Inflation and monetary policy in the twentieth century
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Inflation and monetary policy in the twentieth century Lawrence J. Christiano and Terry J. Fitzgerald Introduction and summary the early part of the century behave quite differently Economists continue to debate the causes of inflation. in many ways from the data we are accustomed to study- One reason for this is that bad economic outcomes are ing. In particular, we emphasize four differences be- frequently accompanied by anomalous inflation behav- tween the pre- and post-war data:4 ior. The worst economic performance in the U.S. in the ■ Inflation is much more volatile, and less persistent, twentieth century occurred during the Great Depression in the first half of the twentieth century. of the 1930s, and there was a pronounced deflation at ■ Average inflation is lower in the first half of the that time. Economic performance in the U.S. in the century. 1970s was also weak, and that was associated with a pronounced inflation. ■ Money growth and inflation are coincident in the So, what is it that makes inflation sometimes high first half of the century, while inflation lags money and sometimes low? In one sense, there is widespread by about two years in the second half. agreement. Most economists think that inflation cannot ■ Finally, inflation and unemployment are strongly be unusually high or low for long, without the fuel of negatively related in the first half of the century, high or low money growth.1 But, this just shifts the ques- while in the second half a positive relationship tion back one level. What accounts for the anomalous emerges, at least in the lower frequency components behavior of money growth? of the data. Academic economists attempting to understand These shifts in the behavior of inflation constitute the dynamics of inflation pursue a particular strategy. potentially valuable input in the quest for a good model. They start by studying the dynamic characteristics of The outline of our article is as follows. To set the inflation data, as well as of related variables. These char- background, we begin with a brief, very selective, over- acteristics represent a key input into building and re- view of existing theories about inflation. We divide the fining a model of the macroeconomy. The economist’s set of theories into two groups: those that focus on model must not only do a good job in capturing the be- “people” and those that focus on “institutions.” We havior of the private economy, but it must also explain describe the very different implications that each group the behavior of monetary authorities. The hoped-for final of theories has for policy. We then turn to documenting product of this research is a model that fits the facts the facts listed above. After that, we review the implica- well. Implicit in such a model is an “explanation” of tions of the facts for theories. We focus in particular the behavior of inflation, as well as a prescription for on the institution view. According to this view, what what is to be done to produce better outcomes.2 To date, much research has focused on data from the period since World War II. For example, considerable Lawrence J. Christiano is a professor of economics at attention and controversy have been focused on the Northwestern University, a research fellow at the National apparent inflation “inertia” in these data: the fact that Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), and a consultant to the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. He acknowledges inflation seems to respond only with an extensive delay support from a National Science Foundation grant to the to exogenous shifts in monetary policy.3 We argue that NBER. Terry J. Fitzgerald is a professor of economics at much can be learned by incorporating data from the St. Olaf College and a consultant to the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. first half of the century into the analysis. The data from 22 1Q/2003, Economic Perspectives
is crucial to achieving good inflation outcomes is the Another explanation of the high inflation of the proper design of monetary policy institutions. Our dis- 1970s that falls into what we call the people category cussion reviews ideas initially advanced by Kydland appears in Clarida, Gali, and Gertler (1998). They char- and Prescott (1977) and later developed further by Barro acterize monetary policy using a framework advocated and Gordon (1983a, b), who constructed a beautifully by Taylor (1993): Fed policy implements a “Taylor rule” simple model for expositing the ideas. We show that under which it raises interest rates when expected in- the Barro–Gordon model does very well at understand- flation is high, and lowers them when expected infla- ing the second and fourth facts above concerning in- tion is low. According to Clarida, Gali, and Gertler, flation in the twentieth century.5 We also discuss the the Fed’s mistake in the 1970s was to implement a ver- well-known fact that that model has some difficulty sion of the Taylor rule in which interest rates were in addressing the disinflation that occurred in the U.S. moved too little in response to movements in expected in the 1980s. This and other considerations motivate inflation. They argue that this type of mistake can ac- us to turn to modern representations of the ideas of count for the inflation take-off that occurred in the U.S. Kydland–Prescott and Barro–Gordon. While this work in the 1970s.6 In effect the root of the problem in the is at an early stage, it does contain some surprises and 1970s lay in a bad Taylor rule. According to the insti- may lead to improved theories that provide a better tution view, limitations on central bankers’ technical explanation of the inflation facts. knowledge about the mechanics of avoiding high in- flation are not the key reason for the bad inflation out- Ideas about inflation: People versus comes that have occurred in the past. This view institutions implicitly assumes that achieving a given inflation Economists are currently pursuing several theories target over the medium run is not a problem from a for understanding inflation behavior. However, the technical standpoint. The problem, according to this theories are still in their infancy and are best thought view, has to do with central bankers’ incentives to keep of as “prototypes”: They are too simple to be credibly inflation on track and the role of government institu- thought of as fitting the facts well. Although these re- tions in shaping those incentives. search programs are still at an early stage, it is possible to The institution view—initiated by Kydland and see two visions emerging. Each has different implications Prescott (1977) and further developed by Barro and for what needs to be done to achieve better inflation out- Gordon (1983a, b)—focuses on a particular vulnera- comes. To understand what is at stake in this research, bility of central banks in democratic societies (see it is interesting to sketch the different visions. Our loose figure 1). If people expect inflation to be high (A), they names for the competing visions are the people vision may take protective actions (B), which have the effect on the one hand and the institution