India in Transition: International Agricultural Development
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
India in Transition: Challenges and Opportunities in Fresh Produce Marketing and Agricultural Technology George Alexander Wilbanks University of California, Davis M.S. International Agricultural Development Capstone Report Advisory committee: Travis Lybbert, J.K. Ladha, and Jeffrey Williams Page 1 of 69
Acknowledgements Thokchom Sony, I cherish all our adventures in Delhi (past, present, and future) and the warmth of your friendship (and space heater) after long days spent traipsing to far flung meetings throughout NCR. I am still thankful for your family’s kindness nursing me through fevered tropical illness during my time in Imphal. Abhimanyu Singh Ranawat, Aditi, Ameera, Aryan, and Twitch, I cannot thank you all enough for the delicious meals, winter fires, storytelling, and the warm guest room – thanks again for taking a third child into your home! Rinchen Norbu Wangchuk, inveterate newspaperman and beloved conversationalist, I am thankful for your (and Sharon’s) gracious hospitality and connections in Bangalore. I will be continually in your debt for the invaluable insights you continue to provide on both hiphop and the Indian political and media landscape (and introducing me to Mangalorean cuisine). To the Chakraborty Clan, our excursions in Bombay were lovely but forced a devastating re-examination of the lies we told ourselves about living in Delhi. Anindita and Ipshita, you are both marvelous women, thanks again for never missing an opportunity to inform me I’m wrong and that my Hindi is garbage. Etrajisahibsir, India Hand and global financial sage, your wisdom and patient guidance have provided invaluable context for my experiences in India. Page 2 of 69
Preface In the Spring of 2012, I quit my job in New York working for a family office investment advisory consultant and boarded a flight to Hyderabad, India.1 I spent several months visiting a friend who was working for an impact investor, Bob Pattillo, through the IDEX Accelerator. IDEX is a unique social enterprise fellowship program which, at the time, was matching young professionals with executive teams at social enterprises (primarily affordable private schools) throughout Andhra Pradesh to serve as management consultants. Bob is an interesting character who, I would come to learn later in my career, has had a hand in guiding the careers of several prominent figures in the impact investing and social enterprise space through his various endeavors IDEX, Gray Matters Capital, and Gray Ghost Ventures (including, in no small part, influencing my own professional trajectory). My first two months in India I interviewed with firms across several industries and was offered a role with a newly launched Delhi-based boutique corporate sustainability and development finance consulting firm. cKinetics was founded by two of the original partners at the Aavishkaar-Intellecap Group, a prominent Indian impact investment advisory firm. During the two years I spent with cKinetics, frequently working 80-100 hour six day weeks, our projects fell into four areas: • Operational consulting work in textiles funded by Stockholm International Water Institute • Informing the design and adoption of non-financial (ESG) disclosure regulations promulgated by the Indian Institute of Corporate Affairs and funded by the German development agency GIZ • Leading field operations and data collection efforts for a Rockefeller Foundation funded project exploring rural electrification • Conducting due diligence for a €20 million KfW (German development bank) loan facility targeting conventional energy service companies (ESCOs), micro-grid companies, solar irrigation installers, and telecom developers/tower managers. 1 Out of college, I worked as a personal research assistant to Jed Emerson Page 3 of 69
On a daily basis, I was a voracious consumer of India’s vibrant English language media landscape and an avid spectator of Indian politics during what would turn out to be some of the more contentious and transformational years of the past several decades.2 Food and agriculture dominate India’s political discourse in a manner which is difficult to convey to American audiences. On a nearly monthly basis, newspapers would run front page stories about volatility in onion markets and critiques of recent political pandering to farmers. Lal Bahadur Shastri, the second Prime Minister of India, coined the political slogan “Jai Jawan! Jai Kisan!” [“Salute the Soldier! Salute the Farmer!”] rallying the nation at the outset of the Indo- Pakistani War of 1965.3 Some fifty years later, this mantra seems strangely apropos in India’s current political environment, as the Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP)-led Union government has faced election defeats stemming from agricultural economic distress, the Congress Party’s Rahul Gandhi is videotaped on social media driving a tractor through campaign events in Punjab, and both parties clamor to support farm loan waivers (writing off nearly Rs. 1.9 trillion, or approximately $27B USD) (Bera 2018b and Scroll 2019). Simultaneously, the country finds itself again embroiled in a series of military engagements with Pakistan along the Line of Control. In 2019, while delivering a speech to the 106th Indian Science Congress, PM Modi explicitly appropriated Lal Bahadur Shastri’s words while asserting his government’s commitment to supporting scientific research.4 2 Narendra Modi (right wing Bharatiya Janata Party) was swept into office in 2014 amidst the considerable ascent of Hindu nationalism throughout the country. Arvind Kejriwal assumed office as Chief Minister of Delhi in 2013 and his newly launched populist Aam Aadmi Party has won numerous seats in several critical Delhi Assembly elections, carrying 67 of 70 seats in 2015. Modi’s “Make in India” initiative was launched in 2014. Foreign direct investment (FDI) restrictions were also relaxed in several sectors while I was there. 3 You will also frequently see this translated as “Hail Soldier! Hail Farmer!” 4 https://www.outlookindia.com/website/story/india-news-pm-modi-adds-jai-anusandhan-to-jai-jawan-jai-kisan-and-jai- vigyan/322875 Page 4 of 69
