In Tax, Gender Blind is not Gender Neutral: why tax policy responses to COVID-19 must consider women
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
In Tax, Gender Blind is not Gender Neutral: why tax policy responses to COVID-19 must consider women by Michelle Harding, Grace Perez-Navarro, and Hannah Simon, OECD Centre for Tax Policy and Administration (CTPA) Women are at the core of the fight against the COVID-19 crisis: they make up the vast majority of healthcare workers and shoulder much of the childcare and home schooling burden during lockdowns. And while tax policy measures play a crucial role in supporting individuals and businesses as we navigate this crisis, the gender impact of taxation is often overlooked – with serious consequences for gender equality. Gender equality is a fundamental human right, as laid out in the UN’s Sustainable Development Goal #5, and failing to achieve it costs us up to 16% of world income every year. Yet, in the context of government revenue collection, gender balance is often neglected as a policy rationale. Could it be that there simply is no need to assess the interaction of tax and gender, or have gender imbalances in tax systems so far been overlooked? And what does this mean for policy-makers in the face of Covid-19? Gender blind or gender neutral? The good news first: tax provisions that explicitly
disadvantage women relative to men are rare, although they used to be more common. Historically, married men in the Netherlands for example, were granted a higher income tax-free allowance than married women (until 1984). Meanwhile, on the Island of Jersey, married women will continue to need their husbands’ permission to talk to tax authorities and to file taxes under their own name until a new law comes into force in 2021. While examples of explicit bias are rare, this does not mean that our tax systems do not affect men and women differently. Tax systems that are gender-blind on paper can, in practice, exhibit a hidden, implicit bias and may even exacerbate gender inequalities, particularly in times of crises. As long as men and women face different socioeconomic realities, tax systems will affect them in different ways. Therefore, it is necessary to go beyond a cursory analysis of the tax law and to understand how it interacts with the different socioeconomic realities of men and women – such as persisting gender gaps in income levels, labour-force participation, consumption, entrepreneurship and wealth. The hidden impacts of taxation are most visible in personal income taxation. Although men and women are typically taxed under the same rules, their different income levels and labour force participation characteristics mean that the impact of the tax system can be far from neutral. In more than two-thirds of OECD countries, second-earners face a disproportionately high tax burden when entering the workforce. Compared to a single worker at the same level of income, second earners face higher average tax rates, meaning that, due to family-based taxation and reductions in dependent spouse credits, their household income increases less for
every dollar earned. In the nine OECD countries with family- based taxation, the net personal average tax rate of second earners is 40%, meaning that they take home only 60% of their gross wage – seven percentage points less than a single individual at the same wage level. This – alongside various other factors that influence the decision of individuals to enter (or re-enter) the workforce, such as educational level or the availability of childcare – reduces the incentives for second earners to work. And given that a large majority of second earners are female, it is mostly women that face this disincentive. Add consumption taxes to the picture and this disincentive is exacerbated. Consumption taxes on services such as cleaning and childcare make it more attractive to produce these services at home rather than buying them on the market, especially for low-income households. This further decreases the (predominantly female) second-earner labour supply.