vision on the other. of placing the central bank in a dilemma. On the one Although it is not the case that all research neatly falls hand, it can accommodate the inflationary expectations into one or the other of these categories, they are never- with high money growth (C). This has the cost of pro- theless useful for spelling out the issues. ducing inflation, but the advantage of avoiding a re- Under the people vision, bad inflation outcomes cession. On the other hand, the central bank can keep of the past reflect the honest mistakes of well-mean- money growth low and prevent the inflation that people ing central bankers trying to do what is inherently a expect from occurring (D). This has the cost of pro- very difficult job. For example, Orphanides (1999) ducing a recession, but the benefit that inflation does has argued that the high inflation of the 1970s reflects not increase. Central bankers in a democratic society that policymakers viewed the low output of the time will be tempted to accommodate (that is, choose C) as a cyclical phenomenon, something monetary poli- when confronted with this dilemma. If people think cy could and should correct. However, in retrospect this is the sort of central bank they have, this increas- we now know that the poor economic performance of es the likelihood that A will occur in the first place. the time reflected a basic productivity slowdown that So, what is at stake in these two visions, the people was beyond the power of the central bank to control. vision versus the institution vision? Each has different According to Orphanides, real-time policymakers under implications for what should or should not be done to a mistaken impression about the sources of the slow- prevent bad inflation outcomes in the future. The people down did their best to heat up the economy with high vision implies that more and better research is need- money growth. To their chagrin, they got only high ed to reduce the likelihood of repeating past mistakes. inflation and no particular improvement to the econ- This research focuses more on the technical, opera- omy. From this perspective, the high inflation of the tional aspect of monetary policy. For example, research 1970s was a blunder. motivated by the Clarida, Gali, and Gertler argument Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 23
FIGURE 1 Central banker in a democratic society Accommodate inflation expectations with high money growth: Get inflation, but avoid recession (C) Private They take Central individuals protective bank expect inflation actions (B) faces to rise (A) dilemma Do not accommodate inflation expectations: Avoid inflation, but produce recession (D) focuses on improvements in the design of the Taylor rule the dataset into the periods before and after 1960. To to ensure that it does not become part of the problem. The better characterize the movements in the data, we break institutional perspective, not surprisingly, asks how better the data down into different frequency components. to design the institutions of monetary policy to achieve The techniques for doing this, reviewed in Christiano better outcomes. This type of work contemplates the con- and Fitzgerald (1998), build on the observation that sequences of, say, a legal change that makes low infla- any data series of length, say T, can be represented tion the sole responsibility of the Federal Reserve. Other exactly as the sum of T/2 artificial data series exhibiting possibilities are the type of employment contracts tried in different frequencies of oscillation. Each data series New Zealand, which penalize the central bank governor has two parameters: One controls the amplitude of for poor inflation outcomes. The basic idea of this liter- fluctuation and the other, phase. The parameters are ature is to prevent scenarios like A in figure 1 from occur- chosen so that the sum over all the artificial data series ring, by convincing private individuals that the central precisely reproduces the original data. Adding over bank would not choose C in the event that A did occur. just the data series whose frequencies lie inside the In this article, we start by presenting data on infla- business cycle range of frequencies yields the business tion and unemployment and documenting how those cycle component of the original data. We define the data changed before and after the 1960s. We argue that business cycle frequencies as those that correspond to these data are tough for standard versions of theories fluctuations with period between two and eight years. that there is a time consistency problem in monetary We also consider a lower frequency component of the policy. We then discuss whether there may be other ver- data, corresponding to fluctuations with period between sions of these theories that do a better job at explain- eight and 20 years. We consider a very low frequency ing the facts. component of the data, which corresponds to fluctua- tions with period of oscillation between 20 and 40 years. The data Finally, for the post-1960 data when quarterly and This section describes the basic data on inflation monthly observations are available, we also consider the and related variables and documents the observations high frequency component of the data, which is com- listed in the introduction. First, we study the relation- posed of fluctuations with period less than two years.7 ship between unemployment and inflation; then we We begin by analyzing the data from the first part turn to money growth and inflation. of the century. The raw data are displayed in figure 2, panel A. That figure indicates that there is a negative Unemployment and inflation relationship between inflation and unemployment. This To show the difference between data in the first is confirmed by examining the scatter plot of inflation and second parts of the twentieth century, we divide and unemployment in figure 2, panel B, which also 24 1Q/2003, Economic Perspectives
shows a negative relationship (that is, a Phillips curve).8 We can formalize and quantify our impressions The regression line displayed in figure 2, panel B high- based on casual inspection of the raw data using fre- lights this negative relationship.9 Figure 2, panels C, quency components of the data, as reported in figure 3, D, and E exhibit the different frequency components panels C–F. Thus, the frequency ranges corresponding of the data. Note that a negative relationship is appar- to periods of oscillation between two months and 20 ent at all frequency components. The contemporaneous years (see figure 3, panels C–E) are characterized by a correlations between different frequency components noticeable Phillips curve. Table 1 shows that the corre- of the inflation and unemployment data are reported lation in the range of high frequencies (when available) in table 1. In each case, the number in parentheses is and in the business cycle frequencies is significantly a p-value for measuring whether the indicated corre- negative. The correlation between inflation and unem- lation is statistically different from zero. For example, ployment is also negative in the 8–20 year range, but a p-value less than 0.05 indicates that the indicated it is not statistically significantly different from zero correlation is statistically