During a consulting engagement with cKinetics, a colleague and I sat in the office of an executive at ITC (India Tobacco Company) pitching a sustainability reporting project within their agricultural supply chains which spanned multiple businesses from tobacco to branded foods, personal care products, and hotels. It became clear very quickly that the firm was not interested in having us uncover Environmental, Social, and Governance (ESG) irregularities within a supply chain encompassing some several million smallholder farmers. During my numerous visits to India, I have ridden approximately 20,000 miles by motorcycle through Manipur in the Northeast, coastal Tamil Nadu in the south, from Manali to Leh, Uttarakhand and Himachal Pradesh, throughout Hyderabad, in addition to daily commuting throughout Delhi NCR. India’s last mile challenges in agricultural value chains were brought into sharp focus while stopping at roadside dhabas (truck stop/restaurants) next to smallholder operations hand harvesting rice and sugar cane, riding through fields in Punjab where one farmer is irrigating with diesel pumps while his neighbor drives cattle around a water lift, avoiding tractor and bullock carts hauling sugar cane loaded twenty feet high, or passing overturned trucks with workers shoveling rice and wheat back into large woven polypropylene bags. Frequenting fresh produce markets (subzi mandis), joking around with the local vegetable stall owner (subziwallah), and cooking in Delhi were central parts of my life and favorite topics of conversation with my colleagues and friends. In numerous discussions with Indian professionals ranging from academics at prominent economic think tanks, investors, NGO staff, and a cohort of visiting Fulbright scholars I solicited perspectives on how agriculture in India might modernize in the coming decades, and the subsequent impacts this might have on the economy and politics as rural communities transitioned into new professions (and Page 5 of 69
potentially resettled). There was a consistent skepticism around the idea that India’s structural transformation would resemble anything like the path to modernization in agriculture elsewhere. I have spent a great deal of time attempting to deconstruct the various anxieties that are baked into this commonly held belief – that there is something inherently different about the role of agricultural productivity in India’s ongoing, very unique, path to structural transformation. Introduction India’s unique path toward structural transformation is captured in myriad contrasts between public and private, old and new, analog and digital, biological and mechanical, rural and urban. This capstone is the culmination of my struggle to comprehend the astonishing scale and scope of India’s impending structural transformation and contextualize my own experiences witnessing the rate of modernization in Indian agriculture. This paper explores the historical roots of several central structural challenges which currently impede improvements in India’s agricultural productivity. Through the course of my research, it is clear many of these same challenges have been identified by Indian agricultural technology entrepreneurs as central opportunities to innovate within fresh produce value chains (Appendix 1). I examine land reform as a domain with particularly salient historical roots and an enormously complex contemporary political legacy. This paper provides analysis which contrasts traditional models of uncoordinated, smallholder, production with the increased popularity of contract farming networks as a strategy developed by large processors to maintain consistency and predictability in their supply chains. Page 6 of 69
As India’s economy continues to liberalize, many of its legacy socialist institutions have struggled to remain relevant and responsive to market-driven trends. I examine the Indian agricultural research and extension model and provide case studies highlighting the Indian Government’s attempt to promote technology adoption among smallholder farmers. In contrast, the project introduces a new paradigm, in which private players in the processing space have stepped in and are actively providing extension services and introducing technology platforms within their contract farming networks. Finally, this paper will examine the historical motivations behind government intervention in markets and subsequent public policy reforms in recent years. Produce markets in India, through their unique function, provide a useful means of contrasting traditional markets, where smallholders are disadvantaged through fraught credit relationships and information asymmetries with the advent of large-scale, technology-enabled, coordination of downstream processors and demand aggregators reaching upstream to the farm gate. Methods of Analysis This project provides an analysis of India’s unique agricultural political economy through a review and synthesis of the literature, case studies, and key informant interviews. Several case studies are introduced around land holding, agricultural extension, and fresh produce marketing to examine the motivating factors underlying several key government interventions in the function of these markets. To supplement this analysis, from December 9th, 2018 through January 11th, 2019 I spent five weeks in India visiting Bombay, Delhi, and Bangalore to conduct key informant interviews with a diverse group of Indian agricultural business, policy, and finance stakeholders Page 7 of 69
(Table 1). These conversations were structured around identifying the underlying challenges to improving agricultural productivity on a per hectare basis, soliciting detailed descriptions of the organization’s function or business model, and attempting to capture existing efforts to promote technology adoption with key fresh produce value chain participants. For simplicity, I have opted to focus my analysis primarily on activity in fresh produce value chains targeting large metropolitan areas in India. While this focus arguably captures trends largely driven by demand from wealthier urban consumers, the share of smallholders operating in fruit/vegetable cropping systems is higher than in food grains – so there may very well be important trends captured here. Additionally, high-value horticultural production in India has witnessed substantial growth in both volume and value over the past two decades, overtaking food grain production in 2010. Furthermore, the feedback that I received throughout my conversations in India indicated that fruit and vegetable production had the highest levels of private sector investment and entrepreneurial participation with relatively low levels of government intervention. Indian Agriculture: A Primer “Reality is not a function of the event as event, but of the relationship of that event to past, and future, events.” —Robert Penn Warren, All the King’s Men In the Zamindars’ Shadow Rural land tenure is a subject of both tremendous complexity and considerable historical import in India. Beginning in the medieval period, India’s rural land was administered through the zamindari system, an agrarian feudal hierarchy which institutionalized the disenfranchisement of a rural peasantry in a manner not dissimilar to the function of the European system of serfdom (Bandyopadhyay 1993). Zamindars were an aristocratic ruling Page 8 of 69
