Property prices and bank lending in China
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 63–75 Property prices and bank lending in China Qi Liang a,b,*, Hua Cao a a Department of Finance, School of Economics, Nankai University, Tianjin 300071, China b Institute of Japanese Studies, Nankai University, Tianjin 300071, China Received 15 September 2006; received in revised form 20 November 2006; accepted 21 November 2006 Abstract This paper investigates the relationship between property prices and bank lending for the case of China over the period 1999Q1–2006Q2. Under a high dimensional autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) framework with gross domestic product (GDP) and interest rate also being taken into account, we find that there exists unidirectional causality running from bank lending to property prices, and that the causality runs interactively through the error correction term from bank lending, GDP and interest rate to property prices. Our findings have important policy implications. # 2007 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved. JEL classification : E52; C32; G21 Keywords: Property prices; Bank lending; ARDL; China 1. Introduction The development of the property sector in China is significantly remarkable since China adopted the economic reform policy in the late 1970s. The value added created by the property sector has increased gradually, and property sector has made more and more contributions to the economic growth. In the years 1953–1978, China’s gross domestic product (GDP) had increased 6.1% annually, in which property sector had increased 5% annually. Besides, the value added created by property sector accounted about 2% in GDP and the property sector had contributed 1.83% to the economic growth. In the years 1978–2005, China’s GDP had increased 9.6% annually, and the corresponding figures relating to the property sector had increased respectively * Corresponding author at: Department of Finance, School of Economics, Nankai University, Tianjin 300071, China. Tel.: +86 22 2350 8544; fax: +86 22 2350 1816. E-mail addresses: liangqi@nankai.edu.cn (Q. Liang), caohua@nankai.edu.cn (H. Cao). 1049-0078/$ – see front matter # 2007 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.asieco.2006.12.013
64 Q. Liang, H. Cao / Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 63–75 to 11.4%, 4.1% and 2.39%.1 Recently, the prominent position of property sector as a pillar industry in the national economy has even been endorsed by the official documents of the State Council. On the other hand, the property prices have been quite strong over the last decade. Particularly, since 2004, the property prices have gone up extraordinarily. The annual growth rates of property prices increased 15.1% and 19.5% in 2004 and 2005, comparing to respective previous year. Some scholars pointed out that bank lending has played an important role in the roaring property prices, e.g., the credit exposure of commercial banks to the property and property-related sector had increased from only 3.6% in 1998 to 14.8% in 2004 and the mortgage loan to total loan ratio had increased from only 0.59% in 1998 to 8.88% in 2005.2 These figures have resulted growing interests among academics and policymakers to study the interactions between property prices and bank lending, especially the possible responsiveness of property prices to reserve rate and interest rate adjustments so that central bank may prevent the disruptive effects of property prices shock on financial stability and the whole economy. Policymakers appear to have taken the notice. On April 28, 2006, central bank raised the base lending rate from 5.58% to 5.85%. Moreover, central bank also raised the required reserve rate three times this year on July 5, July 21 and August 15, up 0.5% each time. These measures appear to have certain effects, as the growth rate of property-related investment started to head down in 2005. Nevertheless, property prices, especially residential property prices, are rising as ever, although at a relatively slower pace. From the viewpoint of policymakers, reliable and timely examination of the relationship between property prices and bank lending could help them formulate effective policy decisions. Moreover, market practitioners also need accurate estimations to make effective investment and risk management decisions. Theoretically, there exists potentially bidirectional causality between property prices and bank lending. On one hand, property prices may influence the availability of bank lending via the wealth effect and the Tobin’s Q effect and the financial accelerator effect (e.g., Bernanke & Gertler, 1999; Kiyotaki & Moore, 1997). Movements in property prices may change the borrowing capacity and credit demand of corporations and households. On the other hand, credit availability may also affect property prices, as increases in credit availability may expand the demand for properties. So far, abundant international evidences have documented the coincidence of property price cycles with bank lending cycles (e.g., Zhu, 2003). Empirical studies of developed economies often find unidirectional causality running from property prices to bank lending. Shimizu (2000) presents a theory of bank lending and collateral to explain the banks’ lending behavior and the important role played by rising land prices in Japan. Based on the estimated impulse-response functions, empirical analysis on the relationships among land prices, bank loans and funds raised in the capital market indicates that there exists causality between land prices and financial market activities, and loans to small and medium-sized firms and funds raised in the capital markets are significantly affected by land prices. In another study, using a number of indicators of land prices and bank lending, Shimizu (2006) also finds unidirectional causality running from the former to the latter in the March 1956 to March 1999 periods in Japan. Gerlach and Peng (2005) investigate the long-run relationship between bank lending and property prices in Hong Kong under a vector autoregressive framework with multivariable such as property prices, bank lending, interest rate and gross 1 Data source: China’s property development condition and trend forecasting, China’s Property Development Fore- casting Report 2006–2010, Macroeconomic Research Section, Development Research Center of State Council, China. 2 Data source: People’s Bank of China and Wind Database.
