Market Liquidity and Creditor Runs: Feedback, Ampli cation, and Multiplicity - FBE HKU
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Market Liquidity and Creditor Runs: Feedback, Ampli…cation, and Multiplicity Xuewen Liuy Hong Kong University of Science and Technology This draft: August 2018 Abstract In the global games framework, this paper studies bank runs in a …nancial system, in which there are many banks and they share a common asset market. Our model 1) endogenizes market liquidity, 2) demonstrates two-way feedback between market liquidity and creditor runs, and 3) shows the possibility of multiple equilibria in the system: even when the precision of creditors’ private signals approaches in…nity, multiple equilibria (i.e., a self-ful…lling systemic crisis) can still emerge. Our model helps explain ampli…cation and multiplicity in …nancial crises. JEL classi…cation: G01; G21; D82; D53 Keywords: Systemic crises, bank runs, strategic complementarities, equilibrium multiplicity I am grateful to Deniz Okat for valuable discussion and suggestions. I thank Liang Dai, John Kuong, John Nash, Ming Yang, and seminar participants at HKU, HKUST, Society for Economic Dynamics (SED) Annual Meeting 2018, and International Conference on Economic Theory and Applications 2018 for helpful comments. y Associate Professor of Finance, Department of Finance, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology (HKUST), Clear Water Bay, Hong Kong. Tel: (+852) 2358 7679. Email: xuewenliu@ust.hk.
1 Introduction At the heart of the recent …nancial crisis of 2007-2009 was a series of bank runs that caused imme- diate failures of a number of major …nancial institutions (Gertler et al. (2017)). Remarkably, the systemic bank runs coincided with the “sudden dry-up” of asset market liquidity.1 Fire-sale dis- counts of asset-backed securities and repo rates for securitized bonds exhibited jump discontinuities at the climax of the runs.2 Commentators have attributed the sudden discrete drops in market liquidity in the absence of any apparent large exogenous disturbance to the economy to multiplicity jumps from one equilibrium to another under self-ful…lling beliefs (see, e.g., Brunnermeier (2009), Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009)). Why do systemic runs occur simultaneously with market liquidity dry-ups? What gives rise to jump discontinuities (multiple equilibria)? These phenomena seem di¢ cult to explain with current banking theory which was built on the global games framework. In fact, the seminal works of Rochet and Vives (2004), Goldstein and Pauzner (2005), and Morris and Shin (2009) have shown the existence of a unique equilibrium for a Diamond-Dybvig (1983) bank run model.3 They demonstrate that as long as the precision of private signals of depositors (creditors of a bank) is su¢ ciently high, the equilibrium is guaranteed to be unique. However, their models include only one bank and so do not consider the interaction between di¤erent banks in the system. In this paper, we further advance these works to study a …nancial system, in which there are many banks and they share a common asset market. We show that when an asset market is present with market liquidity being endogenous, equilibrium multiplicity can emerge: even if the precision of creditors’ private signals approaches in…nity, multiple equilibria (i.e., a self-ful…lling crisis) in the system can exist. The driving source of multiplicity in our model is that the presence of an asset market gives rise to strategic complementarities between creditors of di¤erent banks, besides complementarities between creditors of the same bank. Speci…cally, when the creditors of one bank run, that bank is forced to conduct …re sales in the asset market; this decreases market liquidity for all other banks’ assets because of the limited risk-absorbing capacity of investors in the asset market. As lower market liquidity increases coordination risk, the creditors of the other banks thus also have incentives to run. The increased degree of strategic complementarity results in a higher likelihood of equilibrium multiplicity. To put it di¤erently, equilibrium multiplicity under self-ful…lling beliefs can arise in our model because of the two-way feedback between market liquidity and creditor runs (coordination risk). If creditors think market liquidity to be low, they will optimally choose to run 1 See evidence in Gorton and Metrick (2011), Covitz et al. (2013), and Krishnamurthy et al. (2014) among others. 2 The e¤ect of securitized borrowing (against assets as collateral) is similar to the e¤ect of asset sales/liquidation: both concern an exchange of cash ‡ows across time. In this sense, a repo rate is essentially a …re-sale discount. 3 Carlsson and van Damme (1993) and Morris and Shin (1998) are the pioneering works on global games. 1