class which facilitated the administration of the Mughal Empire through taxing the peasantry, a function which they continued to perform (largely unchanged) through British colonial administration in India. While not a facsimile, the current function of traders is often viewed rather unfavorably through this lens (essentially as a tax by wealthier merchants on the rural poor). This paper will not attempt to describe in depth, or provide any critique on, post- Independence redistributive land reform policies beyond noting that this process abolished the zamindari system and has been differentially administered at the state level across four broad categories laid out by (Besley and Burgess 2000): i) tenancy reform (regulating contractual terms – often included efforts to transfer ownership to tenants) ii) abolishing intermediaries (previously worked on behalf of Zamindars as rent collectors) iii) implementing ceilings on landholdings (redistributing surplus land to the landless) iv) consolidation of disparate landholdings During my conversation in Delhi with Dr. P.K. Joshi (South Asia Director at the International Food Policy Research Institute), in response to my line of inquiry regarding the Land Ceiling Act’s continued relevance, he provided an invaluable perspective on the importance of Indians’ connection to land and how the history of dispossession has played a complex role influencing post-Independence land policies. Currently, several state laws only allow individuals to acquire agricultural land with some that further restrict ownership to residents of that state while other states allow companies and individuals both to acquire and farmland (these include Delhi, Goa, Bihar, and Tamil Nadu). However, in all states, foreigners are prohibited from buying agricultural land. Land leasing reform has been the subject of some interest lately, an important white paper was released in 2015 by Arvind Panagariya, then Vice Chairman of The National Institution for Transforming India (NITI Aayog), encouraging the states to revisit their Page 9 of 69
regulations to reduce barriers to leasing agricultural lands. This appeal seems to have gained little to no traction in the ensuing 4 years. Farmer Producer Organizations (FPOs) and cooperatives are other mechanisms for aggregating agricultural land into units large enough to warrant the requisite investment in germplasm, inputs, mechanization, postharvest storage/processing, transportation, and organizing aggregation of supply which allows farmers to exert market power in channels outside of the traditional mandi/trader relationship. Given that approximately 85% of farms are small and marginal (< 2 hectares) with 70% of holdings < 1 hectare, there is intense introspection around the viability of smallholders as India looks to increase yields to meet domestic demand while also meeting goals the government has set to increase participation in high-value export markets (Agarwal 2010 and Mehta 2013). Similarly, restrictions around foreign direct investment (FDI) in agriculture have been a highly politicized subject closely regulated by the Indian government. Only in 2011 did the Department of Industrial Policy and Promotion allow 100% FDI in several limited areas of agriculture (while it remains explicitly banned in any other activity), these include (Government of India 2011): • floriculture, horticulture, apiculture and cultivation of vegetables and mushrooms (under controlled conditions: greenhouses, net houses, and poly tunnels) • development and production of seeds and planting material • animal husbandry and aquaculture (under controlled conditions) • services related to agro and allied sectors This is a significant consideration given the financing landscape for innovative businesses addressing production, processing, and marketing challenges in India’s agriculture sector. For venture capital funds with portfolio companies in the Indian agricultural technology space, a significant percentage of the general partners (GPs) I spoke with were managing money from limited partners (LPs) that included (mostly foreign): institutional investors, foundations, Page 10 of 69
development finance organizations, and large family offices. Several entrepreneurs I spoke with had domestic Indian corporates, VCs, commercial banks, and ultra-high net worth individuals, as well as foreign foundations (Gates Foundation) participating in various funding rounds. Reliable data around LPs allocating capital with private equity and venture funds focused on Indian agriculture is somewhat spotty with anecdotal coverage coming from media outlets like AgFunder (US-based), VCCircle (Indian-based), Global AgInvesting (US-based with minimal India coverage), and occasionally Indian financial daily newspapers. Admittedly, I also have not consulted any legal professionals to determine precisely how these instruments are impacted by FDI rules.5 Anecdotally, most of the capital fueling the innovation landscape in Indian agriculture (horticultural production) appears to be foreign in origin – creating an interesting tension with the intended political goals of FDI restrictions. Public Law (P.L.) 480 – Food for Peace India’s total export growth in agricultural products in the 2000s is astonishing, increasing 686% from $5B USD (2003) to $39.3B USD (2013) (USDA 2014). One of the regrettable state interventions in the agricultural export market has been the occasional imposition by the Commerce Ministry of either an ad-hoc ban (frequent in milk powder, wheat, edible oils, pulses, and non-basmati rice) or what is known as the Minimum Export Price (MEP) for an individual commodity (usually onions, potatoes, and basmati rice) (Saini and Gulati 2017). MEP is usually fixed above actual export market prices, to disincentivize traders from exporting, with the stated goal of stabilizing domestic prices in times of volatility (often citing food security 5 i.e., if you are an India-based VC or Non-Banking Financial Company (NBFC) – does it even matter if you are managing foreign money? Page 11 of 69
concerns). As of 2018, there were indications emanating from both Arun Jaitley (finance minister) and Suresh Prabu (commerce minister) that the MEP on onions would be lifted in an effort to promote exports as part of Modi’s promise to double exports by 2022 (to roughly $60 billion USD) (Bera 2018a). Whether this is an indication of permanent reform or temporary concession in the perennial political tug of war between farmer incomes (wholesale) and enraged consumers (retail) remains unclear (The Hindu Business Line, 2018). A scarcity mindset pervades the Government of India’s approach to regulating agricultural markets, particularly in staple food grains. This commentary was voiced in virtually every single conversation I had with investors and bankers throughout my last visit to India. Several investors suggested that I dig into the literature surrounding P.L. 480 and indicated their strong conviction that this experience had a profound psychological impact on the Government of India’s agricultural policy in the ensuing sixty years. The broad argument is that the bitter taste leftover from this experience was the impetus for successive regimes of import substitution, export restrictions, and the operation of buffer stock schemes on a grand scale in several staple commodities. In fairness, this mentality is a conviction borne out of a fairly recent, valid, lived experience by many policymakers in which food scarcity was a calamitous reality as recently as the mid-1960s. India’s post-Independence years were racked by food shortages and as foreign exchange reserves began to evaporate in the mid-1950s, the government, under Jawaharlal Nehru took on politically sensitive negotiations around securing food aid and concessional sales through the Public Law (P.L.) 480 program. Briefly, the function of this disbursement of aid involved sales by the Indian government of imported commodities with the proceeds being Page 12 of 69