Q. Liang, H. Cao / Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 63–75 65 domestic product (GDP),3 and find that the strong correlation between property prices and bank lending appears to be due to bank lending adjusting to property prices, rather than the converse. They suggest that excessive bank lending was not the root cause of the boom and bust cycles of the property market in Hong Kong. In a similar study, Hofmann (2003) analyzes the direction of causality between bank lending and property prices in 20 industrialized countries over the last two decades. The long-run causality also appears to go from property prices to bank lending, suggesting that property price cycles, reflecting changing beliefs about future economic prospects, drive credit cycle. However, empirical studies on emerging market economies often find that there exists an opposite unidirectional causality. Collyns and Senhadji (2001) find that credit growth has a significant contemporaneous effect on residential property prices in a number of Asian economies. Koha et al. (2005) investigate the Asian property price run-up and collapse in the 1990s and identify financial intermediaries’ underpricing of the put option imbedded in non-recourse mortgage loans as a potential cause for the observed price behavior. Unfortunately, most existing literature utilized cointegration approaches such as two-step residual-based technique (Engle & Granger, 1987) or system-based reduced rank regression method (Johansen, 1991), and might potentially suffer model specification problem due to the fact that there is considerable doubt concerning the order of integration of variables such as interest rate.4 In the presence of a mixture of stationary series and series containing a unit root, standard statistical inference based on conventional likelihood ratio tests is no longer valid (Harris, 1995). Recently, Pesaran, Shin, and Smith (2001) propose an autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) bounds test, which could be applied to cointegration identification irrespective of whether the variables are integrated of order zero or integrated of order one. In addition, the main body of the existing literature for the case of China focuses on subjective analysis, with a conspicuous lack of studies being made to empirically determine this. Thus, within a high dimensional ARDL framework, this paper attempts to fill the gap by examining the relationship between property prices and bank lending in China, and the possible causality and causal direction. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides stylized facts about the developments of property sector in China. Section 3 discusses the methodological issues. Section 4 presents the empirical results and policy implications. Section 5 concludes the whole paper. 2. Development in China’s property sector Before adopting the economic reform program in the late 1970s, China had implemented welfarism housing system, characterized with low rent and allotment in kind. During the pre- reform periods, property market was almost in non-existence. Therefore, we concentrate on the development of China’s property sector in the post-reform period.5 In China, central government plays a pivotal role in the residential property sector. According to the role played by the central government in the residential property market, we classify the residential property sector 3 The real interest rate was not included since it did not enter significantly in the cointegrating vector (Gerlach & Peng, 2005, p. 469). 4 For example, Luintel and Khan (1999) find that half of the real interest rate series are stationary out of their sample countries in a study focusing on the reassessment of the finance-growth nexus. 5 Since residential property sector has closely related to the households and its development has exerted a crucial impact on households’ economic behavior, we focus on residential rather than commercial property sector. However, due to the data availability, we have to use data from property sector instead of residential property sector in a few cases.