Consumption taxes can also directly affect the distribution of income between men and women due to gendered differences in consumption patterns, but these are harder to infer. COVID-19 amplifies these dynamics by increasing women’s unpaid work burdens and by destabilizing the labour market. Widespread closure of schools and childcare facilities and other confinement measures will increase the time that parents have to spend on childcare and home schooling as well as on routine housework such as shopping, cooking and cleaning – much of which is likely to fall on women. Fulfilling these demands will be difficult for many parents, especially for dual-earner households, which increases the risk of second- earner women to leave the workforce. In addition, men and women typically exhibit differences in employment patterns: in OECD countries, men are overrepresented among the self-employed, while female employees are, on average, almost three times more likely to work part-time. These non-standard workers are among the most vulnerable during the current crisis, facing higher risks of job or income loss, and often fall outside of standard safety nets. This makes fair taxation of different employment forms as well as increased access to out-of-work benefits for non- standard workers – which some countries have temporarily introduced in response to the current crisis – a key dimension of gender balance. In developing countries, the challenge is magnified by large degrees of informality and limited fiscal space. With the majority of female workers in informal employment, lockdown measures and the resulting economic hardship pose an acute threat to women’s livelihoods, and a focus on officially labeled taxes does not fully capture the complex linkages
between gender and taxation. User fees and informal taxes, often used to finance basic goods such as education, healthcare and water, can impose a significant financial burden on households and can discourage low-income individuals from accessing healthcare, which is particularly problematic in the midst of a pandemic. During the Ebola epidemic in West Africa, donor money shifted to the most urgent humanitarian and public health needs and away from financing local public goods and services, such as schools, teachers and water wells. A similar shift in donor money during the current crisis would increase the financial burden on individuals and communities in funding these goods and services, which is likely to reinforce unequal societal practices: if schooling is too costly, girls are the first to stay home, particularly during times of extreme economic hardship. “This is not the last pandemic we’re going to have”, said Ngozi Okonjo-Iweala, who previously served as Nigeria’s minister for both finance and foreign affairs and is one of the governing board members of the OECD-UNDP TIWB programme. “We had better make sure that those at the bottom of the ladder are not pushed further back. That inequality is not exacerbated”, she added in a recent interview with TIMES. How can governments address gender differences in their tax systems? Government spending programmes and tax policy measures play a central role in supporting individuals and businesses as we navigate and exit this crisis. However, as the Finnish Prime Minister Sanna Marin said at the World Economic Forum in Davos
earlier this year, gender equality “just doesn’t happen by itself”. To ensure that the tax system does not inadvertently reinforce gender biases in society, governments need to include the impact of taxes on gender as a key policy dimension in their tax policy responses to COVID-19. Improving data on the impact of COVID-19 on women as well as on previously unexplored dimensions such as intra-household dynamics, asset ownership and corporate participation will be crucial to understand these impacts. To address the complex interactions of tax and gender, governments will need to consider options to redesign key taxes to avoid exacerbating existing gender differences, or use tax or other instruments to compensate for differences in income levels as part of their long-term response to the crisis. When it comes to tax and gender, let’s #BuildBackBetter! For more information, please see: Milanez, A. and B. Bratta (2019), Taxation and the future of work: How tax systems influence choice of employment form, OECD Taxation Working Papers, No. 41, OECD Publishing, Paris. OECD (2020a), Emergency tax policy responses to the Covid-19 pandemic, Updated 20 March, OECD, Paris. OECD (2020b), Tax and Fiscal Policy in Response to the Coronavirus Crisis: Strengthening Confidence and Resilience,
OECD, Paris. OECD (2020c), Women at the core of the fight against COVID-19 crisis, OECD, Paris. Saint-Amans, P. (2020), Tax in the time of COVID-19, 23 March 2020 on The Forum Network Covid-19 as a wake-up call: Three considerations going forward by Philippe Aghion, Collège de France, drafted by Shashwat Koirala, OECD Economics Department As a part of the Chief Economist Talks series, the OECD hosted Philippe Aghion, Collège de France on May 11, 2020. This blog presents the takeaways from his presentation. More information regarding the OECD’s Chief Economist Talks, including previous speakers, can be found here. COVID-19 has prompted many difficult questions, chief among which is how we should re-envision the world after the crisis. This pandemic has revealed the shortcomings of our current social, economic and political systems, and addressing these will be central to rebuilding the post-coronavirus society.