more often because lower market liquidity increases coordination risk for them; then more banks will fail which reduces market liquidity, con…rming the creditors’initial beliefs. Our model thus has implications for …nancial fragility at the system level. When the funda- mentals of the aggregate state worsen continuously, the equilibrium outcome may change discon- tinuously. That is, when the fundamentals of the aggregate state worsen to a certain point, there is a regime change from uniqueness to equilibrium multiplicity. Around that critical point, a small decline in the fundamentals can lead to a big jump (to the “bad” equilibrium), which corresponds to a discontinuous drop in market liquidity simultaneously with systemic creditor runs on …nancial institutions. Our paper contributes to understanding ampli…cation and multiplicity in …nancial crises by 1) endogenizing market liquidity, 2) demonstrating two-way feedback between market liquidity and creditor runs, and 3) showing the possibility of multiple equilibria in the system.4 One distinct feature of our model is that we study bank runs in a …nancial system, in which the interim liquidation price of a bank is endogenous and depends on its fundamentals as well as on the market liquidity in the system which in turn endogenously depends on the status of other banks.5 Goldstein and Pauzner (2005) and Rochet and Vives (2004) treat the liquidation price or market liquidity as exogenous and Eisenbach (2017) models the liquidation price as fundamentals–independent. Our model demonstrates the feedback loop between market liquidity and coordination risk, which is related to, but di¤erent from, the feedback loop between market liquidity and margin requirements in Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009). The recent papers of Liu (2016) and Eisenbach (2017) study the interplay between asset prices and creditor runs. However, Eisenbach’s (2017) paper implicitly assumes the existence of a unique equilibrium and does not mention equilibrium multiplicity at all. Liu’s (2016) model, on the other hand, shows equilibrium multiplicity only under the condition that creditors’private information is su¢ ciently noisy, as in the standard global games literature. Our current paper develops a simple and tractable model framework showing the existence of multiple equilibria even when the precision of private signals approaches in…nity. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the model setting. Section 3 presents the model equilibria. Section 4 includes robustness analyses. Section 5 concludes. 4 See the recent survey by Brunnermeier and Oehmke (2013) on …nancial crises and systemic risk. 5 Diamond and Rajan (2005) study banking crises and aggregate liquidity shortages, and there are no coordination issues (panic) among creditors in their model. Allen and Gale (2000) study …nancial contagion through interbank claims and assume that banks face exogenous idiosyncratic liquidity shocks (see also Bhattacharya and Gale (1987)). 2
2 Model Setting There are three dates in the model: t = 0, 1 and 2. We discuss banks, the asset market, and creditor runs, in order. 2.1 Banks There is a continuum of banks with unit mass, indexed by i 2 [0; 1]. At t = 0, each bank invests in one unit of its own assets with the cost being 1. The cost is …nanced from two sources: an amount F comes from a continuum of its creditors with F mass, each one contributing 1, and an amount 1 F comes from its equityholder (bankowner).6 At t = 1, a creditor of a bank has the right to decide whether or not to roll over his lending to the bank. If he decides not to roll over, his claim is the par value 1 at t = 1; if, instead, he decides to roll over, the (promised) notional claim to him is R at t = 2, where R > 1 is the gross interest rate.7 Creditors and bankowners are risk-neutral. The payo¤ of bank i’s assets at t = 2 is vi = i + ei , which follows a normal distribution as in Grossman and Stiglitz (1980). Speci…cally, ei is a random variable with distribution ei N (0; 2) and resolves its uncertainty at t = 2. For simplicity and e without loss of generality, we assume that ei e is perfectly correlated across banks.8 The term i, interpreted as asset quality, has its realization at t = 1, which is independently drawn from an identical distribution N( ; 2) across banks. Denote 1= 2 and 1= 2. i e e Although the asset quality of a bank is realized at t = 1, its creditors are not informed of it. Nevertheless, a creditor of a bank receives imperfect information (a signal) at t = 1 about the asset quality of the bank. Speci…cally, the signal for creditor h of bank i (about asset quality i) at t = 1 is shi = i + s h, where s > 0 is constant, and the individual-speci…c noise h N (0; 1). h is independent across creditors of a bank, and each is independent of 2. i. Denote s 1= s 2.2 Asset Market If a bank su¤ers a creditor run (to be elaborated), its assets must be liquidated or under …re sales at t = 1 in a competitive asset market, which consists of a continuum of competitive investors with 6 We assume that each bank has its own creditor base (for example, these banks are regional banks). 7 Without loss of generality, we normalize the interim notional claim to 1. What matters to the model is the interest rate between t = 1 and t = 2, i.e., the R. 8 As long as ei is correlated across banks to some degree (i.e., not perfectly diversi…ed away), our model results will hold true. In reality, the number of banks is not in…nite; therefore, ei cannot possibly be diversi…ed away even when ei is independent across banks. 3
unit mass. Investor j has utility function U (W j ) = exp Wj ; where W j is the end-of-period wealth at t = 2, and is the risk-aversion (CARA) coe¢ cient. The risk-free (gross) interest rate between t = 1 and t = 2 is normalized as 1. Investors have private information (signals) about banks’asset qualities. Speci…cally, the signal j for investor j about asset quality i at t = 1 is i = i + "ji , where 0 is constant, and the individual-speci…c noise "ji N (0; 1). "ji is independent across assets for a given j and independent across investors for a given i, and each "ji for a given i is independent of i. Suppose that the system has, in total, a mass of ' (2 [0; 1]) of banks su¤ering creditor runs. Then, there are ' units of assets in the system under …re sales.9 Denote by li the liquidation (…re-sale) price of bank i’s assets. 