66 Q. Liang, H. Cao / Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 63–75 development into three stages in the post-reform period.6 The first stage started in June 1980, symbolized by the publicized National Construction Meeting Report, which raised the curtain on housing reform by allowing households themselves to build house, buy house and own house. Moreover, government budget began to afford only part of the construction and maintenance costs, with the rest shared between households and their affiliations. Funds from financial institutions were also allowed to enter the residential property sector, e.g., China Construction Bank (named China People’s Construction Bank at that time) started to issue property-related credit and a few residential saving banks have been set up in coastal areas. The residential property sector underwent its preliminary development. In May 1990, Regulations on Sell and Transfer the Right of Use of State-owned Land in City and Town Areas was publicized, which put forward that it is allowable to sell and transfer the right of use of state-owned land in city and town areas. Therefore, a tradable property market began to form. The Regulations stipulates that local government authority could retain part of the revenue from the state-owned land transfer and sales, thus, foreshadowing the property boom in the coming years. At this stage, government attempted to withdraw the residential property sector through housing reform. The second stage started in 1992 when Deng Xiaopeng called for speeding up the rate of economic reform, which led to a major ideological breakthrough that for the first time China’s socialist market economy was endorsed by the central government. Soon after, the residential property prices were opened to the market and a number of examinations and approval rights were being gradually deregulated. These measures suddenly drove the residential property sector into quick development lane, manifested by high growth rate of residential property-related investments, significant space increases in land development, establishment of numerous new property-related firms, active property market with huge trading volumes and rising prices. The investments in property-related development increased 117.5% in 1992 and 165% in 1993. The proportion of property-related development investments in total fixed asset investments also increased suddenly from 9.0% in 1992 to 14.8% in 1993. There were only 1991 property-related development companies in 1986, while the new establishments in only one year in 1992 reached 8438. Unfortunately, this property boom soon brought about a lot of problems, such as runaway land supply and inequitable return distribution. Accordingly, central government set about in July 1993 to formulate macro regulations towards property sector, which came into effect immediately, as the annual growth rate of property-related development investments dropped 133.2% in 1994 comparing to that of the previous year. In 1996, the annual growth rate further dropped to only 2.1% and in 1997 it even turned out to be negative (1.2%). At this stage, although central government tried to withdraw the residential property market as a key financing supplier, its policy caused to a certain degree the property boom-burst cycle. The latest stage started in July 1998 when central government publicized the Notice on the Deepening of Housing Reform and Fasten Housing Construction, which stipulated (i) stopping house allot in kind and implementing progressively house allot by money; (ii) establishing a multi-layer house supplying system in city and town with the economically suitable house to be the mainstay; (iii) developing the house financing system and raising the residential property trading market. The government role in the residential property market transformed to provide favorable policy and fund subsidy only to economically suitable house. This symbolized that market began to function as an 6 So far, there is no generally accepted standard among economists on the classification of residential property sector. A few scholars used to classify the residential property market development in the post-reform periods into three or four stages according to the level or growth rate of property-related investments.
Q. Liang, H. Cao / Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 63–75 67 Fig. 1. Growth rates of investments in property-related development and total fixed assets. invisible hand in the residential property financing system. At the same year, the annual growth rate of property-related development investment began to rise and the rate has kept about 20% since then. Fig. 1 plots the annual growth rate of investment in property-related development and in total fixed assets during the 1990–2005 periods. It is clear that the turning points in the two series are generally in accordance with the classified development stages of the residential property sector. Besides, it shows that at the second stage, the growth rates of property-related development investments were lower than those of investments in total assets in most of the years, while the situation reversed at the third stage. However, it is worthwhile to note that recently in 2005 the growth rate of property-related development investments was lower than that of the investments in total assets for the first time in six consecutive years. This might ascribe to the tight regulations implemented since 2003 with an objective to contain the heated investments and roaring residential property price. Similar to the stages of residential property sector development, the movements in residential property prices can also be classified into three stages (see Fig. 2). Interestingly, the price Fig. 2. Average residential property prices and its annual growth rate.
