (all not geographically For much of the 20th century, market forces had located near existing successful tech hubs) would tended to reduce wage, investment, and business- UHFHLYHVXEVWDQWLDOoQDQFLDODQGUHJXODWRU\ formation disparities between more- and less- support for 10 years to get “over the hump” developed regions. By narrowing the divides, and become self-sustaining new innovation the economy ensured a welcome “convergence” centers. Such an initiative would not only bring among communities and regions. VLJQLoFDQWHFRQRPLFRSSRUWXQLW\WRPRUHSDUWV RIWKHQDWLRQEXWDOVRVLJQLoFDQWO\ERRVW86DQG However, in the 1980s, that trend began to break innovation-based competitiveness, including in down as digital technologies and innovation the competition with China. moved to the center of economic activity. Intense new demands for talent and insights increased What follows is a discussion that situates the the value of “agglomeration” economies, nation’s divergence problem, and highlights a set unleashing self-reinforcing dynamics that RIUHOHYDQWoQGLQJVDQGUHFRPPHQGDWLRQV LQFUHDVLQJO\EHQHoWHGELJFRDVWDOFRUHUHJLRQV often to the detriment of cities and metro areas THE PROBLEM in other parts of the nation. Rather than growing together, the nation’s Amid these conditions, the convergence trend regions, metropolitan areas, and towns have been gave way to “divergence,” as a top tier of big, growing apart. That has been a shock, including tech- and innovation-heavy metro areas such for an economic and policy mainstream that as Boston, San Francisco-San Jose, and Seattle has long trusted the self-regulating, welfare- began to consistently outperform less-tech- Indexed average annual wages Indexed employment level 1969 - 2017 (1969 = 100) 1969 - 2017 (1969 = 100) 180 280 170 250 160 220 150 140 190 130 160 120 130 110 100 100 Bottom third of metro areas Median metro areas Top 2% of metro areas Source: Brookings analysis of BEA data THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 4
based places on measures of innovation-driven recommendations in the process of laying out prosperity. what a federal innovation-based growth centers program might look like. These takeaways include The result is a crisis of regional imbalance. the following: Among the superstar metro areas, the winner- take-most dynamics of the innovation economy 1. Regional divergence has reached extreme have led to dominance but also livability and levels in the U.S. innovation sector. The competitiveness crises: spiraling real estate costs, innovation sector—comprised of 13 of the WUDIoFJULGORFNDQGLQFUHDVLQJO\XQFRPSHWLWLYH nation’s highest-tech, highest-R&D “advanced” wage and salary costs. Meanwhile, in many of industries—contributes inordinately to regional the “left-behind places,” the struggle to keep up DQG86SURVSHULW\,WVGLIIXVLRQLQWRQHZ has brought stagnation and frustration. These SODFHVZRXOGJUHDWO\EHQHoWWKHQDWLRQ V uneven realities represent a serious productivity, well-being. However, far from diffusing, the competitiveness, and equity problem. sector has been concentrating in a short list of superstar metropolitan areas. Most notably, FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS MXVWoYHWRSLQQRYDWLRQPHWURDUHDVBoston, San Francisco, San Jose, Seattle, and San Assuming that nonchalance is no longer tenable, Diego—accounted for more than 90% of the the present report presumes that the time has nation’s innovation-sector growth during come for the nation to offset the pull-away of the years 2005 to 2017. In this fashion, they the innovation superstars with a concerted have increased their share of the nation’s intervention to support the emergence of new total innovation employment from 17.6% to tech stars in new places. Along these lines, 22.8% since 2005. In contrast, the bottom the report draws a number of conclusions and 90% of metro areas (343 of them) lost share. Innovation sector job creation has been strongest in metro areas that already FIGURE 2 FIGURE 2 have the largest sectors Innovation sector employment index (2005 = 100), 2005-17 115 115 110 110 105 105 100 100 95 95 90 90 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 Bottom 75% Next 15% Next 5% Top 5% Bottom 75% Next 15% Next 5% Top 5% 1RWH3HUFHQWDJHkELQVyUHpHFWFRKRUWVRIPHWURDUHDVUDQNHGLQHDFK\HDU7KHkWRSyLQFOXGHVPHWURV Source: Brookings and ITIF analysis of Emsi data THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 5
Metros by change in share of total innovation sector jobs Share of innovation sector jobs change, 2005-17 0.4% - 2.0% 0.0% - 0.4% 0.0% -0.1% - 0.0% -0.7% - -0.1% Innovation sector jobs, 2005 Top 5% of metros Next 5% Next 15% Bottom 75% Source: Brookings and ITIF analysis of Emsi data $VDUHVXOWWKH86LQQRYDWLRQLQGXVWU\ is the stark gap between the productivity of has become heavily entrenched in just a the relatively few metropolitan areas with few places. Fully one-third of the nation’s high shares of innovation industries and innovation jobs now reside in just 16 counties, the many more with less. These patterns and more than half are concentrated in 41 are hurting the country’s innovation-based counties. competitiveness, since the skyrocketing costs of the most successful tech hubs mean that All of this points to the extent to which tech investment is often made in other places— innovation-sector dynamics compound over but not in other parts of America, given the time, leaving most places falling further shortage of vibrant lower-cost hubs. The behind. UHVXOWLVWKDWLQYHVWPHQWVpRZWRSODFHVVXFK as Bangalore, Shanghai, Taipei, or Vancouver, 2. Such high levels of territorial polarization rather than Indianapolis, Detroit, or Kansas are now a grave national problem. At the City. economic end of the equation, the costs of excessive tech concentration are creating Equally concerning is the fact that the serious negative externalities. These range nation’s divergence is unfair. So many IURPVSLUDOLQJKRPHSULFHVDQGWUDIoFJULGORFN Americans reside far from the opportunities in the superstar hubs to a problematic associated with the nation’s innovation “sorting” of workers, with college-educated centers, undercutting economic inclusion workers clustering in the star cities and and raising social justice issues. Regional leaving other metro ares to make do with divergence is also clearly driving “backlash” thinner talent reservoirs. As a result, whole political dynamics that are exacerbating the portions of the nation may now be falling into nation’s policy stalemates. “traps” of underdevelopment. Of concern here THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 6