Notably, there are three, albeit non-exhaustive, areas that merit reflection: trade and value chains, social and health insurance, and civil society and trust. Trade and value chains Although COVID-19 has incited criticisms against the international trading and production systems, there is evidence that trade has actually helped mitigate the crisis and may even help countries exit and recover quicker. For example, preliminary estimates suggest that, on average, countries that are net exporters have lower daily cumulative deaths. The cases of France and Germany are also revealing, as the differences in medical capacity between the two countries mirror their divergence in trade. Whereas Germany entered the crisis with high medical capacity (e.g. 25 000 hospital beds with respirators) and was able to test on a large scale (e.g. 500 000 tests per week), France had much smaller capacity (e.g. 5 000 hospital beds with respirators) and was unable to perform mass testing until recently. This was driven not by any form of protectionism in Germany, but rather a consistent growth in its trade of vital medical supplies, amounting to a trade surplus today of over EUR 20 billion. Meanwhile, French imports and exports of these goods have grown minimally since 2002 (see Figure 1).
However, there is some scope for domestic production in strategic sectors to improve resilience to acute shocks. Again, the differences in the value chains of French and German firms for medical supplies are telling. Since 2000, domestic production of pharmaceuticals in France has stagnated while that in Germany has increased substantially. Simultaneously, German asset holdings abroad (both in terms of number of foreign affiliates and direct investment assets abroad) in the pharmaceutical sector have remained flat over time while those of French firms have grown markedly. Given France’s lower medical capacity at the onset of the pandemic, this raises the question of whether French firms outsourced excessively, and whether policies are needed to maintain domestic reserves in strategic sectors. This does not, however, suggest that massive re-shoring of production is needed, but rather that policies concerning the storage of vital goods and investment in domestic industries could be warranted. These include policies to boost investment in automation/robotisation, which generate cost savings for firms and provide incentives to re-shore some production (Kilic & Marin, 2020).
Social and health insurance COVID-19 has also elucidated the importance of social safety nets to protect against unexpected shocks and their adverse impacts on employment, health, and poverty. Social protection mechanisms tend to vary by country. A clear dichotomy is apparent between the United States and Germany, even prior to the crisis, as the former is much less protective than the latter. This is reflected in outcome indicators such as the Gini index for inequality (0.39 in the U.S. vs. 0.289 in Germany) and the poverty rate (0.178 in the U.S. vs. 0.104 in Germany).[1] These differences in social protection systems have been made abundantly clear by the crisis. Forecasts show that the unemployment rate in the United States is set to jump sharply in 2020, compared to a much smaller increase in Germany (Figure 2). Furthermore, empirical estimates extrapolating from past relationships between unemployment and poverty risk and healthcare coverage indicate a substantial increase in 2020 in the share of uninsured population in the United States, owing to the bundling of health insurance with employment, as well as in the percentage of population at risk of poverty. In Germany, no such increase is evident. These differences hold even when comparing the United States with other European countries, such as France, Italy, Spain, and the U.K. What this data reveals is that the American system has less social protection relative to Europe. This lack of protection increases the vulnerability of its citizens, especially in times of crises. There is, thus, a need to reform the American social insurance system to incorporate more safeguards. Doing so is not only key for social wellbeing, but also can foster
the innovation that is often considered the hallmark of American capitalism, for example by boosting education and quality of work. Trust and civil society COVID-19 has revealed the extent to which society rests on a bedrock of trust and social norms, for which civil society is indispensable. Practices used to limit the spread of the virus include many voluntary actions that are dependant on mutual trust and respect. Countries that were most successful in limiting the spread of the virus, such as Germany and South Korea, have civil society systems that played an important role in instilling self-discipline and civic spirit needed for the implementation of measures like large-scale social distancing. While market incentives and government actions are important elements of addressing the pandemic, they alone cannot prevail without a fundament role for civil society and the values of community, fairness, and reciprocity that it promotes (Bowles & Carlin, 2020).