68 Q. Liang, H. Cao / Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 63–75 Table 1 Descriptive data on outstanding of household mortgage loan and total loan Year Household mortgage Growth Total loan Growth Mortgage-total loan outstanding rate outstanding rate (%) loan ratio (%) (billion Yuan) (%) (billion Yuan) 1998 51.40 170.5 8652.41 15.5 0.59 1999 135.77 164.2 9373.43 8.3 1.45 2000 337.69 148.7 9937.11 6.0 3.39 2001 559.79 65.8 11231.47 13.0 4.98 2002 826.87 47.7 13980.30 24.5 5.89 2003 1177.97 42.5 16977.10 21.4 6.94 2004 1592.23 35.2 18856.60 11.1 8.44 2005 1836.60 15.3 20683.80 9.7 8.88 movements generally lag behind the corresponding property sector development by one or two years. At the first stage in the 1990–1992 periods, residential property prices rose steadily due to the factors that in response to the macroeconomic conditions, commercial banks developed new financial products providing firms with both short-term working capital and long-term fixed asset investment fund, and also providing households with consuming-related loan. Beside, each special bank set up its owned property credit section. In 1992, the growth rate of the residential property prices reached 30.9%, the highest level ever have since the housing reform started. At the second stage in the 1993–1999 periods, central government began in 1993 to readjust and rectify the property sector through implementation of restrictive monetary policies. Central bank required each special bank to draw up credit plan and fixed asset investment plan for every new property-related loan. The tight regulation led the growth rate of the residential property prices touching bottom in 1996, and even turning out to be negative (0.5%) in 1999. Since 1996, the central bank has embarked to apply expansive monetary policy by lifting the tight regulation and lowering interest rates progressively. Particularly, the Regulations on Mortgage Loan to Households publicized in 1998 stipulated that all commercial banks could grant mortgage loans to the households, thus, bring in competitive mechanism into the house financing market used to be monopolized by China’s Construction Bank. Hence, the amount of mortgage loan increased immediately and explosively. Table 1 presents the outstanding of household mortgage loan and total loan of the financial institutions in the 1998–2005 periods. Data indicate that the average annual growth rate of the household mortgage loan outstanding reached 161.13% in the first 3 years. Although stepping down gradually in recent years, the growth rates of the household mortgage loan outstanding are still significantly higher than those of the total loan outstanding. Moreover, the mortgage loan to total loan ratio has also risen up steadily since 1998. On the other hand, commercial banks have involved more and more deeply in the residential property financing market, encouraged mainly by the lower interest rate. Table 2 presents the sources of funds of enterprises for property development in the 1997–2004 periods. Data show that funds from the state budgetary appropriation, bonds and foreign investment have decreased gradually in these years, while funds from domestic loan, self-raising fund and others have increased constantly, with the latter there items accounting averagely 22.62%, 27.78% and 45.05%, respectively. Although data show that domestic bank credit only accounts for about one fifth in the sources of funds of enterprises for property development, it covers important fact because of the advance
Q. Liang, H. Cao / Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 63–75 69 Table 2 Source of funds of enterprises for property development (one hundred million Yuan) Year Total funds State budgetary Domestic Bonds Foreign Self-raising Others appropriation loans investment fund 1997 3817.07 12.48 911.19 4.87 460.86 972.88 1454.79 1998 4414.94 14.95 1053.17 6.23 361.76 1166.98 1811.85 1999 4795.90 10.05 1111.57 9.87 256.60 1344.62 2063.20 2000 5997.63 6.87 1385.08 3.48 168.70 1614.21 2819.29 2001 7696.39 13.63 1692.20 0.34 135.70 2183.96 3670.56 2002 9749.95 11.80 2220.34 2.24 157.23 2738.45 4619.90 2003 13196.92 11.36 3138.27 0.55 170.00 3770.69 6106.05 2004 17168.77 11.81 3158.41 0.19 228.20 5207.56 8562.59 Fig. 3. Property prices, bank lending and GDP (1999Q1–2006Q2). house booking system implemented nowadays in the residential property market, i.e., self-raising funds are mainly transformed from house sales revenues in which most origin from the bank mortgage loan. Together, bank lending may account for as many as 55% in the property development (Yi & Huang, 2006). Due to the lagged effects of the expansive policy, together with the low interest rate and increased bank lending, the residential property prices moved upward once again in 2000 and in the third stage starting from 2000, the average annual growth rate reaches 8.1%, especially in the last two years the prices rose rapidly with annual growth rate of 15.1% and 19.5%, respectively in 2004 and 2005. Fig. 3 plots the quarter property prices, bank lending and GDP in real terms in the 1999Q1–2006Q2 periods.7 Bank lending and output appear more stable than property prices and this finding is compatible with the existing literature (Gerlach & Peng, 2005). However, since 2004, it seems that both property prices and GDP have increased more rapidly than bank lending. 7 We normalized the real variables by demeaning them and dividing through with their standard deviations in order to facilitate comparison.