Localization economies make innovation industries clustered together more FIGURE 4 productive Avg. output per worker by industry group, 2017 $400,000 $371,306 $350,000 $300,000 $264,119 $260,658 $246,265 $250,000 $200,000 $150,000 $100,000 $50,000 $0 Bottom 75% Next 15% Next 5% Top 5% Basic manufacturing Retail Healthcare Finance Innovation industries 1RWH3HUFHQWDJHkELQVyUHpHFWFRKRUWVRIPHWURDUHDVUDQNHGLQHDFK\HDU7KHkWRSyLQFOXGHVPHWURV Source: Brookings and ITIF analysis of Emsi data 3. Markets alone won’t solve the problem; Moreover, “bottom-up” technology-based place-based interventions will be essential economic development efforts cannot in ameliorating it. When the economy was VLJQLoFDQWO\FKDQJHWKHVHSDWWHUQVE\ “converging,” it was easy to assume that themselves, in part because the resources any problems of regional unevenness would states and cities can bring to bear are limited. naturally resolve themselves. Indeed, until $FFRUGLQJO\WKH86QHHGVQRWMXVWQDWLRQ very recently, self-correction remained the scaled solutions for its regional imbalances but expectation of mainstream economists, place-based ones. with their embrace of traditional doctrines RIkDOORFDWLYHHIoFLHQF\ykHTXLOLEULXPy 4. The nation should counter regional and “welfare-maximizing” spatial results. divergence by designating eight to 10 However, the rise of newer innovation-oriented new regional “growth centers” across economic theories has thrown more attention the heartland. The time is right for, among onto the power of local “agglomeration” other initiatives, a 21st century comeback HIIHFWVE\ZKLFKODUJHEHQHoWVDFFUXHWR and update of “growth pole” strategy—the oUPVZKHQWKH\ORFDWHWRJHWKHULQXUEDQ 1960s and 1970s emphasis in regional areas. Substantial evidence now suggests economic planning that called for focusing that agglomeration brings with it strong transformative investment on a limited self-reinforcing tendencies that not only do number of locations to catalyze the takeoff of not support the “spread” of development, those regions and the nation. What is needed but are likely to exacerbate its concentration. in this respect will be: Generous awards of key THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 7
federal innovation inputs (including support 5. Numerous metropolitan areas in most IRUVFLHQWLoFDQGHQJLQHHULQJUHVHDUFK regions have the potential to become one of UHJXODWRU\EHQHoWVDQGVXSSRUWVIRUKLJK America’s next dynamic innovation centers. quality placemaking) coupled with a rigorous Skeptics may doubt that eight to 10 metro and competitive selection process to identify areas worthy of growth center investment the most promising locations for intervention. FDQEHLGHQWLoHGDQGFDWDO\]HGIRUkWDNHRIIy and self-sustaining growth. However, even Along these lines, the federal government a fairly restrictive list of eligibility criteria should: yields plenty of potential candidates. Based on a demonstration in this report, some 35 • Assemble a major package of federal potentially transformative metro areas surface innovation inputs and supports as candidates for growth center designation. for innovation-sector scale-up in Candidates are situated in at least 19 states, metropolitan areas distant from existing lie in multiple regions (especially the Great tech hubs. Central to this package will be a /DNHV8SSHU6RXWKDQG,QWHUPRXQWDLQ:HVW direct R&D funding surge worth up to $700 and exist often at far remove from the coastal million a year in each metro area for 10 superstars. \HDUV%H\RQGWKDWZLOOEHVLJQLoFDQWLQSXWV such as workforce development funding, Many more promising metro areas exist. WD[DQGUHJXODWRU\EHQHoWVEXVLQHVV There is likely a score of “up-and-coming” oQDQFLQJHFRQRPLFLQFOXVLRQ, and federal metro areas that hold a solid capacity for land and infrastructure supports. The countering the nation’s regional divides by increasing preference of innovative people bringing tech-based development closer to and companies for mixed-use downtowns, the nation’s left-behind places. waterfront areas, and urban “innovation districts” means that federal contributions * to urban placemaking also should be prominent. To be sure, there will be objections. Some will say the present proposal goes way too far, while Overall, a rough estimate of the cost of such others will say it doesn’t go far enough. a program suggests that a growth centers surge focused on 10 metro areas would cost 7RWKHoUVWSRLQWPDQ\FRQYHQWLRQDOHFRQRPLVWV the federal government on the order of $100 will argue that any such push to promote billion over 10 years. That is substantially regional equity will come at the expense of OHVVWKDQWKH\HDUFRVWRI86IRVVLOIXHO HIoFLHQF\+RZHYHUEHFDXVHRIERWKWKHQHJDWLYH subsidies. externalities from growth in booming tech hubs and the positive externalities of growth in • Establish a competitive, fair, and rigorous targeted emerging hubs, intervention can help process for selecting the most promising underperforming metro areas turn the corner, potential growth centers to receive escape a cumulative causation trap, and add to the federal investment. To distribute its the nation’s total welfare, including its global supports, the proposed growth center competitiveness. Other critics will deny the program would select for awards the eight ability of the federal government to effectively to 10 metropolitan areas that had best pick regional “winners” or reject that the demonstrated their readiness to become a emergence of existing clusters had anything to new heartland growth center. The process do with government efforts. But one has only to would employ a rigorous competition H[DPLQHWKHKLVWRU\RI86WHFKQRORJ\KXEVVXFK characterized by an RFP-driven challenge, as Boston, the Bay Area, and North Carolina’s goal-driven criteria, and an independent Research Triangle to see that the federal selection process. THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 8
Strong potential candidates for Growth Center designation appear across the country Source: Brookings and ITIF analysis of Emsi data government has often played important, if not supply chain relationships, commuting, and other decisive, roles in helping new tech centers attain interdependencies with the growth centers. critical mass. In that spirit, then, the present initiative is best viewed as but one component of the full federal To the other point, others may say that a agenda needed to ameliorate the nation’s JURZWKFHQWHUVSXVKGRHVQRWVXIoFLHQWO\ unbalanced economic geography. “change capitalism” or address the full crisis of America’s smaller cities, towns, and rural As such, a concerted growth centers surge—while areas. And certainly that is true. There is much not a total solution of the nation’s now-acute set more that needs doing, especially for the of regional imbalances—would represent a major most deeply struggling communities. But the break with past inaction and demonstrate that proposed innovation surge would absolutely federal action can not only bring technology- begin to transform the nation’s spatial malaise. based opportunity to more parts of the nation, Most notably, it would bring new vitality closer EXWDOVRVSXUPRUHLQQRYDWLRQDQGLQFUHDVHG86 to more struggling communities, allowing for economic competitiveness. VPDOOHUWRZQVDQGFRXQWLHVWREHQHoWWKURXJK THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 9
