POVERTY AND SOCIAL IMPACT ANALYSIS OF INCREASED NATURAL GAS PRICES AND SELECTED SOCIAL GUARANTEES IN UKRAINE - KYIV 2011
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Poverty and Social Impact Analysis of Increased Natural Gas Prices and Selected Social Guarantees in Ukraine Kyiv - 2011
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without prior permission. This is an independent publication commissioned by UNDP. The views expressed in this publication are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the United Nations Development Programme or any other UN agency. ISBN ^^^^^ © UNDP 2011 All rights reserved. United Nations Development Programme Manufactured in Ukraine
Team for the Preparation of the Publication Authors Oleksandra Betliy Veronika Movchan Mykola Pugachov Advisory Group Marcin Swiecicki Coordination Katerina Rybalchenko Editor of English version Greg McTaggart Editor of Ukrainian version Tetyana Luzhanska Acknowledgements This research has benefited from the valuable input by Dmytro Naumenko. The team of researchers was supported by the Blue Ribbon Analytical and Advisory Centre (BRAAC), a project funded by the EU, co-funded and implemented by UNDP in Ukraine. In particular, Andriy Zayika, BRAAC Communication Officer, managed outreach and communications activities related to this research. This publication has been prepared within the UNDP Poverty and Social Impact Analysis (PSIA) initiative led by the Poverty Practice in the Bureau for Development Policy in cooperation with Poverty and Economic Policy (PEP) Research Network. We appreciate cooperation with the Ministry of Social Policy of Ukraine, which made this research possible. 3
Table of contents LIST OF TABLES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 LIST OF FIGURES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 INTRODUCTION. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 SECTION 1. UKRAINE’S SOCIO-ECONOMIC SITUATION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 1.1 DEMOGRAPHIC TRENDS. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 1.2 MACROECONOMIC SITUATION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 1.3 FISCAL POLICY AND THE BUDGET SITUATION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19 1.4 DEVELOPMENT OF LIVING STANDARDS OF UKRAINIANS. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 1.5 GAS MARKET IN UKRAINE . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 SECTION 2. METHODOLOGY OF THE STUDY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 2.1 DATA REVIEW. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 2.1.1 Households’ survey . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 2.2 MAIN METHODS OF RESEARCH . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30 2.2.1 Poverty measures. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30 2.2.2 Approaches towards evaluating the efficiency of social welfare programmes . . . 32 2.2.3 Computable general equilibrium model. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35 SECTION 3. WELFARE OF UKRAINIAN HOUSEHOLDS. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40 3.1 POVERTY: INCIDENCE AND DEPTH. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40 3.1.1 Official poverty lines . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40 3.1.2 Poverty rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42 3.1.3 Poverty depth . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45 3.2 HOUSEHOLD INCOME STRUCTURE . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46 3.3 CONSUMPTION PATTERN. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 3.3.1 Consumption structure. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 3.3.2 Energy consumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50 SECTION 4. IMPACT OF GAS PRICE INCREASE ON POPULATION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54 4.1 SCENARIOS. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54 4.2 MACROECONOMIC IMPACT . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55 4.3 IMPACT ON POVERTY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57 SECTION 5. IMPACT OF SELECTED SOCIAL WELFARE PROGRAMMES ON POVERTY IN UKRAINE. . . . 61 4
5.1 SOCIAL SUPPORT PROGRAMMES IN UKRAINE: OVERVIEW . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 5.1.1 Brief overview. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 5.1.2 Family assistance. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62 5.1.3 Housing subsidies and benefits. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63 5.2 EVALUATION OF SOCIAL ALLOWANCES TO LOW-INCOME FAMILIES. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66 5.2.1 Coverage by the programme . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66 5.2.2 Efficiency of the program. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 5.2.3 Impact of the programme on poverty reduction. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69 5.3 EVALUATION OF HOUSING AND UTILITY SUBSIDIES TO HOUSEHOLDS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70 5.3.1 Coverage by the programme . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70 5.3.2 Efficiency of the program. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71 5.3.3 Impact of the programme on poverty reduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75 5.3.4 Possible changes in the provision of housing and utility subsidy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76 CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78 Conclusions and recommendations regarding the gas market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78 Conclusions and recommendations regarding social protection system . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79 BIBLIOGRAPHY. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82 5
LIST OF TABLES Table 1.1. Transfers from the State Budget to the Pension Fund, 2005-2010.............................. 20 Table 1.2. Primary energy consumption in Ukraine by fuels, 2005-2009...................................... 25 Table 1.3. Gas balance of Ukraine, 2006-2010......................................................................................... 26 Table 2.1. Household breakdown by the number of members and existence of children, 2009, percent.......................................................................................................................................................... 31 Table 2.2. Advantages and disadvantages of three poverty measures......................................... 34 Table 2.3. The structure of the SAM............................................................................................................ 39 Table 2.4. Aggregate social accounting matrix for Ukraine with base year 2008, UAH billion.....40 Table 2.5. Elasticity parameters.................................................................................................................... 