different from zero at the 5 in this case. Presumably, this reflects the relative paucity percent level.10 The negative correlation in the business of information about these frequencies in the post-1960s cycle frequencies is particularly significant. data. Finally, figure 3, panel F indicates that the cor- We analyze the post-1960 monthly inflation and relation between 20 and 40 year components is now unemployment data in figure 3, panels A–F.11 There is positive, with unemployment lagging inflation. These a sense in which these data look similar to what we results are consistent with the hypothesis that the Phillips saw for the early period, but there is another sense in curve changed relatively little in the 2–20 year frequency which their behavior is quite different. To see the simi- range, and that the changes that did occur are primarily larity, note from the raw data in figure 3, panel A that concentrated in the very low frequencies. Formal tests for frequencies in the neighborhood of the business of this hypothesis, shown in table B1 in box 1, fail to cycle, inflation and unemployment covary negatively. reject it. That is, the Phillips curve seems to be a pronounced Some of the observations reported above have been feature of the higher frequency component of the data. reported previously. For example, the low-frequency At the same time, the Phillips curve appears to have observations on unemployment have been document- vanished in the very lowest frequencies. The data in ed using other methods in Barro (1987, Chapter 16). figure 3, panel A show a slow trend rise in unemploy- Also, similar frequency extraction methods have been ment throughout the 1960s and 1970s, which is reversed used to detect the presence of the Phillips curve in the starting in early 1983. A similar pattern occurs in in- business cycle frequency range.13 What has not been doc- flation, though the turnaround in inflation begins in umented is how far the Phillips curve extends into the April 1980, roughly three years before the turnaround lowest frequencies. In addition, we show that inflation in unemployment. The low frequency component of leads unemployment in the lowest frequency range. the data dominates in the scatter plot of inflation versus Finally, we noted in the introduction that inflation unemployment, exhibited in figure 3, panel B. That in the early part of the century was more volatile and figure suggests that the relationship between inflation less persistent than in the second part. We can see this and unemployment is positive, in contrast with the by comparing figure 2, panel A with figure 3, panel A. pre-1960s data, which suggest otherwise (see figure 2, We can see the observation on volatility by compar- panel B).12 ing the scales on the inflation portion of the graphs. TABLE 1 CPI inflation and unemployment correlations High Business cycle 8–20 20–40 Sample frequency frequency years years 1900–60 (annual) –0.57 (0.00) –0.32 (0.19) –0.51 (0.23) 1961–97 (annual) –0.38 (0.11) –0.16 (0.41) 0.45 (0.32) 1961:Q2–97:Q4 (quarterly) –0.37 (0.00) –0.65 (0.00) –0.30 (0.29) 0.25 (0.34) 1961, Jan.–97, Dec. (monthly) –0.24 (0.00) –0.69 (0.00) –0.27 (0.30) 0.23 (0.40) Notes: Contemporaneous correlation over indicated sample periods and frequencies. Numbers in parentheses are p-values, in decimals, against the null hypothesis of zero correlation at all frequencies. For further details, see the text and notes 7 and 10. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 25
FIGURE 2 Unemployment and inflation, 1900–60 A. The unemployment rate and the inflation rate C. Frequency of 2 to 8 years percent percent 25 18 6 Inflation 10 Unemployment (right scale) (left scale) 13 4 20 5 Inflation 8 2 15 (right scale) 0 3 0 10 -5 -2 -2 5 Unemployment -10 -7 -4 (left scale) 0 -12 -6 -15 1900 ’10 ’20 ’30 ’40 ’50 ’60 1900 ’10 ’20 ’30 ’40 ’50 ’60 B. Unemployment versus inflation D. Frequency of 8 to 20 years inflation percent 20 6 8 Unemployment (left scale) 6 15 4 4 10 2 2 5 0 0 0 -2 -2 -5 -4 -4 Inflation -10 -6 -6 (right scale) -15 -8 -8 0 5 10 15 20 25 1900 ’10 ’20 ’30 ’40 ’50 ’60 unemployment E. Frequency of 20 to 40 years percent 8 8 Inflation Unemployment 6 6 (right scale) (left scale) 4 4 2 2 0 0 -2 -2 -4 -4 -6 -6 -8 1900 ’10 ’20 ’30 ’40 ’50 ’60 Note: Shaded areas indicate recessions as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research. The black line indicates inflation and the green line indicates unemployment. Source: Authors’ calculations based upon data from the U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 26 1Q/2003, Economic Perspectives
FIGURE 3 Unemployment and inflation, 1960–99 A. The unemployment rate and the inflation rate D. Frequency of 1.5 to 8 years percent percent 11 14 2.0 6 10 12 1.5 Unemployment 4 9 1.0 (left scale) Unemployment 10 Inflation (left scale) 8 (right scale) 0.5 2 8 7 0.0 6 6 -0.5 0 4 5 -1.0 Inflation -2 2 (right scale) 4 -1.5 3 0 -2.0 -4 1959 ’64 ’69 ’74 ’79 ’84 ’89 ’94 ’99 1959 ’64 ’69 ’74 ’79 ’84 ’89 ’94 ’99 B. Unemployment versus inflation E. Frequency of 8 to 20 years inflation percent 15 1.5 3 Unemployment (left scale) 1.0 2 12 0.5 1 9 0.0 0 6 -0.5 -1 3 -1.0 -2 Inflation (right scale) 0 -1.5 -3 3 5 7 9 11 1959 ’64 ’69 ’74 ’79 ’84 ’89 ’94 ’99 unemployment C. Frequency of 2 months to 1.5 years F. Frequency of 20 to 40 years percent percent 0.6 15 1.2 1.5 Unemployment 0.4 (left scale) 0.8 Inflation 1.0 10 (right scale) 0.2 0.4 0.5 5 0.0 0.0 0.0 0 -0.2 -0.4 -0.5 Inflation -5 Unemployment -0.4 -0.8 -1.0 (right scale) (left scale) -0.6 -10 -1.2 -1.5 1959 ’64 ’69 ’74 ’79 ’84 ’89 ’94 ’99 1959 ’64 ’69 ’74 ’79 ’84 ’89 ’94 ’99 Note: Shaded areas indicate recessions as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research. The black line indicates inflation and the green line indicates unemployment. Source: Authors’ calculations based upon data from the U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 27
In the early period, the scale extends from –12 percent observe in the higher frequencies. Figure 5, panels D to +18 percent, at an annual rate. In the later sample, and E show how the variables are so far out of phase the scale extends over a smaller range, from 0 percent in the business cycle and lower frequencies that they to 14 percent. In addition, the inflation data in the early actually have a negative relationship. The strong pos- period are characterized by sharp movements followed itive and contemporaneous relationship between the very almost immediately by reversals in the other direction. low frequency components of the data that we noticed By contrast, in the later dataset, movements in infla- in figure 5, panel A, is quite evident in panel F. tion in one direction are less likely to be reversed im- mediately by movements in the other direction. Implications of the evidence for macroeconomic models Money growth and inflation The differences in the time series behavior of in- We report our results for money growth and infla- flation in the first and second parts of the last century tion in detail in Christiano and Fitzgerald (2003), so here offer a potentially valuable source of information on we just summarize the findings. We display these re- the underlying mechanisms that drive inflation. For sults in figure 4, panels A–E and figure 