Introduction T he stark facts of the widening regional the 20th century, after all, market forces tended GLYLGHLQ$PHULFDoQDOO\KLWKRPHLQWKH to reduce regional disparities in employment, aftermath the 2016 presidential election. wages, investment, and business formation. By narrowing these divides, the economy ensured a As nothing before it did, the election exposed a welcome “convergence.”2 Midsized and smaller deep fault line: the widening gap between two cities, as well as once-lagging regions such as separate Americas, one centered in the nation’s the South, were catching up with richer, bigger dynamic, high-tech “superstar” metropolitan places. areas, and the other encompassing pretty much everywhere else. However, in the 1980s, that trend began to break down. Rather than growing together, the nation’s communities are growing apart—and that has As innovation moved to the center of economic been a shock, especially for an economic and activity, the advance of digital technology policy mainstream that has long trusted the increasingly rewarded the most talent-laden local self-regulating nature of the market.1 For much of FOXVWHUVRIVNLOOVDQGoUPV,QWHQVHQHZGHPDQGV THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 10
Figure 1. Since the 1980s, wage and employment growth convergence among metro areas has broken down Indexed average annual wages Indexed employment level 1969 - 2017 (1969 = 100) 1969 - 2017 (1969 = 100) 180 280 170 250 160 220 150 140 190 130 160 120 130 110 100 100 Bottom third of metro areas Median metro areas Top 2% of metro areas Source: Brookings analysis of BEA data for talent and insights increased the dominance hubs such as Boston, San Francisco, and Seattle— of “agglomeration” economies, unleashing forces along with smaller hubs including Austin, WKDWEHQHoWHGELJFRDVWDOFRUHUHJLRQVRIWHQWR Denver, Raleigh-Durham and San Diego, as well the detriment of the midsized cities and smaller DVoQDQFLDODQGFRQWHQWRULHQWHGPHJDPDUNHWV “heartland” towns that had found manufacturing- such as New York and Los Angeles—have pulled based prosperity in the 20th century. away and secured themselves as America’s core domain of advanced industry activity.4 These Amid these conditions, convergence gave way to SODFHVHQMR\WKHEHQHoWVRIZKDWHFRQRPLVWVFDOO “divergence.” Over time, a fortunate upper tier cumulative causation, through which their earlier of big, techy metro areas (about 20 in all) began NQRZOHGJHDQGoUPDGYDQWDJHVQRZDWWUDFWHYHQ to consistently grow faster than the median and more talented workers, startups, and investment, less-prosperous ones. creating a gravitational pull toward the nation’s critical innovation sectors while simultaneously By the 2010s, a clear hierarchy of economic draining key talent and business activity from performance based on innovation capacity had other places. become deeply entrenched.3 Large innovation THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 11
TERMINOLOGY “Advanced industries” are America’s 50 high-R&D, high- “Superstar cities” are the 20 metropolitan areas with the STEM manufacturing, energy, and services industries, largest absolute number of jobs in innovation industries. ranging from aerospace and automobile manufacturing to These mostly coastal, high-tech metro areas represent solar electricity generation to internet publishing to bio- about 5% of the nation’s metropolitan areas and are almost tech. all growing relatively rapidly. “Innovation industries” are a subset of advanced Source: Mark Muro and others, “America’s Advanced industries that include the 13 most STEM- and R&D- Industries: What They Are, Where They Are, and Why They intensive industries. Matter.” (Washington: Brookings Institution, 2015). In contrast, most midsized cities and smaller For the many metro areas that are going towns (let alone rural areas) have struggled to sideways or declining, the struggle to keep up has make progress in amassing critical innovation brought a mood of desperation as their fears of industries, with many falling farther behind. For VWDJQDWLRQKDYHEHHQUHDOL]HG3XEOLFRIoFLDOV most of them, “innovation” or advanced-industry- working families, and business and development sector employment and incomes have declined. leaders in these places are often deeply Many such places have been left to cope with frustrated and at a loss for what to do to get brain drain, the hollowing out of the labor market, onto the prosperity track—in part because many and industrial decline. of the most well-intentioned local interventions, such as tech-based economic development As a result, few can now deny that the programs, have proven incomplete on their own. imbalanced geography of America’s current Indeed, since these efforts are all chasing a economy is spawning disturbing negative limited amount of innovation activity, they almost externalities—or side effects—that cry out for all are falling short in their quest to reach the response. needed “critical mass” to succeed, while the less fortunate of them face the corrosion of drift, Among the superstar metros, the “winner-take- brain drain, and lost capacity. most” dynamics of the innovation economy have led to dominance thanks to their deep $QGIRUWKHQDWLRQDVDZKROHoQDOO\WKH SRROVRIWDOHQWDGYDQFHGoUPVDQGFDSLWDO%XW juxtaposition between a few dominant those dynamics have also spawned tumultuous innovation stars and the many other places OLYDELOLW\FULVHVVSLUDOLQJUHDOHVWDWHFRVWVWUDIoF trending sideways or downward raises broader gridlock, and homelessness.5 Firms in these problems. For the aggregate economy, there metro areas increasingly move activity elsewhere, is the likelihood that while the importance of or launch it in other places, although too often star agglomerations remains unquestionable, the move is to lower-cost overseas tech hubs, WRRPXFKLVEHLQJVDFULoFHGWKURXJKWKH rather than equally cost-competitive centers underperformance of so many less successful LQWKH8QLWHG6WDWHV6XFKG\QDPLFVUHSUHVHQW regions.7 WUXHGLVHFRQRPLHVRIVFDOHDQGGUDJVRQ86 competitiveness.6 THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 12