directed toward rural development projects to improve agricultural productivity. In what may be one of the more elegant presentations of the calculating, Cold War containment, rationale which ultimately brought the United States into negotiations with India, (Cullather 2007) describes the coalescing around economic development as a bulwark against “an evolving strategy of Communist subversion employing influence, negotiation, and economic penetration.” Ray Vickery, in his text The Eagle and the Elephant: Strategic Aspects of US-India Engagement offers insight into President Johnson’s instructions to Secretary of Agriculture Orville Freeman ahead of his November 1965 meeting with Indian Minister for Agriculture C. Subramaniam in Rome. In Vickery’s account, Johnson left Freeman with “strict orders to ‘trade hard’ to secure a written document setting forth Indian commitments on agricultural reform” noting that the document which was produced from this meeting offered several key concessions, “the first provision of the agreement was that India would double its investment in agriculture during the Fourth Plan period as compared to the previous Five-Year Plan” this agreement further spelled out that “India would be ceding to bilateral agreement with the United States not only overall actions but also to internal governmental processes by which those actions would be accompanied.” To add salt to the wounds, there were several hard bargains driven which advantaged the US-based fertilizer industry (the leading importer to India) with provisions that for any shortfalls in agreed upon application rate targets, the difference would be made up in imports at unsubsidized market rates. It is the intention of this capstone merely to provide a brief exploration of the potential relevance of P.L. 480’s legacy in shaping India’s contemporary agricultural political economy rather than a rigorous evaluation Page 13 of 69
of the macroeconomic soundness and overall economic impacts of P.L. 480 regimes in the 1950s and 60s. However, a significant body of literature has set out to provide just such analysis (Rath and Patvardhan 1967, Seevers 1968, Srivastava 1972, Shenoy 1974, Isenman and Singer 1975, Hatti 1977, and Ahlberg 2007). However, the legacy of both land reform and P.L. 480 arguably loom large over policy responses to the seemingly intractable productivity dilemma for India’s smallholder farming population. “The Indian farmer is doing agriculture, not agribusiness.” --Dr. P. K. Joshi, South Asia Director, IFPRI I have seen derivations of the following yield gap table, sourced from what appears to be 2011 FAO data, reproduced in at least three different slide decks presented by Indian academics at global agricultural conferences and feel that it is invaluable for contextualizing the productivity challenges facing India’s agriculture sector (Pandey 2009, Mehta 2013, Singh 2014. FAO 2019).6 Crop Global Production Rank Global Productivity Rank Fruits 2nd (10.9% global share) - Vegetables 2nd (8.6% global share) - Paddy Rice 2nd 30th Wheat 2nd 22nd Maize 6th 35th Total cereals 3rd 36th Groundnut 2nd 40th Rapeseeds 3rd 28th Pulses 1st 44th Potato 4th 26th Sugarcane 2nd 9th 6Singh 2014 has estimates which show significant improvements in Productivity Rank (however, it is unclear where he is sourcing these numbers from) – the Production/Productivity numbers from Pandey 2009 and Mehta 2013 largely match up). Exploring the most recent data from 2017/2018 would be an interesting comparison with the 2011 data I present here. Page 14 of 69
While estimates tend to vary, India’s net sown area is roughly 140 million hectares (42% of India’s total land area) with 55-60% of Indians participating in agricultural production and 71% of the population living rural areas (Gov’t of India 2001, 2014, 2018 and Mehta 2013).7 Agriculture and Allied Sectors represent roughly 16% of GDP (as of 2015-16) representing a significant decline from the 1960s, when it represented roughly 50% of India’s GDP (Gov’t of India 2018). Provisional results from India’s Agriculture Census: All India Report on Number and Area of Operational Holdings (covering 2015-16) does not paint a very optimistic picture regarding the viability of many of the country’s farming operations (Rao 2016). Operational holdings in the Agriculture Census 2015-2016 are broken into the following classes: 2015-16 Group Size of holding Operational holdings (% of total) Marginal 0.5 < 1.0 ha. 69% Small 1.0 < 2.0 ha. 18% Semi-medium 2.0 < 4.0 ha. 9% Medium 4.0 < 10.0 ha. 4% Large 10.0 – 20.0 + ha. 1% An alarming pattern can be observed in a 176% increase from 1970-71 to 2015-16 in the number of Marginal operational holdings throughout the country (Figure 1) while the average size of holdings dropped over the same period from 2.28 ha to 1.08 (Figure 2) with the area operated under Large holdings falling by 71% (Figure 3). As the average area under cultivation has been on a decline, so too has the availability of labor in peak season. Several bankers I spoke with indicated this trend resulted from a combination of migration to cities and the relative vitality of employment in rural non-farm economy in recent years (in part bolstered by 7 I have seen this Ag labor force participation number vary somewhat, from (56.6%) in the 2001 Census data, (this 2001 number is then cited as 58.2% and then as 55% in the Ministry of Finance’s Economic Survey 2017-18) and (59%) in the National Sample Survey Report No. 554: Employment and Unemployment Situation in India, 2011-12 Page 15 of 69
MNREGA: the Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Act). With 87% of farming operations under 2 ha., economically viable investments in the underlying agronomic resources to increase yields (e.g., mechanization, high quality germplasm, nutrients, herbicides, pesticides, fungicides, irrigation, and harvesting labor) can be a challenging proposition. Table 2: Mechanization Adoption Rates Penetration Rate Operations (mechanization) Cultivation and seed bed prep 42% Seeding and planting 29% Plant protection 34% Irrigation 34.5% 60-70% for wheat/rice Harvesting and threshing and