2.3 Creditor Runs li Let us consider a typical bank i. If it has greater than F proportion of its creditors declining to roll over their lending at t = 1, its liquidation value will not be su¢ cient to cover these creditors’ claims, leading to its failure (we call this scenario a “creditor run”). Alternatively, one may think of li as the collateral value of the bank’s assets. This means that the bank can raise at most li amount of cash at t = 1 by using its assets as collateral. If the demand for cash exceeds li at t = 1, the bank will fail. Following the work of Rochet and Vives (2004), we use a simpli…ed payo¤ structure of the creditor-run game. Speci…cally, as in Rochet and Vives (2004), we assume that each creditor of a bank is an institutional investor (a fund), run by its fund manager. A fund manager has the following compensation scheme. If the fund manager calls his fund’s investment at t = 1, his payo¤ is a constant w0 , or the face value 1 multiplied by proportion w0 . This could be because a creditor who calls loans at t = 1 will either fully recover the face value of investment 1 (in the case of bank survival) or su¤er a small loss (in the case of bank failure). If, instead, the fund manager holds the investment at t = 1, he obtains compensation w conditional on his fund’s investment not defaulting (i.e., the investment return is no less than R), where w > w0 . Compensation contingent on non-default captures the reality that “breaking the buck” has severe consequences. A creditor’s payo¤ depends crucially on the actions of other creditors of the same bank. Let denote the proportion of creditors of a bank who choose not to roll over (i.e., choose to call). Then, the payo¤ for a particular creditor is given in Table 1. 9 We will focus on the case of s ! 0. In equilibrium, then, if a bank su¤ers a creditor run, it will liquidate its assets entirely (i.e., no partial liquidation). 4
Total calling proportion 2 [0; Fli ) Total calling proportion 2 [ Fli ; 1] (bank survives) (bank fails ) ! F 1 li i (1 )F R Hold w F 0 1 li e Call w0 w0 Table 1: Creditor-run payo¤ structure If 2 [ Fli ; 1], a creditor run occurs and the bank fails at t = 1; its staying creditors get nothing and thus their fund manager’s compensation is 0 because of the default. If 2 [0; Fli ), the F bank must liquidate li units of its assets to raise cash to pay its F calling creditors. Thus, at F t = 2, 1 li units of assets will remain, the payo¤ distribution of which, conditional on i, is 2 F F F 2 1 li vi N 1 li i; 1 li e . Since the number of staying creditors at t = 2 is (1 ) F , these creditors’total notional claim is (1 ) F R. Hence, the probability ! that the bank F 1 li i (1 )F R will not default to these creditors at t = 2 conditional on i is F , where () 1 li e stands for the c.d.f. of the standard normal and ( ) denotes its p.d.f. By introducing a third party, fund managers, we have a discrete-state payo¤ structure of the creditor-run game. This simpli…ed structure captures the key feature of the creditor-run game: if li the proportion of creditors of a bank calling is higher than F, the optimal strategy for an individual li creditor is to also “call;”if, however, the proportion of creditors calling is less than F, the optimal strategy for an individual creditor is likely to also “hold.”The simpli…cation in the payo¤ structure is a convenient way to deal with the fact that the property of global strategic complementarities fails to exist in a creditor-run game (see Goldstein and Pauzner (2005)).10 For a cleaner and simpler analysis, we follow Morris and Shin (2009) to simplify the payo¤ structure of the creditor-run game in Rochet and Vives (2004). Morris and Shin (2009) assume that “if there is not a run, new creditors will eventually be found and the balance sheet reverts to its initial state after the failed run.” Basically, they are assuming that “the partial liquidation of assets has no long-run e¤ect”(in the language of Vives (2014a)). Concretely, if a bank has less than li F proportion of its creditors calling, partial liquidation will occur but the bank can still survive to t = 2, in which case Morris and Shin (2009) assume that the bank’s balance sheet reverts to its initial state. Essentially, after an unsuccessful run, the asset side of the balance sheet of the bank is restored to vi and the liability side reverts to the total notional debt value F R claimed by F creditors.11 In short, the assumption of Morris and Shin (2009) gives the simpli…ed payo¤ structure 10 See also Dasgupta (2004). Relatedly, He and Xiong (2012) use a staggered debt structure. 11 For example, as long as the bank is still alive (after an unsuccessful run), it can buy back its (partially) liquidated 5
in Table 2. Total calling proportion 2 [0; Fli ) Total calling proportion 2 [ Fli ; 1] (bank survives) (bank fails ) FR Hold w i e 0 Call w0 w0 Table 2: Simpli…ed creditor-run payo¤ structure Notice that Table 2 is identical to Table 1 if we set = 0 for the payo¤ of holding in the case li li of 2 [0; F ). That is, as long as 2 [0; F ), the bank continues as if it had not experienced any withdrawals in Table 2. In the main model, we use the simpli…ed payo¤ function in Table 2. In section 4, we will show that our model results are robust under the alternative payo¤ structure in Table 1. 2.4 Timeline At t = 0, the liability side of the balance sheet of a bank is given by (F , 1 F ) and the contract term (1; R) with the creditors is …xed. At t = 1, creditors move …rst by making their rollover decisions based on their private information shi , and banks move later by conducting asset sales in the asset market based on the total withdrawals requested by their creditors. 