So You Think You Can Dance? Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

Page created by Shawn Kennedy
 
CONTINUE READING
So You Think You Can Dance? Lessons from the U.S. Private
Equity Bubble
Catherine J. Turco, Ezra W. Zuckerman
Massachusetts Institute of Technology

    Abstract: This article develops a sociologically informed approach to market bubbles by integrating insights from
    financial-economic theory with the concepts of voice and dissimulation from other cases of distorted valuation studied
    by sociologists (e.g., witch hunts, unpopular norms, and support for authoritarian regimes). It draws on unique data—
    longitudinal interviews with private equity market participants during and after that market’s mid-2000s bubble—to test
    key implications of two existing theories of bubbles and to move beyond both. In doing so, the article suggests a crucial
    revision to the behavioral finance agenda, wherein bubbles may pertain less to the cognitive errors individuals make when
    estimating asset values and more to the sociological and institutionally driven challenge of how to interpret complex
    social and competitive environments.
    Keywords: financial markets; bubbles; valuation; private equity
    Editor(s): Jesper Sørensen, Olav Sorenson; Received: September 16, 2013; Accepted: October 27, 2013; Published: March 24, 2014
    Citation: Turco, Catherine J., and Ezra W. Zuckerman. 2014. “So You Think You Can Dance? Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble.” Sociological
    Science 1: 81-101. DOI: 10.15195/v1.a7
    Copyright: c 2014 Turco and Zuckerman. This open-access article has been published and distributed under a Creative Commons Attribution License,
    which allows unrestricted use, distribution and reproduction, in any form, as long as the original author and source have been credited.

   vexing question for both social scientists and                                ticular community, thus limiting their use of exit,
A   policy makers is why public valuations (the
majority’s publicly enacted preferences) often be-
                                                                                 and voicing dissent may be socially risky, even if
                                                                                 formally permissible.
come wildly disjointed from objective conditions.                                    From this perspective, though, financial mar-
Well-known examples include moral panics like                                    ket bubbles are hard to explain. After all, finan-
witch hunts, in which fantastical beliefs are widely                             cial markets are defined by vehicles for exit and
endorsed; the cult of personality in authoritar-                                 voice, with such vehicles eliminating distortions
ian regimes, where millions of people proclaim                                   in prevailing public valuations (prices). Consider
allegiance to a cruel leader or bankrupt ideology;                               the stock market. If investors believe stocks are
norms that are broadly enforced despite question-                                overpriced, they can exit by selling their shares,
able social value; and financial market bubbles,                                 thus lowering prices. Also, investors can publicly
when prices greatly exceed valuations justified by                               question the inflated prices with no attendant
the economic fundamentals.                                                       social risk, both informally and through various
    A common account of such episodes is that                                    forms of arbitrage. Because such arbitrage gen-
people have succumbed to mass hysteria or delu-                                  erates high returns when skeptical investors are
sion. However, sociological and political science                                right, significant gaps between price and value
studies highlight mechanisms of exit and voice                                   should never endure. Accordingly, the orthodox
(Hirschman 1970). That is, support for author-                                   financial-economic view of bubbles—as summa-
itarian regimes often depends less on citizens’                                  rized in the efficient market hypothesis (EMH)—
delusion about how the regime governs and more                                   argues that the mechanisms supporting exit and
on restrictions on speech and assembly that si-                                  voice in markets are so powerful, and the incen-
lence their dissent, and on social pressure that                                 tives for using them so high, that bubbles are
motivates them to dissimulate (publicly feign al-                                effectively impossible (Garber 2000).
legiance) (Wedeen 1999). Similar logic holds in                                      Yet bubbles do occur. Examples include Dutch
less extreme cases like moral panics and ques-                                   tulips in the 1630s, shares of the South Sea Com-
tionable norms (Centola, Willer, and Macy 2005).                                 pany in 1720, the U.S. stock market of the 1920s,
There, actors may be highly committed to a par-                                  Internet stocks in the late 1990s, U.S. housing

sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com                          81                                                  March 2014 | Volume 1
Turco and Zuckerman                                                               Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

in the 2000s, and the subject of this article—                  gies that dissenting investors adopt and that fuel
the mid-2000s U.S. private equity bubble, when                  bubbles.
asset prices rose far above historic levels. Echo-
ing accounts of other distorted public valuations,              Silenced Voice through Rational
heterodox scholars have adopted one of two ap-
                                                                Sitting
proaches when explaining these phenomena.
                                                                During a bubble, short selling is the key way skep-
                                                                tical investors can dissent from prevailing public
Collective Delusion                                             valuations and correct market distortions. It is
                                                                the market equivalent of standing in the common
The most prominent heterodox approach assumes
                                                                square and proclaiming that the authoritarian
that bubbles inflate when a majority of investors
                                                                regime is bankrupt or the witch hunt overblown.
become collectively deluded about asset values.1
                                                                Specifically, it involves an investor borrowing a
By some accounts, investors are driven to un-
                                                                security the investor thinks is overpriced and
reasonable estimates of value when they con-
                                                                selling it at that inflated price, then buying it
vince themselves that “this time is different”—
                                                                back later after the price has fallen to repay the
that inflated prices make sense because of fun-
                                                                original owner and keep the profit. When ortho-
damental economic changes invalidating “the old
                                                                dox theory assumes that bubbles are impossible
rules of financial valuation” (Reinhart and Rogoff
                                                                because price–value distortions are immediately
2009:xxxiv). Some argue that inflated valuations
                                                                eliminated, it explicitly assumes this sort of arbi-
are especially likely when investors can obtain
                                                                trage is unrestricted and riskless.
capital (in particular credit) cheaply because in-
                                                                    In reality, short sellers risk massive losses if
vestors often ignore the cost of financing when
                                                                prices continue to rise before correcting (De Long
estimating asset values (Minsky 1975, 1992). In
                                                                et al. 1990a; Shleifer and Vishny 1997). Risk
general, behavioral economists focus on cognitive
                                                                aside, short selling opportunities are often quite
biases that lead investors to make mathemati-
                                                                limited too. For example, the small float of In-
cal errors or factual mistakes when estimating
                                                                ternet stocks prevented dissenters from shorting
asset values (Lamont and Thaler 2003; Rashes
                                                                the 1990s bubble (Ofek and Richardson 2003),
2001), whereas sociologists emphasize investors’
                                                                and before 2006, there were no institutional vehi-
reliance on flawed theories of value that render
                                                                cles whatsoever for shorting the U.S. real estate
them oblivious to major mispricings (MacKenzie
                                                                market (Gorton 2008; Zuckerman 2009).
2011; Zuckerman and Rao 2004). Yet whether
                                                                    Accordingly, rational sitting models observe
ascribed to “animal spirits” (Akerlof and Shiller
                                                                that when prices rise, skeptical investors who
2009), “euphoria” (Kindelberger [1978] 2005:13),
                                                                would otherwise short sell are often unwilling to
a “fieldwide delusion” (Fligstein and Goldstein
                                                                (because of risk) or unable to (because of market
2010:34), or a “miasma of irrationality” (Pozner,
                                                                conditions), and so instead they sit on the side-
Stimmler, and Hirsch 2010:5), all such accounts
                                                                lines (Miller 1977; Zuckerman 2012b). This cedes
suggest that bubbles are driven by widespread
                                                                the market to more optimistic investors, and bub-
delusion about asset values.
                                                                bles can inflate unchallenged. A key implication—
                                                                and one that distinguishes this perspective from
Institutionalist Perspective                                    collective delusion accounts—is that significant
                                                                private dissent can be contemporaneous with a
In contrast, a second approach suggests that bub-               bubble: bubbles may be driven not by a deluded
bles can form without widespread delusion. In-                  majority but by a deluded minority and silenced
vestors may recognize a mispricing, but institu-                majority.
tional conditions prevent them from voicing dis-
sent and correcting the distortion. Two variants
of this perspective propose two distinct strate-                Dissimulation through Optimal
   1 By “majority of investors,” we mean the majority of
                                                                Dancing
capital in the market.                                          Sharing this expectation of widespread dissent,

sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com         82                                        March 2014 | Volume 1
Turco and Zuckerman                                                          Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

dancing models suggest that dissenters them-               ist perspective seems compelling, it has received
selves may fuel a bubble by participating in—not           little direct empirical validation. In fact, we find
sitting out of—the inflated market (Harrison and           evidence of widespread investor recognition dur-
Kreps 1978). The logic comes originally from               ing the PE bubble that asset prices far exceeded
Keynes’s ([1936] 1960) observation that in liquid          any reasonable estimate of fundamental value,
markets—where investors can move in and out                and this constitutes the first direct evidence that
of positions quickly and without affecting prices—         a bubble can persist despite significant private
paying inflated prices may be rational if investors        dissent from prevailing prices. While collective
expect to resell at even higher prices. This strat-        delusion about value may drive other bubbles,
egy is the market equivalent of dissimulation in           this test strongly suggests that bubbles do not
other cases of distorted valuation: investors’ be-         depend on such delusion.
havior suggests they endorse the public valuation,              Second, we test institutionalist theories’ com-
yet they privately dissent from it.                        mon prediction about investor behavior in illiq-
    Investors often call such dissimulation “danc-         uid markets. Both rational sitting and optimal
ing until the music stops,” and we label this set          dancing models assume that investors who are
of related theories optimal dancing models be-             sophisticated about value (who know prices are
cause they portray dancing as an optimal strategy,         inflated) are also sophisticated in reading the
where dancers profit from their speculation, exit-         market environment so as to know whether to sit
ing the market just before it crashes (e.g., Abreu         or to dance—and, if they dance, that they know
and Brunnermeier 2003; Brunnermeier and Nagel              how to time their exit before a crash. There is
2004; De Long et al. 1990b; Temin and Voth                 no precedent, then, for our finding that in the
2004).                                                     illiquid PE market, most dissenters danced. Post-
    Crucially, though, dancing is only predicted           bubble evidence we present indicates this was a
in liquid markets. Keynes ([1936] 1960:149–54)             flawed investment strategy and the reason the
and all modern optimal dancing models assume               PE bubble inflated to such heights.
this necessary condition, for without a high level              These findings lay the groundwork for a pro-
of liquidity, dancers run the risk of holding over-        posed theoretical revision. We argue that bub-
priced assets when the “music stops,” and this risk        bles can inflate even when there is no collective
outweighs the potential benefits of riding the bub-        delusion about value but, instead, when there is
ble. In illiquid markets, optimal dancing models           collective error in the investment strategies pur-
reduce to rational sitting models: investors who           sued. Such errors are unanticipated by existing
see that the market is in a bubble are expected            theory, and we draw on in-depth qualitative data
to withdraw.                                               from the PE market to probe their nature. The
                                                           data reveal how misperceptions about market
                                                           liquidity and peers’ strategies can make dancing
Agenda: Testing and                                        seem viable even when it is not, and our analysis
Developing Heterodox Theory                                moves beyond institutional restrictions on voice
                                                           to identify the crucial importance of institutional
This article begins by testing key implications of         restrictions on market visibility as well.
the heterodox approaches reviewed earlier against               Taken together, this article’s findings suggest
unique data—longitudinal interviews with pri-              that the errors fueling bubbles may pertain less to
vate equity (PE) participants during and after             the cognitive and behavioral challenges of ascer-
that market’s mid-2000s bubble. First, we test             taining asset values and more to the sociological
competing predictions about investor sentiment             and institutionally driven challenge of how to
during the PE bubble. The collective delusion              interpret one’s social and competitive landscape.
perspective expects optimistic investors to pre-           This calls for a revision to the current behav-
dominate, whereas the institutionalist approach            ioral finance agenda and offers a sociologically
expects significant private dissent. This test is          informed path forward for research on financial
important because even though the institutional-           markets.

sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com    83                                        March 2014 | Volume 1
Turco and Zuckerman                                                                Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

