RECESSIONS AND RECOVERIES IN LABOR MARKETS: PATTERNS, POLICIES, AND RESPONSES TO THE COVID-19 SHOCK
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
3 CHAPTER RECESSIONS AND RECOVERIES IN LABOR MARKETS: PATTERNS, POLICIES, AND RESPONSES TO THE COVID-19 SHOCK Despite remarkable adaptation and extraordinary Introduction policy support in many economies, economic turmoil Over a year since its onset, the COVID‑19 pan- and labor market dislocations from the COVID-19 demic continues to generate widespread economic pandemic shock continue, with highly unequal effects disruptions and worker dislocations. Even with the across workers. Youth and the lower-skilled are among extraordinary policy support already deployed (out- the most heavily impacted, with sharp rises in unem- lined in Chapter 1 of the April 2021 World Economic ployment rates, which already tend to be at higher Outlook (WEO) and of the April 2021 Fiscal Monitor), levels. Some of these effects reflect the asymmetric, average unemployment rates are up and labor force sectoral, and occupational nature of the COVID-19 participation down compared with their pre-pandemic shock, with less-skill-intensive sectors tending to be averages in both advanced and emerging market and hit harder. The shock is also accelerating preexisting developing economies, according to the latest data employment trends, hastening a shift away from sectors (Figures 3.1 and 3.2, panels 1 and 2). that are more vulnerable to automation. Worker The employment impacts from the pandemic reallocation across sectors and occupations is more likely have been highly unequal across groups of workers after an unemployment spell, but it comes at a high (Figures 3.1 and 3.2, panels 3–8). In particular, youth cost, as average earnings fall for those who switch. Job and the lower-skilled have been hit harder in the retention policies—those aimed at maintaining existing average advanced and emerging market and developing employment matches—can help reduce job separations, economies, with larger rises in unemployment rates particularly for the lower-skilled, while measures to and declines in labor force participation. Women in support worker reallocation can boost job finding emerging market and developing economies have seen a prospects. A new, model-based analysis shows how job slightly higher rise in unemployment and larger drop in retention policies are extremely powerful at reducing participation than men, on average, while in advanced scarring and mitigating the unequal impacts of a pan- economies there is little difference in average unem- demic shock across workers, while reallocation policies ployment across genders.1 These movements in unem- supporting job creation can help ease the adjustment ployment and labor force participation rates imply that to the more permanent effects of the COVID-19 shock average employment rates have declined across groups. on the labor market. Retention measures are best while In the near term, the consequences for these more the shock is acute and social distancing high to preserve vulnerable demographic groups are potentially dire, as ultimately viable job matches, with support relying they face earnings losses and difficult searches for job more on reallocation measures as the pandemic sub- opportunities after unemployment spells. Even after the sides. Careful monitoring of the intensity of the pan- pandemic abates, some of the effects on the structure demic (including cases and deaths, the extent of social of employment may be persistent, with some sectors distancing, and rollout of vaccines) is needed to gauge and occupations (job types) permanently shrinking and when the economy can cope with the reduction of job others growing.2 For these persistent effects, the speed retention support and switch toward greater reliance on reallocation. 1Early in the crisis, studies indicated that women’s employment was impacted more than men’s in some advanced economies, unlike most previous downturns (Alon and others 2020). However, The authors of this chapter are John Bluedorn (lead), Francesca with some recovery as the year proceeded, the average differences Caselli, Wenjie Chen, Niels-Jakob Hansen, Jorge Mondragon, Ippei have diminished. See Bluedorn and others (2021) for a more Shibata, and Marina M. Tavares, with support from Youyou Huang, in-depth exploration of the phenomenon. Christopher Johns, and Cynthia Nyakeri. Yi Ji also provided data 2Barrero, Bloom, and Davis (2020) focuses on the experience of support. The chapter benefited from discussions with Tito Boeri and the United States and argues that 32 percent to 42 percent of layoffs from comments by internal seminar participants and reviewers. from the COVID-19 pandemic shock are likely to be permanent. International Monetary Fund | April 2021 63
WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: Managing Divergent Recoveries Figure 3.1. Labor Market Conditions in Advanced Economies Figure 3.2. Labor Market Conditions in Emerging Market and (Percentage points) Developing Economies (Percentage points) The COVID-19 pandemic has caused large worker dislocations in advanced economies, with highly unequal impacts across workers, on average, hitting youth The COVID-19 shock has led to sharp deteriorations in labor markets in emerging and the lower-skilled harder. market and developing economies, hurting youth, women, and the lower-skilled worse, on average. Unemployment Rate Labor Force Participation Rate 10 1. Total 1.0 100 2. Total 0.0 Unemployment Rate Labor Force Participation Rate 8 0.8 80 –0.1 12 1. Total 2 80 2. Total 0 10 6 0.6 60 –0.2 60 –1 8 4 0.4 40 –0.3 6 1 40 –2 2 0.2 20 –0.4 4 20 –3 0 0.0 0 –0.5 2 Average Change as of Average Change as of 0 0 0 –4 2018–19 2020 2018–19 2020 Average Change as of Average Change as of (right scale) (right scale) 2018–19 2020 2018–19 2020 (right scale) (right scale) 20 3. By Age 4.0 120 4. By Age 1.0 Prime Youth 100 Prime Youth 0.5 30 3. By Age 4 120 4. By Age 2 15 3.0 Prime Youth 100 80 0.0 Prime Youth 3 10 2.0 60 –0.5 20 80 0 40 –1.0 2 60 5 1.0 10 40 –2 20 –1.5 1 0 0.0 0 –2.0 20 Average Change as of Average Change as of 0 0 0 –4 2018–19 2020 2018–19 2020 Average Change as of Average Change as of (right scale) (right scale) 2018–19 2020 2018–19 2020 (right scale) (right scale) 8 5. By Gender 1.5 120 6. By Gender 0.2 Men Women 16 5. By Gender 2 120 6. By Gender 1 Men Women 100 6 0.0 Men Women 100 Men Women 1.0 80 12 0 80 4 60 –0.2 8 1 60 –1 0.5 40 2 –0.4 40 20 4 –2 20 0 0.0 0 –0.6 Average Change as of Average Change as of 0 0 0 –3 2018–19 2020 2018–19 2020 Average Change as of Average Change as of (right scale) (right scale) 2018–19 2020 2018–19 2020 (right scale) (right scale) 10 7. By Skill 2.0 120 8. By Skill 0.8 14 7. By Skill 2 120 8. By Skill 2 8 Higher-skilled 100 Higher-skilled 0.4 12 1.5 Higher-skilled 100 Higher-skilled 1 Lower-skilled 80 Lower-skilled 6 0.0 10 Lower-skilled 80 Lower-skilled 1.0 60 8 0 4 –0.4 1 60 40 6 –1 0.5 4 40 2 20 –0.8 20 –2 2 0 0.0 0 –1.2 Average Change as of Average Change as of 0 0 0 –3 2018–19 2020 2018–19 2020 Average Change as of Average Change as of (right scale) (right scale) 2018–19 2020 2018–19 2020 (right scale) (right scale) Sources: International Labour Organization; Organisation for Economic Sources: International Labour Organization; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; and IMF staff calculations. Co-operation and Development; and IMF staff calculations. Note: “Change” is the average change in the indicated variable across countries in Note: “Change” is the average change in the indicated variable across countries in the group, calculated relative to its average value over 2018–19. the group, calculated relative to its average value over 2018–19. Higher-skilled = tertiary education and above; Lower-skilled = above secondary Higher-skilled = tertiary education and above; Lower-skilled = above secondary and nontertiary education and below. Prime age = 25 to 54 years old; Youth = 15 and nontertiary education and below. Prime age = 25 to 54 years old; Youth = 15 to 24 years old. To account for sample coverage changes, the average within the to 24 years old. To account for sample coverage changes, the average within the group over time is calculated from the normalized time fixed effects from a group over time is calculated from the normalized time fixed effects from a regression of the indicated variable on country and time fixed effects regression of the indicated variable on country and time fixed effects (Karabarbounis and Neiman 2014). See Online Annex 3.1 for further details. (Karabarbounis and Neiman 2014). See Online Annex 3.1 for further details. 64 International Monetary Fund | April 2021
CHAPTER 3 RECESSIONS AND RECOVERIES IN LABOR MARKETS: PATTERNS, POLICIES, AND RESPONSES TO THE COVID-19 SHOCK with which economies can reemploy and reallocate The main findings of the chapter are: workers across sectors and occupations will determine •• The COVID-19 pandemic shock is accelerating preex- how long lived the effects on employment are. isting employment trends with uneven impacts across With an eye to understanding the potential after- demographic groups. The shock has hit sectors that are math of the COVID-19 shock, this chapter studies more vulnerable to automation harder. Around the unemployment, labor market transitions (job findings, world, youth and the lower-skilled are more heavily separations, and employment changes across sectors impacted, on average, partly reflecting differences in and occupations), and earnings over the business cycle workforce composition across sectors. In emerging and across demographic groups. It investigates how market and developing economies, women’s unem- policies—specifically those supporting job retention ployment has risen more than men’s, on average, while (preserving and maintaining existing employment in advanced economies there is not much difference. matches) and worker reallocation (fostering new •• The pandemic recession is likely to inflict sizable costs on matches, assisting job search, and helping workers unemployed workers, particularly the lower‑skilled. While obtain useful new skills)—can mitigate the damage it is not uncommon for workers to reallocate across done by the shock. Given that the ultimate effects sectors and occupations after spells of unemployment, of the pandemic on the economy’s structure remain such reallocation is costly. On average, workers finding highly uncertain and may vary across countries, the reemployment in an occupation different from their chapter uses a newly developed labor market model to previous job experience an average earnings penalty examine how policies and the shock’s persistence inter- of about 15 percent, pointing to large costs—both act. Drawing on empirical and model-based analyses, personal and social—from reallocation via unem- the chapter investigates the following key questions: ployment.3 Lower-skilled workers experience a triple •• What is the sectoral character of the COVID‑19 whammy: they are more likely to be employed in pandemic recession so far and how does it compare sectors more negatively impacted by the pandemic; are with past recessions? more likely to become unemployed in downturns; and, •• How have labor market inflows and outflows across those who are able to find a new job, are more likely to sectors behaved in recessions and recoveries? Do need to switch occupations and suffer an earnings fall. recessions tend to amplify sectoral employment •• Both retention and reallocation policies can help trends (in vulnerability to automation)? mitigate the impact on workers. The persistence •• How do individual-level labor market outcomes and asymmetry of the pandemic shock are crucial (including sectoral and occupational employment for the choice between retention and reallocation. transitions and associated earnings gains/losses) Job retention policies—such as wage subsidies and behave and differ across demographic groups (such short-term work schemes—are effective in lowering as age, gender, and skill) and the business cycle? separations, while worker reallocation policies—such •• How effective are labor market policies encourag- as hiring incentives, job search-and-matching assis- ing job retention versus worker reallocation against tance, and retraining programs—boost job finding the adverse effects from asymmetric shocks across and on-the-job occupational switches by those still sectors and occupations? Does the persistence of the in employment. Historically, the lower-skilled have shock matter? tended to benefit more from job retention policies, while worker reallocation policies have bolstered Importantly, the chapter reflects on what the women’s and youth’s prospects more. findings imply for the labor market during and after oo For a transitory and asymmetric shock (such as a the COVID-19 pandemic recession and the role of lockdown or sharp rise in social distancing affect- policies. Due to data availability constraints, much of ing sectors differently), job retention policies are the historical empirical analysis is based on a sample extremely powerful in reducing unemployment of largely advanced economies over the past 30 years. and providing near-term income insurance. As such, the patterns in labor markets identified and assessments of policy effectiveness and options may 3See Helliwell and Huang (2014) and Reichert and Tauchmann be less applicable to economies where large shares of (2017) for evidence on the large social costs of unemployment aris- employment are informal (as in some emerging market ing from spillovers across individuals to the larger labor market and and developing economies). increasing perceptions of job insecurity. International Monetary Fund | April 2021 65
WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: Managing Divergent Recoveries oo For a permanent shock (such as a permanent shift There are some important caveats to the findings. in demand across sectors or drop in productivity First, country and time coverage vary across empirical in some sectors), worker reallocation policies that exercises because of differences in data availability and foster job creation perform better in the long are typically more representative of advanced econo- term and hasten adjustment toward the new mies’ experiences. Recent studies of emerging market equilibrium. and developing economies suggest that economies with oo Where the shock is a mix of transitory and per- larger shares of informal employment are suffering manent components, a policy package that favors initially sharper declines in employment from the pan- job retention while social distancing is pervasive, demic, but that they may also be poised to experience and then reallocation once it lifts, better mitigates faster labor market recoveries after the shock passes unemployment dynamics. as informal jobs can be (re)created more