5, panels A–F. example, in the introduction, we talked about the re- The style of analysis is much the same as for the un- cent literature that focuses on explaining the apparent employment and inflation data. inertia in inflation: the tendency for inflation to respond Consider the data from the early part of the cen- slowly to shocks. These findings are based on analysis tury first. Figure 4, panel A shows that money growth of data from the second half of the century. We sus- (M2) and inflation move together very closely. The re- pect that similar analysis of data for the first part of lationship appears to be essentially contemporaneous. the century would find less inertia. This is because we This impression of a positive relationship is confirmed saw that inflation is less persistent in the early sample, by the scatter plot between inflation and money growth and its movements are more contemporaneous with in figure 4, panel B. To the eye, the positive relation- movements in money. These observations provide a ship in figure 4, panel A appears to be a feature of all potentially important clue about how the private econ- the frequency components of the data. This is confirmed omy is put together: Whatever accounts for inflation in figure 4, panels C–E. Here we see the various fre- inertia in the second part of the century must be some- quency components of the data and how closely the thing that was absent in the first part. For example, some data move together in each of them. have argued that frictions in the wage-setting process Now consider the data from the later part of the cen- and variability in the rate of utilization of capital have tury. The raw data are reported in figure 5, panel A. The the potential to account for the inflation inertia in post- differences between these data in the early and late parts war data.14 If this is right, then wage-setting frictions of the century are dramatic. At first glance, it may must be smaller in the early sample, or there must have appear that the two variables, which moved together been greater limitations on the opportunities to achieve so closely in the early sample, are totally unrelated in short-term variation in the utilization rate of capital. the late sample. On closer inspection, the differences The remainder of this section focuses on the change do not seem so great after all. Thus, in the very low in the relationship between inflation and unemploy- frequencies there does still appear to be a positive re- ment. At first glance, the change appears to lend sup- lationship. Note how money growth generally rises in port to the institutions view of inflation, as captured the first part of the late sample, and then falls in the in the work of Kydland and Prescott (1977) and Barro second part. Inflation follows a similar pattern. It is and Gordon (1983a, b). A second glance suggests the in the higher frequencies that the relationship seems evidence is not so supportive after all. Therefore, we to have changed the most. Whereas in the early sample, begin with a brief review of the Barro-Gordon model. the relationship between the two variables appeared to be contemporaneous, now there seems to be a sig- Barro–Gordon model nificant lag. High money growth is not associated im- The model comprises two basic relationships. The mediately with high inflation, but instead is associated first summarizes the private economy. The second sum- with high inflation several years later. These observa- marizes the behavior of the monetary authority. The tions, which are evident in the raw data, are confirmed private economy is captured by the expectations-aug- by figure 5, panels B–F. Thus, panel B shows the mented Phillips curve, originally associated with scatter plot between money growth and inflation, which Friedman (1968) and Phelps (1967): exhibits a positive relationship. Clearly, this positive relationship is dominated by the low frequency behavior 1) u – uN = –α(π – πe), α > 0. of the data. It masks the very different behavior that we 28 1Q/2003, Economic Perspectives
BOX 1 Formally testing our hypothesis about the Phillips curve Formal tests of the hypothesis that the Phillips curve pre-1960s VAR so that the implied small sample mean changed relatively little in the 2–20 year frequency lines up better with the pre-1960s empirical estimate of range fail to reject it. Table B1 displays p-values for –0.51. Presumably, such an adjustment procedure would the null hypothesis that the post-1960s data on infla- shift the simulated correlations to the left, reducing tion and unemployment are generated by the bivariate the p-value. It is beyond the scope of our analysis to vector autoregression (VAR) that generated the pre- develop a suitable bias adjustment method.2 However, 1960s data. We implement the test using 2,000 arti- we suspect that, given the large magnitude of the bias, ficial post-1960s datasets obtained by simulating a the bias-corrected p-value would be substantially small- three-lag VAR and its fitted residuals estimated using er than the 14 percent value reported in the table.3 the pre-1960s unemployment and inflation data.1 In each artificial dataset, we compute correlations be- 1 We redid the calculations in table B1 using a five-lag VAR and tween filtered inflation and unemployment just like we found that the results were essentially unchanged. The only no- did in the actual post-1960s data. Table B1 indicates table differences in the results are that the p-value for the busi- that 9 percent of correlations between the business ness cycle correlations between inflation and unemployment is 0.06 and the p-value for these correlations in the 20–40 year cycle component of inflation and unemployment ex- range is 0.11. ceed the –0.38 value reported in table 1 for the post- 2 One could be developed along the lines pursued by Kilian (1998). 1960s data, so that the null hypothesis fails to be 3 To get a feel for the likely quantitative magnitude of the ef- rejected at the 5 percent level. The p-value for the fects of bias adjustment, we redid the bootstrap simulations by 8–20 year correlation is quite large and is consistent adjusting the variance-covariance matrix of the VAR distur- with the null hypothesis at any standard significance bances used in the bootstrap simulations. Let V = [V]ij denote level. the variance-covariance matrix. In the pre-1960s estimation results, V1,2 = –0.1024, V1,1 = 0.0018, V2,2 = 6.0653. When we The statistical evidence against the null hypoth- set the value of V1,2 to –0.0588 and recomputed the entries in esis that there has been no change in the 20–40 year table B1 in box 1, we found that the mean correlations were component of the data is also not strong. This may in as follows: business cycle, –0.75 (0.01); 8–20 year, –0.54 (0.09); part reflect a lack of power stemming from the rela- and 20–40 year, –0.51 (0.06). The numbers in parentheses are the analogs of the p-values in table B1. Note how the mean cor- tively small amount of information in the sample relation in the 20–40 year frequency coincides with the empiri- about the 20–40 year frequency component of the data. cal estimate reported in the first row of table 1, and that the But, the p-value may also be overstated for bias rea- p-value has dropped