The Private Equity Market                                        chase multiples to a company’s recent operating
                                                                 profit, whereby a dollar of operating profit is
There are approximately 600 PE firms in the                      worth the same across time and within industry.
United States.2 Together they possess more than                  PE prices typically reflect multiples of earnings
$1 trillion in capital and own and control compa-                before interest, tax, depreciation, and amortiza-
nies that employ more than 8 million American                    tion (EBITDA)—that is, the price, or purchase
workers.3 Although the few largest firms employ                  multiple, for the investment is the total capital
100 or more investors, most have staffs of 20 or                 used to purchase the company (in equity and
fewer.                                                           debt) divided by the company’s operating cash
    PE firms purchase companies with the goal                    flow.
of reselling them at a profit. Purchases are struc-
tured as leveraged buyouts (LBOs), meaning they
are financed using not only equity but also debt
                                                                 The Mid-2000s Bubble
raised from third-party lenders (e.g., commercial
or investment banks).4 The debt is secured by                    The earliest PE firms were founded in the late
the assets of the acquired company. The equity is                1960s and 1970s, and the market experienced
drawn from PE funds—10-year limited partner-                     its first bubble in the 1980s. From $1 billion
ships for which the PE firm serves as general part-              in transactions in 1980, the market soared to
ner and its capital providers serve as limited part-             more than $60 billion in transactions by 1988,
ners (LPs). LPs are generally large institutions,                then crashed, contracting to $4 billion by 1990
including public and corporate pension funds,                    (Kaplan and Stein 1993). During the 1990s and
university and foundation endowments, and in-                    early 2000s, the industry retrenched, then grew
surance companies. When a PE firm raises a fund,                 slowly. In the mid-2000s, an even larger bubble
LPs commit a set amount of capital. The PE                       emerged.
firm is then responsible for investing the fund’s                    Figure 1 shows the total value of all U.S. LBO
capital. As it finds companies to purchase over                  deals from 1990 to 2012. Between 2005 and 2007,
the ensuing years, it calls down LPs’ capital com-               PE firms invested approximately $960 billion,
mitments to finance the purchases. Upon selling                  far more than they had invested over the entire
a company, the PE firm returns to LPs the orig-                  previous decade. This run-up was characterized
inal capital plus 80 percent of any profit, and                  by an unprecedented number and size of LBOs.
retains 20 percent (called carried interest).                    The median LBO deal averaged $51 million in
    When evaluating prospective investments, PE                  the 10 years prior to 2005 but grew to $59 million
investors engage in months-long due diligence to                 in 2005 and $100 million by the bubble’s 2007
value a target company. Two common methods                       peak. Importantly, these larger deals reflected
of valuation are (1) a discounted cash flow analy-               the fact that PE investors were paying higher
sis, whereby a company is worth its future cash                  prices for the same fundamentals than they had
flows discounted by time and risk, and (2) the                   historically. For the 5 and 10 years prior to 2005,
application of historical, industry-specific pur-                median purchase multiples in PE averaged 6.6
   2 Unless otherwise specified, quantitative data on the        times EBITDA, but they rose considerably during
PE market concern U.S., leveraged-buyout-focused PE              the bubble, reaching a record high of 11.4 times
firms and were obtained from Pitchbook, a commercial             EBITDA in Q4 2007 and Q1 2008.
data set focused on this market. Complete, reliable
data on the PE market are notoriously difficult to ob-
                                                                     With the broader economic collapse in 2008
tain (Stucke 2011), but comparison of alternative data           and 2009, the PE bubble popped and the market
sources (based on Harris, Jenkinson, and Kaplan [2011])          crashed. By 2009, the industry had returned to
suggested that Pitchbook offered at least as complete            its early-2000s size, with only $58 billion in LBOs,
data as alternative sources. We extensively cross-checked
Pitchbook’s data against other sources.
                                                                 a median deal size of $40 million, and median
   3   Employment data from Private Equity                       purchase multiples of 5.9 times EBITDA. Since
Growth Council website, accessed May 7, 2012:                    the depths of the downturn, multiples and deal
http://www.pegcc.org/education/pe-by-the-numbers/.               activity have increased somewhat, but the PE
   4 This section draws from Kaplan and Stromberg

(2009:123–30) and Tuck (2003); also industry reports,            market remains far below its 2007 peak. Today
trade press, and our extensive interviews.                       there is widespread consensus among analysts and

sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com          84                                        March 2014 | Volume 1
Turco and Zuckerman                                                                Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

Figure 1: Aggregate LBO Deal Value by Year

market participants that this period constituted              in the cost of capital. However, the qualitative
a bubble of historic proportions.5                            data we present later cannot be reconciled with
    Both to understand how this happened and                  this. For now, it is sufficient to note that such
to develop more robust general theory, we test                an account is inconsistent with the fact that mid-
existing theories of bubbles against evidence from            2000s PE investments have performed consider-
PE. Several conditions make this an ideal setting             ably worse than those of other times: estimated
to pursue this agenda.                                        average returns for PE funds raised during the
                                                              bubble are 52 percent of the historical average.6
Conditions Suggesting Widespread                                  In fact, over the industry’s history, prices
                                                              have risen and returns have suffered during pe-
Delusion
                                                              riods of cheap and abundant capital, suggest-
Collective delusion is a plausible explanation for            ing bubbles are particularly likely at just these
this bubble given capital market dynamics at the              moments (Kaplan and Stein 1993; Kaplan and
time. Just as the first PE bubble occurred during             Schoar 2005; Axelson, Jenkinson, and Strömberg
the 1980s’ junk bond craze, this one occurred                 2013; Robinson and Sensoy 2011a). The surging
during an unprecedented surge in the credit mar-              capital markets, combined with poor investment
kets. In the early 2000s, lenders began syndi-                returns, specifically suggest PE may have experi-
cating a portion of LBO debt, packaging it into               enced the sort of capital-fueled collective delusion
collateralized loan obligations to trade in the sec-          bubble Kindelberger (1978) described—that is,
ondary market. This shifted originating lenders’              perhaps PE investors unwittingly paid inflated
incentives and encouraged more aggressive lend-                   6 At the time of this writing, current Pitchbook esti-
ing practices, meaning PE investors could ac-                 mates of the median internal rate of return (IRR) for PE
cess more debt at cheaper rates than ever before              funds raised from 2005 to 2007 average 8.37 percent, com-
(Acharya, Franks, and Servaes 2007). Concur-                  pared to 16.07 percent for funds raised from 1980 to 2004.
                                                              This may overstate returns during the bubble because
rently, equity capital from LPs also spiked (Figure           IRR calculations for those years are based, in part, on PE
2).                                                           investors’ own estimates of as-yet unrealized returns (i.e.,
    Orthodox theory would argue that price in-                companies bought during the bubble but not yet resold).
creases merely reflected these exogenous changes              A method of calculating PE returns that avoids this issue
                                                              is the “realization multiple,” that is, the capital actually
   5 In our interviews in 2010 and 2011, PE investors         returned from investments thus far divided by the total
unanimously reported that the mid-2000s had been a            initial capital invested. For funds raised from 1994 to
massive bubble. Numerous industry reports and press           2004, the median realization multiple five years after a
articles discuss the unprecedented run-up in PE during        fund was raised averaged 0.56; for funds raised in 2005 to
those years (e.g., Pitchbook Data Inc. 2011).                 2007, it is 0.23.

sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com       85                                           March 2014 | Volume 1
Turco and Zuckerman                                                         Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

Figure 2: Limited Partner Capital Commitments to Private Equity

prices because abundant debt and equity blinded                For example, PE investors are required to
them to the actual cost of this capital.                  co-invest alongside LPs, with at least 1 percent
    A contemporaneous market development may              of any PE fund’s capital coming from its own
have reinforced such value delusion. Historically,        personal capital (Kaplan and Strömberg 2009).
PE firms found LBO targets through proprietary            They also share in their investments’ long-term
networks. By the 2000s, however, target compa-            profits through the 20 percent carried interest.
nies were increasingly retaining investment banks         This carried interest is itself typically contingent
to run formalized auctions in which PE firms              on factors that further motivate them to pay fair
bid against one another. Auctions often induce            prices in pursuit of long-term returns—for ex-
participants to overpay (Thaler 1988), and be-            ample, LPs are often guaranteed a “hurdle rate,”
cause investment banks receive a percentage of            meaning PE investors receive no carried interest
the winning bid, they have an incentive to elicit         until LPs reach a preset return on their capital;
the highest valuations possible regardless of fun-        and PE firms face “clawback” provisions allowing
damentals (cf. Ho 2009; Perrow 2010).                     LPs to recall carried interest from earlier deals
                                                          if later investments perform poorly (Metrick and
                                                          Yasuda 2010). Given this set of incentives, insti-
Conditions Suggesting Widespread                          tutionalist theories that explain bubbles in the
Dissent                                                   absence of widespread value delusion seem like
But could a majority of PE investors really have          promising candidates for explaining the PE bub-
been so deluded about asset values? While the             ble.
untrained “noise” traders driving many collec-
tive delusion stories may fall prey to behavioral
biases and collective euphoria (see Akerlof and           Conditions Leading to Testable
Shiller 2009; Barberis and Thaler 2005; Black             Predictions
1986), PE is composed entirely of the type of
investors and incentives thought to rationalize           Though compelling, institutionalist theories have
markets. Specifically, both PE firms and their            received little direct empirical testing or valida-
LPs are sophisticated institutional investors, and        tion, and collective delusion theories remain the
the market has been explicitly structured to mo-          most prominent account of bubbles. Two condi-
tivate PE investors to overcome behavioral biases         tions, however, make PE ideal for testing institu-
and value target assets accurately (Jensen 1989).         tionalist predictions.

sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com   86                                        March 2014 | Volume 1
Turco and Zuckerman                                                                 Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

     Short selling constraints. Testing institution-              holding periods, mean investors cannot expect to
alist theories requires a market with short selling               sell assets readily, any time they wish.
constraints, the mechanism assumed to silence                         Consequently, we should not expect PE in-
even widespread dissent. PE certainly meets this                  vestors to adopt a speculative orientation wherein
condition: short selling is not just limited be-                  they determine what price to pay today based
cause of costliness or riskiness (as it is, say, in the           on where they expect prices to move in the short
public stock market) but rather it is outright im-                term. Because they cannot liquidate holdings
possible here. The assets being traded are private                quickly, PE investors should be willing to pay
companies, so there are no freely traded securi-                  only what they estimate the asset’s intrinsic value
ties to short. Moreover, the entire investment                    to be. In short, given PE’s illiquidity, institution-
thesis is to go “long,” not short, and LPs contrac-               alist theories carry a clear common prediction in
tually bind PE firms to limit their investment                    this market: dissenters should sit out of a bubble,
activities to LBO-like transactions. The strict                   not dance.
mandate is to use LP capital to purchase compa-                       This hypothesis is compelling, but given the
nies, increase their value by driving operational                 bubble and market conditions just described,
and strategic improvements, then resell them at a                 there is reason to doubt it will be supported in PE.
higher price. Finally, just as PE investors cannot                If PE investors are sophisticated and motivated
short the market, neither can industry outsiders                  to recognize when prices have risen above funda-
short the equity of privately owned companies.7                   mental value, and if illiquidity makes dancing a
Because few PE firms are publicly traded and                      poor strategy, then we should never see bubbles
only a portion of their capital comes from the                    in this market. Yet PE experienced a massive
public market, there are insufficient freely traded               bubble in the mid-2000s. This implies the market
shares for outsiders to exercise an effective short               was dominated by one or two kinds of investors
selling strategy.                                                 not easily reconciled with existing institutionalist
     The complete absence of short selling means                  theory and intuition: (1) those who are actually
we can test theoretical predictions about investor                deluded into overestimating value despite their
sentiment during the PE bubble: institutionalist                  sophistication and incentives and/or (2) those
theories predict considerable silent dissent on ac-               who recognize that prices are inflated, yet opt to
count of the restrictions on voice, whereas collec-               dance even though it is a poor strategy. Given
tive delusion theories expect widespread delusion.                this, we will not only test the predictions of col-
     Market illiquidity. Because PE is a highly                   lective delusion and institutionalist accounts for
illiquid market, we can also test institutional-                  PE but also use our data on investor sentiment
ist predictions about investor behavior during                    and strategies to move beyond these existing ac-
the bubble. Entire companies—not shares on                        counts.
an exchange—are bought and sold in this mar-
ket. PE firms hold investments for an average
of six years (Kaplan and Strömberg 2009), and,                    Methods
when they finally do exit an investment, they
                                                                  This agenda necessitates capturing investors’ pri-
must sell the company to another company or
                                                                  vate beliefs about value during a bubble as well
PE firm or via public offering on the stock market.
                                                                  as their investment strategies. Our data and
These exits—like the initial LBO itself—are long,
                                                                  methods—interviews with PE market partici-
complex transactions that take months and some-
                                                                  pants (N =82) in 2005 and re-interviews with
times years to complete given financial, legal, and
                                                                  those same participants in 2010 and 2011—are
regulatory issues. This, and the industry’s long
                                                                  uniquely suited to obtaining such evidence.
    7 Some hedge funds have considered shorting the debt

of PE-owned companies by buying credit default swap
protection on public companies that PE firms could con-           The 2005 Sample: Capturing Market
ceivably take private in the future (ZeroHedge 2010). This        Sentiment in a Rising Bubble
is highly indirect, and public company LBOs are a frac-
tion of all PE investments, so such trades have minimal           In 2005, the lead author conducted 43 interviews
impact.
                                                                  in the PE industry as part of a larger multi-year

sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com           87                                        March 2014 | Volume 1
Turco and Zuckerman                                                                Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

study on the nature and structure of PE investing.               high (90 percent overall) regardless of method of
The author entered the industry with no previous                 access.
awareness of—nor intent to study—a PE bubble,
and no interview questions asked directly about                  Re-interviews in 2010 and 2011: Iden-
the issue. Rather, the interviews included several
                                                                 tifying Investment Strategies during
open-ended questions, such as, “Is there anything
else I need to know about the current PE mar-                    a Bubble
ket as I begin to study it?” and “Are there any                  Following the crash, we re-interviewed the orig-
recent trends in the industry I should be aware                  inal sample, asking directly about respondents’
of?” In response to these and other questions,                   views of the mid-2000s market (which could be
respondents routinely volunteered their personal                 compared to their earlier statements) and about
opinions on valuation levels in the current mar-                 their firms’ specific investment strategies during
ket. These responses reveal market participants’                 those years. We later used a range of sources (in-
beliefs about public valuations, but, crucially,                 dustry reports, coverage of PE investments in the
without priming the idea of a bubble.                            trade press, firms’ own press releases during the
     PE firms were randomly selected from a strat-               bubble) to validate these self-reported investment
ified sampling frame. First, the author compiled                 strategies.
a comprehensive list of all PE firms. Because in-                    The second wave contains 31 re-interviews (72
dustry participants and observers regularly iden-                percent re-interview rate), where we interviewed
tify three distinct market segments—PE firms                     either the original respondent from 2005 or some-
with small funds (several hundred million dollars                one from the original firm. During re-interviews,
or less), medium funds (several hundred million                  respondents consistently identified several PE
to a few billion dollars), and large funds (multi-               firms and LPs known for particularly good or
billion-dollar funds, the largest of which are called            bad performance during the bubble as well as a
mega-funds)—and because the dozen or so largest                  consulting firm that actively advised firms dur-
firms represent a sizable portion of all capital in              ing the bubble. Because these institutions could
the market, it was important to stratify the list                offer useful analytical traction and insight into
of firms by size to gain a representative sample                 dynamics during the bubble, we added them to
of both perspectives and capital in the market.                  the sample.
PE firms were then randomly selected from each                       In total, the 2010 and 2011 sample contains 39
stratum.8                                                        interviews. A supervised research assistant con-
     Interviews with PE investors (N =21 individ-                ducted the majority; the lead author conducted
uals; N =18 firms)9 were then used to build a                    the remainder. Table 1 presents each wave’s sam-
theoretical sample of other key PE market par-                   ple structure.
ticipants, including LPs (N =6) that invest in
numerous PE firms; major investment banks
(N =7) that interact with hundreds of PE firms
as lenders, advisors, and auctioneers; consultants               Test 1: 2005 Market Sentiment–
(N =6) who advise PE firms on due diligence;                     Collective Delusion or Unvoic-
and trade journalists (N =3) who cover the en-
tire industry. Given the industry’s reputation for               ed Dissent?
intense secrecy, the author initially relied on key
informants and personal contacts to gain access                  Our first result is straightforward. Despite factors
to the randomly selected PE firms and other mar-                 in the capital markets and auctions that could
ket participants. However, response rates proved                 have fed delusion, during the bubble, there was
                                                                 significant investor dissent from market prices,
   8 The first author also interviewed two non-randomly
                                                                 not widespread delusion that these prices re-
selected firms, where personal contacts enabled deep ac-
cess and early background discussions.                           flected assets’ true value.
   9 Because the author conducted interviews with several            In 2005, 16 of 18 (89 percent) PE investors in
investors at each of the non-randomly selected firms, the        our sample reported that the market was cur-
N s for firms and PE investors differ slightly.                  rently in a bubble with prices inflated above

sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com          88                                        March 2014 | Volume 1
Turco and Zuckerman                                                                  Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

Table 1: Qualitative Sample

                                                                                    2005              2010             2010
                                                                                 Interviews       Reinterviews         New
 Private Equity Investorsa
   Large (>$2bn)                                                                     8                    6              4
   Medium ($500m−$2bn)                                                               7                    5              −
   Small (
Turco and Zuckerman                                                              Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

“suspect of the market,” a consultant warned, “At             as in PE, such investors should sit out until prices
some point, the market will have a correction.”               correct (Miller 1977).
Another said, “We worry about what happens                         Our data are surprising, then. While 4 of the
when the music stops.” Note that trade journal-               16 PE investors who recognized the bubble in
ists cover hundreds of firms and cultivate sources            2005 curtailed investment activity over the next
across the entire industry, and any one invest-               few years, the majority—9 of 16—participated
ment bank or consulting firm works with numer-                actively in the inflating market.11 Three of the
ous PE firms. So, the fact that these respondents             firms added in 2010 did the same. These investors
believed public valuations were inflated further              purchased more companies, at a faster pace and
validates that skepticism was prevalent across the            in larger transactions than ever, paying prices
entire market, not just our sample. Furthermore,              they knew to be in excess of the companies’ un-
as early as 2005 and continuing throughout the                derlying values. We classify these investors as
bubble, there was public speculation about the                “dancers” because, as in optimal dancing models
existence of a PE bubble both in the national                 (e.g., Abreu and Brunnermeier 2003), they spoke
news and trade press as well as among industry                in terms of Keynesian speculation, that is, paying
leaders at major PE conferences (e.g., Primack                high prices today with the intention of selling at
2005; Dixon 2007).                                            even higher prices tomorrow. An investor whose
    The foregoing evidence constitutes the first              firm danced during the bubble explained, “We’d
contribution of our article. Across all categories            project out the price that we felt we could get
of respondents, there was widespread dissent from             when we sold the business, and we felt we were
prevailing public valuations in 2005. Comments                basing this [the price they paid] on appropriate
that prices were “crazy,” “outrageous,” “stupid,”             assumptions of sales prices.”
and bound to “crash” cannot be reconciled with                     Such behavior was not just limited to our sam-
an orthodox account, which assumes prices accu-               ple. The prevalence of dancing across PE actu-
rately reflect value conditional on the financing             ally inspired what has become the most infamous
environment; nor can they be explained by a col-              quote of the broader financial market excesses
lective delusion account. Instead, they represent             of that time. In 2007, Chuck Prince, CEO of
the first, direct evidence in support of the key              Citibank (a lender in many PE deals), told his
prediction of institutionalist accounts that mar-             employees that so long as PE investors wanted
kets with restricted short selling can experience             to keep dancing—as they were widely believed to
bubbles despite widespread recognition of the                 be doing—then Citibank should keep providing
market’s mispricing.                                          them with debt to finance their deals: “When
                                                              the music stops in terms of liquidity, things will
                                                              get complicated. But as long as the music is
                                                              playing, you’ve got to get up and dance. We’re
Test 2: 2005 to 2007 Dissenter                                still dancing.” Moreover, given the prevalence of
Behavior–Rational Sitting or                                  skepticism about price levels both in our sample
                                                              and in the broader PE market dialogue of the
Optimal Dancing?                                              time, the sheer volume of PE investment activ-
                                                              ity in 2005 to 2007 implies considerable dancing
But what did these dissenters (investors who be-
                                                              (Figure 1).
lieved current prices were inflated) do during the
                                                                   Our 2005 interviews reveal specific examples
ensuing bubble years? As noted, existing institu-
                                                              of investor dancing at the time, offering direct
tionalist theories predict that, in markets where
                                                              evidence of this strategy. For instance, the in-
there are limits to arbitrage, the degree of liq-
                                                              vestor who called prices “outrageous” and “crazy”
uidity in the market determines how dissenters
                                                              explained in the same interview that his firm was
behave. When markets are liquid, the optimal
                                                                11 Given data limitations, we were unable to classify
strategy is often to dance, buying assets at to-
day’s inflated prices to resell at higher prices prior        three firms in our 2005 sample as either a sitter or a
                                                              dancer. Even if all three had sat out (which anecdotal
to the market’s correction (Abreu and Brunner-                evidence suggests is not the case), dancing still would
meier 2003). However, when markets are illiquid,              have been the majority strategy in our 2005 sample.

sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com       90                                         March 2014 | Volume 1
Turco and Zuckerman                                                         Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

nevertheless highly focused on “closing deals” (in        this finding is consistent with the sociological
the homebuilding product sector, one of the most          and political science literature that says “dissim-
overpriced). Other investors who said prices were         ulation” can drive distorted valuations (Wedeen
inflated spoke similarly about being highly “pre-         1999), such behavior occurred in the absence of
occupied” (in the words of one) with finding ever         the key condition existing institutionalist theory
more investments to make in the current market.           assumes is necessary for observing it: liquidity.
    Post-crash interviews provide further evidence        As one PE investor remarked, “We are not public
of dancing and additional insight into the strat-         market investors who can get in and out of the
egy. Dancers admitted knowingly paying high               market by picking up the phone to a broker when
prices that were unjustified by the underlying            we see things start to turn. We’re dealing with
fundamentals. An investor whose firm danced               sizable companies, transformative transactions
articulated the logic, “We knew we were paying            that take weeks and months and sometimes years
prices above average for historical LBOs. . . We          to line up.” Given this, theory tells us that danc-
believed ‘we can justify paying x times [EBITDA]          ing would be suboptimal and therefore avoided.
because we’ll get x plus times on the way out.” ’         The finding of prevalent suboptimal dancing in
Across all market segments, dancers made similar          the absence of theory to explain it constitutes
admissions:                                               our article’s second contribution.
                                                              It appears that the PE bubble would not have
       We all recognized that we were get-                occurred had all the investors who recognized that
       ting to a point where—let’s just say               prices were too high sat out of the market. We
       to an unsustainable pace. . . [But] we             learn from this that bubbles can be fueled by
       were active. . . We made a lot of in-              investors who are sophisticated in their approach
       vestments then. It’s absolutely not                to value but nonetheless err in the investment
       the case that we said, “Let’s stay out             strategies they pursue. This calls for development
       of market.” (PE investor, mega firm)               of new theory. To do so, we must first address
                                                          two key questions: Was dancing really suboptimal
                                                          for PE investors? If so, why did some investors
       We were fully aware we were in a                   nevertheless adopt it?
       bubble. . . We did some deals at the
       peak. (PE investor, medium firm)
                                                          Was Dancing Suboptimal?
       There was a collective belief that                 The puzzle of PE dancing would be resolved if
       things were at relatively high                     dancing were suboptimal only for LPs, not PE
       prices. . . The idea that people didn’t            investors. Indeed, PE investors receive signifi-
       know there was a bubble didn’t                     cant short-term economic benefits from dancing,
       exist. People knew these were frothy               irrespective of long-term returns. They collect
       times. . . We definitely overpaid for              transaction fees every time they buy or sell a
       the [deals] we did then. (PE investor,             company and annual monitoring fees from each
       small firm)                                        portfolio company (Metrick and Yasuda 2010).
                                                          For each fund, they also collect an annual man-
    A trade journalist who had identified the             agement fee of 2 percent of the fund’s committed
bubble in his 2005 interview reflected back in            capital. Because they cannot raise a new fund un-
2011, “PE had a bubble. Prices were rising                til their existing one is mostly invested, they may
unsustainably. . . I thought for the most part            disregard prices and invest quickly to raise that
they [PE investors] agreed with me intellectu-            next fund and collect more management fees.
ally [that prices were inflated] but ultimately it             Given recent examples of financial market
didn’t change their behavior.” That it didn’t—            malfeasance (cf. Perrow 2010), we must ask
that many investors continued to invest despite           whether these short-term incentives alone can ex-
realizing the market was overpriced—leaves us             plain PE dancing during the bubble. Careful con-
with a puzzle. Although we observe that dancing           sideration suggests a more nuanced perspective,
occurred and fueled the PE bubble, and although           though, and the data demonstrate that despite

sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com   91                                        March 2014 | Volume 1
Turco and Zuckerman                                                                    Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

