Places that matter: Australia's crisis intervention framework and voter response
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society doi:10.1093/cjres/rsab002 Places that matter: Australia’s crisis intervention framework and voter response Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 Sally Weller Business School, University of South Australia, Level 5, Way Lee Building, City West Campus, Adelaide 5000, South Australia, sally.weller@unisa.edu.au This article contributes to understandings of geographies of discontent by focusing on the way that political frameworks condition the demand for fringe or protest voting. It discusses how Australia’s federal political framework, preferential voting system and timely crisis intervention policies combine to reduce the demand for fringe voting. The local effects of this system are illustrated via an examination of voting patterns in two disadvantaged and deindustrialising locations in the State of Victoria. The conclusion suggests that European jurisdictions have much to learn from the Australian example. Keywords: deindustrialisation, regional policy, electoral systems, crisis intervention, voting pat- terns, Australia JEL Classifications: D72, F63, F68, O18, R11 The problem of places that do In an important contribution to this litera- not matter ture, Spicer (2018, 116) argues that extant ex- planations of this shift have paid insufficient The academic and policy literatures are awash attention to ‘the interaction of globalisation- with articles attempting to comprehend and induced, rising regional disparities with ma- address the waning support for mainstream joritarian national political systems’. He shows political parties across Western democracies how the majoritarian systems of the UK and (Emmenegger et al., 2015; Essletzbichler et al., US contribute to political discontent via the 2018; Rodríguez-Pose, 2018; Spicer, 2018). combination of a declining ‘ideological con- The rejection of established political options gruence’ between the political platforms of in favour of fringe and populist parties has a major parties and the sentiments of voters, cre- distinctive spatial expression, concentrating ating a ‘representation gap’ that is often col- in disadvantaged locations in what has been oured by the perception of inadequate policy called a ‘geography of discontent’ (McCann, responses to persistent spatial disparities. 2020; Nel-lo and Gomà, 2018). Alternatively, Spicer (2018; citing Manow, 2009) observes Goodwin and Heath (2016) associate discon- that nations with preferential electoral sys- tent with places ‘left behind’ by globalisation tems are more ideologically congruent, more and market-driven development processes, likely to retain redistributive policies and more while Rodríguez-Pose (2018) characterises the likely to maintain policy settings that deliver phenomenon as a revenge of people and places inter-regional equity. that ‘don’t matter’. © The Author(s) 2021. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Cambridge Political Economy Society. All rights reserved. For permissions, please email: journals.permissions@oup.com
Weller Following from these insights, this article supply factors in the context of electoral ar- contributes to uncovering the sources, manifest- rangements (Golder, 2016). However, most of ations and consequences of ‘geographies of dis- the literature focuses on the demand for popu- Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 content’ by explaining how Australia’s political list politics, rather than on the electoral struc- framework and crisis intervention systems com- ture or the factors influencing the supply of bine to mollify discontent and to contain the populist candidates. These explanations agree political alienation that, in majoritarian jurisdic- that a combination of socio-economic, political tions, has been associated with deindustrialisa- or cultural factors produce a sense of discon- tion. The focus of this article is how Australia’s tent and a consequent rejection of the status framework of localised and timely crisis inter- quo, but there is considerable disagreement ventions following economic shocks influences about the exact nature of the processes and voting patterns and the degree of support for their causal pathways. fringe parties in disadvantaged locations. This is A growing literature associates discontent illustrated by means of a close analysis of voting with the material inequalities between regions patterns in two contrasting deindustrialising (McCann, 2020), and some argue these material neighbourhoods in the Australian State of differences underpin and produce the observed Victoria. It confirms that the demand for pro- social and cultural influences (Essletzbichler test voting is generally weak in crisis locations, et al., 2018). Some socio-economic explanations but it is stronger in the location marked by re- are concerned with the impact of long-term tra- peated intervention policy failures. jectories of change and some with the impact The article is structured as follows. The next of short-term crises. The longer view identifies section reviews the literature on the relation- the plight of people ‘left behind’ by globalisa- ship between voting patterns, regional dispar- tion and marketisation (Ford and Goodwin, ities and redistributive funding. It is followed 2017; Goodwin and Heath, 2016; Gordon, by a description of the Australian political 2018), a view supported by qualitative studies system, its preferential electoral framework revealing the ‘slow violence’ of entrenched and crisis-based regional interventions. The socio-economic deprivation and the way it empirical section begins with a brief discussion concentrates spatially to produce particularly of methodological issues before introducing disadvantaged places (McQuarrie, 2017; Pain, the two case study localities—Norlane and 2019). The shorter-term view emphasises the Morwell in the southern State of Victoria—and effects of economic shocks, such as those pro- contrasting their voting patterns. The discus- duced by austerity policies, industrial change sion suggests that preferential political systems and local plant closures (MacLeod and Jones, produce more spatially sensitive policies and 2018; Meek, 2019). are more responsive to voter discontent. Voter How material conditions affect voting behav- confidence in mainstream political options is iour is less well understood. Wiertz and Rodon influenced by local perceptions of the efficacy (2019) suggest that political preferences vary of interventions. The conclusion points to les- with short-term personal hardship, although sons for majoritarian jurisdictions. people often revert to an earlier position after the negative experience has receded from aware- ness. Some research suggests that economic Economic conditions, redistribution hardships increase the likelihood of abstaining and voting patterns from voting, consistent with a sense of disillusion- Explanations for the surge of anti-establish- ment or despair; others suggest that it stimulates ment voting preferences in Europe and the voting for fringe and protest parties, consistent USA draw in a complex mix of demand and with notions of discontent (Emmenegger et al., Page 2 of 16