substantially, from 0.23 to 0.06. This is sons. The table indicates that there is a small sample consistent with our conjecture that bias adjustment may have an important impact on the p-value for the 20–40 year correla- bias in this correlation, since the small sample mean, tion. However, the other numbers indicate that the bias adjust- –0.35, is substantially larger than the corresponding ment procedure that we applied, by varying V1,2 only, is not a probability limit of –0.45. A bias-adjustment proce- good one. Developing a superior bias adjustment method is dure would adjust the coefficients of the estimated clearly beyond the scope of this article. TABLE B1 Testing null hypothesis that post-1960s equal pre-1960s correlations Small sample Standard deviation, Frequency Plim mean small sample mean p-value 2–8 year –0.66 –0.61 0.0036 × 2000 0.09 8–20 year –0.36 –0.38 0.0079 × 2000 0.25 20–40 year –0.45 –0.35 0.0129 × 2000 0.14 Notes: Data-generating mechanism in all cases is a three-lag, bivariate VAR fit to pre-1960s data. p-value: frequency, in 2,000 artificial post-1960s datasets, that contemporaneous correlation between the indicated frequency components of x and y exceeds, in absolute value, the corresponding post-1960s estimate. Plim: mean, over 1,000 artificial samples of length 2,000 observations each, of correlation. Small sample mean: mean of correlation, across 2,000 artificial post-1960s datasets. Standard deviation, small sample (product of Monte Carlo standard error for mean and 2000 ): standard deviation of correlations across 2,000 artificial post-1960s datasets. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 29
FIGURE 4 Measuring money growth and inflation, 1900–60 A. The M2 growth rate and the inflation rate C. Frequency of 2 to 8 years percent percent 25 18 8 Inflation 10 (right scale) 20 6 M2 growth 13 15 4 5 (left scale) 10 8 2 0 5 0 3 0 -2 -5 -5 -2 -4 Inflation -10 (right scale) -6 M2 growth -10 -7 -15 -8 (left scale) -20 -12 -10 -15 1900 ’10 ’20 ’30 ’40 ’50 ’60 1900 ’10 ’20 ’30 ’40 ’50 ’60 B. M2 growth versus inflation D. Frequency of 8 to 20 years inflation percent 20 8 8 6 Inflation 6 15 (right scale) 4 4 10 2 2 5 0 0 0 -2 -2 -5 -4 -4 M2 growth -10 -6 (left scale) -6 -15 -8 -8 -20 -15 -10 -5 0 5 10 15 20 25 1900 ’10 ’20 ’30 ’40 ’50 ’60 M2 growth E. Frequency of 20 to 40 years percent 8 5 6 3 4 M2 growth (left scale) 2 1 0 -2 -1 -4 Inflation -3 -6 (right scale) -8 -5 1900 ’10 ’20 ’30 ’40 ’50 ’60 Note: Shaded areas indicate recessions as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research. Source: Authors’ calculations based upon data from the Federal Reserve System and the U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 30 1Q/2003, Economic Perspectives
FIGURE 5 Measuring money growth and inflation, 1960–99 A. The M2 growth rate and the inflation rate D. Frequency of 1.5 to 8 years percent percent 14 14 6 6 M2 growth 12 12 4 (left scale) 4 M2 growth 10 (left scale) 10 2 2 8 8 0 6 6 0 -2 4 4 Inflation -2 2 2 -4 Inflation (right scale) (right scale) 0 0 -6 -4 1959 ’64 ’69 ’74 ’79 ’84 ’89 ’94 ’99 1959 ’64 ’69 ’74 ’79 ’84 ’89 ’94 ’99 B. M2 growth versus inflation E. Frequency of 8 to 20 years inflation percent 14 1.5 3 M2 growth 12 1.0 (left scale) 2 10 0.5 1 8 0.0 0 6 -0.5 -1 4 -1.0 -1.5 Inflation -2 2 (right scale) 0 -2.0 -3 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 1959 ’64 ’69 ’74 ’79 ’84 ’89 ’94 ’99 M2 growth C. Frequency of 2 months to 1.5 years F. Frequency of 20 to 40 years percent percent 25 15 2.0 1.5 Inflation 20 (right scale) 1.0 10 1.0 Inflation 15 (right scale) 0.5 5 0.0 M2 growth 10 (left scale) 0.0 5 0 -1.0 -0.5 0 -5 -2.0 -5 M2 growth -1.0 (left scale) -10 -10 -3.0 -1.5 1959 ’64 ’69 ’74 ’79 ’84 ’89 ’94 ’99 1959 ’64 ’69 ’74 ’79 ’84 ’89 ’94 ’99 Note: Shaded areas indicate recessions as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research. Source: Authors’ calculations based upon data from the Federal Reserve System and the U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 31
Here, u is the actual rate of unemployment, uN is In practice, the monetary authority would not neces- the natural rate of unemployment, π is the actual rate sarily go for the ideal level of unemployment, because of inflation, and πe is the rate of inflation expected by the increase in π that this requires entails costs. These the private sector. The magnitude of α controls how are captured by the γπ2 term in the objective. According much the actual rate of unemployment falls below its to this term, the ideal level of inflation is zero.16 The natural rate when inflation is higher than expected. The higher the level of inflation, the higher the marginal cost. natural rate of unemployment is the unemployment rate The Barro–Gordon model views the monetary that would occur if there was no surprise in inflation. authority as choosing π to optimize its objective, sub- The natural rate of unemployment is exogenous to the ject to the expectations-augmented Phillips curve and model, evolving in response to developments in unem- to the given value of πe. The optimal choice of π reflects ployment insurance, social attitudes toward the unem- a balancing of the benefits and costs summarized in ployed, and other factors. the monetary authority’s objective. A graph of the best Note that according to the expectations augmented response function appears in figure 6, where πe appears Phillips curve, if the monetary authority raises infla- on the horizontal axis, and π appears on the vertical. The tion above what people expected, then unemployment 45-degree line in the figure conveniently shows the level is below its natural rate. The mechanism by which this of inflation that the policymaker would select if it chose occurs is not explicit in the model, but one can easily to validate private expectations of inflation. imagine how it might work. For example, πe might be Note how the best response function is flatter than the inflation rate that is expected at the time wage con- the 45-degree line. This reflects the increasing marginal tracts are set. Suppose that expectations of inflation are cost of inflation at higher levels of inflation. At low low, so that firms and workers agree to low nominal levels of expected inflation, the marginal cost of inflation wages. Suppose that the monetary authority decides— is low, so the benefits outweigh the costs. At such an contrary to expectations at the time wage contracts are inflation rate, the monetary authority would try to sur- written—to increase inflation by raising money growth. prise the economy by moving to a higher level. On the Given that wages in the economy have been pre-set other hand, if expected inflation were very high, then at a low level, this translates into a low real wage, which the marginal cost of going even higher would outweigh encourages firms to expand employment and thereby the benefits, and the monetary authority would choose reduce unemployment.15 to violate expectations by choosing a lower inflation The second part of the Barro–Gordon model sum- rate. Not surprisingly, there is an inflation rate in the marizes the behavior of the monetary authority, which middle, π*, where the monetary authority chooses not chooses π. Although the model does not specify the to surprise the economy at