42 Table 3.1. Subsistence minimum levels, UAH per person, average per year................................ 44 Table 3.2. Poverty incidence and structure of poverty........................................................................ 46 Table 3.3. Inequality indicators estimated in terms of overall income, 2007–2009.................. 48 Table 3.4. Poverty gap index and severity of poverty.......................................................................... 49 Table 3.5. Consumption of energy-related goods and services in 2009, poverty line: personal income below 75 percent of median........................................................................................... 54 Table 3.6. Consumption of energy-related goods and services in 2009, poverty line: personal income below official subsistence minimum........................................................................... 54 Table 4.1. Matrix of Scenarios........................................................................................................................ 58 Table 4.2. Economy-wide effects of gas price increase: medium-term model, percent change over period.............................................................................................................................................. 60 Table 4.3. Economy-wide effects of gas price increase: long-term model, percent change over period.............................................................................................................................. 60 Table 4.4. Impact on poverty indicators, percent change over period.......................................... 62 Table 4.5. Welfare impact by households’ poverty level, percent change over period............ 62 Table 4.6. Welfare impact by households’ location, percent change over period..................... 63 Table 4.7. Welfare impact by households’ skill level, percent change over period.................... 63 Table 4.8. Welfare impact by households’ size level, percent change over period.................... 64 Table 5.1. Coverage by low-income allowance, 2009........................................................................... 72 Table 5.2. Financing and size of the low-income families allowance, 2009................................. 72 Table 5.3. Beneficiaries of low-income family allowance by poverty and locality, 2009......... 73 Table 5.4. Targeting of low-income family benefits as a social welfare programme, 2009.... 74 Table 5.5. Efficiency of low-income family benefits as a social welfare programme, 2009.... 75 Table 5.6. Poverty measures before and after receiving low-income family assistance according to the poverty line ‘Subsistence minimum’, 2009................................................................. 76 6
Table 5.7. Coverage by subsidies................................................................................................................. 77 Table 5.8. Beneficiaries of housing and utility subsidy by poverty and locality, 2009............. 78 Table 5.9. Beneficiaries of liquefied gas and solid fuel subsidy by poverty and locality, 2009....79 Table 5.10. Targeting of utility subsidies, 2009......................................................................................... 79 Table 5.11. Efficiency of housing and utility subsidies as a social welfare programme, 2009.. 80 Table 5.12. Efficiency of liquefied gas and solid fuel subsidy as a social welfare programme, 2009.................................................................................................................................................. 81 Table 5.13. Poverty measures before and after receiving housing and utility subsidies against the poverty line ‘Subsistence minimum’, 2009........................................... 82 Table 5.14. Change in poverty status due to receiving housing and utility subsidy, 2009 (Percent of all households)................................................................................................................................ 83 Table 5.15. Eligibility for the programme, 2009........................................................................................ 84 Table 5.16. Targeting to the poor, 2009, in per cent of all households............................................. 84 7
LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1.1. Total Population in Ukraine, 1990-2011, as of 1 January. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 Figure 1.2. GNI per capita in PPP terms, Ukraine vs. Poland, 1990-2009. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16 Figure 1.3. Growth of real GDP, 1991-2012. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 Figure 1.4. Growth of consumer price index, 1997-2012. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 Figure 1.5. Labour market developments, 1991-2010. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20 Figure 1.6. Minimum wage and minimum pension, 2000-2010. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22 Figure 1.7. Distribution of workers by wage size, 2005-2009 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 Figure 1.8. Price for imported natural gas for Ukraine, 2004-2011 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25 Figure 1.9. Gas prices in Ukraine by types of consumers, as of 1 January 2011 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27 Figure 2.1. Poverty measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35 Figure 2.2. Targeting versus universal social welfare programmes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36 Figure 3.1. Poverty lines and social standards, UAH. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46 Figure 3.2. Income structure. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 Figure 3.3. Income structure by groups. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49 Figure 3.4. Per capita income by groups, UAH thousand. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50 Figure 3.5. Expenditures structure by groups . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51 Figure 3.6. Per capita expenditures by groups, UAH thousand. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52 Figure 3.7. Territorial structure of energy-related products and services consumption of households. . . . 55 Figure 3.8. Structure of energy-related products and services consumption of households depending on income level. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55 Figure 5.1. Expected share of expenditures on energy, 2009 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80 8
LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS CGE Computable general equilibrium DASP Distributive Analysis Stata Package EC European Commission EU European Union FGT Foster-Greer-Thorbecke class GAMS General Algebraic Modelling System GDP Gross domestic product GNI Gross national income GTS Gas transport system HBS Household Budget Survey IEA International Energy Agency IER Institute for Economic Research and Policy Consulting IMF International Monetary Fund M&A Mergers and acquisitions MEU Ministry of Economy of Ukraine MPSGE Mathematical Programming System for General Equilibrium analysis NERC National Electricity Regulation Commission of Ukraine NJSC National Joint-Stock Company OECD Organisation of Economic Cooperation and Development p.p. Percentage point PPP Purchasing power parity PSIA Poverty and Social Impact Analysis SAM Social Accounts Matrix SPGI Severe poverty gap index SSCU State Statistics Committee of Ukraine SSSU State Statistics Service of Ukraine TPES Total primary energy supply UAH Ukrainian hryvnia UGS Underground gas storages UN United Nations UNDP United Nations Development Programme USD US dollar USSR Union of Soviet Socialist Republics UTS Unified Tariff Schedule VAT Value-added tax VET Vocational education and training yoy Year-on-year 9
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Over the last decade until the end of 2008, Ukraine had demonstrated robust economic growth, with average real GDP increasing by 6.9 percent annually. This growth was based on favourable external demand and on institutional changes launched, and partially implemented in the 1990s and early 2000s. However, stable growth rates undermined the incentives of central authorities to conduct necessary economic reforms and a lot of issues remained unresolved. They include, inter alia, incomplete social welfare reform, low energy efficiency, out-dated infrastructure, fiscal disequilibrium and an unattractive investment climate. As a result, the recent financial and economic crisis hit Ukraine very hard raising poverty issue with more attention. Years of economic growth, known as a best way to combat poverty, resulted in sharp reduction of the absolute poverty measured against administratively defined subsistence minimum level. Between 2001 and 2008 absolute poverty declined from 77.1 percent of households to 19.7 percent.1 Such rapid change was explained by increase in two major households’ income components. In particular, wages grew due to growth of labour productivity as well as administrative increase of minimum wage to the subsistence minimum level for working able individuals. Social assistance payments grew primarily due to increase in minimum old-age pension to subsistence minimum level set for people that lost ability to work as well as higher birth grants. At the same time, relative poverty2 has remained stable at about 27 percent, which could reflect the stratification of households in terms of income, the same level of inequality, and the lack of structural changes. Consequently during the recent decade more people were able to afford basic basket of goods and services. However, nearly 27 percent of families could not purchase the set of goods and services, which are considered as necessary for the average household. The level of poverty among households with children remains a major problem, which is likely to be a result of an inefficient state policy for supporting such families. During last decade poverty has declined more in urban areas being higher in rural areas. Such trends reflect the little effort the authorities towards improving the situation in rural areas, particularly, concerning the labour market, infrastructure, etc. Often, rural development is perceived by the Government as agricultural development, although these two concepts are very different. Poor households tend to allocate a higher share of their expenditures to energy consumption than do non-poor. The analysis of households’ consumption patterns of energy-related products and services allows us to identify that about half of energy-related consumption is likely to be very sensitive to a gas price increase. In urban areas, the major price pass-through will go through centralized gas consumption and district heating, while in rural areas it will primarily be through centralized gas consumption. This channel of transmission is likely to cause the greatest problem for the poor population in time of gas price hikes since they extensively rely on this supply. Until now, gas and other energy prices for households have been generously subsidized by the Government. However, suppressed energy prices lead to excessive use of gas and make investment in saving energy inefficient. In addition, Ukraine’s dependence on imported gas contributes to trade imbalances and growing pressure on the devaluation of the national currency. Thus, the issue of raising gas prices for the population remains critical in Ukraine. 1 The estimation of poverty incidence as well as the evaluation of efficiency of social welfare programs is based on the data from the Household Budget Survey, conducted by the State Statistics Service of Ukraine. 2 In the research relative poverty is measured against the line of 75 percent of conditional per capita expenditures. 10
In particular, this step is also envisaged in an ambitious reform agenda announced in mid- 2010 aimed at restoring stable high growth of the economy. To evaluate the impact of the increase in gas prices on households’welfare, we employ the computable general equilibrium model for Ukraine with a micro-simulation approach in line with Cockburn, Corong and Cororaton (2010). In particular, information about households’ expenditure and income patterns from national households’ surveys into Ukraine’s CGE model is integrated According to the results of the medium-term model simulation, the overall welfare losses (measured as Equivalent Variation) arising from a 50 percent increase of import gas prices constitute about 5.5 percent of consumption, while the impact of internal price adjustment is more moderate staying at 3.4 percent of welfare loss. In the long-term model allowing for changes in capital endowment over time, the figures are about 10 percent and 5.7 percent of Ukrainian consumption, respectively. The shock would be transmitted through both output/employment and consumption channels. The simulation of gas price shocks showed that all categories of households would experience a welfare loss due to higher gas prices. Absolute poverty incidence would increase by 8.7 percent over medium-term horizon and by 19.5 percent over long-term horizon due to external price shock. Internal price adjustments would cause increase in absolute poverty incidence by 1.5 percent and 4.5 percent, respectively. Location seems to be a key factor in determining the variation in welfare responses of households. In the majority of scenarios urban households tend to experience higher losses than rural households. This can be explained by differences in their consumption structure. In particular, in urban areas the major items of energy-related consumption are centralized gas consumption and district heating, while in rural areas – primarily centralized gas consumption. High urban heating consumption is very important for determining the welfare impact of gas price shock. Thus, the CGE simulation suggests that urban poor households should be in the focus of social welfare programs for mitigation of increased