Figure 4: Land ownership and the probability of liking farming Why should this matter? Plenty of people are unhappy in their chosen vocations! I believe this reflects, in part, the lack of economic viability in marginal landholdings and a very rational series of frustrations regarding smallholders’ inability to gain power in marketing, access to affordable credit, and scale to profitability. Using World Bank workforce estimates (around 510 million as of 2019) and assuming a 40% dropout rate (Agarwal and Agrawal 2016) from India’s agricultural workforce (approximately 60% of total employment), this represents approximately 122,400,000 workers who will need to be retrained, relocated, and reemployed (World Bank 2019a). To put this in context, Japan’s most recent population estimate (as of October 2018) is 126,443,000 (Government of Japan 2019). Researchers at the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank have provided an interesting analysis of India’s atypical structural transformation by comparing it to the United States, where the percentage of the population participating in agriculture went from around 50% in 1860s to under 2% by 2000 (Goel and Restrepo-Echavarria Page 17 of 69
2015). If we look at the Indian agricultural labor force and apply that same percentage reduction, assuming only 12% of the existing agricultural labor force is retained, you are talking about transitioning almost 147 million people out of agriculture, which is roughly the population of Russia. Mechanization and Tractors: A Lens into Technology Adoption What if there was a way to make farming more attractive to those who decide to stay in the occupation? “Tractorization” in India is an area which has generated a substantial body of academic literature in agricultural economics and is the subject of government promotion schemes dating back to the Agro Industries Corporations (AICs) of the mid 1960s (Puri and Gumpert 2016). Trends in mechanization offer an interesting perspective on adoption challenges and opportunities in other realms of agricultural technology going forward. Beginning in the 1960s, the government provided irrigation pumps, tractors, power tillers/threshers on a rent-to-buy model through AIC-sponsored Agricultural Machinery Service Centres. AICs were a spectacular failure and suffered massive losses from bad loans and were eventually shuttered. Private entrepreneurs entered this segment and by the time the Government of India introduced the Agro-Service Centre (ASCs) model in 1971, there was already a burgeoning rental (custom hiring) industry in many parts of the country. ASCs provided custom hiring (machine rental) services for tractors and tractor-operated equipment in addition to input sales and servicing facilities for machinery (Puri and Gumpert 2016). In 2010, the government introduced 100 agricultural extension centers under the National Innovations on Climate Resilient Agriculture (NICRA) program located throughout “drought/flood/hill area and other difficult terrains” and these provided an important platform Page 18 of 69
for popularizing custom hiring services. As part of the 12th Five Year Plan, the Government of India’s Sub-Mission on Agricultural Mechanization (SMAM) has been tasked with expanding access to mechanization to small and marginal farmers through providing financial assistance and expanding custom hiring centers (Government of India 2019). SMAM has laid out seven components: 1. Promotion and strengthening of agricultural mechanization through training, testing, and demonstration 2. Introduction of new postharvest technology and management 3. Financial assistance or procurement subsidy for selected agricultrural machinery/equipment 4. Establishing farm machinery banks for custom hiring by small/marginal farmers 5. Establishing hi-tech and high productivity equipment hubs for custom hiring 6. Enhancing farm productivity at village level through the introduction of appropriate farm mechanization (in selected villages) 7. Promoting farm equipment ownership among small/marginal farmers in the east/northeastern regions Mechanization adoption rates are a significant indicator in the substantial productivity gains which tend to accompany the deployment of equipment across all cropping systems, in cereals for instance, this yield relationship is striking as presented in (Mehta 2013) (Figure 6). YES Bank’s Food and Agri Strategic Advisory and Research unit, under Nitin Puri, has compiled a comprehensive list of custom hiring programs as of 2016 (Puri and Gumpert 2016) (Figure 7). Private sector participation through supporting platforms which promote adoption through reducing financial barriers to entry is an important innovation to highlight with the extension space. For instance, niche startups like Gold Farm (an Uber-type platform for harvesting equipment) are actively working with sugar mills to try and scale a model to make mechanized harvesting equipment more available to their contract farming networks. These mills tend to run sporadically, through actively coordinating resources in the field these processor players are working toward driving predictability into harvesting which, hopefully, leads to more consistent mill operations (and higher profitability). Addressing the perceived Page 19 of 69
shortcomings of imported equipment manufactured in more developed countries, Kamal Kisan is a small firm manufacturing mechanized tillage, seeding, and input application equipment tailored to specifically to Indian smallholder management strategies. Mechanization presents a compelling model where initial efforts undertaken by the Indian Government have laid the groundwork for private sector distribution models to innovate. It will be important to track how these platforms begin to incorporate technologies which move beyond mechanization into geospatial imagery interpretation, precision agriculture, no-till seed drills, -- the challenge will be to evaluate the ability of these firms to provide adequate customer training and support on these newer technologies. This presents a unique opportunity for public private partnerships to emerge around collaborations with technology providers, equipment manufactuers, and India’s National Agricultural Research System (NARS). Agricultural Research and Extension in India National Agricultural Research System (NARS) With 102 research institutes and 73 agricultural universities across the country, India’s NARS is a bureaucratic undertaking on such a massive scale, and with such institutional complexity, that even under close examination it remains a struggle to understand how all the parts fit together (Figure 8). The Indian Council of Agricultural Research (ICAR) has a storied history dating back to its founding in 1929 as the Imperial Council of Agricultural Research, the organization played a key role during the Green Revolution and has continued to support innovation in Indian agriculture (Figure 9). The Integrated National Agricultural Resources Information System (INARIS) is a fascinating project which will make critical agronomic data available to the public with the real potential to generate substantial economic value for Page 20 of 69