quickly.5 The lack of channels to provide job retention support Taken together, the findings suggest that countries to informally employed workers may also mean that with fiscal space should maintain support for job greater reliance on policies such as cash transfers may retention until the pandemic abates markedly, helping be needed to provide income insurance.6 Second, given to avoid socially costly unemployment spells and to that national policies and individual labor market dampen the effects on more disadvantaged worker outcomes may be affected by many different variables groups. In particular, the findings suggest that the use for which the analysis is unable to fully account, the of retention policies could be linked to the duration estimated effects of national-level job retention and and intensity of the pandemic. Uncertainties about worker reallocation policies on individual-level labor the pandemic and its path mean that the phaseout market transition probabilities should be interpreted as of such measures is more complicated in practice; it associational rather than causal. Third, the model-based requires careful monitoring of the pandemic (including analysis should be considered illustrative, highlighting rollout of vaccines) and judgment of the economy’s key considerations relevant to the choice between job ability to weather a reduction in support. Although retention and worker reallocation support. Uncer- the model-based analysis is unable to take account of tainties about the size and structure of permanent tight fiscal space constraints, the powerful effects of job effects from the COVID-19 shock are large, and past retention policies in avoiding deeper and more pro- recoveries may not be fully representative. Policy- tracted employment deterioration from the pandemic makers may need to be nimble in their responses (see suggest that such measures should be prioritized. also Chapter 2). Policies could also be designed to target more- This chapter begins with a look at differences in affected worker groups—for example, increasing the labor market impact of the COVID‑19 pandemic wage subsidies for youth or lower-skilled workers—to recession across sectors; how past downturns compare; discourage firms from letting these workers go and and the relationship between sectoral reallocation and reduce the unequal impact of the shock. As a recovery the business cycle through the lens of worker flows, gets under way, a more vigorous deployment of worker focusing on vulnerability to automation. It then turns reallocation support can hasten labor market adjust- to individual-level labor market transitions, earnings ment. However, it is important to be realistic about changes, and differences across demographic groups. It how quickly progress in reallocation—particularly the also estimates how these have varied across past busi- long-term shifting of workers from occupations more- ness cycles and what these patterns may imply for the to less-vulnerable to automation—can be achieved COVID-19 shock. The penultimate section presents given skill mismatches. Human capital investments empirical estimates of the associations of job retention to help workers reskill for new occupations will 5For take time.4 in-depth looks at specific emerging market and developing economies and how informality in employment may affect the impact of the COVID-19 shock, see Alfaro, Becerra, and Eslava 4See World Bank (2018, 2019) for how policymakers can adjust (2020); Balde, Boly, and Avenyo (2020); Kesar and others (2020); policies and improve education and lifetime learning systems to and Levya and Urrutia (2020), among others. Historically, greater help workers adapt to the changing nature of work as technology informality has been associated with a lower cyclical sensitivity of advances. See also Edelberg and Shevlin (2021) for a discussion of employment (Ahn and others 2019). how policies to boost workforce training may help ease the employ- 6See Díez and others (2020) for a discussion of delivery modalities ment recovery from the pandemic in the United States. for support to informal workers during the pandemic. 66 International Monetary Fund | April 2021
CHAPTER 3 RECESSIONS AND RECOVERIES IN LABOR MARKETS: PATTERNS, POLICIES, AND RESPONSES TO THE COVID-19 SHOCK and worker reallocation policies with labor market Figure 3.3. Sectoral Employment Growth and the Business transitions and the findings from a model-based Cycle analysis illustrating the effectiveness of these policies in responding to a lockdown or social-distancing shock. COVID-19 has hit sectors unevenly, with the most-impacted different than in past recessions, but still hastening an uptick in automation trends. The chapter concludes with a summary of the main takeaways and policy implications. More vulnerable to automation Less vulnerable to automation 4 1. Average in 2020 (Year-over-year percent change) Sectoral Shocks, Trends in Reallocation, and the 2 Business Cycle 0 Reflecting the larger direct impact of the pandemic on more contact-intensive work and sectors, the –2 COVID‑19 shock has been highly asymmetric in its –4 employment effects across sectors (Figure 3.3, panel 1; see also Chapter 2). –6 Total economy Agri. Min./Ener. Manuf. Constr. Trade/Acc. Arts/Serv. Info./Com. Fin./Ins. Real Est. Pro. Serv. Edu./Heal. The COVID-19 Shock’s Impacts Differ across Sectors In advanced economies, the sharpest drops in 4 2. Average in Past Recessions (Year-over-year percent change) employment were in the wholesale and retail trade, 2 transportation, accommodation and food service, 0 and arts and entertainment sectors, unlike during –2 previous recessions over the past 50 years, when the manufacturing and construction sectors were typically –4 the most negatively impacted (Figure 3.3, panel 2). –6 Some sectors, such as information and communica- –8 tion and finance and insurance, have even experienced Total economy Agri. Mining Manuf. Utilities Constr. Trade Transport Acc./Food Arts/Serv. Info./Com. Fin./Ins. Real Est. Pro. Serv. Public Ad. Educ. Health employment growth during the pandemic, further highlighting divergent fortunes. Interestingly, the broad sectoral pattern is similar to that observed in 4 3. Average Trend Growth (Year-over-year percent change) previous recessions, which seem to accelerate preexist- 2 ing structural trends hastening a shift in employment away from sectors more vulnerable to automation 0 (Figure 3.3, panel 3).7 –2 The Shock Hits Workers Unequally, with Youth and the –4 Lower-Skilled More Affected Total economy Agri. Mining Manuf. Utilities Constr. Trade Transport Acc./Food Arts/Serv. Info./Com. Fin./Ins. Real Est. Pro. Serv. Public Ad. Educ. Health Inequalities in the labor market impacts of the pandemic across demographic groups highlighted in the introduction may in part reflect these asym- Sources: Choi and others (2018); EU KLEMS; International Labour Organization; metric sectoral impacts of the COVID‑19 shock. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; Statistics Canada; US Bureau of Economic Analysis; World KLEMS; and IMF staff calculations. 7Some recent studies have also classified jobs according to their Note: Sector groupings in panel 1 are slightly different from those in panels 2 and “teleworkability” (for example, Dingel and Neiman 2020). Most 3 due to reporting differences in the quarterly sectoral national data. Total economy indicates employment for the economy as a whole. Sectors are classified teleworkable jobs are found in sectors that are classified as less vul- according to ISIC Revision 4. Sectors are classified as more (less) vulnerable to nerable to automation, meaning there is also a trend toward greater automation if more (less) than half their share of employment is in occupations teleworkability in employment. However, there are some differences. classified as highly exposed to routinization (Carrillo-Tudela and others 2016). Sectors that are less vulnerable to automation but not teleworkable Underlying data for panel 1 cover 2019:Q1–2020:Q4 and for panels 2 and 3 span include utilities and arts and entertainment, while sectors that are 1970–2019, as available. Patterns in average trend growth are similar over the teleworkable but more vulnerable to automation include administra- shorter period, 2010–19. See Online Annex 3.1 for further details, including the list tive services. See Online Annex 3.1 for a tabulation. of abbreviations. International Monetary Fund | April 2021 67
WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: Managing Divergent Recoveries Figure 3.4. Changes in Sectoral Online Job Posting Trends When split according to the proportion of these demo- (Percent; gap in trend from a year ago, indexed to February 1, 2020) graphic groups represented in a given sector, the latest high-frequency data on trends in online job postings Sectoral workforce composition accounts for some of COVID-19’s unequal impact across groups of workers. suggest that sectors that tend to have more youth, women, or lower-skilled workers are likely to have 10 1. By Age underperformed more than other sectors (Figure 3.4). 0 In other words, demographic differences in employ- ment across sectors and occupations—such as a con- –10 Higher share of youth centration of workers from disadvantaged groups—are Lower share of youth –20 likely contributing to differences in outcomes across groups in the current crisis.8 –30 –40 Past Recessions Suggest COVID-19 Shock Requires –50 Feb. Apr. Jun. Aug. Oct. Dec. Feb. Worker Reallocation 2020 20 20 20 20 20 21 Based on past shocks, it seems likely that some of 10 2. By Gender this uneven sectoral impact from the COVID‑19 pan- demic shock reflects a longer-lived labor reallocation 0 shock that is contributing to the unemployment rise. –10 Higher share of women As seen in the behavior of gross worker flows, built Lower share of women –20 up to the country level from microdata on workers, recessions are typically characterized by declines in –30 gross hiring rates (hires into new or existing jobs as a –40 share of employment) and rises in gross separations (job terminations, whether voluntary or involuntary, –50 Feb. Apr. Jun. Aug. Oct. Dec. Feb. as a share of employment), consistent with a rise 2020 20 20 20 20 20 21 in unemployment during downturns (Figure 3.5).9 10 3. By Skill Level 8See Cajner and others (2020) on how the sectoral nature of the 0 COVID-19 shock may drive much of the disparity in effects across Higher share of lower-skilled workers worker groups. Dam and others (2021) and Klein and Smith’s –10 Lower share of lower-skilled workers (2021) early analysis of the COVID-19 pandemic’s impact in the –20 United States indicate that workers from ethnic minorities (African American and Hispanic) have been disproportionately hurt. Previous –30 research has also pointed out the unequal effects of downturns, with historically more disadvantaged groups (youth and ethnic minorities, –40 among others) more likely to experience protracted unemployment and income losses (Altonji and Blank 2004; Raaum and Røed 2006; –50 Oreopoulos, von Wachter, and Heisz 2012; among others). Earlier Feb. Apr. Jun. Aug. Oct. Dec. Feb. 2020 20 20 20 20 20 21 work has also suggested that composition of employment across sectors and occupations, and hence unequal exposure to shocks, may account for some differences (Davis and von Wachter 2011; Peiró, Sources: EU Labour Force Survey; Indeed; Integrated Public Use Microdata Series, Belaire-Franch, and Gonzalo 2012; Albanesi and Șahin 2018). Beyond Current Population Survey; and IMF staff calculations. differences in the sectoral or occupational exposure to the shock, Note: Data are as of February 16, 2021. Higher (lower) demographic representation in employment by sector is defined as whether the share of young or lower-skilled other features that could be associated with sector of employment and workers is above (below) the economy-wide average or whether the share of occupation may contribute to inequalities across worker groups (for women employed is above (below) 50 percent in a sector. The sample includes a example, the prevalence of temporary versus permanent employment mix of advanced and emerging market economies. Vertical line = March 10, 2020 contracts, strength of worker bargaining power). See Kikuchi, Kitao, (Italy enters country-wide lockdown). See Online Annex 3.1 for further details, and Mikoshiba (2020), which finds that more employment on tem- available at www.imf.org/en/Publications/WEO. porary contracts may account for the large impact of the COVID-19 shock on women in Japan in the early phase of the pandemic. 9Recessions are years of negative real GDP growth. Recoveries are years after a recession when output remains below its previous histor- ical maximum. See Online Annex 3.1, available at www.imf.org/en/ Publications/WEO, for a description of the business cycle dating algorithm used to identify phases. 68 International Monetary Fund | April 2021
CHAPTER 3 RECESSIONS AND RECOVERIES IN LABOR MARKETS: PATTERNS, POLICIES, AND RESPONSES TO THE COVID-19 SHOCK Figure 3.5. Labor Market Turnover across Business Cycles Figure 3.6. Sectoral Employment, by Vulnerability to (Percent) Automation, Skill Level, and Business Cycle Hiring falls and separations rise in recessions compared with expansions, Employment trends favoring higher-skilled sectors that are less vulnerable to reversing somewhat in recoveries. automation occur more as a result of joblessness spells than on-the-job sectoral changes, accelerating during recessions. 18 Expansion Recession Recovery Other sector Unemployment Nonparticipation Total 15 90 1. Average Employment Share1 2. Average Net Hiring Rates 5 (Percent) (Percentage points) 4 More lower-skilled 12 80 More vulnerable to 3 automation 70 2 9 1 60 6 0 50 –1 3 1990 2000 10 20 More vulnerable Less vulnerable sectors sectors 0 6 3. Average Net Hiring Rates 4. Average Net Hiring Rates 5 Gross hiring rate Gross separation rate Gross job-to-job hiring rate in Recessions in Recoveries 4 (Percentage points) (Percentage points) 4 Sources: EU Labour Force Survey; Integrated Public Use Microdata Series, Current 3 Population Survey; and IMF staff calculations. 