gas price shock. While poor households are likely to be impacted by increase in gas prices, the question remains on the efficiency of social welfare system to protect poor. Overall, the Ukrainian social protection system provides a wide range of social benefits, but they are not sufficiently differentiated by recipients’ levels of income. Moreover, the system is focused on universal protection, precluding the targeting of the most vulnerable groups, and on categorical benefit schemes, which generate overlapping beneficiary categories, many of which do not provide support to those who are in need. However, the effective social welfare system should be aimed at ensuring households with minimum standards of living that are supposed to cover all the basic needs including basic nutrition and housing and utility expenditures. Thus, the country needs a well-targeted and efficient social protection system to mitigate the negative social shock on the poorest and the most vulnerable groups of society. At the moment there could be defined two programmes that were initially introduced to help poor people. One is low-income family allowances, which are provided to poor households with income below the guaranteed minimum income (GMI). Another refers to housing and utility subsidy provided to individuals with spending for respective services above a specified threshold.3 Analysis of the efficiency of these two social welfare programs demonstrate that housing and utility subsidies help households in urban area, who could be most impacted by the gas shock, while the provision of the low-income family assistance does not significantly 3 Since 2010, households whose charges for housing and utility services exceed 15 percent of the ag- gregate household income are entitled to housing and utility subsidy (10 percent for the most vulner- able household categories) 11
contribute to a decline in poverty. Overall, the efficiency of both programs remains low in combating poverty. The targeting of housing and utility subsidies is much lower than of low-income family assistance likely due to the absence of mean-testing eligibility criteria. Both programs are characterised by large under-coverage of poor. These results allow making specific policy recommendations regarding reform of social protection system in Ukraine. To sum up, there could be made two major answers to the research question. First, increase in gas prices will result in welfare loss of all categories of households, with more profound impact on urban households. Second, the current social welfare programs are not very efficient in targeting the poorest households. Therefore, the reform of social welfare system is required to ensure the safety net for poor households in times of gas price hikes. 12
INTRODUCTION Over the last decade until the end of 2008, Ukraine had demonstrated robust economic growth, with average real GDP increasing by 6.9 percent annually. This growth was based on favourable external demand and on institutional changes launched, and partially implemented in the 1990s and early 2000s. However, stable growth rates undermined the incentives of central authorities to conduct necessary economic reforms and a lot of issues remained unresolved. They include, inter alia, incomplete social system reforms, low energy efficiency, out-dated infrastructure, fiscal disequilibrium and an unattractive investment climate. As a result, the recent financial and economic crisis hit Ukraine very hard. Ineffective economic and social policies hindered the achievement of tangible results in reducing poverty in Ukraine. Even though the country managed to decrease absolute poverty, relative poverty, showing inequality, has remained stable at about 27 percent. The economic recession of 2009, which resulted in severe budget limitations, has further complicated the handling of the poverty issues and the pursuit of an active social policy to alleviate it. The Ukrainian social protection system provides a wide range of social benefits, but they are not sufficiently differentiated by recipients’ levels of incomes. Moreover, the system is focused on universal protection, precluding the targeting of the most vulnerable groups, and on categorical benefit schemes, which generate overlapping beneficiary categories, many of which do not provide support to those who are in need. Fiscal constraints, which became binding during the recession, have once again emphasized the drawbacks of the system. An ambitious reform agenda announced in mid-2010, and necessary to restore the stable, high growth of the economy, includes changes inevitably resulting in adverse social shocks. Increase in gas pricing for households are among these reforms. Until now, gas and other energy prices for households have been generously subsidized by the Government. However, suppressed energy prices lead to excessive use of gas and make investment in saving energy inefficient. In addition Ukraine’s dependence on imported gas contributes to trade imbalances and growing pressure on the devaluation of the national currency. Thus, the issue of raising gas prices for the population remains critical in Ukraine. Basic needs, such as housing and utility services, depend on natural gas, since it is extensively used for heating, cooking, hot water production, and electricity generation. The minimum standards of living are supposed to be able to cover all the basic needs of a citizen including basic nutrition and housing expenditures. Thus, the country needs a well-targeted and efficient social protection system to mitigate the negative social shock on the poorest and the most vulnerable groups of society. The question is whether current social protection system could handle this problem appropriately. The Report aims to answer these questions. To do so, several issues are tackled. First, the impact of gas price increases on welfare and poverty are simulated to understand the depth of the shock. Second, the existing social protection system is analysed focusing on two programmes, i.e. social assistance to low-income families and housing and utility subsidies to households to evaluate their efficiency and impact on poverty reduction, and thus to verity its absorption capacity in the case of adverse social shock. Combining the results of the assessment of the impact of gas price increases on poverty and the social programmes efficiency evaluation permits identification of the drawbacks/gaps in the existing social protection system to develop policy recommendations. In particular, the simulation of gas price shocks showed that all categories of households would experience a welfare loss due to higher gas prices. However, the impact on urban households 13