all. This is the inflation rate details of how this control is implemented, we should where the best response function crosses the 45-degree think of it happening via the monetary authority’s control line. Because of the linear nature of the expectations- over the money supply. At the time that the monetary augmented Phillips curve and the quadratic form of authority chooses π, the value of πe is predetermined. monetary authority preferences, the best response func- If the monetary authority can move π above πe, then, tion is linear, guaranteeing that there is a single crossing. according to the expectations-augmented Phillips curve, What is equilibrium in the model? We assume unemployment would dip below the natural rate. It is everyone—the monetary authority and the private assumed that the monetary authority wishes to push economy—is rational. In particular, the private econ- the unemployment rate below its natural rate, and this omy understands the monetary authority’s policymaking is captured by the notion that it would like to minimize: process. It knows that if it were to have expectations, πe < π*, then actual inflation would be higher than πe. 2) ½ [(u – kuN)2 + γπ2], γ > 0, k < 1. So, it cannot be rational to have an expectation like this. It also understands that if it were to have expec- The first term in parentheses indicates that, ideally, tations, πe > π*, the monetary authority would choose the monetary authority would like u = kuN < uN. The an inflation rate lower than πe. So, this expectation can- model does not specify exactly why the monetary author- not be rational either. The only rational thing for the ity wants unemployment below the natural rate. In prin- private economy to expect is π*. So, this is equilibri- ciple, there are various factors that could rationalize this. um in the model. The formula for this is For example, the presence of distortionary taxes or mo- nopoly power could make the level of economic activity α (1 − k ) inefficiently low, and this might translate into a natu- 3) π = ψu , ψ = > 0. γ ral rate of unemployment that is suboptimally high. 32 1Q/2003, Economic Perspectives
FIGURE 6 lion can climb out. The lion cries out from Effect on macroeconomic models the depths of its soul, with a most solemn commitment not to eat the (juicy-looking) Actual rabbit once it gets out. But, the rabbit is inflation, π skeptical. It understands that the intentions Monetary authority's best announced by the lion while in the hole response function are not time consistent. While in the hole, the lion has the incentive to declare, with complete sincerity, that it will not eat the rabbit when it gets out. However, that plan is no longer optimal for the lion when it is out of the hole. At this point, the lion’s optimal plan is to eat the rabbit after all. Equilibrium inflation, π* The rational rabbit, who understands the time inconsistency of the lion’s optimal plan, would do well to leave the lion where it is. What the lion would like while it is in the hole is a commitment technology: 45˚ something that convinces the rabbit that the lion will have no incentive or ability Expected inflation, πe to change the plan it announces from the hole after it is out. In some respects, the rabbit and the According to the model, inflation is predicted to lion resemble the private economy and the monetary be proportional to the actual level of unemployment. authority in the Barro–Gordon model. Before πe is There are several crucial things to note here. First, the chosen, the monetary authority would like people to actual level of unemployment is equal to the natural rate, believe that it will choose π = 0. The problem is that because in equilibrium the monetary authority cannot after the private economy sets πe = 0, the monetary au- surprise the private economy. So, monetary policy in thority has an incentive to choose π > πe (see figure 6). practice does not succeed in driving unemployment be- As in the fable, what the monetary authority needs is low the natural rate at all. Second, inflation is positive, some sort of commitment technology, something that being proportional to unemployment. This is higher convinces private agents that if they set πe = 0, the mon- than its ideal level, here presumed to be zero. These two etary authority has no incentive or ability to deviate to observations imply that in equilibrium, all the monetary π > 0. Rational agents in an economy where the mone- authority succeeds in doing is producing an inflation tary authority has no such commitment technology do rate above its ideal level. It makes no headway on unem- well to set πe = π* > 0. This puts the monetary author- ployment. That is, this optimizing monetary authority ity in the dilemma discussed in the introduction. Its simply succeeds in producing suboptimal outcomes. optimal choice in this case is to validate expectations How is this possible? by setting π = π* (that is, it chooses C in figure 1). The problem is that the monetary authority lacks The crucial point of Kydland–Prescott and Barro– the ability to commit to low inflation. At the time the Gordon is that if the monetary authority has a credible monetary authority makes its decision, the private econ- commitment to low inflation, then better outcomes omy has already formed its expectation about inflation. would occur than if it has no such ability to commit. The private economy knows that if it expects inflation In both cases, the same level of unemployment occurs to occur at the socially optimal level, π = 0, then the e (that is, the natural rate), but the authority with com- monetary authority has an incentive to deviate to a mitment achieves the ideal inflation rate, while the mone- higher level of inflation (see figure 6). 17 tary authority without commitment achieves a socially Eggertsson (2001) has recently drawn attention suboptimal higher inflation rate. The problem, as with to one of Aesop’s fables, which captures aspects of the the lion in the fable, is coming up with a credible com- situation nicely. Imagine a lion that has fallen into a mitment technology. The commitment technology must deep pit. Unless it gets out soon, it will starve to death. be such that the monetary authority actually has no in- A rabbit shows up and the lion implores the rabbit to centive to select a high inflation rate after the private push a stick lying nearby into the hole, so that the economy selects πe. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 33