At the same time, civic and political leaders have grown deeply concerned about the social and political side effects of such unevenness.8 For Few can now deny that the some, the isolation of millions of people from imbalanced geography of America’s the dynamic innovation economies of superstar metro areas is a justice issue.9 For others, the current economy is spawning fear looms that the widening gap between the disturbing negative externalities— superstars and everybody else is eroding the national ideal of equal access to opportunity.10 or side effects—that cry out for response. All of which raises the question of what ought to be done about the concentration of the innovation sector, and the regional imbalances it entails. tech cities and the drift of most everywhere else seem tenable. Instead, a growing number Historically, the convergence trend of the of voices are concluding that a new set of economy minimized worry about the nation’s viewpoints and policies are needed to actively uneven economic geography. Wage convergence— respond to the imbalances of today’s innovation companies in high-wage areas moving to lower- map—not only to heal geographic divides, but wage ones—supported the belief that regional WRDGYDQFHWKH86 VLQQRYDWLRQEDVHGJOREDO imbalances would naturally even out, thanks to competitiveness. WKHLQKHUHQWO\HIoFLHQWDQGZHOIDUHPD[LPL]LQJ nature of the market economy. However, more $QG\HWIRUDOORIWKDWIHZVSHFLoFDQG recently, other voices have noted the powerful substantial ideas for countering the winner-take- positive links of innovation and agglomeration, most dynamics of the innovation sector have and warned that efforts to reduce variation been forthcoming. To the extent any are offered, across places might be detrimental to the they mostly resemble lectures on self-help, based innovation sector’s ability to drive national on the opinion that if local leaders were just a bit productivity.11 more creative, they could overcome the powerful forces of cumulative causation on their own.14 Accordingly, mainstream economists have until recently remained largely unphased by the Which is where this report comes in. Concerned nation’s spatial divides and thus skeptical of ideas WKDWWKHGLYHUJHQFHRI86PHWURDUHDVKDV to counter it.12 Such scholars would have the become self-reinforcing and destructive, the nation rely mainly on spurring migration from discussion that follows presumes that the time lagging to leading regions, ignoring the fact that has come for the nation to offset the domination most leading regions are already bursting at the of innovation superstars with a concerted seams—not to mention that many Americans intervention to support the emergence of at retain deeply rooted ties to their home places. least a few new stars in new places. As such, this brief urges the federal government to undertake In recent years, however, the heightened a major new effort to counter divergence with awareness of regional imbalances, especially a robust set of carefully targeted innovation, in the innovation sector, has prompted new business-development, placemaking, and responses. Economists, investors, politicians, related investments of a type only it can deliver journalists, and economic development leaders systematically. This effort would at once add to are all beginning to reassess the costs of inaction the nation’s net innovation effort (as is sorely after decades of exactly that.13 No longer does needed), spur global competitiveness, and push nonchalance about the pull-away of superstar back against the nation’s dangerous economic divides.15 THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 13
markets acting alone won’t solve the divergence problem, and proceeds to argue why robust The transformation of even a short intervention will be necessary. list of metro areas in new, interior From there, the report plays out one possible UHVSRQVHWRWKHH[FHVVLYHFRQFHQWUDWLRQRI86 areas could be expected to improve innovation activity in superstar cities: a plan for the fortunes of whole regions building up dynamic new growth centers in a set of promising metropolitan areas that have modest but not dominant existing strengths. Section 6 of the report articulates a vision for In pursuing this vision, the report assumes that updating the concept of “growth poles” as a while the innovation economy can be more theory for creating more innovation centers geographically dispersed, not every place can across the nation, and Section 7 lays out what become an advanced industry hub. In fact, a federal, innovation-based growth centers the following discussion suggests that only a program might look like, including how the modest number of places are likely to be able to government might select eight to 10 promising transform themselves into self-sustaining tech metro areas and provide them with a host of hubs with large-scale (but temporary) help from innovation inputs in order to become strong, self- the federal government, if for no other reason sustaining technology hubs. than the innovation economy is not big enough to act as the engine of growth for an extremely After that, Section 8 shows how one possible set large number of places. At the same time, the of selection criteria for growth center contestants transformation of even a short list of metro presents an array of up-and-coming locations areas in new, interior areas could be expected to whose accelerated emergence could improve improve the fortunes of whole regions, opening on the nation’s imbalanced geography. Section up new possibilities for intraregional worker 9 anticipates and responds to the possible mobility and deeper supply chain ties. This objections, and Section 10 concludes the report. transformation should be vigorously pursued, because it will affect not only the targeted cities To be sure, ours is not a strategy for mitigating but surrounding communities as well. the full enormity of the nation’s regional imbalances, or for jump-starting scores of worthy Accordingly, the paper urges the federal metro areas (that is the even more expansive government to update a forgotten 1960s and vision espoused in Jonathan Gruber and Simon 1970s strategy—growth poles—for transforming Johnson’s book, Jump-Starting America).16 Our promising places by fusing it with modern “growth centers” proposal, rather, is focused on methods. Metropolitan areas would compete accelerating the growth of the most promising yet WRZLQPDVVLYHLQpRZVRIIHGHUDOUHVHDUFK lagging metropolitan areas in the nation’s interior, business development, and placemaking inputs rather than on saving the most distressed cities DQGEHQHoWVLQH[FKDQJHIRULPSOHPHQWLQJEROG and towns across the vast totality of America’s innovation, economic growth, and transformation economy. That too needs doing, but that work strategies. lies beyond the scope of this proposal. Instead, we focus here on the dangerous core problem In that vein, the discussion here begins by of the hyperconcentration of the innovation reviewing the entrenched nature of America’s and advanced industries economy, accepting concentrated innovation sector and why it is that even on that narrower front it is simply not a problem. After that, the report explains why possible to “target” everywhere at once. THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 14
