Re-electing Politicians and Policy Outcomes Under no Term Limits: Evidence from Peruvian Municipalities
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Re-electing Politicians and Policy Outcomes Under no Term Limits: Evidence from Peruvian Municipalities∗ Fernando Aragón, and Ricardo Pique January 2018 Abstract This paper examines whether, in the absence of term limits, re-elected, more experienced politicians perform differently than their newly elected peers. Using a sharp regression discon- tinuity design and data from Peruvian district municipalities, we find that having a re-elected mayor has few meaningful effects on a broad set of local policy outcomes. Our findings sug- gest that the potential gains from re-electing more experienced politicians may be offset by rapid learning-by-doing and diminishing electoral incentives. Re-elected mayors only exhibit greater capacity and performance levels at the beginning of the mayoral term. Moreover, even though there are no term limits, newly-elected politicians are more likely to be re-elected for an additional term. Overall, our results cast doubts on the advantages of re-electing experienced politicians. JEL: O12, D72, H7 ∗ Aragón: Simon Fraser University, Burnaby, British Columbia, V5A 1S6, Canada. Email: faragons@sfu.ca. Pique: Ryerson University, Toronto, Ontario, M5B 2K3, Canada. Email: rpique@ryerson.ca. We are grateful to Lori Beaman, Stephen Easton, Georgy Egorov, Tim Feddersen, Alexey Makarin, Matt Notowidigdo and Krishna Pendakur for useful comments and suggestions. We are also thankful to Bruno Barletti and Javier Pique; Luis Bernal and Franco Maldonado at the Peruvian Ministry of Economy and Finance; Jose Hugo Eyzaguirre and Jose Carlos Hurtado at the National Jury of Elections and Vladimir Zavala at the Office of the Public Prosecutor Specialized in Corruption Crimes for their help in accessing and collecting the data. 1
1 Introduction Elections allow voters to hold politicians accountable by re-electing those authorities who act in the voters’ interest. However, term limits, which block the possibility of consecutive re-election, have been introduced in several democracies. By limiting electoral incentives, these restrictions may lead to re-elected, term-limited incumbents exerting less effort and implementing policies which are closer to their party or personal ideology. Empirical evidence supports the claim that “lame duck” politicians perform differently than newly-elected ones (Besley and Case, 1995; Johnson and Crain, 2004; Alt et al., 2011). Less is know about the effect of re-electing incumbents in the absence of term limits. In this case, both re-elected and new politicians have the incentive to win the next election. Since the for- mer have greater on-the-job experience, these may perform better than the latter. However, political continuity may also lead to more corruption (Coviello and Gagliarducci, 2017). To avoid the costs of political entrenchment, voters may be less willing to give an additional term to re-elected politi- cians, reducing their incentive to put effort. This ambiguity shows the need for empirical evidence on the effect of re-electing experienced politicians. This evidence will also be informative for the debate on the consequences of term limits. In this paper, we study whether re-elected local politicians perform differently than newly- elected ones in a setting with no term limits. Our analysis uses data from Peruvian district munic- ipalities after the 2002 decentralization process. This context has several useful features for this study. First, unlike other settings, incumbent mayors do not have a strong advantage in terms of election probabilities. This, together with the large number of political movements, means that there are multiple competitive elections between incumbents and new candidates. Second, Peru- vian municipalities are responsible for various local tasks and manage an important share of the government budget. Hence, a politician’s on-the-job experience should be a key determinant of local outcomes. Finally, detailed data on municipalities and candidates is available. To identify the effect of having a re-elected mayor, we use a sharp regression discontinuity design. Our empirical strategy compares outcomes in municipalities where the incumbent barely won re-election versus those in which the incumbent barely lost (and thus a new mayor was elected). These municipalities should have comparable characteristics and only differ in the type of authority. 2
Hence, our findings can be interpreted as the causal effect of re-electing the incumbent. Our results show that re-elected mayors do not systematically differ from newly-elected ones in terms of a broad set of local government outcomes. We find that having a re-elected mayor has no significant effects on measures of budget size such as per capita municipal revenue, total spending and public investment. Our estimates are statistically insignificant and small in magnitude. For all measures, the effects represent less than 6.5% of a standard deviation. A similar pattern of results holds for indicators of municipal performance and budget allocation. Re-elected politicians do not appear to have a significant impact on public investment implementa- tion rates, a measure commonly used by the central government to evaluate municipal performance. Moreover, there is no evidence of an effect on the percentage of the budget allocated to sectors with high social returns such as agriculture, education, health, and social services. However, we do observe a positive effect on transportation expenditures of around 0.2 standard deviations. This change appears to come at the expense of a reduction in administrative spending. Hence, there is some, albeit limited evidence that re-elected mayors use their bureaucratic experience to partially redirect public spending. Our results are robust to changes in the polynomial of the treatment assignment variable and to the inclusion of covariates such as municipal characteristics and past realizations of the outcome variable. More importantly, the absence of significant effects is not driven by a lack of statistical power. As aforementioned, our estimates are small in magnitude. The average standardized effect for our measures of budget size, and for budget allocation and investment performance is less than 6% and 9% of a standard deviation, respectively. The lack of stronger effects is surprising as political experience is expected to lead to differ- ent policies and better performance. Hence, we examine several factors that could be smoothing potential differences between re-elected and newly elected mayors. We first check whether our results are due to differences in selection. In particular, we analyze how do politicians differ in terms of age, education and work experience. We find that the only significant difference is that re-elected politicians are more likely to have worked in the public sector and have 2.9 more years of public sector experience. This difference is expected as re- elected incumbents have spent the last 4 years in an elected office. Hence, it is not the case that our treatment also involves changes in other politician characteristics that may be smoothing the effect 3