2 Note: Hiring and separation rates and their components are calculated as annual 2 hires/separations divided by average employment over the current and previous 0 years. All rates are statistically significantly different, except those for job-to-job 1 hiring rates for recession and recovery and those for separation rates for recovery and expansion. See Online Annex 3.1 for further details about the data and –2 0 business cycle dating. –4 –1 More vulnerable Less vulnerable More vulnerable Less vulnerable sectors sectors sectors sectors The job-to-job hiring rate (hires from the employed as a share of employment) also tends to drop, suggesting Sources: EU Labour Force Survey; Integrated Public Use Microdata Series, Current that reallocation through job-to-job changes is inhib- Population Survey; and IMF staff calculations. Note: Sectors are classified as more vulnerable to automation if more than half ited during downturns. Within the job-to-job flows, their share of employment is in occupations classified as highly exposed to about two-thirds of all flows are within the same sec- routinization (Carrillo-Tudela and others 2016). Sectors are classified as more lower-skilled if the sectoral share of lower-skilled employment is greater than the tor. All of these mechanisms are likely to be operating economy-wide average. Net hiring rates are calculated as the difference between during the COVID‑19 pandemic recession. annual hires and separations, divided by the average employment over the current and previous year. See Online Annex 3.1 for further details. 1 To account for sample coverage changes, the average share of employment in working-age population across selected economies over time is calculated Sectors More Vulnerable to Automation Are Harder Hit, according to the normalized time fixed effects from a regression of the indicated variable on country and time fixed effects (Karabarbounis and Neiman 2014). Similar to Past Recessions Over time, employment has been shifting away from sectors that are more vulnerable to automation, tends to work more through joblessness, its social and the share of employed workers with lower skills costs can be high, particularly during recessions has fallen (Figure 3.6, panel 1). The shift reflects in when sectors that are more vulnerable to automation part direct movement of workers from more vul- exhibit large outflows into unemployment, as is likely nerable to less vulnerable sectors, but more often it with the COVID-19 shock (Figure 3.6, panel 3). results from net hiring of workers from unemploy- Indeed, as remarked above, employment in sectors ment and nonparticipation (Figure 3.6, panel 2). that are more vulnerable to automation has declined This suggests that sectoral reallocations often happen more steeply during the COVID-19 pandemic, simi- after a spell of nonemployment. Because reallocation larly to earlier recessions. International Monetary Fund | April 2021 69
WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: Managing Divergent Recoveries In sum, the COVID-19 pandemic shock has been Figure 3.7. Labor Market Transition Probabilities across Business Cycles and Demographic Groups highly asymmetric in its employment impacts across sectors and demographic groups. Moreover, if the past Individual labor market transitions exhibit business cycle patterns similar to those is any guide, these effects may have a long half-life of worker flows, but there is significant variation in prospects across demographic and entail the need for some reallocation. In partic- groups, with youth and the lower-skilled at particular disadvantage in the labor market. ular, the shock is accelerating preexisting automation trends, leading more vulnerable sectors to shrink, and 40 1. Average Probabilities across Business Cycles encouraging employment growth in expanding sectors. (Percent) Differences in workforce composition across sectors 30 imply that some worker groups—particularly the Expansion Recession Recovery lower-skilled—face more tenuous job prospects. 20 Labor Market Transitions, Inequality, 10 and Recessions 0 An alternative perspective to aggregate worker flows Job finding Job separation On-the-job emerges from an examination of individual-level labor sectoral switch market transitions—such as an unemployed person 15 2. Average Probabilities across Demographic Groups1 finding a job, an employed person losing or separating (Percentage point deviation from the base group) from a job, and sectoral and occupational changes in 10 employment (either on the job or after an unemploy- 5 ment spell)—which allows for demographic differ- 0 ences in prospects to be identified. As shown here, lower-skilled workers are likely to be particularly hurt –5 Women Lower-skilled Youth by the COVID-19 pandemic recession. –10 –15 Job finding Job separation On-the-job Job Finding Is Lower and Job Separation Higher in sectoral switch Recessions than in Expansions 6 3. Average Probabilities across Demographic Groups in Recessions1 The probability of finding a job is lower in recessions (Percentage point deviation from the base group in recessions) and recoveries than in expansions, while the reverse is true 4 for job separations (Figure 3.7, panel 1). The likelihood of 2 switching the sector of employment while on the job also tends to follow the cycle—rising in expansions and falling 0 in recessions—although the estimated difference across –2 business cycle phases is not statistically significant.10 –4 Women Lower-skilled Youth These average labor market transition likelihoods mask systematic differences across demographic groups. –6 Job finding Job separation On-the-job Using a linear probability model augmented with sectoral switch individual-level characteristics, the average effects of these characteristics on labor market transitions are estimated. Sources: EU Labour Force Survey; Integrated Public Use Microdata Series, Current The results suggest that finding a job is easier for young Population Survey; and IMF staff calculations. Note: Job finding calculations comprise individuals who were unemployed in the than prime-age workers while, on average, it is more previous year and are employed in the current year. Job separation calculations difficult for women than men and the lower-skilled than comprise individuals who were employed in the previous year and are unemployed in the current year. On-the-job sectoral switches comprise individuals who are the higher-skilled (Figure 3.7, panel 2). Losing a job employed in the previous and current years and changed their sector of tends to be more likely for the young or lower-skilled, occupation. The whiskers indicate the 95 percent confidence band. See Online Annex 3.1 for further details. 1 Base group is prime-age and higher-skilled men. 10The procyclicality of sectoral switches in employment is also found in the literature (Carrillo-Tudela, Hobijn, and Visschers 2014; Carrillo- Tudela and Visschers 2014; and Carrillo-Tudela and others 2016). 70 International Monetary Fund | April 2021
CHAPTER 3 RECESSIONS AND RECOVERIES IN LABOR MARKETS: PATTERNS, POLICIES, AND RESPONSES TO THE COVID-19 SHOCK while the separation likelihood for women appears about changes do not occur in a vacuum; they likely depend the same as that of men. At the same time, youth are on a worker’s employment history. also more likely than prime‑age individuals to change Based on a panel data set of individuals from a jobs across sectors while employed. sample of European economies, the probability of an occupational switch and earnings change reflect this dependence. Among those who are “on the job” Youth and the Lower-Skilled Were Also Most Affected in (continuously employed over the past two years), occu- Past Recessions pational switch incidence is only about 10 percent; for a Zooming in on transitions during past recessions, worker reemployed after a one-year unemployment spell systematic differences across groups are also evident (“via unemployment”), it is nearly five times higher, (Figure 3.7, panel 3). Youth tend to be particularly at almost 50 percent (Figure 3.8, panel 1).13 In other disadvantaged in finding a job and more likely to