The focus of this report is on distributing high- strategy and promising potential participants quality economic development more widely exist for spreading innovation-driven growth DFURVVWKH8QLWHG6WDWHVLQSDUWE\VWLPXODWLQJ farther across the nation’s map. Individual metro new innovative activity in the most promising areas, whole new regions including smaller metro areas proximate to more places in the nearby communities, and the nation as a whole country’s interior. Such an innovation surge is ZRXOGEHQHoWIURPVXFKDQLQLWLDWLYH0RUHRYHULI only one part of the needed push to counter America is to avoid ceding its innovation lead to the nation’s regional divergence, but it should China, it is vital that we create more innovation be counted as an important element of such a hubs in America, if for no other reason than to campaign. Such a campaign has a good chance JLYHDGYDQFHGWHFKQRORJ\oUPVLQWKH8QLWHG of beginning to stem the epidemic of inequality States an alternative to places like Shanghai and in the nation by helping places beyond the Shenzhen for their future growth. immediate targets of action, which would likely EHQHoWIURPWKHSURJUDPWKURXJKVXSSO\FKDLQ The same is true if we are going to cease labor market, and other spillover gains. growing apart and begin to grow together again. Accelerating the emergence of 10 new growth In sum, this report argues that the moment is centers in the heartland would help with that. urgent and the prospects favorable for launching It is time, then, for Congress and a farsighted a major national push to counter regional administration to embrace the present challenge divergence—and with it, the nation’s current crisis and opportunity. of economic and social inequality. Both a feasible THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 15
2. The entrenched geography of America’s innovation industries T he steady narrowing of economic $VWKH86SURGXFWLRQV\VWHPJUHZDIWHU:RUOG GLVSDULWLHVDPRQJ86UHJLRQVWKURXJK War II—powered by nationwide telephony, most of the last century licensed a strong the interstate highway system, air travel FRQoGHQFHDPRQJHFRQRPLVWVWKDWUHJLRQDOJDSV and, importantly for the South and West, air would “naturally” close.17 Initially as a fact and conditioning—manufacturing and corporate then as a reassuring orthodoxy, the conventional functions that had historically been centralized wisdom assumed that even seriously lagging in the Midwest and Northeast now had many regions would “catch-up” to leaders through more options for where they could locate. Given natural equilibrium processes, as the “costs” of that many of the mass production industries of success—such as increased labor or real estate the time had evolved to compete primarily on costs—accumulated and eventually motivated costs, it made sense that as costs increased in oUPVDQGZRUNHUVWRUHORFDWHWRORZHUFRVW some regions, industry would grow faster in less- regions. expensive regions, which would then “catch-up.” THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 16
For years, regional trends comported with such DIVERGENCE AT WORK IN THE neoclassical theory. From 1880 to 1980, incomes INNOVATION SECTOR across states “converged” at a rate of 1.8% a year.18 In other words, low-income states grew The geography of the nation’s most important faster than high-income ones. Wages in poorer industries—its core “innovation industries,” which metropolitan areas likewise grew 1.4% faster are a key portion of its 50 most “advanced” than those in higher-wage metro areas between industries—epitomizes the new dynamic.22 1940 and 1980.19 These trends, coupled with the America’s innovation sector has, in truth, seen simplistic, cost-based version of neoclassical few triumphal “catch-up” stories and very little economics that many economists subscribed to, diffusion into new places. In fact, despite four licensed great optimism about the self-regulating decades of state and local technology-based nature of the nation’s regional dynamics. economic development policies, what we call WKH86kLQQRYDWLRQVHFWRUy UDQJLQJIURP Nor has that hands-off view of regional pharmaceutical manufacturing and aerospace imbalance fully dissipated, even as convergence products to software publishing and data broke down in recent decades. Right up to the services) has remained strikingly immobile and election of President Trump, most economists highly concentrated in a short list of “superstar” seemed to have assumed that market forces metropolitan areas for many years. would still correct for harmful variations among places and lead to greater regional balance, at This concentration is important because the least in time.20 At most, they held, the federal innovation sector—consisting of 13 of the government could provide free bus tickets for nation’s highest-R&D industries (at the four- auto workers in Flint, Mich. to move to Silicon digit NAICS code level)—matters inordinately Valley, where they could be retrained as software for the nation’s competitiveness and prosperity, engineers. given that innovation industries encompass the nation’s “tech” sector at its most dynamic, And yet, market forces haven’t reduced such competitive, and valuable.23 As a group, these gaps in recent decades, and especially not 13 industries—which also include chemicals, when it comes to the geography of the nation’s computer equipment manufacturing, telecom, innovation sector. Nor has the problem been a DQG5 'VHUYLFHVLQRUGLQDWHO\FRQWULEXWHWR86 lack of bus tickets. Instead, the welcome reality prosperity. While innovation industries account of convergence has been faltering and in fact for just 3% of the nation’s jobs, they generate 6% shifting towards divergence—the polarization of of the nation’s GDP, a quarter of its exports, and places. Several careful researchers have looked two-thirds of business R&D expenditures. They across the economy and tracked dramatic also support solid economic multipliers in their declines of income and other measures of regions (and nationally), and provide especially prosperity across states and metropolitan area well-paying jobs even for workers without a in the years 1980 until now.21 This should not be bachelor’s degree.24 surprising, given that the innovation industries of the last 40 years largely do not compete on cost :KLFKLVZK\LWZRXOGEHH[WUHPHO\EHQHoFLDO but rather on the richness of the local innovation if more of the nation’s innovation activity was ecosystem, where success begets more success. diffusing outward, so that more metropolitan But the change, while slow to be fully recognized, areas were joining the nation’s assortment of has at last been recognized as an emergency. THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 17