70 Q. Liang, H. Cao / Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 63–75 3. Econometric methodology We employ the autoregressive distributed lag bounds testing approach suggested by Pesaran et al. (2001) as the most appropriate model specification to carry out cointegration analysis among property prices, bank lending, GDP and interest rate. The bounds testing approach has numerous advantages. Besides that it can be applied irrespective of whether the variables are stationary or nonstationary, bounds testing approach has better small sample properties (Narayan & Smyth, 2005). Moreover, a dynamic error correction model (ECM) can be derived from ARDL through a simple linear transformation (Banerjee, Dolado, Galbraith, & Hendry, 1993). The ECM integrates the short-run dynamics with the long-run equilibrium without losing long-run information. The ARDL approach to cointegration involves estimating the conditional error correction version of the ARDL model as follows: X p X p Dyt ¼ p10 þ p11 yt1 þ p12 xt1 þ g i1 Dyt1i þ a j1 Dxt j1 þ e1t (1A) i1¼1 j1¼0 X p X p Dxt ¼ p20 þ p21 xt1 þ p22 yt1 þ g i2 Dxti2 þ a j2 Dyt j2 þ e2t (1B) i2¼1 j2¼0 where y and x are model variables, and et is assumed to be white noise error processes. The ARDL approach estimates ( p + 1)k number of regressions for each equation in order to obtain optimal lag length for each variable, where p is the maximum number of lag to be used and k is the number of variables in the equation. The optimal lag structure of the first difference regressors is selected by the Schwarz–Bayesian criteria (SBC) to ensure an absence of serial correlation in the estimated residuals.8 Following Pesaran et al. (2001), two separate statistics are employed to ‘bounds test’ for the existence of a long-run relationship, e.g., for Eq. (1A): an F-test for the joint significance of the coefficients of the lagged levels in Eq. (1) (so that H0:p11 = p12 = 0), and a t- test for the significance of the coefficient of the lagged level of dependent variable in Eq. (1) (so that H0:p11= 0). Two asymptotic critical value bounds provide a test for cointegration when the independent variables are I(d) (where 0 d 1): a lower value assuming the regressors are I(0), and an upper value assuming purely I(1) regressors. If the test statistic exceeds the upper critical value, we can conclude that a long-run relationship exists regardless of whether the underlying orders of integration of the variables are zero or one. If the test statistics fall below the lower critical values we cannot reject the null hypothesis of no cointegration. However, if the statistics fall between these two bounds, inference would be inconclusive. Then, the long-run relationship is estimated using the selected ARDL model. If variables are cointegrated in case y is used as dependent variable, then the conditional long-run model can then be produced from the reduced form solution of Eq. (1A), when the first-differenced variables jointly equal zero, i.e., Dy = Dx = 0. Thus, yt ¼ Q0 þ Q1 xt þ mt (2) where Q0 = p10/p11;Q1 = p12/p11, and mt is random error. The long-run coefficients are estimated by the ARDL model in Eq. (1) by OLS. When there is a long-run relationship 8 SBC is known as selecting the smallest possible lag length to specify a parsimonious model.
Q. Liang, H. Cao / Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 63–75 71 between variables, there exists an error correction representation. Therefore, the error correction model is estimated, and can be used to conduct the conventional Granger non- causality tests. Xh yt g g 12i yti c v ð1 LÞ ¼ ð1 LÞ 11i þ ECTt1 þ 1t (3) xt i¼1 g 21i g 22i xti u v2t where (1 L) is the difference operator, ECTt1 is the lagged error-correction term derived from Eq. (2) and this term is included only if the variables are cointegrated. The lag lengths are selected by the general-to-specific approach. The t-statistics on the coefficients of the lagged error- correction term indicates the significance of the long-run causal effect while the F-statistics or t- statistics on the lagged explanatory variables indicates the significance of the short-run causal effect. 4. Estimation results The study employs quarter time series data from 1999Q1–2006Q2 and all data are extracted from Wind Database and Information Center of Development Research Center of State Council. The period for the empirical analysis was dictated by data availability of the quarter property prices. The real property prices (P), real GDP (Y), real total bank lending (BC) and the real interest rate (R) are derived by dividing nominal values with consumer price index (CPI) with 1999Q1 as the base.9 In addition, all variables except interest rate were seasonally adjusted and were then transformed into natural logs. The reason to choose total bank lending instead of property-related lending is that in addition to provide residential mortgage loans, banks also lend extensively to the corporate sector for construction and property development. Moreover, there is anecdotal evidence that part of the other loans to the corporate and household sectors were effectively for property-related investment. A four-stage procedure is followed to analyze the long-run relationship between property prices, bank lending, GDP and interest rate.10 First, we test the order of integration using PP unit- root test. Second, we conduct the bounds test for the null hypothesis of no cointegration. Third, we model the long-run relationship among variables using the estimated coefficients from the selected ARDL specification. Forth, we carry out dynamic analysis using the error correction model. Unit-root test statistics indicate that P, BC and Y are trend non-stationary, significant at 5% level or better, while R is level stationary.11 The first differences of P, Y and BC are tested to be stationary. Hence, series P, Y and BC are integrated of order one and series R are integrated of order zero. A mixture of I(1) and I(0) variables show that the ARDL framework is a particularly relevant application given the time series properties of our data. 9 The interest rate denotes lending rate in one year. 10 The correlation coefficient between bank lending and lending rate is 0.0165 during the sample periods, thus, we conclude that including both of them in the model might not give rise to multicolinearity problem. In addition, as indicated by the referee, it is better to take into account the impact of administrative measures such as window guidance on lending to the property sector, however, these factors are difficult, if not impossible, to be quantified. 11 Following standard practice in unit-root test literature and judging from the visual inspection of the series, we include a linear deterministic trend in the unit-root test for series P, BC and Y.