of tenure in office. Given this, why is it that greater political experience does not translate to differences in policy outcomes? A possible explanation is that the returns to experience quickly diminish. Relevant knowledge may be learned in the first year of the mayoral term and experience gained in latter years may be redundant. To provide evidence on this, we evaluate how differences in municipal performance and capacity fluctuate by term year. We find that re-elected mayors lead to a significant increase in public invest implementation rates in the first year of the term. The effect is equivalent to more than 0.2 standard deviations. However, in latter years, the effect is insignificant and close to 0. A similar pattern holds for an index of municipal needs for assistance and personnel training, which we use as a proxy for municipal capacity. Re-elected mayors have significantly lower needs in the first term year but this difference gradually disappears. An alternative explanation is that re-elected politicians face lower electoral incentives. If this holds, the gains from experience may be assuaged by re-elected mayors exerting less effort. Lower incentives for re-elected incumbents are usually linked to term limits. However, in the absence of term limits, lower electoral incentives may arise from voters trying to avoid the perils of political entrenchment or from re-elected politicians focusing on a higher elected office or a career outside politics. Our analysis on re-election rates supports this explanation. We find that re-elected incumbents are 17 p.p. less likely to run for the same office in the next election than newly elected ones. Moreover, the former are 16.1 p.p. less likely to gain re-election. If we condition this probability on those incumbents running for re-election, re-elected mayors are 19.6 p.p. less likely to win the electoral contest. This last finding is particularly important as, to the best of our knowledge, it is the first evidence of an electoral disadvantage for re-elected incumbents vis-á-vis newly-elected ones. Taken together, the above results suggest that, even under no term limits, re-elected politicians may face lower electoral incentives. While we do not disregard alternative explanations, our results show that rapid learning of administrative tasks and lower electoral incentives for re-elected incumbents may be smoothing the effect of politician experience. These findings shed light on how the absence of term limits need not translate into a difference in policy outcomes between re-elected and newly elected mayors. Our study relates to two strands of the literature. First, our results complement findings related 4
to the effect of tenure in office and the returns to experience. In the private sector, on-the-job experience is considered an important contributor to human capital and performance. A body of evidence finds significant returns to experience and seniority in the form of higher wages, and better promotion prospects.1 Less is known about how political tenure affects performance. To the best of our knowledge, Coviello and Gagliarducci (2017) provide the only causal evidence on the topic. Their study focuses on public procurement outcomes in Italy and finds that tenure reduces the number of bidders and the cost of public works. Our study complements theirs in several ways. First, we analyze the effect of tenure in a context with no term limits. Hence, the effect of additional tenure is not confounded by restrictions on electoral accountability.2 Second, we study the impact on a broad set of outcomes that are relevant in the many decentralized contexts where local governments have a substantial role in public spending. Most importantly, we find opposite results and provide evidence on two novel mechanisms that may smooth the effect of tenure. These highlight that the value of political experience may differ in developing countries and that factors such as learning of administrative tasks and electoral incentives have to be accounted for. This paper also relates to a broader literature on the effect of politicians’ incentives and selection on policy outcomes. Empirical studies have shown that factors that shape politicians’ incentives, such as term limits (Alt et al., 2011; Besley and Case, 1995), informed voters (Besley and Burgess, 2002), political competition (Besley et al., 2010), or monetary rewards (Ferraz and Finan, 2009), can affect government policy. Similarly, evidence suggests that leaders’ identity and education mat- ter for economic growth (Jones and Olken, 2005; Besley et al., 2011). In this literature, the study most related to ours is that of Alt et al. (2011). The authors analyze the effect of electoral account- ability and competence of U.S. governors on state government outcomes. They find evidence of higher economic growth under term-limited and re-elected incumbents. Our findings complement their results by studying the relative performance of re-elected politicians in a different scenario: a developing country context with no term limits. Most importantly, our methodological approach allow us to avoid confounding the effect of experience with that of other factors such as politician selection. This means we can provide causal evidence on the effect of re-electing politicians under no term limits. 1 For a review of the literature, see Buchinsky et al. (2010), Dustmann and Meghir (2005) and references therein. 2 Coviello and Gagliarducci (2017) studies mayors who may not be restricted to run for immediate re-election but will be term-limited in a future term. 5
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides background information on Peruvian district municipalities and local elections. Section 3 describes the data and the empirical strategy. Section 4 discusses the main results while section 5 provides evidence on the mechanisms that can be driving our findings. Finally, Section 6 presents some concluding remarks. 2 Background District municipalities are the lowest tier of autonomous sub-national government in Peru. In 2014, the year of the last municipal election, there were 1647 district municipalities. Most of these are small, rural and relatively poor. For instance, in 2007, the time of the last census in the period of analysis, the median municipality had around 4,300 inhabitants, out of which 56% live in rural areas, 34% do not have access to water and 38% do not have access to electricity. Peruvian municipalities had a marginal role in local development during most of the country’s history. This changed in early 2002 when the country underwent a process of political and fiscal decentralization. Additional competences were transferred to municipal governments and central government transfers increased.3 Among those transfers is a percentage of corporate tax revenues and royalties from extractive companies operating in the municipality’s region. The commodity boom in the mid 2000s led to a drastic increase in this source of revenue. Due to these transfers, local governments now play an important role in local development, particularly with respect to public investment. Currently, municipalities account for around 20% of the total government budget and close to 40% of national public investment. Municipal government has various roles. They are in charge of providing local services (such as waste collection, and civil register), managing urban planning and business licensing, and par- ticipating as local liaisons in central government programs related to poverty reduction and food assistance. They are also in charge of the construction and maintenance of local infrastructure, such as roads, market places, and parks. In addition, they collaborate with other public agencies to develop basic infrastructure, such as piped water, sewage and electricity, as well as schools and health centers. Municipalities are governed by a mayor and local council members. The mayor holds executive 3 The Municipal Compensation Fund (FONCOMUN) is the main transfer scheme. It redistributes a percentage of sales tax revenues to local governments. 6