The importance of civil society should be well-reflected in how we address future problems and make policy decisions. Existing research already shows that too much government coercion engenders distrust. For example, on average, countries with higher levels of regulation for firm entry, rigidity of employment, and court formalism show higher levels of distrust (Aghion, Algan, Cahuc, & Shleifer, 2009). This suggests an important role for social dialogue in decision- making. Moreover, decentralised decision-making and effective coordination between local and central governments may also help promote civil society and trust, especially as trust tends to be higher at lower levels of government. As countries begin to emerge from stringent containment measures and chart a path to recovery, it is important to address some of the underlying lessons that COVID-19 has highlighted. First, turning inward towards protectionism is not the answer; on the contrary, this may have worsened the crisis and slowed the recovery. However, domestic reserves in strategic sectors may be justified. Second, social safety nets are indispensable in protecting and safeguarding against downturns and hence, should be bolstered. Finally, while governments and markets are important elements of society, civil society should not be overlooked, as strong civil society systems are needed to foster cohesion and trust, which can help navigate shocks like this pandemic. Bibliography Aghion, P., Algan, Y., Cahuc, P., & Shleifer, A. (2009). Regulation and distrust. NBER. Bowles, S., & Carlin, W. (2020). The coming battle for the
COVID-19 narrative. VoxEU. Kilic, K., & Marin, D. (2020). How COVID-19 is transforming the world economy. VoxEU. [1] Data for 2017. Alberto Alesina – a global talent who never forgot Italy by Vincenzo Galasso, Andrea Goldstein and Giuseppe Nicoletti A professor in the United States since 1987, first at Carnegie Mellon for less than a year and then at Harvard, where he had obtained his doctorate just two years earlier, Alberto Alesina was first of all a world-renowned economist whose writings have collected more than 120,000 quotes (google scholar). But he also maintained close professional and intellectual ties with Italy and with Italian economists. The list of Alesina’s Italian co-authors is very long. Of his 142 articles published in academic journals since the first — which he published before graduating in Economia pubblica in 1980 – more than half are the result of collaboration with
other Italian economists, including many doctoral students, such as Silvia Ardagna, Eliana La Ferrara, Enrico Spolaore and Francesco Trebbi. All of them are Bocconi alumni, as were other co-authors – for example Carlo Favero, Paola Giuliano, Vittorio Grilli, Andrea Ichino, Roberto Perotti and Paolo Pinotti – not forgetting of course Francesco Giavazzi and Guido Tabellini who have been teaching in Bocconi for years. Alesina returned regularly to the alma mater, being since 1993 a fellow of IGIER (Innocenzo Gasparini Institute for Economic Research), the centre established in 1990 to contain the “brain drain” and bring to Italy economists from all over the world. During the seminars held in Bocconi it was common to listen to his comments, witty, funny and always constructive – especially towards PhD students and young colleagues. Overall, 42 Italian economists have published with Alesina in 40 years, most of them spent overseas. His latest book, Austerity: When It Works and When It Doesn’t, winner of the prestigious Hayek Book Prize from the Manhattan Institute just a week ago, is also the result of collaboration with Favero and Giavazzi. With the latter, Alesina has written 137 editorials in Corriere della Sera since 2011, spanning a variety of themes, always with a strong penchant for provocation, but always with a constructive spirit – “in the interest of the citizens”, as his last contribution, which appeared on May 10th, was titled. As Silvia Ardagna and Eliana La Ferrara have recalled on il Sole24Ore, his intellectual curiosity pushed him on many different frontlines, from macro-economics to inequality, social capital and culture. But his main field remained political economics: the study of the economic and political motivations that underlie the behaviour of decision-makers (ministers, governments, parliaments, central banks) and their public policy choices. A new strand of economic science that