72 Q. Liang, H. Cao / Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 63–75 In order to test the existence of long-run equilibrium relationships among variables, the following unrestricted error correction models (UECM) are investigated: Xp X p DPt ¼ p10 þ p11 Pt1 þ p12 Y t1 þ p13 BCt1 þ p14 Rt1 þ g i1 DPt1i þ a j1 DY t j1 i1¼1 j1¼0 X p X p þ $s1 DBCts1 þ fl1 Rtl1 þ e1t (4A) s1¼0 l1¼0 X p X p DY t ¼ p20 þ p21 Y t1 þ p22 Pt1 þ p23 BCt1 þ p24 Rt1 þ g i2 DY ti2 þ a j2 DPt j2 i2¼1 j2¼0 X p X p þ $s2 DBCts2 þ fl2 Rtl2 þ e2t (4B) s2¼0 l2¼0 X p DBC t ¼ p30 þ p31 BCt1 þ p32 Pt1 þ p33 Y t1 þ p34 Rt1 þ g i3 DBCti3 i3¼1 X p X p X p þ a j3 DY t j3 þ $s3 DPts3 þ fl3 Rtl3 þ e3t (4C) j3¼0 s3¼0 l3¼0 X p X p DRt ¼ p40 þ p41 Rt1 þ p42 Pt1 þ p43 Y t1 þ p44 BCt1 þ g i4 DRti4 þ a j4 DPt j4 i4¼1 j4¼0 X p X p þ $s4 DY ts4 þ fl4 BCtl4 þ e4t (4D) s4¼0 l4¼0 where the lagged level terms represent the long-run relationship while the terms with the summation signs correspond to the error correction dynamics. We include a minimum of one lag and a maximum of four to ensure lagged explanatory variables are present in the ECM in the bounds test since the costs of over-parameterization in terms of efficiency loss is marginal (Gonzalo, 1994). The results of the bounds test for cointegration are presented in Table 3. The bounds test statistics indicate cointegration are present when property prices or output is the dependent variable due to the fact that both tp(PjY, BC, R) and ty(YjP, BC, R) are higher than the upper bound critical value at the 5% level, and meanwhile both F p(PjY, BC, R) and F Y(YjP, BC, R) are higher than the upper bound critical value at the 1% level. Since we are mainly interested in the correlation relationship and causality between property prices and bank lending, we focus on the cointegration relationship when property price is Table 3 Bounds test statistics for cointegration t-statistics F-statistics ** tp(PjY, BC, R)= 4.2124 Fp(PjY, BC, R)= 6.7371*** ty(YjP, BC, R)= 4.1231** Fy(YjP, BC, R)= 9.2045*** tBC(BCjP, Y, R)= 1.3638 FBC(BCjP, Y, R)= 1.5961 tR(RjP, Y, BC)= 3.4481 FR(RjP, Y, BC)= 5.0473 Note: Bounds test statistics are compared with critical values tabulated in Pesaran et al. (2001, p. 300, p. 303). The symbols (***) and (**) indicate rejection of the null hypothesis at 1% and 5%, respectively.