What makes adopting a commitment technology central message of the analysis in the previous section. particularly difficult is that the monetary authority’s In particular, suppose that the actions of the central preferences in Barro–Gordon (unlike the lion’s pref- bank have an impact on inflation only with a p-period erences in the fable) are fundamentally democratic pref- delay with p > 0. In this way, the monetary authority erences: They reflect actual social costs and benefits. is not able to eliminate the immediate impact of shocks Credible commitment technologies must involve basic to the inflation rate. The policymaker with commitment changes in monetary institutions, which make them, sets the p-period-ahead expected inflation rate to zero. in effect, less democratic. Changes that have been adopt- Suppose that the analogous timing assumption applies ed in practice are the legal and other mechanisms that to the private sector, so that there are movements in make central banks independent from the administra- inflation that are not expected at the time it sets πe. Un- tive and legislative branches of government. The classic der the expectations-augmented Phillips curve, this institutional arrangement used to achieve commitment introduces a source of negative correlation between has been the gold standard. Tying the money supply inflation and unemployment. This sort of delay in the to the quantity of gold greatly limits the ability of the private sector could be rationalized if wage contracts central bank to manipulate π. extended over p periods of time. Under these timing assumptions, the prediction of the model under com- Barro–Gordon and the data mitment is that the actual inflation rate fluctuates, and The Barro–Gordon model is surprisingly effective inflation and unemployment covary negatively, as at explaining key features of the inflation–unemploy- was actually observed over the early part of the twen- ment relationship during the twentieth century. It is tieth century. (The appendix analyzes the model with perhaps reasonable to suppose that the U.S. monetary time delays.) When the monetary authorities drop their authorities more closely resembled the monetary authori- commitment to low inflation in the later part of the ty with commitment in the Barro–Gordon model in the century, the model predicts that unemployment and early part of the last century and more closely resem- inflation move together more closely and that the re- bled the monetary authority without commitment in lationship will actually be positive in the lowest fre- the last part of the century. After World War II, the U.S. quencies. In the higher frequencies, the correlation might government resolved that all branches of government— still be negative, for the reason that it is negative in including the Federal Reserve—should be committed all frequencies when there is commitment: Inflation to the objective of full employment. This commitment in the higher frequencies is hard to control when there reflected two views. The first view, apparently validat- are implementation delays.20 In this sense, the Barro– ed by the experience of the Great Depression, is that Gordon models seems at least qualitatively consistent activist stabilization policy is desirable. It was codified with the basic facts about what happened to the infla- into law by the Full Employment Act of 1946. The tion–unemployment relationship between the first and second view, associated with the intellectual revolution second parts of the past century. It is hard not to be of John Maynard Keynes, is that successful activist impressed by this.21 stabilization policy is feasible. This view was firmly But, there is one shortcoming of the model that entrenched in Washington, DC, by the time of the ar- may be of some concern. Recall from figure 3, panel A rival of the Kennedy administration in 1960. Kennedy’s that inflation in the early 1980s dropped precipitously, Council of Economic Advisors resembles a “who’s just as unemployment soared to a postwar high. This who” of Keynesian economics.18 behavior in inflation and unemployment is so pro- The notion that policymakers were committed to nounced that it has a substantial impact on the very low inflation in the early part of the century and rela- low frequency component of the data. According to tively more concerned with economic stabilization later figure 3, panel F, the 20–40 year component of unem- implies, via the Barro–Gordon model, that inflation ployment lags the corresponding component of infla- in the late period should have been higher than it was tion by several years. As a technical matter, it is possible in the early period. Comparison of figure 4, panel A to square this with the model. The version of the model and figure 5, panel A shows that this is indeed the case. discussed in the previous paragraph allows for the Another implication of the model is that inflation should possibility that a big negative shock to the price level— have been constant at zero in the early period, and this one that was beyond the control of the monetary au- most definitely was not the case (see figure 4, panel A).19 thority—occurred that drove actual unemployment But, this is not a fundamental problem for the model. up above the natural rate of unemployment. But the There is a simple, natural timing change in the model explanation rings hollow. The model itself implies that eliminates this implication, without changing the that, on average, the low frequency component of 34 1Q/2003, Economic Perspectives
unemployment leads inflation, not the other way around these models serve as another reminder of the power (see the appendix for an elaboration). This is because of the original Barro–Gordon model: With it, the read- unemployment is related to the incentives to inflate, so er can reach the core ideas armed simply with a sheet when unemployment rises, one expects inflation to of paper and a pencil. rise in response. In fact, with the implementation and Why should we incorporate the ideas into modern observation delays, one expects the rise in inflation models? First, the ideas have proved enormously pro- to occur with a delay after a rise in unemployment. ductive in helping us understand the broad features of In sum, the Barro–Gordon model seems to provide inflation in the twentieth century. This suggests that a way to understand the change in inflation–unemploy- they deserve further attention. Second, as we will see ment dynamics between the first and second parts of below, when we do incorporate the ideas into modern the last century. However, the disinflation of the early models, unexpected results occur. They may provide 1980s raises some problems for the model. That ex- additional possibilities for understanding the data. Third, perience appears to require thinking about the defla- because modern models are explicitly based on micro- tion of the early 1980s as an accident. Yet, to all direct foundations, they offer opportunities for econometric appearances it was no accident at all. Conventional estimation and testing that go well beyond what is wisdom takes it for granted that the disinflation was possible with the original Barro–Gordon model. In a direct outcome of intentional efforts taken by the modern models, crucial parameters like α, k, and γ Federal Reserve, beginning with the appointment of are related explicitly to production functions, to fea- Paul Volcker as chairman in 1979. Many observers tures of labor and product markets, to properties of interpret this experience as a fundamental embarrass- utility functions, and to the nature of information trans- ment to the Barro–Gordon model. Some would go mission among agents. These linkages make it possi- further and interpret this as an embarrassment to the ble to bring a wealth of data to bear, beyond data on ideas behind it: the notion that time inconsistency is just inflation and unemployment. In the original Barro– important for understanding the dynamics of U.S. in- Gordon model, α, k, and γ are primitive parameters, flation. They