Places that matter 2015; Gallego et al., 2016; Hacker et al., 2013). development programmes in most advanced Fear and uncertainty about the future also play economies have the objectives of improving a role. Wiertz and Rodon (2019) suggest that the economic performance of lagging regions Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 voters veer to the political left when their liveli- while at the same time endeavouring to build hoods are actually compromised—say by the ex- ‘social cohesion’ or the political legitimacy of perience of plant closure or job loss—but to the systems of governance. Interventions are ex- political right when feared adverse outcomes are pected—either explicitly or implicitly—to yet to materialise. As pork-barrelling politicians translate into support for their supplier govern- repeatedly demonstrate, promising tangible im- ments, and there is some research confirming provements to peoples’ personal circumstances this outcome (Dabrowski, 2012). Yet positive can influence a significant proportion of votes electoral effects seem to follow only if the inter- (Hicken, 2017). ventions are well received, and on that score, Cultural explanations focus on nativist and the evidence is contradictory. Some research racist dispositions that coalesce around migra- suggests that regional interventions deliver tion issues (Poutvaara and Steinhardt, 2018). positive economic benefits (Barca et al., 2012; They also take account of social and cultural Camagni and Capello, 2015), some suggest that divisions on issues like same-sex marriage and the benefits are short-lived and tend to evap- climate change that disrupt traditional ‘left’ orate when funding is discontinued (Barone versus ‘right’ political allegiances. Cultural fac- et al., 2016; Crescenzi and Giua, 2016), and tors complicate and perhaps compromise ex- others suggest that they are less effective than planations that equate voting preferences with policies targeting individual welfare (Kline and material interests or with voters’ relatively Moretti, 2014). Even if the material outcomes stable class-based ideological commitments of intervention are positive, the magnitude of (Lipset, 1960). In the UK’s Brexit vote, for ex- the effect may still not be adequate to counter ample, moral economy or moral panic appears market processes that concentrate wealth and to have played a decisive role (Los et al., 2017; power at central places. This debate seems to Morgan, 2017). be resolving in favour of place-based policy Politically oriented explanations focus on the (Bailey et al., 2019). perception of a crisis of political representa- Qualitative and place-based examinations tion. Attentive to the neighbourhood scale and see the political effects of crises and the lived experience, this research discerns a sense quality of policy interventions as two sides of of abandonment by mainstream political par- the same coin. From this perspective, the pol- ties (Telford and Wistow, 2020); rising contempt itical mood is not determined by a material for the dominant social, cultural and political crisis, like plant closures or inequalities, but arrangements and their deceptive language of rather depends on how local debates about consensus and cooperation (McKenzie, 2017); the future play out in the context of strug- and the numbing effects of the realisation that gles to create new employment opportunities the established political system is no longer and to secure redistributive funding (Telford capable of making a difference to ordinary and Wistow, 2020; Willett et al., 2019). This peoples’ lives (Jessop, 2018). The resulting per- perspective reveals deindustrialisation as a vasive sense of disillusionment, hopelessness political and cultural process, as well as an and nihilistic despair concentrates in so-called economic one. Viewing adverse events and ‘left behind’ places. policy responses as inseparable components A central point of contention concerns the of a continuous process reveals local views role of redistributive interventions in mitigating of the quality of interventions at any time or exacerbating these processes. Regional to be filtered through the lens of previous Page 3 of 16
Weller experiences. In contexts coloured by the ill- Australia’s re-distributional political effects of austerity policies, for example, structure well-meaning interventions that are per- Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 Australia is a relatively sparsely populated ceived locally as being imposed by external settler economy, where the deep cultural and decision-makers or as mis-targeted relative language differences that separate European to local priorities are likely to fuel local frus- regions are largely absent. However, as in tration and anger (Telford and Wistow, 2020). other places, there is an increasing divide be- Politically speaking, the effectiveness of re- tween rapidly growing urban centres and distributive funding depends on emotional re- often stagnating regional areas. The Australian ception, which in turn depends on the extent economy is dominated by a handful of large of local integration of funded projects and entrepot cities where incoming population the extent to which local people have a sense fuels growth in specialised consumption and of ownership of them (Willett et al., 2019). trade-related services. The thin economies Thus, whether or not interventions generate of non-metropolitan areas, in contrast, rely political support depends on local percep- on export-oriented primary production and tions of the utility and appropriateness of the (mainly overseas-owned) branch plant indus- interventions as well as the extent to which tries. Since Australia’s post-1990s shift to open, benefits are captured by elites or cliques; the market-oriented policy settings, growth has time gaps between crisis events and subse- concentrated in the city centres. Many regional quent interventions; and the convolutedness areas have been ‘left behind’ by the closure of of chains of association (Willett et al., 2019, manufacturing plants, the withdrawal or pri- Telford and Wistow, 2020). Long gaps and vatisation of government services, declining convoluted accountabilities weaken the asso- employment opportunities and declining popu- ciation between crisis and response. lations (Pritchard and McManus, 2000). What is striking about this literature, to Nonetheless, despite the advance of market- someone observing it from afar, is the ex- isation and liberalisation, the Australian system tent to which it takes for granted European retains a core re-distributional framework institutional arrangements and political sys- (Weller and O’Neill, 2014) that continues to tems as an unquestioned frame and backdrop. sustain the economies of regional areas. The Consideration of the wider