powers and plays a crucial managerial role. They are elected in municipal elections using a simple majority rule and serve a 4-year term. The mayor’s party is also guaranteed at least a simple majority in the local council independent of its vote share. Throughout the period of analysis, there were no term limits for local authorities.4 However, it should be noted that their terms can end prematurely due to a recall vote.5 Almost 60 % of incumbent mayors run for re-election. Success is, however, limited. Conditional on running for re-election, the re-election rate is around 31%. Municipal elections are organized and overseen by central government offices, such as the Na- tional Elections Procedures Office (ONPE) and the National Jury of Elections (JNE).6 These tend to be quite competitive. For instance, the average winning margin is 9 p.p. and the median election has more than 8 candidates. Candidates need to meet only basic requirements, such as being a local resident and not hold positions that may create a conflict of interest. There is no need, however, to belong to a national political party or to have a minimum level of education or working experi- ence. In addition, it is important to note that voting is mandatory and failure to do so is subject to penalties. Local elections run smoothly and electoral fraud does not seem to be a problem(OAS, 2003; ONPE, 2003).7 This is important since manipulation of electoral outcomes could invalidate the identification strategy. We do, however, explore empirically the validity of this assumption. 3 Data and Method 3.1 Data This paper uses a sample of Peruvian district municipalities. We focus on the last three com- plete mayoral terms (2003-2006, 2007-2010, and 2011-2014) and their corresponding municipal elections which took place in 2002, 2006 and 2010.8 Naturally, our sample is restricted to munic- 4 After the 2014 municipal elections, the Peruvian Congress passed a law that prohibits immediate reelection of municipal mayors. 5 Recalls are requested by local citizens and can be carried out during the second and third years of the mayor’s term. 6 Elections take place in the same date during the last quarter of the year before the beginning of a new mayoral term. 7 For instance, in the 2002 elections there were only 13 districts in which elections were invalid due to violence, low turnout, or large share of null votes. 8 We do not include information on the current ongoing term as mayors are now term limited. 7
ipalities in which the incumbent ran for re-election. We aggregate annual observations by taking the average over the term period. Hence, each observation corresponds to a municipality-term pair. The final pooled sample includes around 2,700 observations. Our dataset contains information on electoral results, local fiscal outcomes, municipal attributes and politician characteristics. The data come from several sources. Electoral results for all mu- nicipal elections between 1998 and 2014 were provided directly by the JNE or extracted from the JNE’s data management system INFOGOB.9 It includes information on electoral population, turnout, party vote shares, null and blank votes, among other variables. We match these results with lists of mayoral candidates and elected authorities, which come from the same sources, in order to determined each candidate’s vote share, including that for the incumbent. In addition, based on recall voting results, we determine which incumbents were recalled and were unable to conclude their term. Finally, for all mayors in our final sample, we extracted information on their electoral history from INFOGOB. This data, which goes beyond 1998, allows us to check whether newly-elected mayors have previous mayoral experience. As indicators of budget size, we use per capita amounts of total revenue, local tax collection, total spending and public investment. We also check the effects on local budget allocation across sectors such as administration, education, health, and transport. The data is obtained from annual municipal accounts collected and provided by the Ministry of Economy and Finance.10 These include both budgeted and actual expenditures at the account level of disaggregation. In addition, we compute measures of municipal performance and capacity. First, based on municipal accounts, we calculate implementation rates of the public investment budget. This is the percentage of the municipal investment budget that is actually spent and is frequently used by the central government to measure municipal performance. Second, as a proxy for municipal capacity, we construct an index of self-reported needs of technical assistance and training. It is based on information collected as part of an annual survey of municipalities called RENAMU.11 The survey provides municipalities with a set of municipal tasks and asks them to state, separately, for which 9 The INFOGOB website provides data on electoral results and the electoral history of localities, parties, and politicians. 10 These budget reports have official status and are used for national accounting and auditing. 11 The name of the survey stands for Registro Nacional de Municipalidades or National Registry of Municipalities. This mandatory survey is collected and processed by the National Statistics Institute. 8
do they require and training help.12 We calculate the percentage of tasks for which a municipality requests assistance and the percentage of tasks for which it requires training. The index we use is the average of these two numbers. We interpret higher values of the index as an indicator of lower municipal capacity. To analyze potential differences in politician characteristics, we use data from mayoral candi- dates’ curriculum vitae. Under the electoral law, submitting a curriculum vitae in a standardized format is a requirement for candidacy. From this, we obtain characteristics such as age, education level and previous public sector experience. It should be noted that information is self-reported but penalties are imposed for misrepresentation.13 Data is available for elections from 2006 onward.14 Finally, the dataset includes information on municipal sociodemographic characteristics such as life expectancy, education levels, and family income. This data has been drawn from the UNDP. Table 1 presents summary statistics for the main variables. The sample only includes munic- ipalities where the incumbent run for re-election. As aforementioned, incumbents have limited success. Only 31.8% manage to get reelected and, on average, incumbents lose the election by 5 p.p. Elections are competitive and have high participation levels. On average, 7.2 parties present mayoral candidates, the margin of victory is less than 10% and turnout is around 85%. The average winning candidate is 44 years old, has a 0.36 probability of having a university degree and has more than 7 years of public sector experience. An average municipality has revenues of 740 Peru- vian Nuevos Soles (PEN) per capita, out of which only 4.5 PEN come from local taxes. However, this amount varies significantly as predominantly urban municipalities tend to collect significantly higher amounts. Around 34% of its budget is allocated to administrative duties, 17% to health expenditures, 13.5% to transportation and 11.8% to education. 3.2 Empirical strategy The empirical analysis aims to identify the effect of re-electing the incumbent on local outcomes. The main empirical challenge is that municipalities with and without re-elected incumbents may 12 These tasks include, for instance, management and accounting, planning, municipal legislation, project manage- ment, IT services, statistics, etc. 13 This means that response rates are relatively high. For example, 74% and 84% of mayors in our sample reported at least one job position in 2006 and 2010, respectively. 14 However, the availability of certain characteristics depends on the election year. For example, data on candidates’ sentences is only available for 2010. 9