Q. Liang, H. Cao / Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 63–75 73 dependent variable. Hence, the conditional long-run relationship could be produced from the reduced form solution of Eq. (4A) as follows: P ¼ 1:2926 þ0:5615Y þ 0:0630BC þ 0:0056R (5) where the symbols (***) and (**) indicate the significance at 1% and 5% level. Generally speaking, since increasing bank lending and income, and decreasing interest rate will drive up the property prices, we expect the coefficients of BC and Y to be positive while the coefficient of R negative. The long-run test results reveal that the GDP (income) is the major factor that affects the property prices while bank lending is another less important factor. These findings are as expected and in accordance with a few literatures. However, surprisingly and interestingly, the coefficient of interest rate turns out just opposite to our expectations. This paradox is pretty obscure. It shows that at least in the examined sample periods, the property price movements in China has no sensitivity to the changes of the real interest rate. Perhaps this might be ascribed to (i) property sector earns exorbitant profits so that although a restrictive monetary policy is in place, private capital and financial capital still pour into the property industry, driving up the property prices; (ii) real interest rate does not reflect the short-run opportunity cost due to the somewhat financial depression implemented in China and the rate is further distorted by the lower inflation. Undoubtedly, this result needs further examination. Li and Yang (2005) find a negative relationship between property- related investment and real interest rate. We agree with them to the part that interest rate, in particular the short-term interest rate, is not an effective way to control property prices. At last, we carry out the Granger non-causality tests. Although GDP and bank lending appear to be the long-run forcing variables based on the ARDL model, this is only a necessary but not sufficient condition for rejecting Granger non-causality. The ARDL–ECM are constructed as follows: 2 3 2 32 3 2 3 Pt g 11i g 12i g 13i g 14i Pti c 6 Yt 7 X h 6 g 21i g 22i g 23i g 24i 76 Y ti 7 6 u 7 ð1 LÞ6 7 4 BCt 5 ¼ ð1 LÞ6 4 g 31i 76 7 þ 6 7ECTt1 i¼1 g 32i l33i g 34i 54 BCti 5 4 h 5 Rt l41i g 42i l43i g 44i Rti ’ 2 3 v1t 6 v2t 7 þ6 7 4 v3t 5 (6) v4t In order to obtain the parsimonious model, the lag lengths are selected by the general-to- specific methods by removing insignificant variables step by step, starting with the most insignificant one as indicated by the t-ratios. Then, we test the significance of the coefficient of the lagged error correction term and joint significance of the lagged differences of the explanatory variables. Table 4 presents the short-run and long-run Granger causality within the error correction mechanism. Test statistics show the coefficients on the error correction terms are highly significant, thus, confirming the long-run relationship among variables, as Granger, Huang, and Yang (2000) suggests, a significant error correction term is indicative of long-run causality. Furthermore, F- statistics or t-statistics on the lagged explanatory variables indicates in the short-run GDP (income) also causes property prices while there were no causal relationships running from bank lending and interest rate to property prices, together implying that changes in property prices are
74 Q. Liang, H. Cao / Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 63–75 Table 4 Results of Granger causality tests Dependent variable DP DY DBC DR ECT ** DP – 2.5347 0.6288 0.1327 5.7236*** DY 2.5931 – 2.9485* 2.7824* – DBC 0.9482 1.6159 – 2.5924** – DR 6.4363*** 1.8648 0.7177 – – Note: The symbols (***); (**) and (*) indicate rejection of the null hypothesis at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. a function of disequilibrium in the cointegrating relationship. In other words, the causality runs interactively through the error correction term from bank lending, GDP (income) and interest rate to property prices. Central government in China now is aiming to control property prices. Therefore, our findings have important policy implications. On the one hand, empirical results appear to offer little support to the view that interest rate might be an effective way to exert impacts on the property price movements. On the other hand, the weak impacts of bank lending on property prices suggest that central government might prevent property prices from further rising to a certain degree through formulating tight credit policies. In addition, we warn that, as property development funds depend more and more on bank lending, and bank profits rely more and more on property or property-related sectors, bank itself may face increasing financial risk.12 Particularly, the sharp falling property prices may have devastating impacts on local financial institutions since many of them have high concentration in the local property sector. The collapse of property prices could easily drag down these local banking institutions and generate systemic risk for the whole financial system. As a result, it is crucial for managers and financial regulators to measure accurately the risk exposure of banks and to make sure that such risk does not jeopardize the stability of the financial system.13 5. Conclusion By implementing a high dimensional ARDL framework to the quarter data of China in her 1999Q1–2006Q2 periods, we have empirically examined the long-run relationships and evaluated the causality between property prices and bank lending while also taken GDP and interest rate into account. We find that unidirectional causality exists running from bank lending to property prices, conclusions departing distinctively from previous empirical studies on developed economies. Moreover, in the long run, bank lending, GDP (income) and interest rate Granger cause property prices, meaning that causality run interactively through the error correction term from income, bank lending and interest rate to property prices. Our findings have important policy implications. Interest rate might not be a valid and sufficient tool to control the property prices. However, government may partly accomplish its objective of controlling property prices through tight credit policy. 12 Shimizu (1997) points out that the dominant position of banks in Japan’s financial market and the lack of an effective system of credit risk sharing through the capital market were the fundamental structures that brought about the ensuing financial crisis. 13 Gerlach and Peng (2005) suggest that prudential regulation and risk controls by banks could limit the exposure and vulnerability of the banking sector to swings in property prices.