arrangements framework has three components: the federal that structure the relationship between local form of organisation and the political settle- places and regional policy authorities are ment it provokes, the effects of a compulsory overlooked, as are the macroscale economic and preferential electoral framework and fi- and financial arrangements that sustain and nally the tradition of re-distributional funding intensify inter-regional differences (Harvey, to places experiencing crisis. This political 2011; Hadjimichalis, 2017). This closes off any structure makes less competitive places ‘matter’ discussion of how improvements to govern- more, in government and politics, than compar- mental processes or democratic institutions able places in Europe or the USA. could potentially contribute to closing the ‘representation gap’ that politically oriented explanations position at the heart of local dis- The federal system content (Spicer, 2018, see also Mudde, 2007). All federal systems of government are to some These missing questions are brought into view extent characterised by ‘contestation, conser- by way of the contrast to the Australian model vatism and compromise’ (Taylor, 2000, 107), described in the next section. and in this respect, Australia is no exception. Page 4 of 16
Places that matter Australia was created by the Federation, in government cannot initiate regional develop- 1901, of the continent’s previously quasi- ment projects without active State government independent (British) colonies (which there- support. Moreover, the Federal government has Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 after became the federation’s States). Under no authority to bypass State governments to fund the new Constitution, which was written prior local government directly, so in this context, there to the emergence of ‘party’ politics, the States is no possibility of European-style devolution retained authority over most internal matters, (that is, of devolving responsibility for welfare or while the Federal jurisdiction gained respon- crises to the local scale). This structure produces, sibility for inter-State and inter-national co- and demands, a high level of inter-scalar cooper- ordination. The division of powers was (and is) ation on regional development matters. imprecise, creating space for contestation and This structure has important implications for endemic inter-governmental rivalries (Graycar ways of doing policy. First, the relatively weak and Jamrozik, 1989). authority of the national government creates Over the years, the Federal Government has the incentive for cooperative rather than dir- gradually increased its authority, boosted by ective policymaking. It encourages the com- its control of taxation and its capacity to draw promises necessary to coordinate multiple, power from international treaties (Weller and often competing, and ideologically disparate O’Neill, 2014), but Constitutional authority governments. It tends to preclude dramatic over many aspects of economy and society policy shifts; a Thatcher or Reagan revolution remains with the States. One outcome of this would not be feasible in this context. It makes arrangement is that the shift to market-based it difficult for the Federal government to avoid policies could not ‘hollow out’ national au- responding to crises that cannot be addressed thority in the same way as it did in Europe. To within routine funding arrangements (for ex- date, the semi-autonomy of the State jurisdic- ample, bushfires, trade disputes and pandemics). tions has made it very difficult for any Federal government to impose its will on the States or to delegate responsibilities to the States. The electoral framework Nonetheless, since the States have modest The design of Australia’s electoral system drew revenue-raising capacity, they are obliged to from both English and American precedents. cooperate with the Federal scale. A system of The federal government structure comprises ‘fiscal equalisation’ distributes Federal funds a (lower) House of Representatives and an among the States using a formula based prin- (upper) Senate. The elected members of the cipally on population. The States then provide House of Representatives represent geograph- most services directly (such as health, educa- ically defined local areas (electorates). These are tion, and social and community services) and recalibrated routinely to accommodate popula- distribute funds to local government adminis- tion change, although the result is by no means trations to finance a small range of locally pro- ‘one vote-one value’; rural votes carry more vided services. This entrenches redistribution weight. In the contemporary world, local mem- into the overall system: in contrast to the USA, bers are aligned to political parties and the party for example, a major local plant closure has with the most House of Representatives seats limited impact on local social and community governs. The Senate was designed to represent service provision because these services are the interests of the States, with each State having funded and coordinated from the State level. an equal number of senators regardless of its Regional development in Australia remains size or economy. The Prime Minister’s role is primarily a State responsibility. The Federal constrained by the Cabinet (of portfolio-holding structure means that, in practice, the Federal Ministers); there are no Presidential powers.1 Page 5 of 16
Weller To become law, legislation must pass in both in their interests (see also Cusack et al., 2007). Houses. Yet, the Senate’s structure enables the Preferential systems, on the other hand, im- smaller (and more resource-dependent) States prove the ‘ideological congruence’ between Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 to together muster more votes than the urban- voters and political parties and lead to more ised east coast States (New South Wales and redistributive arrangements (Manow, 2009). Victoria). As a consequence, it is a challenge for In Australia’s electoral system—where vote any government to pass legislation perceived counting is preferential, and voting is compul- to disadvantage regional and rural places. In sory—every vote is effective since every voter effect, the Senate functions as a structural pro- is forced to order their preferences.2 Even in- tection against the growth of inter-State and re- eligible ‘informal’ non-votes are counted and gional inequalities. reported. An additional conservative force is the ab- With preferences determining the outcome sence of coordination of Federal- and State- of most closely fought elections, preferential level elections or electoral boundaries. Coalition voting impels the major parties’ policies to ac- Federal policy initiatives can be blocked when commodate the political fringes with a view to the majority of States have Labor governments, capturing the all-important second preference. and vice versa. The rhythms of the electoral As shown in Figure 1, this system has not pre- cycle