have different unobservable characteristics.15 These differences can confound our estimates. To address this concern, we use a sharp regression discontinuity design (RDD) in which the treatment is having the incumbent mayor re-elected. The assignment of the treatment depends on the incumbent’s electoral results. Let us define the assignment or running variable for municipality i in electoral period t as W Mit = vit,m − max j {vit, j6=m }, where vit,m is the vote share obtained by the running incumbent and max j {vit, j6=m } is the largest vote share obtained by any other candidate. W Mit represents the “previous incumbent’s margin”. It measures by how much the previous in- cumbent won (or lost) the re-election. Given this definition, a municipality is treated (i.e., has a re-elected mayor) if W Mit > 0.16 The regression discontinuity estimand is then defined as: τRD = lim E [Yit |W Mit > 0] − lim E [Yit |W Mit < 0] (1) W Mit ↓0 W Mit ↑0 where Yit is the observed outcome of municipality i in electoral period t. We estimate τRD using local linear regressions. In particular, we use the robust bias-corrected estimator with a data-driven bandwidth selector suggested by Calonico et al. (2014b).17 Following Calonico et al. (2014a), our results report the conventional estimate of τ pRD and standard errors but present the robust bias-corrected p-value levels. In our main analysis, we exclude municipalities in which the previous incumbent was recalled. This allow us to focus on the effect of re-elected mayors who have served a complete term. Includ- ing recalled incumbents may assuage the effect of political experience for two reasons. First, we would be considering re-elected mayors who may only have 2 or 3 years of experience. Second, we would be including newly-elected mayors that may have some immediate mayoral experience after replacing the recalled authority for the remainder of the previous term. However, we still present the estimates for when all mayors are considered. The validity of the sharp RD design relies on the assumption that the expected outcome condi- 15 For instance, municipalities that re-elect mayors may have weaker opposition candidates, fewer informed voters, or better bureaucracies. Similarly, re-elected mayors may be different from newly-elected one in terms of honesty, and voter preference alignment. 16 In case of a tie, elections are decided by a random draw among tied candidates. In our sample, this scenario only occurs 3 times. We account for these by assigning a negligible winning margin of 0.0001 if the incumbent wins the toss and -0.0001 otherwise. Results are robust to excluding these observations. 17 The estimator is implemented by the STATA package rdrobust. 10
tional on treatment status is continuous on the running variable. This assumption may not hold if there is manipulation of treatment status (i.e. if incumbents are able to precisely control their vote share) or if other treatments depend on the same threshold. We check the validity of the our de- sign by testing for manipulation of the treatment assignment variable and for balance of covariates around the treatment cut-off. To check for manipulation, we first use the conventional McCrary (2008) test. Figure 1 shows the estimated density function of the assignment variable for our complete sample and for that which excludes recalled mayors. For the former, we find no evidence of a discontinuity of the density of municipalities at the treatment cut-off. The McCrary (2008) discontinuity estimate is negative and insignificant. For the latter, the equivalent estimate is also negative but significant at the 10% level. This last result is surprising and not consistent with the qualitative evidence on lack of electoral fraud (OAS, 2003; ONPE, 2003).18 Moreover, the estimate sign does not fit expectations. On average, incumbents should have more power to alter their vote shares as they control local government institutions. Hence, if electoral results are manipulable, a positive, significant discontinuity would be expected. We further test for manipulation by calculating an empirical p-value based on carrying out the McCrary (2008) test at 200 equally spaced cut-offs in the interval [−10%, 10%] of the forcing variable. The p-value is around 0.25 for the full sample and close to 0.23 for the restricted sample. The lack of significance supports the claim that there is no manipulation of the running variable. Finally, we perform a recent test proposed by Cattaneo et al. (2016) which has better size properties than the McCrary (2008) one.19 In both cases, the test fails to reject the null hypothesis of no discontinuity with p-values of 0.27 for the full sample and 0.17 for the restricted one. Second, we examine whether there are discontinuities at the cut-off in covariates and past re- alizations of our main outcomes. As before, we do this analysis for both the full sample and that which excludes previously recalled mayors. Table 2 shows the RD estimates for these vari- ables. Consistent with the identification assumption, there are no significant treatment effects on all pseudo-outcomes for both samples.In Figure A1 in the Appendix, we depict the relation between the assignment variable and selected placebo outcomes using a 4th degree polynomial fit on each 18 In Figure 1, no clear discontinuity is observed by comparing the bins around the cut-off. It appears that the result may be 19 The test is implemented using the STATA package rddensity. 11