3 Equilibrium We focus on the equilibrium at t = 1. At t = 1, creditors need to make their rollover decisions. We are interested in the equilibrium where every creditor uses a threshold (monotone) strategy. The strategy is given by ( Call shi < s shi 7 ! , Hold shi s where shi is the signal received by creditor h of bank i and s is the rollover threshold. Because banks are identical ex ante, we naturally consider the symmetric equilibrium in which creditors of all banks use a common strategy, i.e., the threshold s is not bank-speci…c. We will show that an upper dominance region exists for the bank-run game in our model. The assets with re…nancing from its original withdrawing creditors or new creditors. Alternatively, as long as the total amount of early withdrawals at t = 1 is less than li , the bank is able to raise this amount of cash temporarily (from, for instance, some outside deep-pocketed investors) by using its assets as collateral; new creditors will then eventually be found to replace the withdrawing creditors and the re…nancing amount from the new creditors is used to repay the temporary borrowing. 6
existence of an upper dominance region is because in our model the interim liquidation value of a bank is fundamentals-dependent as in Rochet and Vives (2004).12 3.1 Solving the Equilibrium Formally, we de…ne the equilibrium at t = 1 as follows. De…nition 1 The equilibrium at t = 1 is characterized by triplet (s ; fli g ; '), where s is the rollover threshold for creditors, li is the liquidation price of bank i’s assets, and ' is the total mass of banks under …re sales, such that 1) given creditors’ rational expectations of ', they set their rollover threshold as s ; 2) given the rollover threshold s , the mass of failed banks in the system is '; and 3) given the total …re sales ', the equilibrium price of bank i’s assets in the asset market is li . We derive the equilibrium in three steps. Asset market equilibrium The portfolio choice of an investor in the asset market at t = 1 is given by h n o i j max E exp Wj j i ; fli g (1) fxji g Z s.t. W = j xji (vi li )di, where xji is the quantity of demand for asset i for investor j. As long as the risk of vi (i.e., the term ei ) is correlated across i to some degree or the number of banks is …nite, the risk of payo¤ of the portfolio cannot be completely diversi…ed away. For simplicity and without loss of generality, we have assumed that ei e is perfectly correlated across i. For simplicity, we follow the trading game (mechanism) in Vives (2014b) and Benhabib, Liu and Wang (2016) to focus on the fully-revealing equilibrium of the asset market, i.e., the equilibrium in which …nancial prices fully reveal the fundamentals of the trading assets in the spirit of Hayek (1945). In our context, it is the equilibrium in which f i g is fully revealed to the investors through the …nancial prices.13 12 Goldstein and Pauzner (2005), following the original model of Diamond and Dybvig (1983), assume that the interim liquidation value of a bank is fundamentals-independent, so an upper dominance region does not exist in their model. 13 Alternatively, instead of f i g being fully-revealed through the …nancial prices, we can assume that the precision of investors’ private signals approaches the limit ! 0 as in Morris and Shin (2004b), just as s ! 0 for the precision of creditors’private signals; this would also lead to f i g being perfect information for investors. Note that this part of the model is not a focus of our paper, and we can adopt either alternative. 7
The …rst-order condition of (1) implies that xji = xi for any j (i.e., a representative investor exists and demands xi ), and that Z i li xi di = 2 . e Given that the total mass of banks su¤ering creditor runs is ', the market clearing condition dictates Z xi di = ' . Lemma 1 follows. Lemma 1 The liquidation price of bank i’s assets is given by li = 'k, where k 2 and 'k i e measures market liquidity. Proof. See Appendix. The result of Lemma 1 is in the spirit of Grossman and Miller (1988). When the risk-averse market maker sector is forced to absorb more risky assets, the price of every risky asset is a¤ected and reduced because of the limited risk-absorbing capacity of the market maker sector. It is worth noting that every bank is a price-taker in the liquidation market. In fact, there is a large number of investors in the asset market and each individual investor only holds a tiny amount of a particular bank’s assets in his portfolio, as shown in (1). As in Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009), market liquidity is measured as the degree to which the market price of an asset is depressed away from its fundamental value. Market liquidity in our model is thus measured by the term 'k. That is, …re sales conducted by other banks reduce market liquidity for a particular bank. Creditor-run equilibrium for an individual bank Considering that li is fundamentals ( i )-dependent by Lemma 1, when i is su¢ ciently high, bank i will survive even if every creditor of it withdraws. That is, an upper dominance region exists. Therefore, we only need to focus on threshold equilibria (see Morris and Shin (2003) and Vives (2014a)). Given that all other creditors of a bank use threshold s , the bank when realizing asset quality h s as i has a ( i ; s ) = Pr( i + s < s !) = s i proportion of its creditors withdrawing. Moreover, the bank with realized asset quality i will have its asset liquidation value as li = i 'k. Hence, by the nature of credit runs, the threshold of the bank’s failure, denoted by , is given by 'k s = : (2) F s That is, the bank fails if and only if i < and individual creditors rationally anticipate this. Given the bank’s failure threshold , what is the optimal strategy of an individual creditor? He rolls over if and only if his signal is above threshold s , where s is given by the following indi¤erence 8