seem to encourage an oscillation in which vented declining support for the major parties, one of the two main political parties (Labor or especially in the post-global financial crisis era, Coalition) dominates Federally and the other but it has returned the wayward votes to the dominates among the States. two-party mainstream. Figure 1 shows that in Voting systems affect the extent to which recent times Labor has lost more in the decline local dissatisfactions filter up to parliamentary of stable first preference votes, but the effect is decision-makers. According to Spicer (2018, offset because Labor also attracts more second 122), the ‘representation gap’ produced by the preferences. Because preferential voting impels UK’s and USA’s ‘undemocratic’ majoritarian the major parties to court preferences, it shifts systems is a major factor leading people to be- the policies of both major parties in belated ac- lieve that the political system is not working cord with the popular political mood. This, to an 80 80 Stable Labor Don't Know/Not Sure 70 Stable Liberal-National 70 Labor Always voted for same party Liberal-National 60 60 50 50 % 40 % 40 30 30 20 20 10 10 0 0 1967 1969 1979 1987 1990 1993 1996 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013 2016 2019 1996 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013 2016 2019 Stability of Voting Intentions Direction of Preferences Figure 1. First preference votes and preference distribution. Source: Adapted from Cameron and McAllister (2020). Page 6 of 16
Places that matter extent, closes the representation gap, although of bringing people out to vote. This makes arguably it also produces inconsistencies in Australian elections less vulnerable to emo- overall party platforms. tive political campaigns. Compulsory voting Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 In the all-important Senate, preferential also makes it impossible for charismatic or- voting frequently enables a minor party candi- ators to position themselves as representing a date to win one Senate seat in each State. As silent non-voting majority. As such, compulsory a result, minor parties often hold the balance voting has a civilising effect on elections. of power in the Federal Senate. People like this Nonetheless, as in other places, Australia has arrangement because it prevents the major pol- seen the growth in recent years of many pro- itical parties from controlling the Senate, and test, nationalist and anti-globalisation political as such, it ‘keeps the bastards honest’ (Chipp, parties. Australia’s preferential system makes 2004).3 This forces governments to make deals it easy for people to decide to vote for these to pass legislation and increases the difficulty parties, since ultimately their vote will revert faced by all governments in implementing rad- to their second or third preference, but it also ical political programmes. This is especially so makes it harder for these parties to win seats when proposed changes undermine disadvan- (since they tend not to pick up preferences from taged places or groups.4 the main parties). However, these parties have A feature of preferential voting systems succeeded in a limited range of locations. The is that they tend to spawn multi-party polit- appeal of populist One Nation, for example, is ical landscapes (Manow, 2009). At face value, concentrated in rural and regional Queensland Australia has four major political parties—the where discontent is fuelled by a lack of employ- conservative-leaning Liberals, the Australian ment opportunities and a perceived lack of rep- Labor Party (ALP), the rural-oriented National resentation. In Queensland, the merger of the or Country Party and the environment advo- Liberals and Nationals into a single conserva- cates, the Greens.5 Beneath the surface is a cru- tive party—the Liberal Nationals—diminishes cial network of political alliances. The Liberal the National Party’s distinctive rural voice. Party cannot form a government without the support of the (socially conservative and pro- agriculture) National and Country Parties, and Local crisis interventions the Australian Labor Party (which was formed These forces encourage both sides of Federal by, and continues to be structurally tied to, politics to support crisis intervention policies trade unions), similarly, cannot win elections targeting deindustrialising or trade-exposed re- without the active support of organised labour. gional areas. Accordingly, timely interventions The price the Liberals pay for the Coalition is in places facing local crises are a routine feature support for redistributive transfers to rural and of Australian policy. Beer (2015) sees them as regional Australia. The price the Labor party a ‘de-facto’ Federal regional policy and reports pays for union support is (modest) protection expenditure of over $AU 88 billion on 135 of labour rights and the promise of orderly in- separate adjustment programmes in the years dustrial restructuring in deindustrialising loca- 2000–2012. A feature of these interventions tions. Thus, the redistributive core of Australia’s is their direct responsiveness to local crises, long-standing class settlement continues in a with adjustment assistance packages often an- muted form through the dependence of the two nounced in the media as a local crisis unfolds major parties on two crucial constituencies. (for example, Gillard et al., 2013). Typically, A final point concerns compulsory voting. these interventions offer a combination of la- It changes the political complexion because bour market programmes, industry restruc- it absolves politicians from the responsibility turing incentives, assistance to local enterprises Page 7 of 16
Weller and investment attraction strategies, although As in other places, the effectiveness of this the emphasis is on labour adjustment. With sort of intervention has been questioned on such a large number of programmes, there is hard cost-benefit grounds (Daley and Lancy, Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 now some accumulated experience of ‘what 2011; Productivity Commission, 2001; VAGO, works’ in most contexts. The short-term nature 2019). In addition, the responsiveness of the of the interventions and their emphasis on assistance to events—and therefore also to longer-term developmental outcomes sidesteps the political profile of events—means there the market fundamentalist accusation that has never been a clear criterion of what quali- places are relying on hand-outs. This interven- fies for funding or of what level of assistance tion strategy has emerged from the institutional is warranted in the circumstances (VAGO, context in which the Federal government is not 2019). This means that some places can miss primarily responsible for regional develop- out (for example, central Queensland, where ment, but in which it is expected to intervene in One Nation flourishes). The direct link between exceptional circumstances. Crisis intervention events, funding allocations and political parties