would be particularly profound, and this category of households should be in the focus of social welfare programs for mitigation of increased gas price shock. Analysis of efficiency of two social welfare programs - social assistance to low-income families and housing and utility subsidies to households – demonstrated that the housing and utility subsidies to households programme helps households in urban area, who could be most impacted by the gas shock, while the provision of the low-income family assistance does not significantly contribute to a decline in poverty. Moreover, the efficiency of the housing and utility subsidies programme remains low. These results allowed making specific policy recommendations regarding reform of social protection system in Ukraine. The document is organised as follows. Section 1 describes Ukraine’s general economic situation, including the poverty assessment. Section 2 focuses on the research methodology and the data used. In Section 3 welfare of Ukrainian households is analysed with a focus on poverty incidence, income and expenditures patterns. Section 4 discusses the results of simulation of the gas price increase using the computable general equilibrium model for Ukraine, in particular the impact of this shock on poverty. Ukraine’s system of social protection is outlined, and the efficiency of two programmes – social assistance to low-income families and housing and utility subsidies to households – is evaluated in Section 5. Conclusions and policy recommendations end the document. 14
SECTION 1. UKRAINE’S SOCIO-ECONOMIC SITUATION 1.1 DEMOGRAPHIC TRENDS Successful social policy reforms, the development of stable, properly targeted social security system and a reduction in poverty would be impossible without examining demographic trends. Ukraine’s population has been steadily diminishing over last two decades. According to the State Statistics Service of Ukraine (SSSU), Ukraine’s population in May 2011 was 45.7 million (12.5 percent less than the peak of 1993 (Figure 1.1)). The speed of depopulation was highest in the years of structural economic transformation and recession starting in 1994 and peaking in 2001. Since then the population decrease has slowed down but has not turned into growth. This is largely attributable to a natural decrease in population, due to both low fertility and high mortality rates. Figure 1.1. Total Population in Ukraine, 1990-2011, as of 1 January 54 million persons percent per annum 0.6% 0.4% 52 0.2% 50 0.0% -0.2% 48 -0.4% 46 -0.6% -0.8% 44 -1.0% 42 -1.2% 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 total population growth rate of population Source: State Statistics Service of Ukraine, www.ukrstat.gov.ua Another reason for depopulation was negative net external migration. Roughly one quarter of total net reduction of Ukraine’s population could be attributed to outward migration. After a short period of net positive migration during the early 1990’s, the trend sharply reversed and the net migration has been negative till 2004. Since 2005, official statistics report positive net external migration. The largest official stream of migration has been between the CIS countries and Ukraine, in particular between Russia and Ukraine. In the early years of transition, the flows had been especially high. People move to their relatives for permanent residence, or return home after the Soviet Union collapse destroyed their jobs. A lot of people deported during the Soviet times returned to Ukraine. Also, the early 1990s featured so called ethnical migration, e.g. emigration of the Jews to Israel, Germany, and the USA. Later on, external labour migration has become dominant. According to survey conducted by the State Statistics Service of Ukraine together with the World Migration Organisation, World Bank and Open Ukraine Foundation in 2008, two major reasons for labour migration has been low wage in Ukraine and limited job opportunities. 15
The depopulation problem is likely to worsen in the future. According to UNDP “World Population Prospects”, under the medium fertility scenario Ukraine’s population will shrink to 43 million in 2020 and to 36 million in 2050.4 Depopulation – though at a lesser scale – is expected even under high fertility rate scenario estimates. In Ukraine, depopulation is exacerbated by significantly aging population. The share of population above 60 (the official male pension age) will reach 36 percent of total population by 2050 as compared to 23 percent in 2010, while the share of population aged between 20 and 59 – the age cohort basically forming the country’s labour force – will shrink to 44 percent by 2050 (57 percent in 2010). This significant and rapid change in the population’s age structure could have a number of economic implications, including: • Changed consumption patterns, as different age groups have different consumption baskets. This change could affect development of certain industries and service sectors; • Reduced national savings as older population tend to save less and spend more. Narrowed domestic financial base for investments could adversely affect growth prospects of the country; • Increased social expenditure bill for the state, including medical care expenditures and spending of social funds; and • Changed size, composition and productivity of the labour force, hampering output growth and undermining tax revenues. Moreover, changes in labour force could even potentially affect the speed of technological progress. Due to depopulation and population ageing, the number of economically active persons has declined over last two decades to 22.0 million at the end of 2010. As a result, old dependency ratio has already increased and will continue growing exerting pressure on the sustainability of current pension system. Modelling the dynamic effects of population decline and ageing shows that, ceteris paribus, the changed population size and structure could result in about a 15 percent reduction in GDP per capita by 2050 due to the reduced labour force and the increase in taxation necessary to ensure unchanged level of social payments.5 Implementation of pension reform would slow down the negative impact of population ageing on the economic situation in the country, but this reform should be radical enough to make visible changes. According to Lisenkova (2011), an increase in pension age for females to 60 years embedded in current pension reform will have only a minor positive effect on the sustainability of pension system, GDP per capita and public finances. At the same time, a gradual increase in pension age to 65 years for both sexes would have much greater positive impact. GDP per capita by 2050 would decline by about 7 percent compared with 15 percent in case if the pension age is not changed. Summing up, demographic changes will play important changes in long-run development of the country, strongly affecting its social policies. 4 Medium fertility scenario. World Population Prospects, the 2010 Revision. Available here: http://esa.un.org/unpd/wpp/Excel-Data/population.htm 5 Lisenkova (2011) 16