industry if the government can execute on generating up-to-date and accurate cropping system maps, soil resource maps, GIS overlays for water resources and farm mechanization rates (Figure 10). Krishi Vigyan Kendras (KVKs) According to the ICAR, there are currently 706 KVKs spread across eleven distinct Agricultural Technology Application Research Institute (ATARI) zones through the country (Government of India 2019d).8 Managed by State Agricultural Universities and volunteer organizations, KVKs provide general extension services, field-level demonstrations of new technologies, and on-farm trainings around agronomic best practices. KVKs also conduct on- farm trials of specific technologies to collect data on their regional and site-specific performance (Singh et al. 2013). Opinions were mixed in my conversations about the relevance of KVKs for providing tangible value for disseminating new technologies and making meaningful impact on adoption rates. Some key informant interviewees expressed opinions that the KVK system was a hold-over from a bygone, centrally planned, socialist era whose function was essentially to assist farmers with transitioning to new crops at the direction of a centrally planned decision-making apparatus. 8 This is a number which varies depending on which government publication you consult (it ranges from the mid- 600s with 706 as an upper bound) Page 21 of 69
Figure 11: Agricultural Extension System in India Adapted from (Balaguru 2015) Staff at the National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development (NABARD) and IFPRI felt that KVKs would continue to play an important role in the adoption process through demonstrating new technologies locally in farmers’ fields. Sentiment in the private sector was overwhelmingly skeptical with numerous individuals indicating there was no clear channel of communication around ongoing projects within KVKs and expressing dismay that there seemed to be minimal accountability or interest in partnering with industry. There was, however, some interest in the Agricultural Technology Management Agency (ATMA) as a promising district- level mechanism for technology dissemination. An interesting development from my interviews was the frequent mention of several very successful extension partnerships between private sector food processors, ICAR Crop Science Institutes, and private agronomists engaging directly with farmers to solve very specific crop quality and yield issues (case studies outlining Page 22 of 69
this extension work will be discussed at length in the “Emergence of Alternate Marketing Channels” section). Extension IT Projects: Experimenting with e-Extension Limited resources available for farm-level interactions across both State Agricultural Universities (SAUs) and the KVKs are a challenge which results in approximately 60% of farmers in India having no access to extension services (Bhattacharyya et al. 2018). This shift to focusing on e-Extension has significant implications for adoption rates based on my conversation with P. K. Joshi at IFPRI in which he noted that, while KVKs were important for demonstrations, he was observing adoption moving much more rapidly through farmer social networks than the KVKs. While India’s smart phone penetration rate was only 27% in 2017, this number is predicted to jump to 60% of the population by 2022 (Bhattacharya 2018). Coupled with the highly competitive market for mobile data and relatively robust data network coverage, the ability to effectively contact farmers via smartphone-enabled platforms, web portals, and social networks all appear to be highly viable channels for communicating extension services. mKisan is a SMS-based platform launched in 2013 to provide the roughly 380 million rural cell phone users with the ability to send queries which, in turn, receive a response from a wide swath of government resources relating to agriculture available in 12 different languages with semi-literate and illiterate farmers targeted with voice message responses (Government of India 2013). Similarly, Department of Agriculture & Cooperation, Ministry of Agriculture launched twenty-five Kisan Call Centers in 2004 across the country which also provided local language responses to agriculture-related questions from farmers. ICAR Central Institute for Cotton Research’s CICR Cotton App for farmers provides weekly and daily updates and Page 23 of 69
extension information on cotton cultivation and is currently translated into Hindi, Marathi, Gujarati, Telegu, and Tamil. In the NGO space, Digital Green was introduced as a platform which spun out of Microsoft Research in 2008 and has worked with over 15,000 villages in India and provides extension and marketing services across their Community Videos, data collection efforts, Training Courseware, crop marketing ap, and innovation lab. Marketing is an area which continues to benefit immensely from these types of farmer-focused digital information exchange platforms which provide pricing information and low-cost, secure, payment systems. Fresh Produce Marketing in India Agricultural Produce Market Committees (APMCs) APMCs are constituted by State Governments and oversee specific agricultural commodities governed under that state’s Agricultural Produce Market Committee Act. APMCs are tasked with ensuring price transparency, publishing daily arrival data, and same day payments to farmers for their products across the 2,477 regulated markets and 4,843 sub- market yards they operate across the country. These committees have several other functions which include providing market-based extension services to farmers and promoting agricultural processing to add value across all commodities (Government of India 2019b). The stated goals and function of APMCs are laudable, to protect farmers from entering distress sales with their creditors while ensuring transparent pricing and timely payment for their commodities. However, the function of these committees has left much to be desired. Once market committees define a market area or jurisdiction, wholesale marketing activities may only take place under the aegis of the APMC by its licensed commission agents. This has historically prohibited farmers from entering into contract farming arrangements with large processors or Page 24 of 69