“INNOVATION INDUSTRIES” AND “SUPERSTAR METRO AREAS” DEFINED The “innovation sector” as discussed here is an especially “Superstar metro areas” are the 20 metropolitan areas high-tech subsector of the “advanced industries” sector, an with the largest absolute numbers of jobs in innovation earlier delineation of America’s highest-value industries by industries. These mostly coastal, high-tech places represent the Metropolitan Policy Program at Brookings. about 5% of the nation’s metropolitan areas and are almost all growing relatively rapidly. The 20 superstar metro areas “Innovation industries” encompass America’s 13 highest- are: tech, highest-R&D industries. Selected from among the 50 advanced industries, the 13 innovation industries represent • New York-Newark-Jersey City, NY-NJ-PA a cohort whose R&D expenditures exceed $20,000 per • San Jose-Sunnyvale-Santa Clara, CA worker and have a STEM-worker share of 45%. The 13 • Los Angeles-Long Beach-Anaheim, CA innovation industries include: • Seattle-Tacoma-Bellevue, WA • Boston-Cambridge-Newton, MA-NH • Basic chemical manufacturing • San Francisco-Oakland-Hayward, CA • Pesticide, fertilizer, and agricultural chemical • Dallas-Fort Worth-Arlington, TX manufacturing • Washington-Arlington-Alexandria, DC-VA-MD-WV • Pharmaceutical and medicine manufacturing • San Diego-Carlsbad, CA • Computer and peripheral equipment manufacturing • Chicago-Naperville-Elgin, IL-IN-WI • Communications equipment manufacturing • Philadelphia-Camden-Wilmington, PA-NJ-DE-MD • Semiconductor and other electronic components • Phoenix-Mesa-Scottsdale, AZ manufacturing • Minneapolis-St. Paul-Bloomington, MN-WI • Navigational, measuring, electromedical, and control • Houston-The Woodlands-Sugar Land, TX instruments manufacturing • Portland-Vancouver-Hillsboro, OR-WA • Aerospace product and parts manufacturing • Atlanta-Sandy Springs-Roswell, GA • Software publishers • Austin-Round Rock, TX • Satellite telecommunications • St. Louis, MO-IL • Data processing, hosting, and related services • Denver-Aurora-Lakewood, CO • Other information services • Miami-Fort Lauderdale-West Palm Beach, FL • 6FLHQWLoFUHVHDUFKDQGGHYHORSPHQWVHUYLFHV Source: Mark Muro and others, “America’s Advanced Industries: What They Are, Where They Are, and Why They Matter.” (Washington: Brookings Institution, 2015). THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 18
innovation hubs. However, that’s not what has (localization), and take advantage of dense air been happening. Instead, strong centripetal and ground transport links (urbanization). forces—the so-called “localization” and “urbanization”25 dynamics of agglomeration— Map 1 illustrates the strength of agglomeration have produced a remarkably entrenched in the innovation sector. Fully one-third of the LQQRYDWLRQVHFWRUJHRJUDSK\LQWKH8QLWHG nation’s innovation jobs reside in just the 16 States. Two industry-level examples are the counties (those shaded dark blue) that contain nation’s world-class life sciences and digital 1% or more each of the nation’s innovation services sectors, which have remained extremely employment. concentrated in a relatively short list of metropolitan areas.26%HFDXVHoUPVLQVXFK For that matter, more than half of the nation’s innovation industries compete on the basis of innovation jobs are concentrated in just the 41 product and process innovation rather than cost- counties with at least 0.5% of the jobs in the minimization, and are more reliant on knowledge innovation sector. That these counties account for than other industries, they tend to cluster in less than 27% of the nation’s aggregate job total large metropolitan areas where they can tap underscores the strong tendency of innovation specialized workers, suppliers, and institutions industries to cluster in select large regions where related activity is already taking place.27 Map 1. U.S. counties by share of total innovation sector jobs, 2017 1.0% - 5.9% 0.5% - 1.0% 0.0% - 0.5% Source: Brookings and ITIF analysis of Emsi data THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 19
Figure 2. Innovation sector job creation has been strongest in metro areas that already have the largest sectors FIGURE 2 Innovation sector employment index (2005 = 100), 2005-17 115 110 FIGURE URE 3 3 105 2.0% 1.5% 100 1.5% 1.5% 1.0% 95 1.5% 1.5% 0.7% 0.5% 90 0.7% 2005 0.7% 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 0.0% 0.7% Bottom 75% Next 15% Next 5% Top 5% -0.5% 1RWH3HUFHQWDJHkELQVyUHpHFWFRKRUWVRIPHWURDUHDVUDQNHGLQHDFK\HDU7KHkWRSyLQFOXGHVPHWURV Source: Brookings and ITIF analysis of Emsi data 1.0% -1.0% 1.0% % Figure 3. Innovation industries became more geographically concentrated since FIGURE 3 -1.5% the start of the century Change 2001 - 2005 in share of all innovation jobs in 2005 - 2012 metros, 2001-17 2012 - 2017 2001 - 2005 2005 - 2012 2012 - 2017 2.0% Bottom 75% Next 15% Next 5% Top 5% 2005 - 2012 2012 - 2017 Bottom 75% Next 15% Next 5% Top 5% 05 - 2012 2012 - 2017 Next 15% 1.5% Next 5% Top 5% Next 5% Top 5% 1.5% 1.0% 0.7% 0.5% 0.0% -0.5% 1.0% -1.0% -1.5% 2001 - 2005 2005 - 2012 2012 - 2017 1RWH3HUFHQWDJHkELQVyUHpHFWFRKRUWVRIPHWURDUHDVUDQNHGLQHDFK\HDU7KHkWRSyLQFOXGHVPHWURV Bottom Source: Brookings and 75% of Emsi data ITIF analysis Next 15% Next 5% Top 5% THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 20