lose words, workers appear to generally prefer sticking with one than prime-age workers in a downturn. Histori- their current occupation, unless circumstances—such as cally, women have seen smaller drops in job finding prolonged unemployment—force them to switch. and rises in separations than men during a recession. These worker preferences are also evident in the The story for the lower-skilled is more complex, with earnings changes associated with occupational switches both a higher likelihood of finding a job than the when comparing those who switched with those higher-skilled, but also of losing it in a recession. How- who stayed in their original occupations (Figure 3.8, ever, the separation effect likely dominates, leading the panel 2). Among the employed, those who switched lower-skilled to be more prone to end up unemployed occupations saw an average earnings gain of about in a recession than the higher-skilled. On-the-job sec- 2 percent, suggesting that they changed occupations toral switches in employment show no clear pattern. because it was advantageous. In contrast, among unem- These findings suggest that past recessions showed ployed workers who successfully found new employ- many similar features to the current crisis, with youth ment, those who switched occupations saw an average and the lower-skilled particularly disadvantaged in earnings penalty of about 15 percent, indicating that the labor market. The earlier signs that women in they may have had to take a less desirable job.14 advanced economies were also hurt more on average The state of the business cycle does not appear to by the COVID-19 shock—different from the typical significantly impact the occupational switch probabilities patterns of previous recessions—appear to be fading. and the associated earnings changes.15 Even so, the fact that unemployment rises in a recession and that the inci- dence of occupational switches is larger after unemploy- Switches in Occupations Are More Frequent after ment spells, indicates that mechanically there are likely Unemployment Spells and Inflict Earnings Penalties to be more occupational switches and more workers Beyond shifts in sectoral employment, labor market suffering earnings penalties on reemployment after reces- adjustment may also reflect workers changing not only sions, including the COVID‑19 pandemic recession. jobs, but occupations.11 This dimension has become particularly relevant with the COVID‑19 shock, given 13The probability of an occupational switch via nonparticipation is the premium placed on occupations that allow indi- similar to the probability via unemployment. viduals to work from home.12 However, occupational 14Although it is not possible to precisely compare the magnitudes switches by workers and their associated earnings of this measure in the literature because of differences in the sample of countries and level of disaggregation of occupation categories, these results are broadly in line with previous studies—see Huckfeldt 11For the analysis here, these are classified into broad categories, (2018) and Gertler, Huckfeldt, and Trigari (2020). The stylized facts such as managers, clerical support workers, craftspeople, and plant are also consistent with theories of sequential bargaining in which a and machine operators, as per the International Standard Classifica- worker’s bargaining position is affected by their recent employment tion of Occupations 2008 major groups occupational classification. history (see, for example, Postel-Vinay and Robin 2002; Cahuc, See Online Annex 3.1 for more details. Postel-Vinay, and Robin 2006; and Jarosch 2015). An earnings pen- 12For instance, Hensvik, Le Barbanchon, and Rathelot (2021) finds alty with an occupational switch after an unemployment spell also that job seekers tend to redirect their search toward less severely hit arises in a model of selective hiring (Huckfeldt 2018). Furthermore, occupations, beyond what is predicted by the drop in vacancies during the earnings change is due mainly to changes in the hourly wage the COVID-19 pandemic. See also Shibata (forthcoming), which change and not changes in hours worked. finds that more teleworkable jobs are more insulated from the business 15The one exception is the earnings change associated with an cycle, including the pandemic recession, in the United States. on-the-job occupational switch, which is smaller during a recession. International Monetary Fund | April 2021 71
WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: Managing Divergent Recoveries Figure 3.8. Occupational Switches statistically significant). Youth also see larger earnings gains from on-the-job occupational switches. Com- Occupational switches after periods of unemployment are common but costly in earnings. paring the lower-skilled to the higher-skilled, there are no statistically significant differences in occupational 80 1. Occupational Switch 2. Earnings Change due to 20 switch incidence nor their associated earnings changes, Probability Occupational Switch (Percent, conditioned on the (Percent, deviation of although there are some signs that the lower-skilled 10 60 same labor market switchers from stayers) may experience a larger earnings penalty after an occu- transition) pational switch via unemployment. 0 40 These findings on occupational switches and their –10 associated earnings changes across demographic groups 20 do not differ much between expansion and recession –20 periods. However, among lower-skilled workers able 0 –30 to find reemployment, the likelihood of switching On-the-job Via unemployment On-the-job Via unemployment occupations via unemployment increases during a recession.17 This is particularly worrisome in light of Women Lower-skilled Youth the COVID‑19 pandemic recession, given that it sug- gests that the lower-skilled are likely being hit with a 16 3. Occupational Switch 4. Earnings Change due to 80 Probability1 Occupational Switch1 triple whammy: they are more likely to be employed in 12 (Percentage points, (Percentage points, 60 sectors more negatively impacted by the pandemic; are deviation from base group) deviation from base group) 8 40 more likely to become unemployed in downturns; and those who find a new job are also more likely to have 4 20 had to switch occupations and suffer an associated 0 0 earnings penalty. –4 –20 –8 –40 Policy Responses to the COVID-19 Shock: On-the-job Via unemployment On-the-job Via unemployment Job Retention versus Worker Reallocation Sources: EU Statistics on Income and Living Conditions; and IMF staff calculations. As the previous sections have shown, labor market Note: Occupational switches on-the-job are calculated from individuals who are transitions tend to track the business cycle, with the employed in the current and previous year and switched occupations. Occupational switches via unemployment are calculated from individuals who are probabilities of job separation rising and job find- employed in the current year and were unemployed last year and switched ing falling with adverse shocks, and youth and the occupations (based on their occupation of record two years before when last employed). The whiskers indicate the 95 percent confidence band. See Online lower-skilled tending to be hurt even more, on average. Annex 3.1 for further details. Can policies help mitigate these effects while also eas- 1 Base group is prime-age and higher-skilled men. ing any needed labor market adjustment? The COVID‑19 