manufactures. Furthermore, levies and other market charges vary widely between states which has the effect of distorting prices and erecting barriers to entry. During my conversations with technology entrepreneurs and investors looking at wholesale markets, there was consensus that the role of APMC as regulator and market was fraught and they felt very often APMC personnel were forming cartels with traders and commission agents, creating monopsonies which put farmers at a significant disadvantage. In response to the lack of integration and numerous distortions in state agricultural marketing schemes, the Union Ministry of Agriculture introduced the State Agricultural Produce Marketing (Development and Regulation) Act in 2003 (alternatively referred to as the Model APMC Act of 2003) and subsequent Agricultural Produce and Livestock Marketing (Promotion & Facilitation) Act of 2017. This key reform allows farmers to sell outside of APMC-administered markets, gives wholesalers more options around where they can buy and sell, and loosens up licensing and fees levied on sales (Government of India 2003). Because agricultural markets remain a state subject, adoption of the Model APMC Act of 2003 has been uneven across the country. The National Agricultural Market (NAM) first appeared in the Union Budgets of 2014-15 and 2015-16 and became a highly publicized reform topic for the Union Cabinet (Government of India 2019c). Launched in 2016, e-Nam (as it is known) is a national online trading platform connecting APMC mandis with the goal of creating a single marketplace for some 90 commodities across India’s approximately 22,000 distributed agricultural markets by 2022 (PTI 2019). e-NAM’s potential, both to link farmers to buyers and provide a massive source of price and transaction data holds tremendous promise for increasing the efficiency of marketing fresh Page 25 of 69
produce in India. Data generated on this platform represents an immense wealth of information that would be invaluable for informing the more intelligent design of futures contracts and the refining of agricultural credit and insurance products (both of which remain a significant challenge in a data poor environment). However, with only 585 mandis up on the platform as of January 2019, adoption continues to be a struggle – notably, as of December 2018, Delhi’s Azadpur Mandi and six other markets in the National Capital Region (NCR) have yet to join the e-NAM platform (Sally 2018) (Figure 12). Traditional Marketing Channel: Mandis and Arthiyas Figure 13: Traditional Marketing Channels in India Admittedly, the above rendering is a vast oversimplification which does not account on myriad regional permutations nor does it account for multiple actors participating simultaneously in multiple marketing channels (e.g., a potato farmer could be selling to a commission agent (Arthiya) in Azadpur Mandi while at the same time contract farming and selling directly to a processor (McCains or Pepsico), or directly to a large retail outlet (Big Bazaar or Safal). These alternate marketing channels will be explored at length later in this section. However, this model is instructive for providing a general framework for how fresh Page 26 of 69
produce is bought and sold in India metros. Typically, a household has three primary outlets where they will be purchasing fruits and vegetables: 1. Push/Bicycle cart vendors are a ubiquitous feature of Delhi neighborhoods, these vendors will announce their presence and wares early mornings and are a very convenient, highly affordable, and popular option for purchasing staple vegetables and some generic fruits. 2. Vegetable traders in “wet markets” will typically all be located right next to one and other in single area of a neighborhood. These very basic shops will tend to offer a wider selection of fruits/vegetables (arguably, you can expect to see higher quality here versus pushcarts). Some vendors in more affluent neighborhoods will also offer expensive imported items (mostly fruit). 3. Kiranas are local family-owned and operated small neighborhood grocery stores, not unlike bodegas in New York City, which sell a wide variety of consumer goods and generally have fruits and vegetables displayed out in front. Disintermediation is a very sexy topic in both the value chains academic literature and pitch decks from myriad private ventures vying to cut out middlemen and pocket some of their margins through various efficiency-based business models. Price spreads between farmers and consumers in emerging market value chains tend to be quite large and are often attributed to postharvest losses (Murthy et al. 2009), trader margins (Mahalanobis 1972), and transportation/packaging costs (Kumar and Arora 2003). During my conversations, a number entrepreneurs were scaling demand aggregation models which sought to “cut out the middlemen” and purchase directly from farmers, sort/grade, transport, store, and deliver product directly to end consumers like Kiranas, large institutional clients (hotels, hospitals, etc.), and newer branded grocery stores. Middlemen, particularly traders, are often maligned in India and tend to be viewed as rent-seeking actors who are often instrumental in corrupting government officials (weights/measures, false price reporting, etc.) and exploiting farmers by leveraging information asymmetries and colluding with commission agents (Arthiyas). In fairness, it does seem to be the case that in many mandis traders do, indeed, act as oligopsonists (depressing prices paid to farmers). Page 27 of 69
(Ghosh 2013) makes a compelling case that traders provide several important functions in fresh produce value chains which are often not well understood, these include: • Bridging low information rural producers with urban center consumers • Understanding government rules and regulations • Assisting in physical exchanges • Providing timely finance and inputs to producers • Operating in markets and areas of tremendous uncertainty (willingness to undertake risk) • Maintaining informal, highly personalized, relationships with producers Traders tend to be located closer to markets (demand side) and have deeper “domain knowledge” about consumer markets than do producers (and vice versa when transmitting information back up the supply chain). While this information asymmetry can be a source of margin for traders, traders can also play an important role as “knowledge transfer conduits” as they disseminate market information to growers in rural areas (Mulky 2008). Traders and Commission agents (Arthiyas) both play a critical role in a vast system of informal credit, providing working capital loans to numerous participants throughout the value chain. These actors will play the role of insurer (through preharvest contracts) and as merchant bankers, extending informal credit down the supply chain to growers and up the supply chain to Kiranas, Masakhors, and even push/bicycle cart vendors. (Celestine 2011) has done some fantastic reporting on this, documenting that Arthiyas “say they are tapped by farmers for finance to buy everything, from seeds to sacks to bag their produce, and even to finance weddings and homes” while traders at the local level will run sometimes run shops and extend store credit to farmers to purchase groceries. This credit comes at a price, while agricultural loans in India average 8-9% informal credit will run farmers around 25% (it is still unclear to me if this is annualized or is based on some much shorter tenure: 3 days, weekly, monthly) and represents, Page 28 of 69