side of the discontinuity. The graphs illustrate that there are no significant jumps at the cut-off. In addition, we perform a permutation test proposed by Canay and Kamat (2016). Using permutations of a small number of observations, this test checks for the continuity of the distribution of outcomes at the cut-off.20 Columns 2 and 4 in Table 2 report the test p-values. We consistently fail to reject the hypothesis of continuity in the distribution of placebos at the threshold. Taken together, these two set of results yield support to the validity of the identification assump- tion. 4 Main Results Table 3 presents the effects of having a re-elected mayor on our main outcomes under various spec- ifications. Panels A and B show the estimates for measures of budget size and spending patterns, respectively. The analysis excludes incumbents who were recalled in the preceding term. Hence, we focus on the effect of re-elected mayors who successfully completed their past term. The results in Column 1 of Panel A show that, under our baseline specification, re-electing the incumbent has no significant effects on per capita municipal revenue, spending, local tax collection, and public investment. The estimates are not only statistically insignificant but small in magnitude. In all cases, they represent less than 7% of a standard deviation. Moreover, the average standardized effect for all four measures is less than 6% of a standard deviation. Figure A2 in the Appendix presents the graphical representation of these results. The graphs illustrate that there is no sizable discontinuity in outcomes at the assignment variable cut-off. We check the lack of significant effects on budget size indicators by carrying out the Canay and Kamat (2016) permutation test. The test p-values are shown in Column 5. While all of our RD estimates are small and statistically insignificant, the permutation test does find discontinuities in the distribution of outcomes for three of our four measures. Note that the test evaluates changes in the distribution rather than discontinuities in the mean. Hence, even though we fail to reject the latter, we cannot disregard the possibility of changes in higher order moments of budget size measures. 20 Following Canay and Kamat (2016), we use a rule-of-thumb formula to determine the number of observations used in the test and report the test p-values. 12
We also find that re-electing the incumbent has limited effects on how mayors spend their budgets. The results in Panel B of Table 3 show that there are no significant effects on the public investment implementation rate, a commonly used measure to evaluate municipal performance21 and on the percentage of the budget allocated to agriculture, education, health, and social services. All of these effects are less than 6% of a standard deviation. However, we do find a significant effect on transportation expenditures of around 2 p.p. or 0.2 standard deviations. This increase appears to be coming at the expense of a reduction in ad- ministrative spending.22 The permutation test and the graphical representation of the analysis in Figure A3 in the Appendix portray a similar picture. The test rejects the null of no discontinuity for transportation expenditures at the 10% significance level and barely fails to reject it for the case of administrative spending. The above results are robust to changes in the order of the assignment variable polynomial and to the introduction of covariates. Columns 2 to 4 in Table 3 show our estimates for alternative spec- ifications. The only discrepancy that we observe is that the effects are larger in terms of magnitude when we introduce a second order polynomial and do not control for covariates. Under this spec- ification, the average standardized effects for our measures of budget size and spending patterns are 12.5% and 10.7% of a standard deviation, respectively. Most importantly, the pattern of results holds when we introduce covariates such as the past value of the outcome variable and basic munic- ipal sociodemographic characteristics. This exercise increases the precision of our estimates. As before, under these specifications, we only find a significant effect for transportation expenditures. Moreover, our results hold for different samples. First, we check whether the exclusion of observations where the mayor was recalled in the previous term has a sizable effect on our results. The estimates for when these are included are shown in columns 1 and 2 of Table 4. These reveal that our results are similar under the full sample. We still observe that the only significant impact of having a re-elected mayor is on transportation expenditures, though the permutation test still finds discontinuities in the distribution of three budget size measures. That is, including incumbents with partial term experience has no significant impact on our findings. We then check whether the results hold when we further restrict the baseline sample by exclud- 21 SeeLoayza et al. (2014) for further discussion on this measure. 22 While the effect on administrative spending is statistically insignificant, its magnitude is around 0.15 standard deviations. 13
ing where the newly-elected mayor has previous mayoral experience.23 This allow us to compare re-elected mayors with a completed term with newly-elected mayors who assume mayoral office for the first time. The results for these sub-sample are shown in columns 3 and 4 of Table 4. As be- fore, there is a lack of sizable and statistically significant effects. Hence, it appears that our findings are not driven by some municipalities on the left side of the cut-off being treated with an authority with previous mayoral experience. A possible concern is that the lack of significant effects may be due to mayors having limited discretion over local policy outcomes. As documented in Section 2, Peruvian municipalities obtain a significant share of their resources from government transfers. These are set based on prede- fined rules and indicators. Hence, local authorities are generally unable to change these amounts. However, while this may affect our estimates for municipal revenue, other outcomes should be largely unaffected. In particular, this concern is not relevant for our measures of spending patterns as mayors have control over public investment implementation rates and budget allocation. Overall, the estimates point to re-elected mayors not having meaningful effects on government outcomes. This contrasts with the expectation that political experience should lead to differences in policy making. However, we do find some evidence that tenure in office may matter for specific outcomes. 5 Mechanisms Reelected mayors appear to have a limited effect on local government outcomes. In this section, we explore possible explanations for the lack of stronger effects. First, we explore whether reelected and newly elected mayors share similar characteristics, except for their differences in political experience. Second, we check whether inexperienced mayors gain relevant political experience at a rapid pace. We do by examining how differences in outcomes vary throughout the mayoral term. Third, we analyze whether, even in the absence of term limits, reelected mayors face lower electoral incentives that may be reducing their incentive to exert effort and profit from their experience. 23 We define mayoral experience as having served as a mayor in any district or province. Mayors need not have completed an entire term to be excluded. 14