condition: 0 1 Z +1 i + s s i FR 1 @ + s + s Ad w q q i = w0 : (3) e 1 1 + s + s When receiving the signal exactly equal to s , the fund manager of the investor has the expected payo¤ on the right-hand side (RHS) of (3) if he chooses to withdraw, and has the payo¤ on the left-hand side (LHS) of (3) if he chooses to roll over: when i < , the bank will fail and thus the fund manager will get nothing; conditional on i , his expected compensation at t = 2 is FR w i e for a given i. We focus on the limiting case of signal precision: s ! 0. Under the limiting case, we prove that the system of equations (2) and (3) is transformed into = s and s 'k s FR w0 = : (4) F } | {z e w | {z } Illiquidity (coordination) risk Insolvency (fundamental) risk The …rst term on the LHS of (4) characterizes the interim illiquidity risk and the second term gives the insolvency risk at the …nal date. The limit s ! 0 also implies that in equilibrium all creditors of a bank are in the same position ex post, i.e., either all of them decide to roll over or none of them does so. This in turn implies that in equilibrium a bank either completely liquidates its assets or does not liquidate any fraction, i.e., there is no partial liquidation. Bank failures in the system Recall that the asset quality distribution across banks in the system at t = 1 is N( ; 2 ). Banks with realized asset quality s survive at t = 1 while i i all others fail. Hence, the total measure of failing banks in the system is given by s '= . (5) Lemma 2 The creditor-run equilibrium in the system at t = 1, given by (s ; '), solves the system of equations (4)-(5) under the limiting case of s ! 0. Two-way feedback exists between market @s @' liquidity ('k) and the creditor-run threshold (s ): @' > 0 in (4) and @s > 0 in (5). Proof. See Appendix. The two-way feedback highlighted in Lemma 2 is intuitive. When creditors run on banks with a higher threshold, more banks in the system will fail, resulting in market liquidity drying up for every bank. Creditors of a bank have rational expectations on this and thus have higher incentives to run in the …rst place. 9
3.2 Characterization of the Equilibrium It is helpful to start by examining two benchmark cases. First, consider the case where the liqui- dation value li is exogenous. In this case, it is easy to show that the creditor-run equilibrium is given by li s FR w0 = ; (6) F |{z} e w | {z } Illiquidity (coordination) risk Insolvency (fundamental) risk which clearly has a unique equilibrium. Proposition 1 follows. Proposition 1 (A single bank with exogenous liquidation value) Under the limiting case of s ! 0, when li is exogenous, the creditor-run equilibrium at t = 1, given by (6), has a unique (threshold) equilibrium. Proof. See Appendix. The uniqueness of equilibrium for runs on a single bank under global games has been well established in the literature. The result in Proposition 1 is essentially the result in Goldstein and Pauzner (2005). Second, consider the case where a bank’s liquidation value li depends on its own fundamentals i, but not on other banks’situation; that is, ' is exogenous. In this case, the creditor-run equilibrium is given by (4) but with an exogenous '. Proposition 2 (A single bank with fundamentals-dependent liquidation value) Under the limiting case of s ! 0, when ' is exogenous, the creditor-run equilibrium at t = 1, given by (4), has a unique equilibrium. In Proposition 2, our paper studies bank runs with a fundamentals-dependent liquidation value and a fundamentals-dependent payo¤ structure (i.e., the system of equations (2) and (3)) and shows the uniqueness of equilibrium under s ! 0. Solving the equilibrium is nontrivial (see the proof of Lemma 2 in Appendix).14 Now we move to study the equilibrium in Lemma 2, that is, there are many banks with a linkage through the asset market. Combining (4) and (5) yields one equation: 1 s s FR w0 s k = : (7) F e w 14 Similar to Morris and Shin (1998), Rochet and Vives (2004) use a fundamentals-dependent liquidation value (with an exogenous market liquidity or “…re-sales penalty”) but a fundamentals-independent payo¤ structure (i.e., the payo¤ for a fund manager conditional on the bank’s survival or failure does not depend on the bank’s asset fundamental value). The model of Eisenbach (2017) assumes physical liquidation, where an asset’s liquidation value does not depend on its fundamentals. 10
The equilibrium at t = 1 is fully characterized by equation (7). Mathematically, the …rst term on the LHS of (7) can be decreasing in s while the second term is increasing in s , so the function on the LHS with respect to s may be non-monotonic and thus multiple solutions to equation (7) are possible. Write the LHS of (7) as function V (s ; k). Figure 1 plots the function under a set of parameter values, where = 1:4, = 0:4, F = 0:8, R = 1:1, and e = 1. Figure 1: Function V (s ; k) Proposition 3 (Banking system with an asset market) Under the limiting case of s ! 0, when k is low enough, the creditor-run equilibrium in the system at t = 1, given by (4)-(5), is unique. When k is su¢ ciently high, there may exist multiple (typically three) equilibria. Proof. See Appendix. Even under the limit s ! 