1.2 MACROECONOMIC SITUATION A country’s economic might plays a key role in combating poverty and ensuring its citizens’ high living standards. In Ukraine, the difficulties of transitioning from a centrally planned to a market economy have significantly hampered the country’s economic performance and its wellbeing when compared to neighbouring countries. For instance, if Ukraine and Poland had similar levels of GNI per capita in PPP terms in 1990, by 2009 the gap between the countries had tripled (Figure 1.2). Figure 1.2. GNI per capita in PPP terms, Ukraine vs. Poland, 1990-2009 20000 PPP, current international dollars 18000 16000 14000 12000 10000 8000 6000 4000 2000 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Poland Ukraine Source: World Bank Development Indicators, http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GNP.PCAP.PP.CD Factors explaining Ukraine’s lag in economic performance include lack of sovereign knowledge and experience, corruption and a patchy reform path, exacerbated by the on-going deterioration of physical infrastructure and human capital. Ukraine’s macroeconomic development can be tentatively divided into several periods: Period 1: transition (1991-1995). During this period there was a sharp reduction in economic activity, the breakage of Soviet production and retail links, hyperinflation, deficits of basic products and a quick impoverishment of population. Labour adjustments were done mostly through wage arrears, hidden unemployment and in-kind payments. At the same time, liberalisation of prices and foreign trade regimes occurred. Period 2: stabilisation (1996-1997). During this period some macroeconomic stabilisation was achieved, inflation curbed, and national currency was introduced. Mass privatisation was launched. However, the barter economy continued to proliferate, and incomes continued to reduce. To finance public spending, the Government started active domestic and external borrowings. 17
Figure 1.3. Growth of real GDP, 1991-2012 15 percent per annum 10 5 0 -5 -10 -15 -20 -25 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011F 2012F Source: State Statistics Service of Ukraine, consensus forecast (Ministry of Economy, 2011) Note: F – forecast Figure 1.4. Growth of consumer price index, 1997-2012 30 average percent per annum 25 20 15 10 5 0 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011F 2012F Source: State Statistics Service of Ukraine, consensus forecast (Ministry of Economy, 2011) Note: F – forecast Information: Percentage increase in CPI (annual average) was 1527 percent in 1992, 4735 percent in 1993, 891 percent in 1994, 377 percent in 1995, and 80 percent in 1996. Period 3: crisis 1 (1998-1999). In August 1998, Ukraine entered a currency and debt crisis. Its currency devalued more than twofold and it was forced to restructure its debts. At the same time, this crisis stimulated structural reforms. Mass privatisation was completed, stronger fiscal discipline was introduced and the first stage of economic reforms, particularly in the fields of energy, regulatory reform, public administration as well as land reform, was initialised.6 Period 4: recovery 1 (2000-2005). A better domestic institutional environment and a favourable external environment7 allowed real GDP recovery. Real wages and incomes started 6 Åslund (2002) 7 Movchan (2002) 18
to grow and households’ final consumption started to increase. The financial sector achieved greater trust and foreign banks began to enter the market through M&A. Tax reform was started, reducing tax burden on personal income, though high payroll taxes undermined de- shadowing effect of the reform. Pension reform was launched. Negative external market shocks were compensated by strong domestic demand. Period 5: overheating (2006-2007). A growing world economy and strong domestic demand saw the economy overheat. All prices began to soar. Credits were provided widely with little scrutiny. Stock market indices peaked. Foreign capital inflow was very high and a lot of capital was attracted in the form of credits boosting external debt. The Global Financial Crisis, which began in early 2007 in the USA had an adverse impact on foreign capital flow, but did not undermine the country’s boom moods. Against the background of economic upturn and an easing of social problems, the structural and institutional reforms necessary to secure sustainable long-term economic development were retarded. Period 6: crisis 2 (2008-2009). The second wave of the world financial and economic crisis hit Ukraine hard in mid-2008 causing currency devaluation, capital outflow, and a credit crunch. Economic performance plunged, unemployment increased, and poverty increased again. Fiscal problems were aggravated, partly due to the high social promises made during the years of a flourishing economy. Period 7: recovery 2 (2010-now). The country started to recover from the crisis. Real GDP growth revived though at a rather moderate rate and real wages and incomes have followed this trend. At the same time, unemployment has remained higher than pre-crisis, credit access has been much more restrained than before and the housing market has been flat. Moreover, fiscal problems remain acute. The Government launched a series of reforms to facilitate economic recovery and complete institutional restructuring. However, the actual path of reforms has remained patchy, hampering investments and undermining recovery. As shown, Ukraine has never witnessed a period of stable development based on innovation and investment nor has it completed the transformational reforms launched after independence. Both international organisations and national experts claim that, unless reforms are facilitated, the economy will continue to grow slowly, well below its potential, and inflation will remain high. According to the World Bank’s “Ukraine Economic Update”, real GDP recovery will remain fragile with a 4.5-5.0 percent growth rate in 2011-2012 and consumer prices will grow about 10 percent per annum.8 Similar rates are provided by Ukrainian organisations like the Institute for Economic Research and Policy Consulting,9 and Dragon Capital,10 and by a consensus forecast assembled by the Ministry of Economy of Ukraine11 (Figure 1.3 and Figure 1.4). 1.3 FISCAL POLICY AND THE BUDGET SITUATION The current systemic problems of Ukraine’s fiscal position include a distorted structure of fiscal expenditures, including populist policy spending, high centralisation of public finance, an inadequate model of dividing budget powers and the absence of a clear system of public financial control for fiscal expenditure. During recent years Ukraine’s fiscal policy has been marked by short-term planning and spontaneous changes as far as revenues and expenditures are concerned. It has also been aggravated by an inadequate tariff policy at communal level, 8 World Bank (2011) 9 IER (2011) 10 Dragon Capital (2011) 11 MEU (2011) 19