5.1 Politician Characteristics We first explore how reelected an new mayors compare in terms of their individual characteristics. In particular, we check whether they differ in terms of age, education level, gender and work experience. This exercise is important to understand if personal characteristics other than political experience are changing at the treatment cut-off. The results are shown in Panel A of Table 6. We observe that there are no significant differences in age and gender. In terms of education levels, mayors do not differ in terms of the probability of having completed university studies. However, re-elected mayors are more likely to have com- pleted secondary education. This last result should be interpreted with caution as information is only available for candidates in the 2010 election and the permutation test clearly fails to find a discontinuity.24 In addition, we find that mayors do not differ in the likelihood of having a previous sentence.25 As expected, the key difference between re-elected and newly elected mayors is in their public sector experience. Reelected politicians are 14.7 p.p. more likely to have worked in the public sector. Moreover, they have 2.9 more years of public sector experience.26 Note that while the estimate is marginally insignificant, new mayors appear to be more likely to have private sector experience. This is expected as new mayors may have spent part of the previous electoral term working in the private sector. The evidence supports the claim that the dominant distinction between mayors is the difference in their political experience. It also motivates the analysis of alternative mechanisms that may be driving the lack of stronger effects in policy outcomes. However, we cannot rule out that mayors may substantially differ in other unobservable characteristics that may affect policy. 5.2 Learning and Experience At the start of the electoral cycle, reelected mayors are more experienced. However, it is possible that relevant political experience is quickly gained in the first part of the mayoral term. That is, 24 We obtain a p-value of around 0.6. 25 As with the case of secondary education, data for this outcome is only available for the 2010 election. 26 Notice that spending the last four years in elected office need not translate into four more years of public sector experience as the new mayor may have spent those years as a public sector employee. 15
reelected and rookie mayors would have similar levels of expertise by the latter part of the term. In this case, differences in average policy outcomes for the entire electoral cycle may be small. To test for this hypothesis, we check how the mayors’ administrations differ in terms of munic- ipal capacity and performance in each year of their term. As a measure of municipal capacity, we use the index of municipal needs for technical assistance and training in municipal tasks described in Section 3.1. As in Section 4, we use municipal public investment implementation rates as a measure of performance. The results are shown in Table 5 and are illustrated graphically in Figure A4. For both municipal performance and capacity, the general pattern is clear. The largest and most significant differences are observed in the first year of the mayoral term. Reelected mayors perform better in terms of investment implementation. They also appear to be better able to run the municipal governments as they have lower needs for assistance and training. This first-year estimates are equivalent to 0.23 and 0.42 standard deviations for investment implementation and municipal needs, respectively. For the case of investment performance, there are no other significant differences in latter years, though there is a smaller spike in the third year. As for municipal capacity, there is a gradual decline in the estimates. For both measures, mayors are statistically indistinguishable by the end of their terms. Hence, it appears that relevant experience on municipal tasks is gained relatively quickly. This rapid learning by new mayors can help explain why we do not observe more meaningful differences in terms of government outcomes. However, this evidence does not rule out that other factors may be smoothing differences throughout the term. 5.3 Electoral Accountability Under no term limits, both reelected and new mayors can run for consecutive additional terms. However, this need not imply that both face similar electoral incentives. One reason for this is that re-elected mayors may assign a lower value to an additional term. These may be focused on running for higher office or on an alternative career path. Most importantly, it is plausible that re-election probabilities depend on the number of consecutive terms the mayor has already been elected for. This could be due to the possible consequences of political entrenchment. If re-elected mayors face lower re-election probabilities, they may exert less effort than their newly elected peers. Lower electoral incentives could help explain why more experience does not translate to more local tax 16
collection, higher investment implementation rates, or more spending towards high social return sectors. To check for differences in electoral incentives, we estimate the effect of having a re-elected mayor on the probability that the mayor runs in the next election and on re-election probabilities. Panel B of Table 6 shows the results. First, we find that re-elected mayors are 17 p.p. less likely to run for an additional term. Second, we find a large drop in re-election probabilities for re-elected mayors. The unconditional probability, which does not condition on whether the incumbent runs in the next election, decreases by around 16 p.p. The size of the drop highlights that this is not only due to re-elected incumbents pursuing re-election at lower rates. When we condition the re-election probability on those incumbents that opt to run, the drop is slightly bigger and stands at 19.6 p.p. The above results may be due to voters conditioning their behavior on the incumbent’s number of terms. This behavior can be rationalize by considering the possible negative effects of political entrenchment. Coviello and Gagliarducci (2017) finds that increased tenure in office reduces the number of bidders and the cost of public works. That is, experienced politicians may be better at capturing resources. In a context with term limits, voters need not worry about this as those politicians will not be able to run for more consecutive periods. In the absence of these restrictions, voters may anticipate that giving an additional term to an already re-elected mayor implies a high risk of political capture in the next period. Hence, voters may offer re-election probabilities which depend on the number of periods the incumbent has been in office. In particular, they may be more willing to re-elect a one-term than a two-term incumbent. This effect can be particularly important in a weak institutional context where local governments have large budgets. An alternative explanation is based on the observation that re-elected mayors are less likely to run for an additional term. This could be a response to voter’s offering lower re-election probabil- ities to experienced incumbents. However, it could also be due to re-elected mayors being more likely to seek other elected positions or career paths. If those who do not run for an additional term are those whose better attributes lead them to have a higher opportunity cost, then it is pos- sible that the average quality of re-elected mayors who seek an extra term is lower than that of new incumbents seeking re-election. Voters would then be more likely to re-elected a one-term incumbent. We provide evidence on this by estimating the effect on the probability that the incumbent runs 17