0, multiple equilibria (a self-ful…lling crisis) can still exist, which is in contrast to the classical result of the bank-run game for a single bank. The intuition is the following. The presence of a common asset market gives rise to strategic complementarities between creditors of di¤erent banks, besides the complementarities between creditors of the same bank. That is, there is an increased degree of strategic complementarity between the creditors in the system, which makes equilibrium multiplicity more likely. To put it di¤erently, equilibrium multiplicity under self-ful…lling beliefs can arise because of the two-way feedback between market liquidity ('k) and the rollover threshold (s ) discussed in Lemma 2. The recent papers of Liu (2016) and Eisenbach (2017) study the interplay between asset prices and creditor runs. However, Eisenbach (2017) implicitly assumes the existence of a unique equilib- rium and does not mention equilibrium multiplicity at all. Liu’s (2017) model, on the other hand, having other focuses and purposes, shows equilibrium multiplicity under the condition that private 11
information is su¢ ciently noisy, as in the standard global games literature, and cannot show the existence of multiple equilibria when the precision of private signals approaches in…nity. The mechanism of equilibrium multiplicity in our model is di¤erent from that in Angeletos and Werning (2006) and Hellwig et al. (2006). Importantly, in our model, the timeline is that creditors move …rst and banks move later. At the time when creditors make rollover decisions, they do not observe the liquidation prices. In Angeletos and Werning’s (2006) model, there is a …nancial market in the …rst stage which aggregates the dispersed private information of agents, and the endogenous …nancial price is observable by and serves as a public signal for agents who play the currency-crises game in the second stage. When the precision of the private signals of agents increases, the precision of the endogenous public signal can increase even faster, which results in equilibrium multiplicity. Similarly, in Hellwig et al. (2006), the …nancial price — the interest rate — aggregates private information, as well as having direct e¤ects on the traders’payo¤s. The mechanism in our model is instead that the presence of an asset market with endogenous market liquidity increases strategic complementarity between creditors. We have comparative statics with respect to .15 Corollary 1 follows. Corollary 1 The lower the , the more likely the equilibrium multiplicity. Proof. See Appendix. 3.3 Implications for Ampli…cation Multiplicity For simplicity and to illustrate the point, here we can borrow the setup of Liu (2016). Basically, there are three aggregate states at t = 1 with a positive probability for each: “Normal” state, “Slightly Bad” state (small-sized shock), and “Bad” state (medium-sized shock). The better the aggregate state, the higher the realization of (i.e., …rst-order stochastic dominance). Speci…cally, N > S > M, where N, S and M denote the realization of for “Normal” state, “Slightly Bad” state and “Bad” state, respectively. Ex ante, at t = 0, the contract terms with creditors as well as other arrangements are set based on the preparation for the occurrence of the “average” of the three states at t = 1. Now we ask what happens if the “Slightly Bad”state or the “Bad”state actually occurs at t = 1. Proposition 4 (Ampli…cation by Multiplicity) Under the limiting case of s ! 0, it is possible that for the “Slightly Bad” state ( = S) there exists a unique equilibrium while for the “Bad” state ( = M) there are multiple equilibria. Proof. See Appendix. 15 may measure the heterogeneity of assets across banks. Liu (2017), studying bank diversi…cation, endogenizes the heterogeneity across banks. 12
Proposition 4 gives the implication for ampli…cation multiplicity. When a negative shock to is small enough ( = S ), ampli…cation (with the feedback loop) is on a given equilibrium. When the negative shock is big enough ( = M ), there is also a regime change from uniqueness to equilibrium multiplicity, so there may be a jump from one equilibrium to another. Note that function V is increasing in , so a decrease in shifts the solid curve in Figure 1 downward. Figure 2 illustrates ampli…cation multiplicity. Rewrite the LHS of (7) as V (s i ; s ; ) = n h io 1 i s s i FR F s k e . Hence, the solution with respect to s i to equation V (s i ; s ; ) = w0 w gives the best response function s i = r (s ; ). Figure 2 plots the best response function, where di¤erent curves correspond to di¤erent . Suppose that the equilibrium is initially at Point A. When the “Slightly Bad” state ( = S) is realized, the equilibrium is still unique. In contrast, when the “Bad”state ( = M) is realized, the equilibrium goes from A to either B (through the 0 feedback loop of ampli…cation) or B (through a multicity jump).16 That is, when the fundamentals of the aggregate state worsen continuously, the equilibrium outcome may change discontinuously. Figure 2: Ampli…cation Multiplicity When the “Bad” state ( = M) is realized, multiple self-ful…lling equilibria can exist, which gives rise to the role of an ex-post regulatory intervention. For example, to eliminate the ine¢ cient equilibrium, the government can announce and commit to supporting asset prices in the asset market as long as the proportion of failing banks in the system exceeds ' (or equivalently the risk premium is higher than 'k).17 This would su¢ ciently change creditors’ expectation and thereby 16 The new curve after the shock has three intersections with the 450 line. The middle intersection corresponds to an unstable equilibrium. The other two correspond to stable equilibria. 17 In the recent crisis, the Federal Reserve adopted unconventional policies through lending to …nancial institutions, providing liquidity directly to key credit markets, and purchasing long-term securities (Bernanke (2009)). 13