its short-term benefits, dancing was suboptimal                   chased during the bubble and were now valued
for PE investors, not just LPs.                                   either below cost or below the hurdle-rate return,
    First, these short-term incentives are always                 meaning dancers will receive no carried interest
present in PE, so they cannot alone explain why                   from them.
investors would knowingly pay inflated prices dur-                     Furthermore, investors appeared quite aware
ing some periods but not others. Also, if dancers                 that lasting financial success in PE is achieved
were simply exploiting LPs’ capital for short-term                by raising a sequence of increasingly larger funds
personal gain during the bubble, why admit to                     (not by playing a one-shot game of maximizing
us in 2005 that prices were too high? They could                  a single fund’s fees) and that this depends upon
have obscured the malfeasance by claiming prices                  building a track record of strong returns for LPs.
reflected robust economic fundamentals.                           They further recognized that dancing was incon-
    Most important, the data overwhelmingly                       sistent with that. Numerous dancers echoed one
demonstrate that dancing was simply not op-                       investor’s sentiment that “I’d not have invested as
timal for PE investors. In our 2010 and 2011                      actively and would have waited it out,” preserv-
interviews, we asked PE investors what had been                   ing capital to invest after prices corrected. (Also,
the best strategy for a PE firm to adopt during                   whereas sitters took advantage of the bubble’s
the bubble, and all but one (regardless of what                   inflated prices to sell existing companies, dancers
strategy they had adopted) acknowledged that                      tended to hold theirs, believing they could sell
dancing had been wrong and that the first-best                    at even higher prices later. Because transaction
strategy was to have remained disciplined and                     fees are paid when companies are bought or sold,
sat out of the market by refusing to overpay for                  this further suggests dancers were not just trying
deals.12                                                          to maximize fees.)
    The issue is that although there are short-                        In our 2010 and 2011 interviews, dancers
term incentives to dance, there remain powerful                   feared a “judgment day,” “shakeout,” and “catas-
countervailing incentives to care about long-term                 trophic consequences” for the most egregious
investment returns. Recall that PE investors                      dancers, predicting that such firms would die
invest their own capital—not just LPs’—to pur-                    when LPs refused to invest in their subsequent
chase assets, meaning they are not simply agents.                 funds. Indeed, LPs significantly reduced their
In economists’ principal–agent models, having                     commitments postbubble (Figure 2), and dancers
such “skin in the game” (as one respondent put                    have had considerable difficulty raising new capi-
it) is the key mechanism for counteracting short-                 tal relative to sitters.14
term temptations to exploit. Moreover, PE in-                          To be sure, just because dancing might jeopar-
vestors share in the long-term investment profits                 dize LP relationships and suboptimize long-term
through carried interest, and such profit shar-                   returns does not mean PE investors kept these
ing can dwarf fee-driven compensation.13 Yet                      factors in mind. Research on hyperbolic discount-
dancing did not optimize such returns. Returns                    ing demonstrates that actors often struggle to
from investments made during the bubble have                      avoid short-term temptations even in the pres-
been poor relative to historical returns. As of                   ence of powerful long-term incentives. However, a
mid-2013, PE firms still held $776 billion worth                  bedrock principle in that literature is that invest-
of unsold assets, the majority of which were pur-                 ment in illiquid investments is the key mechanism
  12 By contrast, Brunnermeier and Nagel (2004) and               for disciplining actors to discount the future ap-
Temin and Voth (2004) describe dancing as the optimal             propriately (Laibson 1997). Because PE is an
strategy in the bubbles they study.                               illiquid market, PE investors should have been
  13 In 2011, the three founders of the Carlyle Group, a
                                                                    14 Four PE firms in our sample raised new funds at
large PE firm, each made $134 million from their share
of the firm’s investment profits as well as approximately         approximately the same time in 2005. Two danced; two
$70 million from returns on each founder’s own personal           sat. By 2011, one dancer had given up on fund-raising
investments in the firm’s funds, compared to $250,000 in          and appeared to be winding down operations. After a
salary and $3.5 million in bonus (i.e., the two fee-driven        difficult fund-raising process, the other ultimately raised
compensation components). That year, each also put                a new fund that was considerably smaller than the firm’s
between $97 million and $164 million of their own capi-           prior fund. The two sitters (who invested the majority of
tal back into Carlyle’s funds (Zuckerman and Dezember             their 2005 funds postcrash) had both raised new, larger
2012).                                                            funds.

sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com           92                                           March 2014 | Volume 1
Turco and Zuckerman                                                               Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

highly attuned to the future consequences of danc-           prices they knew to be above fundamental value
ing and recognized that this was a suboptimal                because they believed “all the now obviously false
long-term strategy, both for themselves and LPs.             arguments” that conditions in the market had
In fact, when we examine why respondents chose               permanently changed and they would be able to
to dance, we are led directly to their beliefs about         sell at even higher prices later. According to an
liquidity and their LPs’ likely response.                    LP, dancers like this one “fundamentally believed
                                                             the world had changed” and operated with “the
Misperceptions Supporting                                    assumption the capital markets would be there”
                                                             to support dancing.
Suboptimal Dancing
                                                                 Not all dancers in our sample believed liq-
                                                             uidity had permanently changed, however. Like
Our data suggest that two misperceptions about
                                                             sitters, another third of the dancers recognized
the market environment made dancing seem rea-
                                                             that the capital markets were in a cyclical peak
sonable at the time and that dancers held these
                                                             and any increased liquidity in PE was only tempo-
mistaken beliefs, whereas sitters did not. Given
                                                             rary. In 2005, an investor from a mega-fund that
the nature of interview data, a causal link be-
                                                             danced said, “I feel like this will last as long as
tween these misperceptions and suboptimal danc-
                                                             interest rates stay low, but once the cycle turns,
ing should be regarded as preliminary. Never-
                                                             it will be harder to get deals done. . . Interest
theless, the qualitative evidence highlights their
                                                             rates aren’t low forever.”
importance in investors’ decision to dance.
                                                                 The mistake of these dancers was to overes-
    False sense of liquidity. During the bubble,
                                                             timate their firms’ ability to navigate it success-
one-third of the dancers in our sample seemed
                                                             fully.15 The investor quoted earlier as saying
to believe PE’s liquidity environment had perma-
                                                             that “PE will blow up” reported in 2005 that the
nently changed to now support dancing. To be
                                                             success of dancing “all depends on the credit men-
sure, PE was experiencing relatively high levels
                                                             tality,” which he readily acknowledged was tem-
of liquidity, in that debt was cheap and plentiful.
                                                             porary. Yet in his 2010 interview, he recounted
In 2005, sitters and dancers alike mentioned this
                                                             meetings where he and his colleagues had decided
as a major environmental factor. A mega-fund in-
                                                             to dance for a while longer, believing there would
vestor commented, “Capital is a commodity now,”
                                                             still be time to sell their assets at higher prices.
whereas one from a medium-sized firm observed,
                                                             Another dancer summed up the basis for such
“Capital is one of the least difficult things in this
                                                             thinking: “Everyone stayed in. . . People are going
space.”
                                                             to dance as long as the music plays. . . Everyone
    Sitters were appropriately skeptical of this sit-
                                                             was suffering from the same illusions. It was a
uation, noting the debt markets were in a “crazy”
                                                             bubble mentality. . . People’s elevated view of self,
and “cyclical” moment that would not last. They
                                                             ‘I know what I’m doing, I can lead us through
linked the current availability of capital to in-
                                                             the treacherous waters.” ’
creased liquidity in PE but were clear that any
                                                                 False sense of safety in numbers. An addi-
increased liquidity was only as long-lived as this
                                                             tional misperception supported dancing by re-
credit cycle. Some dancers, however, interpreted
                                                             assuring investors that, even if dancing proved
the increased availability of capital as “sustain-
                                                             suboptimal, LPs were unlikely to punish them.
able,” reflecting the long-term “institutionaliza-
                                                                15 A particular strategy that facilitated such thinking
tion” of PE investing. A banker who advised
many dancers during the bubble captured this                 was the increased use of dividend recapitalizations (“re-
                                                             caps”) whereby a PE firm refinances the debt of an ac-
sentiment in 2005, saying, “This [liquidity] will            quired company based on a higher valuation and extracts
never dry up. . . [PE] has gone from an illiquid             a dividend. This strategy may have made it appear that
cowboy-type environment where a small group of               it was easier to exit investments quickly at a profit, but
really bright people made money, to a very liquid            recaps do not provide a level of liquidity sufficient to jus-
                                                             tify dancing (see Grant 2008). Two reasons are that (1)
environment.” Respondents’ postcrash comments                recaps take at least several months to complete and (2)
provide further insight into such thinking. A                they depend on an increase in the company’s valuation
dancer recalled internal meetings during the bub-            from the time of acquisition, and so they depend on ei-
                                                             ther value-enhancing operational improvements or further
ble in which he and his colleagues decided to pay
                                                             price increases, both of which take time to transpire.

sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com      93                                           March 2014 | Volume 1
Turco and Zuckerman                                                                     Lessons from the U.S. Private Equity Bubble

Specifically, dancers assumed they had “safety                        regardless of investments’ long-term prospects.
in numbers” (Zwiebel 1995; cf. Keynes [1936]                          So, although we argued earlier that fee-based
1960:158). In 2005, all of the respondents who                        incentives alone were insufficient for explaining
went on to dance through the bubble indicated                         dancing, once investors mistakenly believed that
that they believed everyone else was also partici-                    they had safety in numbers and/or that the liq-
pating in the bubble. Most believed everyone was                      uidity environment might support such a strategy,
knowingly dancing like themselves, though some                        the temptation to exploit short-term fees likely
suspected there were a few “fools” in the market                      added fuel to the inflating bubble. One sitter
too, unwittingly paying high prices. Post-crash,                      explained, “I guess it’s the Chuck Prince phe-
respondents observed that a “pack mentality” had                      nomenon. You’ve gotta keep dancing. Plus they
operated during the bubble. Such herding is rele-                     were rewarded handsomely to keep playing. The
vant in PE because when LPs decide whether to                         optimal strategy [in their minds] was to raise
invest in a new fund, they typically focus less on                    as much money as you could think of, spend it
a firm’s overall past performance and more on its                     as quickly as possible and take whacking great
relative performance.16                                               fees. . . But the strategy was flawed. It all came
    By this logic, if there was a chance dancing                      crashing down.”
might be successful (because one believed the                             Our data suggest that the reason it “all came
liquidity environment could possibly support it),                     crashing down” was because dancers’ perceptions
then not dancing was risky. A dancer explained,                       of liquidity and safety in numbers were wrong.
“You definitely knew you were in a boom, but                          When the market crashed, dancers had overpriced
you’re worried about being left out.” Moreover, if                    investments they could not unload and dissatis-
dancing failed, the negative consequences would                       fied LPs, whereas sitters had preserved both cap-
be minimal and mistakes easy to justify because                       ital and LP favor. Had dancers read their market
everyone else’s returns would also be poor. Char-                     environment correctly, they would have antici-
acterizing the logic he believed some dancers used,                   pated this outcome and sat out, and the bubble
an LP said, “It was absolutely clear. Everyone                        would never have occurred. Thus, although our
knew it was insanity but you participate. If you’re                   data do not allow us to speculate about why sit-
going to fail, do it with a lot of company. . . Peo-                  ters avoided these misperceptions when dancers
ple [who danced can] say ‘We all drank the Kool-                      did not, these data strongly suggest that the PE
Aid. . . We all made the same mistakes. Now                           bubble was directly fueled by suboptimal dancing
we’re getting back to business.” ’ Consistent with                    and that this dancing was predicated on investors
this, an investor in our sample justified his own                     having misread key environmental conditions. In
firm’s dancing, saying, “We were in the same fish                     the next two sections, we develop the general
tank as everyone else. . . Most funds were hurt,                      implications of this finding for theory.
right?”
    Note that with a sense of safety in numbers,
it then becomes reasonable to take advantage                          I. Theory Development: Mis-
of the short-term incentives to dance (i.e., fees),                   takes about Market Liquidity
  16 Two reasons for this are as follows: (1) It is unclear

whether average PE returns exceed those of the public                 To appreciate this finding’s novelty, contrast it
markets and thus whether LPs should allocate as much                  with two well-known collective delusion theories.
capital as they do to this risky, illiquid asset class (see           Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) attribute bubbles to
Harris et al. 2011; Kaplan and Schoar 2005; Robinson and
Sensoy 2011b). Nevertheless, there is general consensus
                                                                      the widespread belief that “this time is different”
that returns within PE vary considerably and that, at                 and fundamental valuations have permanently
any given time, the best-performing funds outperform                  increased. But in PE, we saw investors invoke
other asset classes. Consequently, LPs try to identify “top-          such language with regard to liquidity to jus-
quartile” funds, a strategy that makes relative performance
central. (2) Individual LP managers are evaluated on a                tify dancing, even while recognizing that this
relative basis themselves. Overall returns often matter               time was not different with regard to valuations.
less for their job security than do returns relative to “peer”        Akerlof and Shiller (2009:152) contend that in-
institutions. Managers thus focus on investing in better              vestors’ animal spirits make them overconfident
PE funds than their peers, again making relative PE
performance salient.                                                  in both their own estimates of value and their

sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com               94                                        March 2014 | Volume 1
You can also read