for provincial mayor in the next election.27 We find that re-elected mayors are more likely to focus on pursuing a higher elected office as they are 7 p.p. more likely to run for provincial mayor. Independent of the explanation, the evidence supports the claim that re-elected incumbents may face lower incentives to exert effort for their current job. These lower levels of effort may dampen the gains from greater political experience and help explain the lack of stronger effects of having a more experienced mayor. 6 Conclusion This paper examines the effect of re-electing incumbents on local government outcomes in the absence of term limits. Using the case of Peruvian local mayors and a regression discontinuity design, we find that having a re-elected mayor has limited effects on a broad set of measures of budget size and budget allocation. We find that re-electing mayors leads to sizable improvements in municipal capacity and per- formance in the first term year. However, these differences later disappear. Moreover, we show that re-elected mayors are less likely to run for an additional term and obtain a new electoral vic- tory. Re-election rates for re-elected incumbents are significantly lower even when conditioning for those mayors who decide to run. Hence, our results suggest that the lack of more sizable ef- fects may be due to rapid learning among newly elected mayors and lower electoral incentives for re-elected incumbents offsetting the effect of political experience. The previous results are informative for the debate on the costs and benefits of term limits for local politicians. Our findings indicate that the gains from tenure in office are not sizable. Moreover, the highest returns to experience appear to occur in the first term year. Hence, while introducing term limits restrict electoral accountability, any negative effect on outcomes due to lower politician experience may be small. This will be particularly so in contexts with long electoral cycles. Finally, our result on the electoral disadvantage that re-elected incumbents face vis-á-vis newly elected ones shows that the former may face lower electoral incentives even under no term limits. There are, however, certain caveats that should be considered when interpreting our findings. First, the results report the average effect of having a re-elected politician. This may be hiding 27 Provincial office is the usual next step for a local politician. 18
heterogeneity across municipalities which we may not be able to accurately characterize. Second, there are outcomes such as quality of public goods which we are not able to observe and for which there can be an effect of tenure in office. References Alt, J., E. B. De Mesquita, and S. Rose (2011). Disentangling Accountability and Competence in Elections: Evidence from U.S. Term Limits. The Journal of Politics 73(01), 171–186. Besley, T. and R. Burgess (2002). The political economy of government responsiveness: Theory and evidence from India. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1415–1451. Besley, T. and A. Case (1995). Does electoral accountability affect economic policy choices? evidence from gubernatorial term limits. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(3). Besley, T., J. G. Montalvo, and M. Reynal-Querol (2011). Do educated leaders matter? The Economic Journal 121(554), F205–227. Besley, T., T. Persson, and D. M. Sturm (2010). Political competition, policy and growth: theory and evidence from the US. The Review of Economic Studies 77(4), 1329–1352. Buchinsky, M., D. Fougere, F. Kramarz, and R. Tchernis (2010). Interfirm Mobility, Wages and the Returns to Seniority and Experience in the United States. The Review of Economic Studies 77(3), 972–1001. Calonico, S., M. D. Cattaneo, and R. Titiunik (2014a). Robust Data-driven Inference in the Regression-discontinuity Design. Stata Journal 14(4), 909–946. Calonico, S., M. D. Cattaneo, and R. Titiunik (2014b). Robust Nonparametric Confidence Intervals for Regression-Discontinuity Designs. Econometrica 82(6), 2295–2326. Canay, I. A. and V. Kamat (2016). Approximate Permutation Tests and Induced Order Statistics in the Regression Discontinuity Design. 19
Cattaneo, M. D., M. Jansson, and X. Ma (2016). Simple Local Regression Distribution Estima- tors with an Application to Manipulation Testing. Unpublished Working Paper, University of Michigan, and University of California Berkeley. Coviello, D. and S. Gagliarducci (2017). Tenure in Office and Public Procurement. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 9(3), 59–105. Dustmann, C. and C. Meghir (2005). Wages, experience and seniority. The Review of Economic Studies 72(1), 77–108. Ferraz, C. and F. Finan (2009). Motivating politicians: The impacts of monetary incentives on quality and performance. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research. Johnson, J. M. and W. M. Crain (2004). Effects of term limits on fiscal performance: Evidence from democratic nations. Public Choice 119(1-2), 73–90. Jones, B. F. and B. A. Olken (2005). Do leaders matter? national leadership and growth since World War II. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 120(3), 835–864. Loayza, N. V., J. Rigolini, and O. Calvo-González (2014). More Than You Can Handle: Decentral- ization and Spending Ability of Peruvian Municipalities. Economics & Politics 26(1), 56–78. McCrary, J. (2008). Testing for Manipulation of the Running Variable in the Regression Disconti- nuity Design. Journal of Econometrics 142(2). OAS (2003, December). Report on the Electoral Observation Mission for Regional and Municipal Elections, Peru 2002. Technical report, Organization of American States (OAS),. ONPE (2003, July). Elecciones Regionales y Municipales 2003 y Municipales Complemen- tarias 2003 - Informe de Resultados. Technical report, Oficina Nacional de Procesos Electorals (ONPE),. 20
Tables and Figures Table 1: Summary Statistics Variables Nr. Obs. Mean S.D. Min Max Incumbent is reelected 2817 0.318 0.466 0 1 Winning margin of incumbent 2817 -5.084 15.32 -61.83 97.65 Log of municipal revenue p.c. 2813 6.606 0.911 4.278 11.26 Log of local tax revenue p.c. 2813 1.495 1.510 0 7.934 Log of municipal spending p.c. 2813 6.351 0.847 4.199 10.04 Log of municipal investment p.c. 2813 5.815 1.078 1.989 9.799 Investment execution rate % 2813 74.68 13.71 14.35 100 Administrative spending, % 2812 34.02 11.45 4.063 76.79 Agriculture spending, % 2812 5.538 8.126 0 73.32 Education spending, % 2812 11.77 8.844 0 53.62 Health spending, % 2812 16.95 12.72 0 84.38 Social services spending, % 2812 10.57 7.550 0.190 54.65 Transportation spending, % 2812 13.54 9.987 0 71.40 Turnout 2817 85.41 5.806 53.17 98.81 Number of parties 2817 7.162 2.814 2 20 Margin of victory 2817 9.417 9.168 0 97.65 Winner’s vote share 2817 34.63 10.50 14.47 98.82 Mayor subject to recall 2817 0.197 0.398 0 1 Mayor recalled 2817 0.0536 0.225 0 1 Mayor’s Age 1979 44.62 8.809 21.43 76.06 Mayor has university degree 1967 0.358 0.480 0 1 Mayor completed tertiary education 1967 0.533 0.499 0 1 Mayor’s years of public service 960 7.270 9.063 0 50.25 Mayor’s number of corruption complaints 965 0.846 1.830 0 28 Mayor has a sentence 960 0.0729 0.260 0 1 Life expectancy, 2003 2814 67.86 3.669 53.33 74.01 % with high school diplomas, 2003 2814 45.49 23.20 0.178 99.93 Average years of education, 2003 2814 6.178 2.187 1.907 13.94 Family income per capita, 2003 2814 283.7 143.8 76.53 1219 Notes: Summary statistics are based on all municipality-year observations in which the in- cumbent ran for re-election. Monetary variables, such as revenue or investment per capita, are measured in Nuevos Soles (PEN). 21