Q. Liang, H. Cao / Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 63–75 75 Acknowledgements We are grateful to the constructive comments and detailed suggestions of Chi Hung Kwan, Yoshinori Shimizu, Eiji Ogawa, Dar-Yeh Hwang, Naoyuki Yoshino and the insights of participants at International Conference on Financial System Reform and Monetary Policies in Asia held on September 15–16, 2006 at Hitotsubashi University in Tokyo, Japan. We would also like to thank Yu-Cao Liu, Dong-Liang Yang, Jun-Shou Wang, Ya-Hui Yang and Jian-Zhou Teng for helpful comments and seminar participants at Nankai University. This work was funded by a research grant (06JA790057) from the Ministry of Education. Any errors or omission are solely our own. An earlier draft of this paper was circulated with the title ‘‘The Impact of Monetary Policy on Property Prices: Evidence from China’’. References Banerjee, A. J., Dolado, J., Galbraith, J. W., & Hendry, D. (1993). Co-integration, error correction, and the econometric analysis of non-stationary data. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Bernanke, B., & Gertler, M. (1999). Monetary policy and asset price volatility. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, 84, 17–52. Collyns, C., & Senhadji, A., 2001. Lending booms, real estate bubbles and the Asian crisis. IMF Working Paper No. 02/20. Engle, R. F., & Granger, C. W. (1987). Cointegration and error-correction representation, estimation, and testing. Econometrica, 55, 251–276. Gerlach, S., & Peng, W. S. (2005). Bank lending and property prices in Hong Kong. Journal of Banking and Finance, 29, 461–481. Gonzalo, J. (1994). Five alternative methods of estimating long-run equilibrium relationships. Journal of Econometrics, 60, 203–233. Granger, C., Huang, B., & Yang, C. (2000). A bivariate causality between stock prices and exchange rates: evidence from recent Asian flu. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 40, 337–354. Harris, R. (1995). Using cointegration analysis in econometric modeling. London: Prentice Hall. Hofmann, B., 2003. Bank lending and property prices: Some international evidence. The Hong Kong Institute for Monetary Research Working Paper No. 22. Johansen, S. (1991). Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegration vectors in Gausian vector autoregression models. Econometrica, 59, 551–580. Kiyotaki, N., & Moore, J. (1997). Credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 105, 211–248. Koha, W. T. H., Marianoa, R. S., Pavlovb, A., Phanga, S. Y., Tana, A. H. H., & Wachterc, S. M. (2005). Bank lending and real estate in Asia: market optimism and asset bubbles. Journal of Asian Economics, 15, 1103–1118. Li, Y. J., & Yang, Y. (2005). The effect of interest rate and money supply impose on real estate investment in China: an empirical analysis. Journal of Xi’an Institute of Finance and Economics, 18, 47–51. Luintel, K. B., & Khan, M. (1999). A quantitative reassessment of the finance–growth nexus: evidence from a multivariate VAR. Journal of Development Economics, 60, 381–405. Narayan, P. K., & Smyth, R. (2005). Electricity consumption, employment and real income in Australia evidence from multivariate Granger causality test. Energy Policy, 33, 1109–1116. Pesaran, M. H., Shin, Y., & Smith, R. J. (2001). Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of level relationships. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 16, 289–326. Shimizu, Y. (1997). Nippon no Kinyu to Shiji Mechanism [The Japanese Financial Market and the Market Mechanism]. Tokyo: Toyo Economic Publishing House. Shimizu, Y., 2000. Convoy Regulation, Bank Management, and the Financial Crisis in Japan. In Mikitani, R., and Posen, A.S., Eds. Japan’s Financial Crisis and Its Parallels to U.S. Experience, Special report 13, Institute for International Economics, 57–99. Shimizu, Y., 2006. Fudousan kagaku to kinyuushijyou [Property Prices and Financial Market], Kinyuu Keizai Kenkyu [Financial Economics Research] 23, 1–14. Yi, X.R., & Huang, Y., 2006. Current house payment in advance system leads to high residential property prices. Shanghai Securities News, July 14. Zhu, H.B., 2003. The importance of property markets for monetary policy and financial stability. BIS paper No. 21.
You can also read