coordinate the agents to the e¢ cient equilibrium. 4 Robustness In this section, we conduct two robustness analyses. 4.1 A Single Bank with a Downward-sloping Liquidation Price Alternatively suppose there is only one bank, and when it liquidates its assets, it faces a downward- sloping demand curve. We show that in this case the creditor-run equilibrium is unique. Speci…cally, assume that the demand function of the bank’s assets (totally one unit) is p = f (q), where q is the quantity of selling and p is the price. Let the revenue function of selling be (q) = pq = f (q)q. Without loss of generality, it is reasonable to assume that 0( ) > 0 for q 2 [0; 1]. Then, (2) is replaced by (1) s = : (8) F s (8)-(3) together gives the creditor-run equilibrium. Hence, like the case of the liquidation value li being exogenous in Proposition 1, the equilibrium is unique. 4.2 Alternative Creditor-run Payo¤ Structure Suppose we use the payo¤ structure in Table 1 instead of the one in Table 2. Under this alternative payo¤ structure, we prove in Appendix that (4) is replaced by 0 1 Z s 'k 1 F s (1 )FR s 'k A d = w0 . F @ (9) 0 1 F w s 'k e Notice that if we set = 0 inside the integral, (9) becomes identical to (4). We prove in Appendix that the following key property of (4) in Lemma 2 remains for (9): @s > 0: @' Therefore, under the alternative payo¤ structure, the results of the model change only quantita- tively, not qualitatively. 14
5 Conclusion This paper presents a simple global-games model that features a banking system with endogenous market liquidity. We show that multiple equilibria can exist even when the precision of creditors’ private signals approaches in…nity. Our paper aids in explaining ampli…cation and multiplicity in …nancial crises and also contributes to the theoretical literature on bank runs with global games. Our model framework may also be useful for future work studying bank runs in a …nancial system. 15
Appendix A Proofs Proof of Lemma 1: Considering that the price li fully reveals the fundamentals i (see the trading mechanism in Vives (2014) and Benhabib, Liu and Wang (2016)), an investor does not rely on his private information in trading. Hence, all investors are basically the same (as a representative investor). Thus, the objective function of (1) can be transformed into maximizing Z Z 1 xi ( i li )di V ar e xi di 2 Z Z 2 1 2 = xi ( i li )di xi di : 2 e The …rst-order condition with respect to any xi implies Z 2 ( i li )di e xi di di = 0; R li R that is, xi di = i 2 . Because xi di = ' by the market clearing condition, we have li = i 'k, e where k 2. e Proof of Lemma 2: Combining (2) and (3), we have 0 1 Z +1 i + s s i FR 1 @ + s + s Ad w0 q q i = , (A.1) i= e 1 1 w + s + s 'k s 1 'k where is given by the implicit function F = s or s = + s F . Write the LHS of (A.1) as Y (s ; s ). We transform Y (s ; s) by changing variables to z = + s s i + s + s q 1 and obtain + s 0q 1 Z 1 1 z+ + s s FR + s + s + s Y (s ; s) = @ A (z) dz, z=z0 e 16
where z0 satis…es the joint equations 1 'k s = + s F = i i + s + + s s s z= q : 1 + s z=z0 That is, z0 satis…es 1 i 'k s = i + s ; (A.2) F q 1 with i = + s + s + s s + z0 + s . Plugging the above expression of i into (A.2), we can express z0 by an implicit function 0 q 1 1 + s s + z0 'k + s (s ) s 1@ + s + s + s A. z0 = q q 1 1 F + s + s So it follows that 1 s 'k lim z0 = : s !0 F Thus, under the limit s ! 0 for a given , we have = s and Z 1 s FR lim Y (s ; s) = (z) dz s !0 e 1 s 'k F s FR s 'k = : e F Hence, (4) is proved. We also need to prove that a creditor rolls over when his signal is higher than s and otherwise withdraws. An individual creditor takes as given. Writing the LHS of (A.1) as Y~ (s ) and + s s i + s + s changing variables to z = q 1 , we obtain + s 0q 1 Z +1 1 z+ + s s FR + s + s + s Y~ (s ) = + s @ A (z) dz. + s + ss z= r e 1 + s We have @ Y~ (s ) =@s > 0. @' @s It is straightforward to show that @s > 0 in (5). As for @' > 0 in (4), write the LHS of @ Y^ s 'k @ Y^ (4) as function Y^ (s ; ') and we have @s = F 1 s FR e + F s FR e 1 e > 0 and @' = k s FR @s @ Y^ @ Y^ F e < 0, and thus @' = @' = @s > 0. 17
Proof of Proposition 1: If the liquidation value li is exogenous, (2) is replaced by li s = : (A.3) F s Similar to the prove of Lemma 1, under the limit s ! 0 for a given , (2)-(3) together will give = s and (6). Proofs of Proposition 3 and Corollary 1: Write the LHS of (7) as function V (s ), where 1 s s FR V (s ) = s k . F e It is easy to show that @V (s ) @s 1 s k s FR 1 s s FR 1 = 1 + s k . F e F e e (A.4) @V (s ) @V (s ) When k ! 0, @s > 0 holds for any s ; when k is small enough, @s > 0 also holds for any w0 s , so V (s ) = w has a unique solution with respect to s . @V (s ) w0 When k is high enough, @s < 0 at some s , so V (s ) is non-monotonic and thus V (s ) = w can admit multiple (typically three) solutions with respect to s . Speci…cally, consider the case where k is high enough, is low enough, and is slightly higher than F R, ceteris paribus. So @V (s ) @V (s ) @s js = < 0, and @s > 0 when s is su¢ ciently far away from (i.e., lower or higher than) . That is, V (s ) is increasing in s initially, and then decreasing in s around s = , and w0 then increasing in s again, as the solid curve in Figure 1 depicts. Thus, for some w , equation w0 V (s ) = w admits three solutions. 1 @V (s ) Clearly, from (A.4), has a similar e¤ect to k. That is, when is big enough, @s >0 w0 also holds for any s , so V (s ) = w has a unique solution with respect to s . When is small @V (s ) w0 enough, @s < 0 at some s , so V (s ) is non-monotonic and thus V (s ) = w can admit multiple (typically three) solutions with respect to s . Proof of Proposition 4: Note that V (s ; ) is increasing in . Hence, when is high enough, w0 w0 it is possible that V (s ) = w has a unique solution; when is low enough, V (s ) = w can have multiple solutions. 18