initiatives were first implemented as a part of enables voters to respond to these redistribu- the Hawke government’s (mid-1980s) corpor- tive transfers (or their absence) at the ballot atist Accord. The original programmes were box. If populist means ‘popular’ (Laclau, 2005), designed to secure worker cooperation and these programmes make all Australian gov- maintain government legitimacy at a time of ernments to a degree populist in their general rapid change as Australia opened its economy orientation. to global forces (see O’Neill, 1996). As such, they can be understood as a key component of Australia’s established political (class) com- Electoral effects promise (Connell and Irving, 1992). Do these interventions actually have a direct Contemporary examples are delivered via effect on voting patterns? Are people more multi-level task forces that include all three likely to support the mainstream parties in levels of government as well as business and places that attract interventions? Or con- union interests. They have a discursive role, versely, are they attracted to fringe political as well as an economic one, with activities parties in places that are not favoured by inter- including explicit efforts to convey to affected vention, or where intervention is mistargeted local communities—through the media, con- or ineffective? If Rodrik (2017, 49) is correct sultations and other communications—the im- that ‘it is not inequality per se, but perceived pression that they do ‘matter’ to the polity. Key unfairness’ that drives the abandonment of to the interventions is recognition: even if the the political mainstream, then the deliberate assistance fails to bring new industries and de- fairness of the Australian system would be velopment, at least local people know that the expected to encourage support for the main- government tried, that they were not forsaken. stream parties in places where interventions This conveys a sense of procedural justice are well-regarded. The direct connection be- (Brockner et al., 1994) that works to mask tween crisis events and policy responses makes the underlying process of disinvestment and for relatively transparent lines of account- thereby helps to neutralise local discontent. The ability and responsibility, making Australia an market-oriented Productivity Commission’s illuminating site for examining the relation- (2001) conclusion that these programmes func- ship between left-behind-ness, policy interven- tion to ‘buy off’ opposition to structural change tions and voting patterns. Because this context recognises their role in securing the (Federal) normalises making places in crisis matter, the state’s political legitimacy. analysis focuses on a critical case in which Page 8 of 16
Places that matter intervention has consistently failed. The advan- modest analysis aims to fill a gap between these tage of critical cases is their capacity to shed two sets of insights. light on causal pathways (Gerring, 2007). The two locations of interest—Morwell in the Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 The analysis begins with the assumptions Latrobe Valley and Norlane in Geelong—were that, in this context, crisis and intervention selected because the detail of their histories is are inseparable and that local responses are familiar to the author, having conducted quan- framed by past experiences. The aim is to con- titative analysis and qualitative field work trast two traditionally working-class neigh- related to plant closures and subsequent inter- bourhoods that are close to the epicentres of ventions in both places: Latrobe Valley since major plant closure events and that have had 2009 and in Geelong since 2016. Figure 2 shows recent experiences of remedial interventions. the location of these sites relative to Victoria’s The neighbourhood closest to the crisis event is dominant capital city of Melbourne. also contrasted to the larger electorate in which The two neighbourhoods of interest are it is embedded. At this fine scale, geographical similar in some ways and different in others. boundaries relate in a meaningful sense to the They are both disadvantaged working-class phenomena of interest, which is the relation- neighbourhoods, and both are the most disad- ship between crisis, intervention and voting. vantaged locale in an already disadvantaged Taking this approach reflects a dissatisfaction regional area. Table 1 shows that Norlane is with large-scale empirical studies that associate more disadvantaged, in objective terms, than discontent with economically disadvantaged Morwell, but that both perform poorly in regions but which—since they rely on correl- comparison to their surrounding area, which ation—cannot establish a causal sequence. in turn underperforms relative to Victorian Moreover, such studies assert a triggering emo- State-wide averages. Both places could be tion—whether discontent, despair, envy, lack of described as ‘left-behind’ relative to their recognition, ‘not mattering’, being left behind, neighbours. or something else entirely—but in fact offer The two places are in the same State, so they no information to distinguish among these face a similar policy environment. Both places options. The comparisons between regional had experienced a sustained process of de- territories is too large a container to draw in- industrialisation over the last 20 years. Both ferences about processes, and the compari- places have a history of union activism, albeit sons undervalue historical factors in a way that with a more oppositional bent in the Latrobe makes them unable to discern the slow violence Valley. Both places had faced uncertainty and of repeated injuries. The qualitative literature crisis in the years immediately before the 2016 suggests that disillusionment and discontent election: the closure of automotive produc- flourish at a much finer scale of resolution—at tion near Norlane and the anguished politics the neighbourhood, street or even individual leading to the closure of the Hazelwood power level (respectively, Berlant, 2011; Pain, 2019; station in Morwell. Importantly, Norlane and Telford and Wistow, 2020)—and suggests that Morwell are similar to the extent that recent the impacts on voting are complexly bound interventions in their respective crises have up in perceptions and anticipations. However, tended to provide funding to developmental these studies are not able to make the empirical initiatives in (more ambitious) adjacent places connection between votes and perceptions. In and not in the most-affected neighbourhoods jurisdictions where voting is voluntary, neither (Weller, 2019). This creates a sense that crisis approach can plausibly link material privation, interventions are mis-targeted, which is known emotional responses and voting behaviour. This to fuel local disaffection. Page 9 of 16