by a lack of necessary reforms to the social security system and by the absence of a clear and efficient system of state aid provision and public procurements.12 The fiscal problems had accumulated before the 2008 crisis. The authorities’ inability to limit social spending during the crisis resulted in an unbalanced fiscal system. The result has been an increase in the fiscal deficit and public debt. Between 2005 and 2010, there had been a steady increase in recurrent social expenditures. In addition, since 2005, a considerable share of the expenditure of the Pension Fund has been financed by subsidies from the State Budget (Table 1.1) rather than by insurance contributions. Moreover, loans to the Pension Fund from the Single Treasury Account were actively used in that period, which allowed the Fund’s liquidity gap to be eliminated.13 With incomplete reforms of the system of social support, increases in social expenditure did not solve the problem of eliminating poverty but created a threat to the stability of the fiscal system as a whole.14 Table 1.1. Transfers from the State Budget to the Pension Fund, 2005-2010 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010Е Total expenditure of the Pension Fund, percent GDP 14.8 13.7 14.1 15.1 18.1 17.8 Overall transfer from the State Budget,* percent GDP 5.2 4.5 3.5 4.2 4.8 6.0 Of which: Transfer to cover the State’s specific pension obligations 1.5 3.2 3.5 4.2 3.3 3.5 Transfer to finance the Pension Fund’s deficit 3.7 1.3 - - 1.5 2.5 Source: State Treasury reports Notes: *Without loans provided by the State Treasury; E – IER estimate Growing fiscal expenditures have required funding. The tax burden (including deductions to social insurance funds) remains higher than the average of the new EU member states. This distorts economic competition and is a reason for the growth of the shadow economy, contributing to growing losses of fiscal receipts. The Tax Code passed in late 2010 provides for lower rates for the main taxes, but requires further refinement, especially in respect of taxation of small business. The new version of the Budget Code15 passed in 2010 includes positive developments like increases in the level of financial support for local self-government functions by assigning them additional revenue sources and increasing the investment component in local budgets. At the same time, the problems of dividing functional powers among the different levels of authority, increasing the efficiency of fiscal funds at the local level and improving the methods of interregional financial equalisation were not addressed fully in the Code. Since 2009, there has been a rapid growth in public borrowing in both external and domestic markets and, accordingly, a marked increase in public debt. At the end of April 2011, public debt reached USD 58 billion i.e. about 35 percent of GDP. Further increase in public debt creates risks of larger fiscal pressure, a destabilised balance of payments, and persistent, chronically high interest rates. These are the integral attributes of high fiscal deficits that will create obstacles to the recovery of investment and for the economy’s transition to a path of sustainable growth. 12 Burakovsky, Movchan (2011) 13 According to the Accounting Chamber of Ukraine, the outstanding loans granted to the Pension Fund from the single treasury account amounted to UAH 22.1 billion as of 1 January 2010. 14 The share of such spending in the Consolidated Budget doubled to between 22-28% during the pe- riod 2005-2009 compared to its share between1999-2001. 15 Law of Ukraine No. 2456 of 8 July 2010 20
1.4 DEVELOPMENT OF LIVING STANDARDS OF UKRAINIANS The economic ups and downs resulted in rather harsh welfare situation for Ukrainians. During the 1990s real wages sharply declined against the background of economic downturn and high inflation. The labour market adjustment went mainly through a decline in real wages. Employment remained rather stable due to hidden employment (Figure 1.5). By the end of the 1990s wages arrears had increased substantially in both the private and public sectors. As a consequence, purchasing power of Ukrainians declined sharply. Figure 1.5. Labour market developments, 1991-2010 110 index, 1990 = 100 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011F 2012F employment real wage Source: State Statistics Service of Ukraine, consensus forecast (Ministry of Economy, 2011), IER forecast Note: F – forecast In 2000 wages finally started to recover against the background of economic recovery and government policies aimed at improving Ukrainians’ welfare. In particular, the government paid off wage arrears in the public sector. An additional factor contributing to wage growth was the gradual increase in the minimum wage. Between 2001 and 2008 real wages grew by 16.7 percent on average. By the end of 2008 they were almost at the level of 1990. During the same period labour productivity also increased. However, during the crisis of 2009 a labour adjustment occurred through wages, which declined by 9.2 percent in real terms. In 2000 the government also paid off pension arrears. During the years of recovery, income of pensioners grew primarily due to increases in the minimum pension. Higher pensions and wages compensated for the impact of higher inflation on the poor.16 The average annual rate of consumer price growth was 14.1 percent during that period. In 2004 and 2005 Ukraine’s authorities sharply increased social standards, primarily the minimum pensions. As a result, imbalances were observed (Figure 1.6). In particular, the minimum monthly pension was increased during 2004 from UAH 102.8 in January to 16 Burakovsky, Movchan (2011) 21
UAH284.6 in September due to the government’s populist decisions on the eve of elections.17 The minimum pension was increased again in 2005 to UAH 332 following the adoption of a law setting the minimum pension at the minimum subsistence level for those who had lost their capacity to work. As a result, the minimum wage was lower than the minimum pension during the period from September 2004 to September 2005. This was an economically unsound policy. Since nominal pension increases were considerably higher than increases in consumer prices, real minimum pension payments went up by 290 percent in January 2005 when compared to January 2004. Thereafter the minimum pension remained relatively stable until the 2008 crisis set in. In late 2008 and early 2009, there was a decline in the real minimum pension because the country’s fiscal problems made any significant pension rise impossible. However, populist policies at the end of 2009 resulted in another swing upwards in minimum pensions. Figure 1.6. Minimum wage and minimum pension, 2000-2010 1000 UAH index, Jan 2000 = 100 1000 900 900 800 800 700 700 600 600 500 500 400 400 300 300 200 200 100 100 0 0 Jan-00 Jul-02 Mar-04 Aug-04 Jun-00 Nov-00 Apr-01 Jan-05 Sep-01 Feb-02 Dec-02 May-03 Jun-05 Nov-05 Apr-06 Jul-07 Sep-06 Feb-07 Dec-07 May-08 Mar-09 Jan-10 Oct-03 Sep-09 Jun-10 Oct-08 Minimum pension payment (LHS) Minimum wage (LHS) Real minimum pension payment (RHS) Real minimum wage (RHS) Sources: Laws on the State Budget Large increases in minimum pensions during the period of strong economic growth were not supported by reform of the entire pension system. This resulted in a considerable deficit of the Pension Fund since the labour remuneration fund, the base for calculating pension contributions, grew at a slower pace. As a result, the current pension system is extremely unstable, thereby creating additional economic risks for the poor people of the country. Increases in minimum wages for those close to the subsistence minimum level contributed to a decline in the percentage of workers receiving wages lower than the minimum subsistence level.18 In particular, it declined from 26.5 percent in December 2005 to 13.4 percent by December 2008 (Figure 1.7). 