Table 2: Balance on Placebo Outcomes Full Sample Excluding Previously Recalled Permutation Permutation Dep. Var. RD Estimate RD Estimate p-value p-value Mean SD (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) A. Socioeconomic Characteristics Life expectancy, 2003 0.040 0.416 0.035 0.455 67.86 3.669 (0.387) (0.383) % with high school diplomas, 2003 0.346 0.652 0.317 0.685 45.49 23.20 (2.434) (2.368) Years of education, 2003 -0.113 0.196 -0.110 0.223 6.178 2.187 (0.222) (0.231) Family income per capita, 2003 -16.371 0.580 -15.492 0.545 283.7 143.8 (16.299) (16.534) B. Public Finance Log of municipal revenue p.c. in previous term 0.039 0.135 0.030 0.285 5.898 0.936 (0.098) (0.096) Log of local tax revenue p.c. in previous term -0.054 0.465 -0.046 0.639 1.318 1.381 (0.152) (0.152) Log of municipal spending p.c. in previous term 0.040 0.215 0.029 0.410 5.698 0.869 (0.092) (0.011) Log of municipal investment p.c. in previous term 0.075 0.279 0.058 0.515 5.058 1.088 (0.123) (0.120) C. Electoral Outcomes Turnout in t 0.477 0.622 0.437 0.667 85.41 5.806 (0.630) (0.631) Number of Parties in t -0.212 0.901 -0.199 0.981 7.162 2.814 (0.291) (0.296) HHI of Parties in t 118.581 0.279 113.166 0.456 2493 924.1 (90.638) (91.086) Notes: * denotes significance at 10%, ** significance at 5% and *** significance at 1%. Standard errors in brackets are calculated using a heteroskedasticity-robust nearest neighbor variance estimator with the minimum number of neighbors equal to three. Column 1 shows conventional RD estimates under our baseline specification excluding municipality-years where the previous incumbent was recalled. Significance levels are based on robust standard errors following Calonico et al. (2014b). Column 2 shows the p-values for the Canay and Kamat (2016) permutation test. Columns 3 and 4 report the mean and standard deviation for the outcome variable based on all municipality-years excluding those where the previous incumbent did not run or where he was recalled. 22
Figure 1: Estimated Density Function of Assignment Variable Full Sample .04 .03 .02 .01 0 -100 -75 -50 -25 0 25 50 75 100 Previous Incumbent's Winning Margin Excluding Recalled Incumbents .04 .03 .02 .01 0 -100 -75 -50 -25 0 25 50 75 100 Previous Incumbent's Winning Margin Estimated density 95% C.I. 23
Table 3: Effect of Re-elected Mayor on Government Outcomes Permutation Effective Dep. Var. RD Estimates p-value N. Obs Mean SD (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Polynomial order 1st 2nd 1st 2nd 1st Baseline Covariates No No Yes Yes No A. Local Budget Size Log of municipal revenue p.c. 0.052 0.126 0.055 0.045 0.0450 1573 6.589 0.907 (0.089) (0.122) (0.049) (0.064) Log of local tax revenue p.c. -0.075 -0.066 -0.023 -0.013 0.650 1492 1.497 1.508 (0.164) (0.217) (0.061) (0.084) Log of municipal spending p.c. 0.055 0.148 0.054 0.036 0.0420 1524 6.335 0.843 (0.084) (0.118) (0.043) (0.057) Log of municipal investment p.c. 0.066 0.153 0.058 0.042 0.0410 1467 5.797 1.076 (0.112) (0.151) (0.061) (0.082) B. Spending Patterns % of investment budget implemented 0.781 1.798 0.208 0.918 0.635 1291 74.72 13.71 (1.754) (2.346) (1.582) (2.220) Administrative spending, % -1.681 -2.520 -1.010 -1.768 0.104 1716 33.97 11.43 (1.247) (1.696) (1.159) (1.669) Agriculture spending, % -0.390 -0.305 -0.578 -0.887 0.360 1804 5.522 8.153 (0.970) (1.308) (1.008) (1.273) Education spending, % 0.490 0.782 0.599 0.580 0.296 1812 11.77 8.862 (0.860) (1.174) (0.867) (1.080) Health spending, % -0.731 -0.109 -1.428 -1.468 0.655 1737 16.90 12.74 (1.249) (1.801) (1.284) (1.666) Social services spending, % 0.333 0.306 0.392 0.260 0.613 1467 10.64 7.563 (0.759) (0.883) (0.644) (0.832) Transportation spending, % 2.004* 2.218 2.087* 2.379* 0.0691 1396 13.54 9.988 (1.122) (1.320) (1.143) (1.330) Average Standardized Effect (joint for A) 0.058 0.125 0.048 0.035 Average Standardized Effect (joint for B) 0.087 0.107 0.088 0.112 Notes: * denotes significance at 10%, ** significance at 5% and *** significance at 1%. Standard errors in brackets are calculated using a heteroskedasticity-robust nearest neighbor variance estimator with the minimum number of neighbors equal to three. Significance levels are based on robust standard errors following Calonico et al. (2014b). Column 1 shows conventional RD estimates under our baseline specification. Columns 2 to 4 present conventional RD estimates under a 2nd order polynomial with no covariates, a 1st order polynomial with covariates and a 2nd order polynomial with covariates, respectively. Covariates used in Columns 3 and 4 include previous value of the outcome variable, and 2003 values of human development index, life expectancy, % with high school diplomas, average years of education, and family income per capita. Column 5 shows the p-values for the Canay and Kamat (2016) permutation test. Column 6 displays the number of observations chosen by the bandwidth-selection algorithm used to compute Column 1 estimates. Columns 7 and 8 report the mean and standard deviation for the outcome variable based on all municipality-years in the sample which excludes those observations where the mayor was recalled in the previous term. All estimates are based on this restricted sample. 24
Table 4: Effect of Re-elected Mayor on Government Outcomes under Different Samples Excluding New Mayors Full Sample with Previous Mayoral Experience Permutation Permutation Dep. Var. RD Estimate RD Estimate p-value p-value Mean SD (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) A. Local Budget Size Log of municipal revenue p.c. 0.055 0.0450 0.082 0.101 6.606 0.911 (0.090) (0.094) Log of local tax revenue p.c. -0.075 0.650 -0.056 0.872 1.495 1.510 (0.164) (0.165) Log of municipal spending p.c. 0.060 0.0541 0.082 0.103 6.351 0.847 (0.085) (0.089) Log of municipal investment p.c. 0.074 0.0290 0.113 0.0711 5.815 1.078 (0.113) (0.120) B. Spending Patterns % of investment budget implemented 0.877 0.638 0.673 0.513 74.68 13.71 (1.735) (1.782) Administrative spending, % -1.699 0.105 -1.676 0.274 34.02 11.45 (1.246) (1.309) Agriculture spending, % -0.404 0.345 -0.527 0.609 5.538 8.126 (0.883) (1.024) Education spending, % 0.619 0.298 0.589 0.457 11.77 8.844 (0.861) (0.891) Health spending, % -0.708 0.648 -0.420 0.976 16.95 12.72 (1.273) (1.271) Social services spending, % 0.274 0.615 0.012 0.522 10.57 7.550 (0.770) (0.829) Transportation spending, % 1.958* 0.0651 1.997* 0.237 13.54 9.987 (1.109) (1.146) Average Standardized Effect (joint for A) 0.062 0.082 Average Standardized Effect (joint for B) 0.089 0.080 Notes: * denotes significance at 10%, ** significance at 5% and *** significance at 1%. Standard errors in brackets are calculated using a heteroskedasticity-robust nearest neighbor variance estimator with the minimum number of neighbors equal to three. Signifi- cance levels are based on robust standard errors following Calonico et al. (2014b). Columns 1 and 2 show conventional RD estimates and p-values for the Canay and Kamat (2016) permutation test for the full sample which also includes incumbents recalled in the previous term. Columns 3 and 4 show conventional RD estimates and p-values for the Canay and Kamat (2016) permutation test for the sample which excludes newly-elected mayors that have previous mayoral experience in any province or district. Columns 7 and 8 report the mean and standard deviation for the outcome variable based on all municipality-years in our sample. Average standardized effects in columns 1 and 3 are calculated based on standard deviations in the respective sample. 25
You can also read