Weller Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 Figure 2. The positioning of the case study places. Table 1. Socio-economic disadvantage, case study locations Norlane (SSC) Geelong (SA3) Morwell (SSC) Latrobe Valley (SA3) All Victoria Median weekly household 728 1234 807 1077 1419 income ($AU) Education: Degree 4.7 18.2 6.9 10.8 24.3 and above (%) Unemployment (%) 17.9 6.6 14.5 9.7 6.6 Both parents not working 37.5 21.8 33.8 24.7 19.5 (couple families) (%) Source: ABS (2020). The two places are different in three im- manufacturing centre; it experienced major job portant ways. The first is with respect to their losses in the 1990s, but its declining industries experience of past interventions, which is attracted generous Federal structural adjust- known to condition perceptions of contem- ment interventions (for example, automotive, porary assistance. Geelong was historically a textiles and clothing). Geelong has also been Page 10 of 16
Places that matter the target of a series of State-government re- The third difference is the position in pol- development initiatives since 2000 (Johnson itical landscapes. Norlane and Geelong are et al., 2021). The Latrobe Valley was histor- located in the safe Labor electorate of Corio, Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 ically specialised in coal-based electricity while Morwell and Latrobe Valley are Labor- production. It had also lost a substantial pro- voting enclaves in the safe National-held rural portion of its employment in the 1990s, but electorate of Gippsland. This might in part ex- as a part of the Victorian State government’s plain the Latrobe Valley’s difficulty in attracting pre-privatisation rationalisation of the elec- intervention funding. Although both Corio and tricity production sector. These job losses did Gippsland are safe seats, the electorate, imme- not attract Federal or State intervention, which diately west of Geelong (Corangamite), was in led to an enduring sense of injury centred in 2015 held by the Liberals by the smallest of mar- the most-affected Morwell area (Weller, 2017). gins, making it one of the 2016 election’s most A series of State government revitalisation contested electorates. A portion of Federal efforts in the 2000s failed to bring new indus- government funding associated with the Ford tries to the Valley. In 2014, the State govern- closure had been distributed to promising ven- ment was slow to respond to a major fire in an tures in the Corangamite territory, potentially open-cut coal mine close to Morwell, despite it raising questions about pork-barrelling.6 compromising the health of local residents. In The analysis below focuses on the 2016 the years before 2016, promised Federal inter- Federal election, the election immediately after ventions in the Latrobe Valley to smooth the a period of crisis in the locations of interest. effects of the impending closure of coal-fired The discussion here is restricted to votes in the power stations did not materialise (Weller, House of Representatives, where candidates 2019). In fact, in 2013, when the US-based Ford represent their local area, rather than the less- Motor Company announced the closure of its locally specific Senate voting. From the discus- Geelong operations, the Federal government sion above, the expectation is greater demand redirected funds promised to the ‘transitioning’ for fringe parties in Morwell. of the Latrobe Valley to the urgent need in Discontent is often associated with waning Geelong. This of course rekindled disaffection support for mainstream parties (Essletzbichler and resentment in the Latrobe Valley. et al., 2018). Australia-wide in 2016, more than The second major difference between the three quarters of all first preference votes two places is their position relative to economic (76.8% of votes) were directed to the two opportunities. Geelong is commuting distance major parties, and just under 25% to all other from Melbourne, making it an attractive site parties. In Corio, a de-industrialising place sup- for construction-led urban re-development, ported by government interventions, the vote especially along its waterfront precincts. The for the two major parties was above the na- Latrobe Valley is too far from Melbourne to tional average, at 77.1% of the vote, while in benefit from commuter-based decentralisation Norlane, it was just below the national average (see Figure 2). Although Norlane is quite disad- (at 74.7%). Fewer people in Gippsland sup- vantaged socio-economically, its location allows ported the major parties (71.1%), but the vote residents to access work, education and enter- fell sharply in Morwell to 66.5% of votes. Put tainment opportunities in both Geelong and another way, a third of voters in Morwell denied Melbourne, whereas Morwell’s physical isola- the two major parties a first preference vote. tion and poor transport networks make it dif- Figure 3 graphs the percentage of first pref- ficult for low-income residents to expand their erence votes for the different parties in the opportunities beyond the immediate local area. electorates and suburbs of interest in 2016. The Page 11 of 16
Weller Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 Figure 3. First preference votes, percent, 2016, case study locations. Source: AEC (2019). voting patterns show, in both places, the rela- (2018) suggests that across Victoria about a half tive unimportance of fringe parties relative to of informal votes are protest votes (blank or the three mainstream options (Labor, Coalition defaced votes). This pattern suggests perhaps and Greens). Gippsland attracted a larger field that disillusionment is at least as widespread in of candidates than Corio. In Gippsland, conser- these crisis locations as discontent. vative Christian and family-oriented parties at- Examining the change in voting in 2016 com- tracted more votes than right-fringe nationalist pared to the previous 2013 election reveals an and anti-immigration candidates, and the total overall swing towards the sitting member in number of right-fringe votes barely exceeded both electorates. Perhaps the message is that at the number of informal votes. In Corio, fringe times of uncertainty voters prefer the security parties fared poorly: there were more informal of the familiar. In Norlane—the most disadvan- votes than votes for right-oriented fringe par- taged area materially—the swing to the Labor ties. All this is consistent with the proposition incumbent was stronger than the seat average. that the Australia system builds political legit- Morwell—a Labor enclave in a National-held imacy in crisis locations. seat—bucked the trend by swinging away from In Australia, compulsory voting means that the sitting member, as would be expected from failure to vote attracts a fine, but people who the failure to secure Federal funding assistance. are disaffected or feel disenfranchised have the Consistent with national trends, there was a option of complying with the law but defacing swing to the Greens in both electorates. There their ballot rather than voting for any of the was also a swing to fringe parties in the 2016 candidates. In both the seats, Gippsland and election relative to 2013, but the 2016 minor Corio, the informal vote declined in the 2016 party votes mostly replaced 2013 votes for election relative to 2013. However, the informal other, now-defunct, minor parties. The net result vote increased in percentage terms in both the is no discernible shift to fringe parties associated local epicentres of industrial change to account with the short-term crisis conditions. Historical for 8.0% of the vote in Morwell and 8.7% in electoral data show a sharp decline in the sup- Norlane (compared to only 4.9% in Corio and port for Labor in the Latrobe Valley from the 7.1% in Gippsland). Of course, the preferen- 2007 election, which local experts attribute to tial system is also relatively complicated when a combination of demographic change and en- there are large numbers of candidates, so many ergy sector workers switching their support to informal votes are genuine errors. The AEC the conservative parties. Page 12 of 16