he and other scholars had helped to create. When the Swedish Academy decides that it is time to award the Nobel Prize in Economics to political economics scholars, it will be very strange not to see his name among the winners. His interest in Italian affairs was reflected in many of his scientific works dealing with general economic issues, but of great relevance to Italy: from public debt to austerity policies, from bureaucracy to the impact of family ties on the functioning of the labour market and gender gaps. During the meetings of the NBER (National Bureau of Economic Research) Political Economy group in Boston, he liked to point out that it was no coincidence that so many political economists were Italian. Researchers love to study what doesn’t work, and in Italy the relationship between politics and economics has not been smoothly functioning. Alesina transferred his ideas into the public debate through his editorials (often with Francesco Giavazzi) and his books. Editorials sometimes lashing, never trivial, that generally requested a change of direction to Italian politics often accused of too timid an approach when it comes to economic reforms. To a country historically reluctant to fully accept the rules of the market, he never stopped reminding, in both scientific research and newspaper columns, the importance of healthy competition among firms for promoting investment and growth. He advocated the need for more competition as well for a simplification in public administration and regulation, especially in traditionally protected sectors of the Italian economy, such as public services and liberal professions, where the productivity gap vis-à-vis other countries bears on Italian relative performance. Competition always invoked by those who try to understand the root causes of the Italian evil and often disregarded by Italian policy-makers, as in the case of Law 99 of 2009 that requires the government to propose
every year to Parliament measures aimed at promoting it. A provision first complied with six years after its approval and then immediately forgotten, Alesina and Giavazzi wrote on July 10, 2017. Europe and the Euro were also enticing topics for Alesina, who in 2010, together with Giavazzi, had edited a NBER volume for the ten years of the common currency. In quiet times, they argued, the benefits (and costs) of the euro are important. But during a crisis, the benefits appear magnified. Words that still sound very current today. Alberto Alesina’s biography is an example of how it is often sterile to talk about brain drain and brain gain, when in fact the circulation of talents can enrich nations and make sense of globalization. * This is the English translation of “Alesina, l’economista di Harvard che non perse mai di vista l’Italia”, Il Sole 24 Ore, 26 May 2020. The OECD COVID-19 Policy Tracker: What are governments doing to deal with the
COVID-19 pandemic? by Tim Bulman and Shashwat Koirala Governments have implemented an extraordinary range of new policy measures to tackle the health and economic consequences of the COVID-19 pandemic, including actions to stop the virus’s spread, to bolster health systems, to support economic activity and livelihoods, and to protect the vulnerable. To identify effective policies to fight the pandemic, policymakers and researchers need to share experiences and learn from each other. The OECD COVID-19 Policy Tracker is a centralised database of government responses to the different dimensions of the COVID-19 crisis, compiled and verified by OECD country experts. Covering over 90 countries, across all continents and income levels, the Tracker summarises each country’s containment and health measures, fiscal responses, monetary and macro-prudential mechanisms, and structural policies. It also links to highly granular information on countries’ responses pertaining to tax policy, social, employment and income policies, policies in support of small and medium-sized enterprises, and health technology policy. The Tracker is updated daily to capture the evolving nature of the crisis. To facilitate empirical analysis of the impact of the pandemic, users will soon be able to access a time-series of countries’ responses, and assess the policies in place on different dates. This blog post presents some of the Tracker’s insights into how OECD and G20 countries are responding to the COVID-19
crisis. Support for the health sector Governments have taken substantial steps to strengthen the capacity of the health sector. Many countries have boosted health funding to cover the costs of increased staffing needs, vital medical infrastructure (e.g. hospitals, ventilators, beds, etc.) and safety equipment (e.g. personal protective equipment). For example, Italy has devoted EUR 845 million to recruit 20 000 health care workers and allocated additional funding to produce and procure necessary equipment. To give their health workforce more flexibility, governments have also relaxed or eliminated certain rules, regulations and administrative procedures. In Denmark and France, working time rules and overtime caps for healthcare employees have been relaxed while in the United States and Brazil, regulatory barriers to telemedicine have been removed to facilitate remote consultations. Meanwhile, Argentina and New Zealand have eased import procedures by temporarily reducing import duties and tariffs on medical supplies. In addition to these instruments, countries have deferred non- essential medical services, promoted research and development of innovative medical equipment (e.g. affordable ventilators), vaccines, treatments and testing-kits, and compenseted medical workers through bonuses or salary increases. Though generally not considered to be good practice, some governments have also imposed restrictions, such as export bans, to preserve access to vital medical supplies.