Looking beneath the snapshot furnished by Map widening—driven in particular by the pull-away 1, Figures 2, 3, 4, and 5 explore the underlying of the top 10% of innovation-job-rich metro innovation sector dynamics driving the nation’s areas. For the 90% of metro areas with fewer remarkable degree of agglomeration at the innovation jobs, however, total employment has metro-area level. effectively remained unchanged in the last 12 years. To begin with, the line chart in Figure 2 makes clear the innovation sector’s concentration has 7KHIROORZLQJEDUFKDUW )LJXUH SXWVDoQHU become self-reinforcing and divergent over point on this divergence by looking at changes in time, to the extent that the innovation “rich” are the share of total innovation jobs by metro-area getting richer as the metro areas with the largest echelons. sectors steadily gained additional innovation employment while most metro areas went The top 5% of metro areas by innovation jobs, sideways. depicted in dark blue, have increased their share of the nation’s total innovation employment Far from catching up, most metro areas have since 2005 while all other size cohorts have been slipping farther behind. This tendency drifted or lost share (the 1 percentage point loss has been strong and sharpening in the last 15 of innovation employment share in the 2001 to years. Since 2005, as the line chart indicates, SHULRGODUJHO\UHpHFWVWKHEXVWRIWKH the geographic divergence of tech-sector tech “bubble”). employment across metro areas has been Figure 4. Localization economies make innovation industries clustered together FIGURE 4 more productive Avg. output per worker by industry group, 2017 $400,000 $371,306 $350,000 $300,000 $264,119 $260,658 $246,265 $250,000 $200,000 $150,000 $100,000 $50,000 $0 Bottom 75% Next 15% Next 5% Top 5% Basic manufacturing Retail Healthcare Finance Innovation industries 1RWH3HUFHQWDJHkELQVyUHpHFWFRKRUWVRIPHWURDUHDVUDQNHGLQHDFK\HDU7KHkWRSyLQFOXGHVPHWURV Source: Brookings and ITIF analysis of Emsi data THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 21
Figure 5. Urbanization economies benefit innovation industries located in larger FIGURE 5 markets Avg. output per worker by industry group, 2017 $450,000 $400,000 $382,291 $344,717 $350,000 $300,000 $263,958 $250,138 $250,000 $200,000 $150,000 $100,000 $50,000 $0 Bottom 75% Next 15% Next 5% Top 5% Basic manufacturing Retail Healthcare Finance Innovation industries 1RWH3HUFHQWDJHkELQVyUHpHFWFRKRUWVRIPHWURDUHDVUDQNHGLQHDFK\HDU7KHkWRSyLQFOXGHVPHWURV Source: Brookings and ITIF analysis of Emsi data The top 20’s share of all metro-area innovation Among metro areas, the average output per jobs rose from 59% to nearly 61% in the period worker in innovation industries rises with both since 2001, even though they accounted for only the absolute number of jobs in the sector 45% of metro-area jobs across all industries. in a given metro area (Figure 4UHpHFWLQJ Moreover, the gains among second-tier metro “localization” economies) and the total number of areas in the early 2000s were more than offset jobs in the metro area overall (Figure 5UHpHFWLQJ by innovation sector employment concentration “urbanization” economies). in the top 20 between 2005 and 2017—a 2.2 percentage point increase among the top 20 at Average innovation sector labor productivity the expense of the bottom 90% (equal to 343 in the top 5% of metro areas with the most metro areas). By 2017, two-thirds of innovation innovation sector jobs—plotted to the far right, sector output originated in those same top 20 UHpHFWLQJDPHUHSODFHVLVPRUHWKDQ metro areas, once again pointing to the clear higher than it is in the 75% of metro areas productivity advantages they continue to confer plotted to the left, which have the fewest RQoUPVWKHUH innovation jobs and encompass 287 different metro areas. The magnitude of this sector-level Figure 4 and Figure 5 show the underlying disparity is similar when metro areas are grouped productivity dynamics driving this remarkable by total employment. degree of agglomeration at the metro-area level. THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 22
By contrast, this relationship appears much GHFDGH$VVXFKWKHoYHPHWURDUHDVFROOHFWLYHO\ weaker for less innovation-centric industry increased their aggregate share of the nation’s groups such as basic manufacturing and health innovation jobs by 5.2 percentage points, from FDUH ZLWKWKHH[FHSWLRQRIoQDQFHDQRWKHU 17.6% in 2005 to 22.8% in 2017. More broadly, traded service sector). some 40 of the largest 100 metro areas increased their share of the sector, although the gains were Mapping some of these patterns further PLQLVFXOHRXWVLGHWKHWRSoYH highlights how a truly small set of “superstar” cities has been determining the nation’s By contrast, 60 of the largest metro areas innovation geography. In this vein, Map 2 shows lost ground, with many seeing quite dramatic that a very short list of large coastal metropolitan shrinkages of their participation in America’s areas has substantially increased its preeminence innovation economy. In this respect, no fewer in innovation industries since 2005, while a very WKDQRXWRI86PHWURDUHDVKDYHVHHQ long list of metro areas actually lost ground. (For their share of the national innovation sector metro-area statistics see Appendix A). decline since 2005. What’s more, 191 metro areas actually shed innovation sector jobs during 2YHUDOOMXVWoYHkVXSHUVWDUyPHWURDUHDV the time period. For instance, absolute local Boston, the San Francisco Bay area (San employment in the innovation sector fell by Francisco and San Jose), Seattle, and San over 20% between 2005 and 2017 in Colorado DiegoDFFRXQWHGIRUVRPHRIDOO86 Springs, Colo., Providence, R.I., Sacramento, innovation-sector growth between 2005 and Calif., Albuquerque, N.M., and Wichita, Kan. 2017. These gains mostly transpired in the digital To be sure, several interior metro areas such as and biopharmaceutical expansion of the last Madison, Wis., Raleigh, N.C., Atlanta, Denver, Map 2. Only a handful of superstar metro areas have seen their share of innovation jobs increase since 2005 Metros by change in share of total innovation sector jobs Share of innovation sector jobs change, 2005-17 0.4% - 2.0% 0.0% - 0.4% 0.0% -0.1% - 0.0% -0.7% - -0.1% Innovation sector jobs, 2005 Top 5% of metros Next 5% Next 15% Bottom 75% Source: Brookings and ITIF analysis of Emsi data THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 23
Salt Lake City, and Provo, Utah have increased WKHLUVKDUHRI86LQQRYDWLRQMREVHYHQDVWKH superstars boomed. But even so, most metro 1RIHZHUWKDQRXWRI86 areas have gone sideways or lost innovation share. In the Midwest and South, multiple metro areas have seen their share metro areas with solid industry, university, and of the national innovation sector workforce assets such as Des Moines, Iowa, Charlotte, N.C. and Minneapolis have added decline since 2005. innovation jobs, but failed to increase their share of the national sector, while metro areas such Chicago and Wichita have both shed innovation jobs and national share. More broadly, most of the nation’s major business hubs—including Los Angeles, Dallas, Washington, D.C., Philadelphia, New York, and Houston—have lost purchase in the sector. All of this points to the extent to which the pull of agglomeration compounds over time in the innovation sector, leaving most places behind and putting those metro areas that lack a self- sustaining critical mass of innovation sector activity at an increasing disadvantage. THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 24