according to official estimates, roughly 35% of the total agriculture credit industry (Yamunan 2017). Azadpur Mandi: Up Close and Personal It is 1:00am on a weekday and the CH. Hira Singh Wholesale Vegetable Market (Azadpur Mandi), Asia’s largest wholesale fruit and vegetable market, is teaming with activity as massive trucks maneuver through tight alleys backing up and being offloaded by “palledars” carrying loads atop their heads to market stalls and bicycle rickshaw carts. Motorbikes, rickshaws, and small trucks zip in and out of storefronts laden with men and massive cargos of tightly packed fresh produce. Delhi’s thick winter fog hangs in the covered stalls and mixes with the acrid smell of beedi smoke, chai, frying parathas, and the sweet earthy smell of ripe fruit (Figure 14). A 12 km drive from Connaught Place, Azadpur Mandi is located in Northwest Delhi on 76 hectares and handles roughly 15-20 MT of fresh produce on a daily basis. Trading in approximately 60-70 vegetables and around as many fruits commences in the late evening and runs through the early morning. Around 2,000 commission agents (Arthiyas) act as brokers for farmers and will run auctions on lot sizes greater than roughly 10 kg and charge the farmer a 5-6% commission (fixed by the state APMC legislation) on the final sale price plus any costs associated with loading/unloading and transport. However, we heard from several industry contacts that the commission agents are frequently illegally charging higher rates of around 7-8%. Arthiyas are market makers, providing liquidity using traders (to whom they extend credit) to buy from farmers in the mandi (5% commission is paid) or directly at the farm level (no commission is paid). I was unable to determine the interest rates charged by Arthiyas (a few people I asked all Page 29 of 69
said generally the same thing, “it depends” – indicating this is a very high touch, relationship- based, business). Traders and Arthiyas will additionally provide some small value addition grading/sorting functions, both are also acting as arbitrageurs attempting to profit from the price spreads between different markets within the region, between the farm gate and the Azadpur Mandi, and across markets in other states. As previously mentioned, Arthiyas also provide a critical function up and down the value chain through extending informal lines of credit. Arthiyas were conducting bidding in two forms, the first was open outcry, although voices were never raised, and several sources indicated they often ran auctions in code (signaling in an effort to fix prices with other wholesale middleman buyers). The second, and far more interesting format, is what one trader described as the “Under Cover Method” for which price discovery involved a handkerchief and some hand signals with no public announcement of a final sale price. If you are buying on credit, this latter method is mandatory. This was a practice I witnessed multiple times but wasn’t eager to capture on camera; however, (Ahmed and Siddiqui 2015) have some fantastic pictures documenting the practice (Figure 15). To be very clear, this is illegal and should, technically, be cracked down on by the 500-600 co-located Agricultural Produce Market Committee (APMC) staff who are tasked with collecting price data and then listing the day’s “Model Rate” for every commodity (this work is supported through a 1% fee charged on each transaction). Page 30 of 69
Figure 15: The “under cover” method of price discovery at Azadpur market For lots smaller than 10 kg, Masakhors (or middlemen) will buy from Arthiyas (commission agents) and then sell on to retailers and vendors (90% of whom are buying on credit) – at this point, some additional level of sorting and grading is happening. As might be expected, prices are constantly changing throughout the evening and according to several people we spoke with the prices track quality and tend to decrease as it gets later into the morning (most Kiranas and street vendors want to be back in their respective neighborhoods to capture early morning footfall). The Emergence of Alternate Marketing Channels APMC reforms post-2003 have been critical to encouraging innovation in marketing fresh produce through opening new channels for farmers to directly access buyers ranging from large modern grocery chains, burgeoning e-grocers (BigBasket and Grofers) to multinational corporate food processors (McCain Foods India and PepsiCo India). Demand aggregation business models are driving efficiency into the fresh produce value chain across a number of key metro markets (Ninjacart, Crofarm, Farm Taaza, and DeHaat), circumventing traditional market yards by pooling various categories of buyers and providing end-to-end logistics from farm to distribution center and local delivery (Figure 16). Lawrencedale Agro Processing (LEAF) Page 31 of 69
provides another example of business models actively disintermediating traditional marketing channels. LEAF started in the value chain for carrots and the firm is now directly sourcing 7,000 tons of fresh produce across 55 commodities annually from farmers and working with over 300 store clients in south India (these include: Spar Hypermarket, Star Bazaar, Aditya Birla More, Future Group, and Godrej Nature’s Basket). ITC Limited’s e-Choupal platform connects to their Agribusiness Division’s supply chain of some 4 million farmers covering soy, coffee, wheat, rice, pulses, and shrimp in 35,000 villages in 10 states. ITC is very careful to note that they are not disintermediating the physical functions of agricultural marketing channels but rather “‘e-Choupal' makes use of the physical transmission capabilities of current intermediaries - aggregation, logistics, counter-party risk and bridge financing - while disintermediating them from the chain of information flow and market signals.” ITC’s platform focuses on removing information asymmetries through launching 6,100 village-level internet kiosks “sanchalaks” which provide farmers with local language information on weather, updated market prices, agronomic extension information, and connection to farm input sales channels (ITC 2019). Despite being the second largest producer of fresh produce globally, less than 2% of India’s fruits and vegetables are entering commercial food processing (Sidhu 2005). As the country’s middleclass experiences an upward trend in income, purchasing habits shift away from more traditional retailers and toward diets that incorporate a larger percentage of processed food products. To meet this growing demand, processors are attempting to face the challenge of how to source quality produce consistently throughout the year to keep their manufacturing operations running smoothly. It bears mentioning that some of these “new” Page 32 of 69
You can also read