argue that, according to the model, the so the only way to obtain information on them is us- only way inflation could fall precipitously absent a ing the data on inflation and unemployment itself. drop in unemployment is with substantial institutional To see the sort of things that can happen when the reform to implement commitment. There was no in- ideas of Kydland–Prescott and Barro–Gordon are in- stitutional reform in the early 1980s, so the institu- corporated into modern models, we briefly summarize tional perspective must, at best, be of second-order some recent work of Albanesi, Chari, and Christiano importance for understanding U.S. inflation. (2002).22 They adapt a version of the classic monetary model of Lucas and Stokey (1983), so that it incorpo- Alternative representation of the notion that rates benefits of unexpected inflation and costs of in- commitment matters flation that resemble the factors Barro and Gordon By the standards of our times, the Barro–Gordon appeal to informally to justify the specification of their model must be counted a massive success. Its two model. However, because the model is derived using simple equations convey some of the most profound standard specifications of preferences and technology, ideas in macroeconomics. In addition, it accounts nicely there is no reason to expect that the monetary author- for broad patterns in twentieth century data: the fact ity’s best response function is linear, as in the Barro– that inflation on average was higher in the second half, Gordon model (recall figure 6). Indeed, Albanesi, Chari, and the changed nature of the unemployment–infla- and Christiano find that for almost all parameteriza- tion relationship. tions for the model, if there is any equilibrium at all Yet, the model encounters problems understand- there must be two. That is, the best response function ing the disinflation of the 1980s. Perhaps this is a prob- is nonlinear, and has the shape indicated in figure 7. lem for the specific equations of the model. But, is it In one respect, it should not be a surprise that there a problem for the ideas behind the model? We just do might be multiple equilibriums in a Barro–Gordon not know yet, because the ideas have not been stud- type model. Recall that an equilibrium is a level of in- ied in a sufficiently wide range of economic models. flation where benefits of additional unexpected infla- Efforts to incorporate the basic ideas of Kydland– tion just balance the associated costs. But we can expect Prescott and Barro–Gordon into modern models have that these costs and benefits change nonlinearly for only just begun. This process has been slow, in part higher and higher levels of inflation. If so, then there because the computational challenge of this task is could be multiple levels of inflation where equilibrium enormous. Indeed, the computational difficulties of occurs, as in figure 7. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 35
There is one version of the Albanesi– FIGURE 7 Chari–Christiano model in which the in- Variant of the Lucas–Stokey model tuition for the multiplicity is particularly simple. In that version, private agents Actual inflation, π can, at a fixed cost, undertake actions to Monetary protect themselves against inflation. In authorities' best response function principle, such actions may involve ac- quiring foreign currency deposits for use in transactions. Or, they may involve fixed costs of retaining professional assis- tance in minimizing cash balances when inflation is high. Although these efforts are costly for individuals, they do mean that on the margin, the costs of inflation are reduced from the perspective of a be- nevolent monetary authority. Turning to Two inflation figure 7, one might imagine that at low equilibria levels of inflation, the basic Barro–Gordon model applies. People do not undertake 45˚ fixed costs to protect themselves against inflation, and the best response function Expected inflation, πe looks roughly linear, cutting the 45-de- gree line at the lower level of inflation in- dicated in the figure. At higher levels of inflation, the best response curve up and down. Notice how the however, people do start to undertake expensive fixed high-inflation equilibrium behaves differently from costs to insulate themselves. By reducing the marginal the low-inflation equilibrium as the best response cost of inflation, this has the effect of increasing the in- function, say, shifts up. Inflation in the low-inflation centive for the monetary authority to raise inflation. Of equilibrium rises, and in the high-inflation equilibri- course, this assumes that the benefits of inflation do um it falls. Thus, these shocks have an opposite cor- not simultaneously decline. In the Albanesi–Chari– relation with inflation in the two equilibriums. This sign Christiano model, in fact they do not decline. This is why switch in equilibriums is an implication of the model in this version of their model, the best response func- that can, in principle, be tested. For example, Albanesi– tion eventually begins to slope up again and, therefore, Chari–Christiano explore the model’s implication that to cross the 45-degree line at a higher level of inflation. interest rates and output covary positively in the low- The previous example is designed to just present inflation equilibrium and negatively in the high-inflation a flavor of the Albanesi–Chari–Christiano results. In equilibrium. Using data drawn from over 100 coun- fact, the shape of the best response function resembles tries, they find evidence in support of this hypothesis. qualitatively the picture in figure 7, even in the ab- But, the Albanesi–Chari–Christiano model is still sence of opportunities for households to protect them- too simple to draw final conclusions about the impli- selves from inflation. cations of lack of commitment for the dynamics of What are the implications of this result? Essen- inflation. The model has been kept very simple so that— tially, there are new ways to understand the fact that like the Barro-Gordon model—it can be analyzed with inflation is sometimes persistently high and at other a sheet of paper and a pencil (well, perhaps one would times (like now) persistently low. In the Barro–Gordon need two sheets of paper!). We know from separate model, this can only be explained by appealing to a work on problems with a similar logical structure that fundamental variable that shifts the best response func- when models are made truly dynamic, say with the tion. The disinflation of the early 1980s suggests that introduction of investment, the properties of equilib- it may be hard to find such a variable in practice. riums can change in fundamental ways (see, for ex- But, is a model with multiple equilibriums testable? ample, Krusell and Smith, 2002). It still remains to Perhaps. Inspection of figure 7 suggests one possibil- explore the implications of lack of commitment in such ity. Shocks to the fundamental variables that determine models. In particular, it is important to explore wheth- the costs and benefits of inflation from the perspective er the disinflation experience of the early 1980s, which of the monetary authority have the effect of shifting 36 1Q/2003, Economic Perspectives
You can also read