3. The costs of hyperconcentration W hy, though, is this intense concentration and services-led growth.29 At the same time, of the nation’s innovation sector such a ameliorative subsidies or other interventions problem? Might the nation’s unbalanced for places that lacked the right mix of size, degree of spatial concentration be the optimal, skills, infrastructure, and amenities were seen— PDUNHWRUGDLQHGJHRJUDSKLFDOFRQoJXUDWLRQIRU at least by federally oriented economists and maximizing innovation? SROLF\PDNHUVDVLPSHGLPHQWVWRWKHHIoFLHQW movement of capital and labor into dense urban To be sure, intense, even extreme, geographic markets where they would receive their highest concentration has long been viewed as inevitable, return. benign, and mostly desirable for advanced economies.28 In this regard, the work of building tech agglomerations has fallen mostly to state In recent decades, agglomeration economies—a and local policymakers, who have made do feature of regional economics for more than a with only small denominations of funding and century—have been understood to be the focal programs that often ended with each political points of national prosperity in an era of tech- administration. At the federal level, meanwhile, THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 25
the proper role of policy was simply to facilitate workers now commute more than an hour to factor mobility by focusing on eliminating work in San Francisco, San Jose, Seattle, and frictions and lowering costs (especially housing) Boston, compared to just 6% in all metropolitan in the country’s most productive metro regions.30 areas. Home prices have more than doubled in Given the assumed big “trade-off” between the Bay Area over the same period, with median HIoFLHQF\DQGHTXLW\WRGRDQ\WKLQJHOVHZRXOG rents for a one-bedroom apartment exceeding be to compromise growth.31 $1,500 a month in both San Francisco and San Jose.33 Indeed, such high housing prices mean The present decade has, however, seen the LWLVQRZQRWXQFRPPRQWRoQGHYHQVRIWZDUH EUHDNGRZQRIWKLVFRQoGHQWQDUUDWLYHDVVFKRODUV developers in the Bay Area living out of their cars and policymakers have begun to recognize the or Winnebagos.34 Such externalities represent untenable economic, social, and political costs of VL]DEOHGUDJVRQUHJLRQDODQGQDWLRQDOHIoFLHQF\ sustained territorial polarization and industrial concentration. At the same time, the current reconsideration of the laissez faire orthodoxy on geographical ECONOMIC COSTS trends has been further driven by frustration with economic stagnation in so many of America’s left- At the economic end of the equation, the costs behind places. 35 In these places, shuttered plants, of hyperconcentration in large innovation faded downtowns, and depopulated residential agglomerations are impossible to ignore. Since neighborhoods exemplify the economic and 2010, average commute times have nearly social costs of regional imbalance. As such, the doubled in San Jose, Calif. and increased by “winner-take-most” ascent of the superstar two-thirds in San Francisco.32 Over 30% of Map 3. Spiking housing costs are one major consequence of the hyperconcentration of innovation sector jobs Metros by housing affordability Ratio of median household income to median housing costs, 2017 12.8% - 15.0% 15.0% - 18.0% 18.0% - 21.0% 21.0% - 24.0% 24.0% - 28.3% Population, 2017 Over 5,000,000 2,500,000 - 5,000,00 1,000,000 - 2,500,000 500,000 - 1,000,000 Less than 500,000 Source: Brookings and ITIF analysis of Emsi data THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 26
metro areas has increasingly been accompanied workers increasingly remain in places with by the decline of virtually everywhere else. diminishing job prospects (both at home and in the distant, more vibrant cities) and slow or 7KLVGHFOLQHLVQRZLPSRVLQJkHIoFLHQF\y stagnant wage growth.37 costs both on communities and the nation. For starters, the divergent, striated economic map These patterns ensure that the nation’s overall is beginning to affect the geographic sorting of ODERUPDUNHWLVEHFRPLQJLQHIoFLHQWO\DQG workers, with negative impacts on the nation’s stubbornly ill-sorted. Metro areas heavily overall welfare. While some economists believe oriented toward innovation work are able to worker migration from low- to high-productivity attract and retain high-skill workers from out-of- places will increase the nation’s aggregate state and abroad, adding to their stock of human HIoFLHQF\UHFHQWVFKRODUVKLSHPSKDVL]HVWKDW capital. By contrast, less innovation-oriented geographic mobility has slowed, limiting its ability metro areas are losing their more mobile, high- WRHUDVHUHJLRQDOSURGXFWLYLW\GLYLGHV6SHFLoFDOO\ skill workers (and the positive externalities they economists Elisa Giannone, David Autor, Peter provide to other workers) while lower-skill, less- Ganong, and Daniel Shoag have all shown that mobile workers remain behind. Over time, these what migration has been occurring is now crosscurrents have locked in place a dangerous sharply segmented by education, with serious VWULDWLRQRIWDOHQWSRROLQJWKDWZLOOEHGLIoFXOWWR implications for non-college-educated workers’ alter absent national-scale intervention. employment prospects.36 Additional market problems result from Consequently, a problematic “sorting” of workers the spread and persistence of economic has developed, as suggested by Table 1. College- underperformance across large swaths of the educated workers have been clustering in fast- nation, raising the possibility that whole regions growing agglomerations with large innovation may be falling into “traps” of underdevelopment, sectors (leaving behind other metro areas with whereby underperforming regions begin to lose thinner talent reservoirs), while noncollege the capacity to catch up to frontier regions at all. Table 1. Innovation hubs draw in highly educated workers, while less-educated workers face declining employment prospects everywhere else Share not in Share of adults with at least a BA, 2017 labor force, 2017 Prime-aged All Out-of-state Foreign Innovation sector jobs adults without residents migrants migrants a BA Top 5% of metros 39.0% 56.2% 55.6% 20.4% Next 5% of metros 34.9% 47.7% 51.5% 20.7% Next 15% of metros 32.0% 43.8% 44.7% 21.2% Bottom 75% of metros 26.4% 35.7% 40.1% 23.4% Note: Migrants relocated sometime in the preceding year. Prime-aged adults are ages 25 to 54. 6RXUFH%URRNLQJVDQG,7,)DQDO\VLVRI,380686$$&6\HDUPLFURGDWD THE CASE FOR GROWTH CENTERS 27
You can also read