pandemic has prompted extraor- When comparing the incidence and earnings dinary policy support in many countries, devoted consequences of occupational switches across demo- largely to preserving employment relationships and graphic groups, some notable differences are apparent. providing workers with income insurance (often Women are less likely than men to switch occupations, through expanded eligibility for and generosity either while on the job or after a period of unemploy- of unemployment benefits; Figure 3.9).18 As the ment. However, once women switch occupations, the pandemic continues, discussion focuses more and associated earnings change (whether gain or penalty) tends to be larger than it is for men.16 Youth are much 17It is important to emphasize that the results shown here on more likely than prime-age individuals to switch occupational switch probabilities and associated earnings changes for occupations, either on the job or via unemployment the lower-skilled already select for lower-skilled workers who found a job after a period of unemployment and exclude lower-skilled (although the difference via unemployment is not workers who could not find a job. 18See the IMF’s COVID-19 Policy Tracker for details on specific measures. Importantly, any disincentives for reemployment from 16See Montenovo and others (2020) and Shibata (forthcoming) extensions to unemployment benefit schemes—key insurance for for related evidence on the distributional impacts of COVID-19 in those who have lost jobs—appear to be markedly reduced during the US labor market. recessions (Schmieder, von Wachter, and Bender 2012). 72 International Monetary Fund | April 2021
CHAPTER 3 RECESSIONS AND RECOVERIES IN LABOR MARKETS: PATTERNS, POLICIES, AND RESPONSES TO THE COVID-19 SHOCK Figure 3.9. Public Spending on Retention and Reallocation between retention and reallocation policies in respond- Policies: Before COVID-19 and Response to COVID-19 (Percent of GDP) ing to an adverse lockdown or social-distancing shock. The laboratory of the model enables key features of Average public spending to preserve employment after the COVID-19 shock is the pandemic shock—such as its asymmetric impacts dramatically larger than job retention spending in the past. The rise in health across occupations—and policies to be considered. sector spending alone is on par with average spending on reallocation in the past. 2.0 Empirical Estimates of Labor Market Policy Effectiveness Building on the analysis of individual-level labor market transitions, variables capturing spending as 1.5 a share of average income per unemployed person on labor market policies aimed at job retention and worker reallocation are included in the linear proba- 1.0 bility model. Although this model incorporates fixed effects (country and time) and macroeconomic controls (such as the output gap), omitted variables correlated with the labor market policy variables remain a con- 0.5 cern, such that the results should be interpreted as associational rather than causal.20 Focusing only on relationships that were estimated 0.0 to be statistically significant, job retention policies are Retention, Reallocation, Preserving Health care sector found to lower job separation probabilities, on average, pre–COVID-19 pre–COVID-19 employment, 2020 increase, 2020 while worker reallocation policies raise the likelihood Sources: IMF, COVID-19 Policy Tracker; Organisation for Economic Co-operation of job finding and on-the-job occupational switches, and Development; and IMF staff calculations. consistent with what many models of such policies Note: Bars show the average public spending on the indicated area as a share of GDP. See Online Annex 3.1 for further details. suggest (Figure 3.10, panel 1).21 At the same time, retention policies also appear to be associated with a higher overall likelihood of on-the-job occupational more on the roles of two broad sets of policies and switches and reallocation policies with a lower separa- when to use them: those aimed at job retention tion probability, which are more puzzling. These results (maintaining existing matches between workers and may reflect imperfect measurement of job retention employers) and those aimed at worker reallocation and worker reallocation policies as aggregates of (creating new jobs and facilitating workers’ shift spending to improve labor market functioning. These away from shrinking and toward growing sectors and include spending on training programs—delivered occupations).19 either on the job in the case of retention, or outside To make some headway on this question, this of work where reallocation is the aim. To the extent section first provides an empirical assessment of the that such programs increase a worker’s productivity, effects of country-level public spending in the broad they may also raise their value to their employers areas of job retention and worker reallocation pol- icies on individual-level labor market transitions. 20Although the fixed effects do effectively capture the average However, recognizing that these estimates should be impacts of country-specific characteristics (such as the stringency interpreted as associational rather than causal, and of labor market regulations and the structure of labor market that the pandemic shock possesses features not seen institutions) on the outcomes, the impacts of these characteristics in recent history, it then presents a newly developed on the effectiveness of the policy interventions explored here cannot be independently assessed. The policy effects shown represent the search-and-matching model to study the choice average policy effect. 21In a canonical Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides search-and-matching 19Specifically, policy tools to encourage job retention include model of the labor market, layoff taxes (a kind of job retention wage subsidies, short-term work schemes, and partial unemployment policy) reduce job destruction while having an ambiguous effect on benefits, while those that foster worker reallocation include hiring job creation (Pissarides 2000). In contrast, hiring subsidies (a kind of and start-up incentives, job search-and-matching assistance, and worker reallocation policy) in the model increase both job creation and retraining programs. job destruction. International Monetary Fund | April 2021 73
WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: Managing Divergent Recoveries Figure 3.10. Effects of Job Retention and Worker (reducing separations) as well as their interest in and Reallocation Policies capability of switching occupations while on the job. Retention and reallocation policies may also have Job retention and worker reallocation policies can help mitigate adverse shocks and improve labor market functioning. different impacts across demographic groups, poten- tially reflecting demographic differences in employ- 20 1. Overall Effects of Policies on Labor Market Transition ment in sectors and occupations benefiting from these Probabilities 16 (Percent) policies as well as direct targeting of specific groups.22 12 Job retention Worker reallocation The empirical results suggest that job retention policies 8 have tended to lower job separation probabilities more 4 for the lower-skilled than the higher-skilled, while 0 worker reallocation policies have tended to boost job –4 finding chances for youth and women more than for –8 prime-age individuals and men (Figure 3.10, panels 2 –12 and 3). The results are consistent with a greater risk Job finding Job separation On-the-job occ. switch of layoff for the lower-skilled after an adverse shock and, thus, their greater benefit from retention policies. Women Lower-skilled Youth In the case of youth, the results may reflect a greater 4 2. Differential Effects of Job Retention Policies across capability to benefit from reallocation spending related Demographic Groups1 to training. Women’s typically weaker labor force 2 (Percentage points) attachment may also translate into a greater sensitivity to reallocation policies that enhance job finding. 0 –2 Economic Policy Responses to a Pandemic: Model-Based –4 Analysis of Job Retention and Worker Reallocation The preceding empirical analysis suggests that –6 Job finding Job separation On-the-job On-the-job retention and reallocation policies can be effective tools sec. switch occ. switch to respond to the labor market deterioration caused by the COVID-19 pandemic recession. As remarked 4 3. Differential Effects of Job Reallocation Policies across Demographic Groups1 earlier, to address concerns that the empirical estimates 3 (Percentage points) are associational and better disentangle the effects of 2 policies, this chapter also presents a newly-developed labor market search-and-matching model to study the 1 roles of job retention versus worker reallocation poli- 0 cies in responding to the COVID-19 shock.23 The model incorporates several features that are –1 essential to a better understanding of labor market –2 support measures at this juncture. There are two occu- Job finding Job separation On-the-job On-the-job sec. switch occ. switch pations in the economy, which differ in their contact intensity (and exposure to the pandemic shock). Work- Sources: EU Labour Force Survey; EU Statistics on Income and Living Conditions; ers in the two occupations differ in their productivities. Integrated Public Use Microdata Series, Current Population Survey; and IMF staff calculations. Firms enter and exit freely in the model, paying a Note: Panel 1 shows the percent change in the indicated transition probability cost to post a vacancy (create a job). Firms also make (relative to its average value) associated with a 1-percentage-point increase in the indicated policy spending as a share of average income per unemployed person. different employment offers, depending on workers’ Panels 2 and 3 show the percentage points of the indicated transition probability as deviations from the base group. Only estimated effects that are statistically 22These estimated differential effects are likely better identified significant at the 95 percent level are shown. See Online Annex 3.1 for further details, including for the specific means of the labor market transition than those for the overall policy effects, given that they are adjusted probabilities. occ. = occupational; sec. = sectoral. for the impact of any omitted variables by country-year that could 1 be confounded with labor market policies. Base group is prime-age and higher-skilled men. 23The model calibration is partially informed by the empirical results. See Online Annex 3.1 for further details. 74 International Monetary Fund | April 2021
CHAPTER 3 RECESSIONS AND RECOVERIES IN LABOR MARKETS: PATTERNS, POLICIES, AND RESPONSES TO THE COVID-19 SHOCK productivity.24 As in the empirical results, workers in Figure 3.11. Model Simulations with Lockdown Shocks and the model who switch occupations while on the job Labor Market Policies experience a modest earnings gain, whereas workers The unemployment rise is larger for the same-size lockdown shock when part of who switch after an unemployment spell see a marked the shock is permanent. Retention policies are powerful in reducing drop in earnings. An unemployment benefit system unemployment over the short term, while reallocation policies work better over the long term and after a permanent shock. operates in the background, offering some insurance to unemployed workers. Unemployment Rate and Distribution of Workers, by Occupation The COVID-19 shock is modeled as an adverse (No-policy scenario) “lockdown” shock associated with an increase in social distancing that hurts one of the two occupations Less-impacted occ. More-impacted occ. Unemployment rate more than the other. The shock is set to replicate (right scale) (right scale) the initial increase in unemployment observed in the 30 1. Transitory Shock 70 30 2. Hybrid Shock 70 United States and is presumed to last for four periods (Percent) (Percent) (quarters). Given uncertainties about the persistence 60 60 of the shock, two cases are considered: (1) a transitory 20 20 50 50 shock, where productivities return to their initial levels 40 40 after the shock abates; and (2) a more likely hybrid 10 10 shock, which is largely transitory but with some per- 30 30 manent component (specifically, half of the shock to 0 20 0 20 the more-impacted occupation is permanent). 0 3 6 9 12 0 3 6 9 12 Three policy scenarios are considered and compared against a no-policy intervention benchmark: (1) job Effect and Cost of Labor Market Policies during Different Shocks (Deviation from no-policy scenario) retention support, in which the government provides transfer payments to firms to support a portion of their 2 3. Unemployment Rate 4. Deficit 60 Retention wage bill when the match between a firm and worker (Percentage points) (Percent) Reallocation becomes unprofitable; (2) worker reallocation support, 40 0 Package in which the government offers a subsidy to firms to 20 reduce their vacancy cost and stimulate job creation; –2 Retention 0 and (3) a package, which first provides job retention Reallocation –4 Package support and then worker reallocation support.25 In –20 the first two scenarios, support is coincident with the –6 –40 transitory component of the shock (for four quarters), 0 4 8 12 16 0 4 8 12 16 while in the package, worker reallocation support is 3 5. Unemployment Rate 6. Unemployment Rate 0.3 offered after the transitory component has passed but under Retention under Reallocation the permanent effects are still unfolding. (Percentage points) (Percentage points) To get a sense of what the persistence of the lock- 0 0.0 Transitory shock down shock means for the economy, consider the Hybrid shock no-policy intervention benchmarks under the transi- –3 –0.3 Transitory shock tory and hybrid shocks (Figure 3.11, panels 1 and 2). Hybrid shock When the shock hits the economy, it reduces the out- –6 –0.6 put produced by firms and workers, making some job 0 4 8 12 0 4 8 12 matches unprofitable and leading to job losses and a sharp rise in unemployment. Given that a firm’s profit- Source: IMF staff calculations. Note: The x-axis indicates the number of quarters after the shock starts. Package ability increases with worker productivity, lower-skilled comprises a sequence of retention and reallocation policies. Panels 3 and 4 show responses to the hybrid shock. See Online Annex 3.1 for the definition of different shocks and policy measures. occ. = occupation. 24Wages are fixed for the duration of the job match once the firm and the worker agree. 25Government transfers for job retention have an upper limit calibrated to replicate public expenditure on job retention policies observed in the data. Policies are financed using public debt in the short term, which the government pays back over time. International Monetary Fund | April 2021 75
You can also read