Places that matter Overall, these data do not suggest a signifi- described by Pain (2019), then a new bridge, cant trend to fringe parties in areas described as museum or business park will without doubt be disadvantaged, left-behind or in crisis. In fact, poorly received. The scope of what is called re- Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 with the exception of Morwell, the uncertainty gional policy needs to expand to encompass the of the time led many voters in these places to arrangements that allow policies like austerity support the sitting member. In Morwell, the to happen (Hadjimichalis, 2017). place that had experienced repeated disap- Second, the European literature too often as- pointments, there was less support for the major sumes that reducing inequality will also reduce parties, more support for fringe candidates and local resentments. This echoing of the old idea more informal voting. The contrast between that the economic base determines the social Norlane and Morwell illustrates the central superstructure is not necessarily true of con- point that Australia’s crisis intervention system, temporary societies. The Australian system’s in conjunction with a redistributive overall gov- strength is that it asks implicitly ‘What needs ernmental framework, does function to mollify to be done to neutralise local dissent?’, which discontent. is quite a different question to the European question of ‘What can be done to reduce in- equality?’. Of course, the question is asked in Conclusion: the importance of a context where most people live above the structural arrangements poverty line, a situation made possible by the The literature struggling to comprehend the Federation’s overall redistributive structure. rise of populist and fringe parties in Europe is Third is the idea that regional assistance focused on socio-economic inequalities. These needs to be designed to lead to economic- are assumed to be responsible for the discon- ally sustainable outcomes, by which is meant tents that motivate support for populist politics. local self-sufficiency in a market economy. The disenchantment with mainstream politics As this suggests that interventions must be in left-behind places is also often attributed to targeted to potentially competitive places the failures of regional policy interventions, in and activities, it also justifies withdrawing particular to their remote ‘top down’ impos- assistance from uncompetitive places. If it is ition and to their insufficient incorporation of agreed that ‘Local inhabitants…want oppor- local concerns and priorities. While there is an tunities rather than assistance and aid; they emerging consensus supporting place-based want a future rather than permanent sup- policy, this is interpreted as meaning more local port’ (Rodríguez-Pose, 2018, 16), then there control and, by implication, therefore more local also must be a strategy to achieve that end in responsibility for policy failures. The Australian places that are unattractive to investors. The exemplar provides an opportunity to rethink Australian framework of in-built redistribu- the problem and its range of solutions. tion provides ‘permanent support’ that is not First, the regional policy literature tends to perceived negatively, as a hand-out. This ac- focus on the specifics of particular regional knowledges that in places that do not offer policy initiatives in isolation from the wider global capital opportunities for a better than policy frameworks of which they are a compo- average return on investment, permanent nent. This enables the local reception of inter- cycles of redistributive assistance are cur- ventions to be discussed independently of the rently the only realistic option. effects of policies like austerity in local com- The overall conclusion suggested by this article munities. If ordinary people are struggling to is that European debates about voter rebellion put food on the table or living in the squalor are not taking enough note of the bigger picture Page 13 of 16
Weller of democratic representation and the responsive- support of the Australian Research Council (grants ness of governments to the plight of places facing FT110100854, LP170100940 and SR200200446) is crises. That wider picture suggests that explan- gratefully acknowledged. The author also thank to Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 ations for the rise of populism in Europe could Cheryl Wragg for her insights on Latrobe Valley voting patterns. spend more time asking why political frameworks have not responded in a timely way to localised crises, and why they have not sufficiently acknow- References ledged that places and the people in them do ABS (2020) 2016 Census Quickstats. Australian matter. The Australian experience opens a space Bureau of Statistics. Available online at: www.abs. for thinking about other possibilities, including gov.au [Accessed May 2020]. about changes in electoral systems. AEC (2018) Analysis of Informal Voting: 2016 House of Representatives Elections. Canberra, Australia: Australian Electoral Commission. Available on- Endnotes line at: https://www.aec.gov.au/About_AEC/re- search/files/analysis-of-informal-voting-2016.pdf 1 These arrangements are by and large replicated [Accessed May 2020]. at State level, although the States are closer to the AEC (2019) 2016 Federal Election House of Westminster model. Representatives First Preferences by Party: 2 In preferential voting, voters rank candidates in Final Results. Australian Electoral Commission. Available online at: www.aec.gov.au/downloads order of preference. The counting of preferences be- [Accessed October 2019]. gins by reallocating the votes for the least favoured Bailey, D., Coffey, D., Gavrisc, M. and Thornley, C. candidate to each voter’s second-preference candi- (2019) Industrial policy, place and democracy, date, and so on, until one winner remains. In 2016, Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and about 30% of seats were decided on the distribution Society, 12: 327–345. of preferences. Barca, F., McCann, P. and Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2012) 3 Don Chipp was the founder and leader of the The case for regional development intervention: place-based versus place-neutral approaches, Australian Democrats, which held the balance of Journal of Regional Science, 52: 134–152. power in the Senate from 1980 to 2005. Barone, G., Francesco, D. and De Blasio, G. (2016) 4 For example, Senate opposition in 2015 forced the Boulevard of broken dreams: the end of EU Abbott government to abandon its attempt to intro- funding in Italy (1997: Abruzzi, Italy), Regional duce Austerity-like budget measures. Science and Urban Economics, 61: 31–38. Beer, A. (2015) Structural adjustment programmes 5 The political forces associated with neoliberalism and regional development in Australia, Local are active across this spectrum. In this system, the Economy, 30: 21–40. politics of the fringe often plays out in factional con- Berlant, L. (2011) Cruel Optimism. Durham, NC: testation within the major parties. University of Durham Press. 