17 In September 2004, the Cabinet of Ministers decided to increase the minimum pension payment. Accord- ingly, each pensioner whose pension was lower than the specified minimum pension payment obtained an additional payment. The minimum pension payment in this report is regarded as the minimum pension since no pensioner could receive a pension lower than the specified minimum pension payment. 18 See Section 3.1.1 for the description and discussion of subsistence minimum. 22
The percentage of persons receiving less than the minimum wage declined to 10.7 percent in December 2009 due to the introduction of legislation providing for the setting of the minimum wage at the minimum subsistence level for persons able to work in November 2009. As a result, due to legislative amendments there has been a slight decrease in the percentage of the working poor. Figure 1.7. Distribution of workers by wage size, 2005-2009 30 percent 25 20 15 10 5 0 December 2005 December 2007 December 2008 June 2009 December 2009 below minimum wage between minimum wage and subsistence minimum** Source: State Statistics Service of Ukraine Notes: * Data is provided for staff members who worked 50 percent or more working hours ** Subsistence minimum for working able persons The largest fall in the percentage of workers, whose wages were lower than the minimum subsistence level occurred in budget-funded sectors, particularly education and health care. This can be explained by the stepped introduction of the Unified Tariff Scale (UTS) for labour remuneration in budget-funded sector institutions, approved by resolution of the Cabinet of Ministers.19 The UTS was partially implemented from September 2005: the salary of a Grade I employee was set at the minimum wage, but with less differentiation in wage levels between various employees. The UTS was fully implemented in September 2008, but only for two months. Owing to a decline in fiscal revenues in late 2008, the government decided to fix the UTS wage level for grade I for December 2008 and for the whole of 2009 at the November 2008 level, although the minimum wage was further increased step by step. The wage for the first tariff scale was only slightly increased in 2010 resulting in a further reduction in wage differentiation in the public sector. Wage differentiation was partially reviewed in 2011, when the Government clearly defined wages for the first seven tariff classes and a base wage for 8th-20th classes. Increased wages and pensions accompanied by increases in other social payments, particularly a large rise in the maternity benefit contributed to people’s growing income. As a result, absolute poverty has declined during these years (Section 3). In particular, the poverty incidence measured against the minimum subsistence level has declined from 77.1 percent in 2001 to 17.8 percent in 2009. 19 Before the implementation of the Unified Rate Schedule, wages in the budget-funded sector were specified by Cabinet of Ministers’ resolutions that clearly set salary rates for various employees. 23
1.5 GAS MARKET IN UKRAINE During the last decade Ukraine’s economy has remained heavily dependent on natural gas and coal as the major sources of total primary energy supply (TPES).20 These two types of fuels accounted for 69 percent of TPES in 2009. Natural gas occupies first place with 38 percent of the total energy consumed in the country (Table 1.2). Many years of low gas prices lead to the importance of this type of fuel in Ukraine’s energy balance. The share of gas consumption in Ukraine is higher than in comparison to European countries where gas share in primary energy consumption is close to 20 percent. Nuclear energy is another significant source of energy in Ukraine’s energy balance, accounting for almost 17 percent of TPES. There are four large nuclear power plants. They generate almost 50 percent of the country’s total electricity. The share of renewable energy resources is relatively small and comprises about 2 percent of total primary energy consumption. Table 1.2. Primary energy consumption in Ukraine by fuels, 2005-2009 Million tonnes oil equivalent Structure, percent 2005 2008 2009 2005 2008 2009 Oil 13.9 15.3 14.1 9.9 11.5 12.5 Natural gas 65.6 54.0 42.3 46.9 40.8 37.5 Coal 37.4 40.3 35.0 26.8 30.4 31.1 Nuclear energy 20.1 20.3 18.6 14.4 15.3 16.5 Hydroelectricity and Renewables 2.8 2.6 2.7 2.0 2.0 2.4 Total 139.8 132.5 112.7 100 100 100 Source: BP Statistical review of world energy Between 2005 and 2009 the structure of primary energy consumption changed, largely driven by the continuous growth of imported gas prices, which more than doubled over the period (Figure 1.8). Natural gas consumption decreased from 47 percent to 37.5 percent of total primary consumption, while coal’s share increased by 4.3 percentage points over the period. The primary reason for this is the increased reliance of electricity generating companies on coal instead of gas in the production process. Measures promoting energy efficiency also helped to reduce gas consumption. The economic crisis also contributed to further contraction in natural gas’s share of the energy balance in late 2008 and in 2009. The largest industrial gas consumers, primarily large chemical plants and steel mills, rapidly decreased their consumption against the background of collapsing demand and output volumes. Another factor in gas’s decline was reduced industrial demand for electricity, meaning there was no need to use any additional gas-based generation capacities. At the end of 2009 almost all electricity was generated by nuclear or coal-fired plants. In terms of natural gas consumption and import, Ukraine is one of the largest countries among its peers. According to BP and IEA, in 2009 it was ranked 15th in gas consuming countries and 6th as a natural gas importer. Ukraine depends heavily on gas imports, primarily from Russia and Central Asian countries. According to the gas balance (Table 1.3), annual gas imports were about 50-55 billion cubic meters between 2006 and 2008. During the crisis industry’s demand for natural gas diminished and gas imports halved to 27 billion cubic meters in 2009. It returned to 36 billion cubic meters in 2010 reflecting output recovery. 20 This definition is used by International Energy Agency. Equivalent one that was used in the report is primary energy consumption. 24
You can also read