Proof in Section 4.2: Under the alternative payo¤ structure in Table 1, equation (3) is replaced by the following equation: ! + s s 0h i h i 1 i + s q + s Z +1 1 F s i i 1 s i FR 1 li s s + s w @ h i A q d i = w0 ; F s 1 1 li s i e + s (A.5) h s by considering Table 1 and ( i ; s ) = Pr( i + s
References [1] Allen, Franklin and Douglas Gale (2000). Financial Contagion, Journal of Political Economy, 108, 1-31. [2] Angeletos, George-Marios and Ivan Werning (2006). Crises and Prices: Information Aggrega- tion, Multiplicity, and Volatility, American Economic Review 96, 5, 1720-1736. [3] Benhabib, Jess, Xuewen Liu and Pengfei Wang (2016). Sentiments, Financial Markets, and Macroeconomic Fluctuations, Journal of Financial Economics, 120 (2), 420-443. [4] Bernanke, Ben (2010). Causes of the Recent Financial and Economic Crisis, Statement before the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, Washington, September 2. [5] Bhattacharya, Sudipto and Douglas Gale (1987). Preference Shocks, Liquidity and Central Bank Policy, in W. Barnett and K. Singleton, eds., New Approaches to Monetary Economics, Cambridge University Press, 69-88. [6] Brunnermeier, Markus (2009). Deciphering the Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007-2008, Jour- nal of Economic Perspectives, 23, 1, 77-100. [7] Brunnermeier, Markus and Martin Oehmke (2013). Bubbles, Financial Crises, and Systemic Risk, Handbook of the Economics of Finance. Amsterdam: Elsevier. [8] Brunnermeier, Markus and Lasse Pedersen (2009). Market Liquidity and Funding Liquidity, Review of Financial Studies, 22, 6, 2201-2238. [9] Carlsson, Hans and Eric van Damme (1993). Global Games and Equilibrium Selection, Econo- metrica, 61, 5, 989-1018. [10] Christian Hellwig, Arijit Mukherji, and Aleh Tsyvinski (2006). Self-Ful…lling Currency Crisis: The Role of Interest Rates, American Economic Review, 96, 5, 1769–1787. [11] Covitz, Daniel, Nellie Liang and Gustavo Suarez (2013). The Evolution of a Financial Crisis: Collapse of the Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Market, Journal of Finance, 68 (3), 815-848. [12] Dasgupta, Amil (2004). Financial Contagion through Capital Connections: A Model of the Origin and Spread of Bank Panics, Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(6), 1049- 1084. [13] Diamond, Douglas and Philip Dybvig (1983). Bank runs, Deposit Insurance and Liquidity, Journal of Political Economy, 91, 401-19. [14] Diamond, Douglas and Raghuram Rajan (2005). Liquidity Shortages and Banking Crises, Journal of Finance, 60(2), 615-647. [15] Eisenbach, Thomas (2017). Rollover Risk as Market Discipline: A Two-Sided Ine¢ ciency, Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming. [16] Gertler, Mark, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki and Andrea Prestipino (2017), A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics, mimeo. [17] Gorton, Gary (2010). Slapped by the Invisible Hand: The Panic of 2007, Oxford: Oxford University Press. 20
[18] Goldstein, Itay and Ady Pauzner (2005). Demand Deposit Contracts and the Probability of Bank Runs, Journal of Finance, 60, 1293-1328. [19] Gorton, Gary and Andrew Metrick (2011). Securitized Banking and the Run on Repo, Journal of Financial Economics, 104(3), 425-451. [20] Grossman, Sanford and Merton Miller (1988). Liquidity and Market Structure, Journal of Finance 43, 617–633. [21] Grossman, Sanford and Joseph Stiglitz (1980). On the Impossibility of Informationally E¢ cient Markets, American Economic Review, 70, 3, 393-408. [22] He, Zhiguo and Wei Xiong (2012). Dynamic Bank Runs, Review of Financial Studies, 25, 1799-1843. [23] Krishnamurthy, Arvind, Stefan Nagel and Dmitry Orlov (2014), “Sizing Up Repo”, Journal of Finance, 69 (6), 2381–2417. [24] Liu, Xuewen (2016). Interbank Market Freezes and Creditor Runs, Review of Financial Studies, 29(7), 1860-1910. [25] Liu, Xuewen (2017). Diversi…cation and Systemic Bank Panics, mimeo. [26] Morris, Stephen and Hyun Song Shin (1998). Unique Equilibrium in a Model of Self-Ful…lling Currency Attacks, American Economic Review, 88, 3, 587-597. [27] Morris, Stephen and Hyun Song Shin (2003). Global games: theory and application. In Ad- vances in economics and econometrics, 56–114. Eds. M. Dewatripont, L. Hansen, and S. Turnovsky. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [28] Morris, Stephen and Hyun Song Shin (2004a). Coordination Risk and the Price of Debt, European Economic Review, 48, 1, 133-153. [29] Morris, Stephen and Hyun Song Shin (2004b). Liquidity Black Holes, Review of Finance, 8, 1-18. [30] Morris, Stephen and Hyun Song Shin (2009). Illiquidity Component of Credit Risk, mimeo. Available at: http://www.princeton.edu/~smorris/pdfs/IlliquidityComponent%2003May2009.pdf. [31] Rochet, Jean-Charles and Xavier Vives (2004). Coordination Failures and the Lender of Last Resort: Was Bagehot Right After All?, Journal of the European Economic Association, 2, 6, 1116-1147. [32] Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert Vishny (1992). Liquidation Values and Debt Capacity: A Market Equilibrium Approach, Journal of Finance, 47(4): 1343–66. [33] Vives, Xavier (2014a). Strategic Complementarity, Fragility, and Regulation, Review of Finan- cial Studies, 27, 12, 3547-3592. [34] Vives, Xavier (2014b). On The Possibility Of Informationally E¢ cient Markets, Journal of the European Economic Association, 12(5), 1200-1239. 21
You can also read