6 A referee queried whether Corio would have re- Brockner, J., Konovsky, M., Cooper-Schneider, R., ceived similar funding if Corangamite had been a Folger, R., Martin, C. and Bies, R. (1994) Interactive effects of procedural justice and out- ‘safe’ seat. My view is that second city development come negativity on victims and survivors of strategies make the answer yes, but perhaps with less job loss, Academy of Management Journal, 37: money spilling from Corio to its marginal neighbour. 397–409. Camagni, R. and Capello, R. (2015) Rationale and design of EU cohesion policies in a period of crisis, Acknowledgements Regional Science Policy and Practice, 7: 25–47. Cameron, S. and McAllister, I. (2020) Trends in A previous version of this article was pre- Australian Political Opinion: Results from the sented at the 2019 RGS-IBG Conference Session Australian Election Study 1987–2019. Canberra, ‘Troubling Rustbelt Revolts: Regional Geographies Australia: Australian National University. of Discontent and Political Grievance’ organ- Available at https://australianelectionstudy.org ised by Gordon McLeod and Sarah Knuth. The [Accessed May 2020]. Page 14 of 16
Places that matter Chipp, D. (2004) Keep the Bastards Honest. Adelaide, geography of the populist surge in Europe, Australia: Don Chipp Enterprises. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Connell, R. W. and Irving, T. (1992) Class Structure in Society, 11: 95–113. Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/advance-article/doi/10.1093/cjres/rsab002/6207957 by guest on 22 September 2021 Australian History: Poverty and Progress. Sydney, Graycar, A. and Jamrozik, A. (1989) How Australians Australia: Longman Cheshire. Live: Social Policy in Theory and Practice. Crescenzi, R. and Giua, M. (2016) The EU cohe- Melbourne, Australia: Macmillan. sion policy in context: does a bottom-up approach Hacker, J., Rehm, P. and Schlesinger, M. (2013) The work in all regions?, Environment and Planning A: insecure American: Economic experiences, finan- Economy and Space, 48: 2340–2357. cial worries, and policy attitudes, Perspectives on Cusack, T. R., Iversen, T. and Soskice, D. (2007) Politics, 11: 23–49. Economic interests and the origins of electoral sys- Hadjimichalis, C. (2017) Crises Spaces: Structures, tems, American Political Science Review, 101: 373–391. Resistance and Solidarity in Southern Europe. Dabrowski, M. (2012) Shallow or deep London, UK: Routledge Europeanisation? The uneven impact of EU co- Harvey, D. (2011) Roepke lecture in economic hesion policy on the regional and local author- geography—crises, geographic disruptions and ities in Poland, Environment and Planning C: the uneven development of political responses, Government and Policy, 30: 730–745. Economic Geography, 87: 1–22. Daley, J. and Lancy, A. (2011) Investing in Regions: Hicken, A. (2017) Clientelism, Annual Review of Making a Difference. Melbourne, Australia: Political Science, 14: 289–310. Grattan Institute. Jessop, B. (2018) Neoliberalization, uneven develop- Emmenegger, P., Marx, P. and Schraff, D. (2015) ment, and Brexit: further reflections on the organic Labour market disadvantage, political orienta- crisis of the British state and society, European tions and voting: How adverse labour market Planning Studies, 26: 1728–1746. experiences translate into electoral behaviour, Johnson, L., Weller, S. and Barnes, T. (2021, forth- Socio-Economic Review, 13: 189–213. coming) (Extra) Ordinary Geelong: state-led Essletzbichler, J., Disslbacher, F. and Moser, M. (2018) urban regeneration and economic revival. In The victims of neoliberal globalisation and the rise Bryson, J., Kalafsky, R. and Vanchan, V. (eds) of the populist vote: a comparative analysis of Ordinary Cities, Extraordinary Geographies: three recent electoral decisions, Cambridge Journal People, Place and Space. Northampton, MA: of Regions, Economy and Society, 11: 73–94. Edward Elgar. Ford, R. and Goodwin, M. (2017) Britain after Brexit: Kline, P. and Moretti, E. (2014) People, places, and A nation divided, Journal of Democracy, 28: 17–30. public policy: Some simple welfare economics of Gallego, A., Buscha, F., Sturgis, P. and Oberski, D. local economic development programs, Annual (2016) Places and preferences: A longitudinal Review of Economics, 6: 629–62. analysis of self-selection and contextual effects, Laclau, E. (2005) On Populist Reason. London, UK: British Journal of Political Science, 46: 529–550. Verso. Gillard, J., Shorten, B. and Emerson, C. (2013) More Lipset, S. (1960) Political Man. The Social Bases of Support to Ford Workers. Joint Press Release: Politics. New York, NY: Anchor Books. The Prime Minister, Deputy Prime Minister, Los, B., McCann, P., Springford, J. and Thissen, M. and Minister for Employment and Workplace (2017) The mismatch between local voting and the Relations. 1 June. Available online at: https:// local economic consequences of Brexit, Regional ministers.dese.gov.au/gillard/more-support-ford- Studies, 51: 786–99. workers [Accessed March 2020]. MacLeod, G. and Jones, M. (2018) Explaining ‘Brexit Gerring, J. (2007) Is there a (viable) crucial-case capital’: uneven development and the austerity method?, Comparative Political Studies, 40: state, Space and Polity, 22: 111–136. 231–253. Manow, P. (2009) Electoral rules, class coalitions and Golder, M. (2016) Far right parties in Europe, welfare state regimes, or how to explain Esping- Annual Review of Political Science, 19: 477–497. Andersen with Stein Rokkan, Socio-Economic Goodwin, M. and Heath, O. (2016) The 2016 refer- Review, 7: 101–121. endum, Brexit and the left behind: An aggregate- McCann, P. (2020) Perceptions of regional inequality level analysis of the result, The Political Quarterly, and the geography of discontent: Insights from the 87: 323–332. UK, Regional Studies, 54: 256–267. Gordon, I. (2018) In what sense left behind by McKenzie, L. (2017) ‘It’s not ideal’: Reconsidering globalisation? Looking for a less reductionist ‘anger’ and ‘apathy’ in the Brexit vote among an Page 15 of 16
You can also read