Containment measures Containment measures aim to limit human interaction through confinement or stay-at-home orders, school closures, and restrictions on international and/or within-country travel. These measures vary in intensity across countries (Figure 1). One-fourth of OECD and G20 countries, covering about 558 million people[1], have instituted nation-wide lockdowns, affecting many but not all groups or regions. Forty-one percent have implemented more moderate confinement measures; many areas or population groups in these countries are restricted, but there are broad exceptions. These countries account for about 2.6 billion people.[2] Meanwhile, only a few countries (11%), with roughly 73 million people, have refrained from or no longer have confinement measures. Countries’ travel restrictions and school closures policies also vary. In 21% of countries, totalling almost 1.9 billion people[3], both international travel and movement within the country are severely restricted. A larger share (53%) have only imposed restrictions on all international arrivals, while allowing internal movement to continue. These countries cover a comparatively smaller number of people (approximately 1 billion). Likewise, whereas schools are completely closed in 25% of countries, some (16%) have kept physical sites open for targeted groups, such as children of essential workers. Nevertheless, these two groups of countries encompass a similar number of people (about 1.7 billion and 1.8 billion respectively[4]). Certain countries have also started lifting their containment measures (e.g. Austria, Spain, and Germany) and have indicated timelines for further easing in the future. As the stringency of containment measures changes across countries, the Tracker
is updated accordingly. Fiscal and monetary policy responses The containment measures, in conjunction with people’s anxieties about the virus, have brought economic activity to a standstill, inducing estimated output and consumption decreases in many countries of 20-25% and 33% respectively (OECD, 2020[1]), as well as severe income losses for firms and households. To address this, governments have implemented expansionary fiscal policies (Figure 2). The most common
schemes are deferral mechanisms for tax or social security contribution payments (96%), credit subsidies (including credit guarantees) for firms (93%), and expanded unemployment income support programs for households (91%). Nearly half of the countries have also introduced targetted support – financial and otherwise – for vulnerable segments of their population (e.g. elderly, low-income, migrant workers, informal workers, etc.). For example, Spain has put in place a special program to provide housing to victims of gender violence. Countries have also eased their monetary policies and macro- prudential regulations to ensure that there is sufficient liquidity in the economy. Common monetary instruments include the reduction of policy rates and large-scale asset purchases by central banks. For example, the United States Federal Reserve has lowered its interest rates by 100 basis points to 0-0.25% and resumed large-scale asset purchases of treasury securities, agency mortgage-backed securities, as well as
assets backed by student, car, credit card and small business loans. Similarly, the Bank of England has reduced its policy rate to 0.15% and increased its holding of UK government and corporate bonds by GBP 200 billion. In terms of macro-prudential regulations, many central banks and financial regulators have reduced reserve and/or capital requirements for banks. The European Central Bank has allowed banks that it supervises to temporarily operate at lower capital levels. Many Eurozone countries have supplemented the ECB’s responses through additional actions at the national level. The French High Council for Financial Stability, for example, has released all banks’ from its countercyclical capital buffer. Given the extraordinary burden of the COVID-19 pandemic on socio-economic systems, many countries are also reaching to tools beyond fiscal and monetary measures, towards sharing the burden across the private sector. This includes payment holidays affecting private transactions between firms and/or households, such as rent freezes or reductions, mortgage deferrals, and exemptions from utility payments. Tracking policies to launch the recovery As governments relax restrictions, the goal of policy responses will shift from bridging the crisis to the recovery. To launch sustained and inclusive recoveries, governments will need to transition from broad economic support mechanisms to targeted initiatives that buttress demand while helping people to find new jobs, viable firms to restructure, and new businesses to emerge and grow. The Tracker will continue to report structural policies implemented by countries in
response to the COVID-19 crisis, such as strengthening safety nets, upgrading skills, raising the effectiveness of public administration, leveraging the benefits of digitalisation, and supporting investment for green growth. Forthcoming OECD Ecoscope blog posts will present further policy insights from the Tracker that can help countries tackle the COVID 19 crisis and prepare the recovery. References OECD (2020), Evaluating the initial impact of COVID-19 containment measures on economic activity, https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/view/?ref=126_126496-evgsi2gmqj &title=Evaluating_the_initial_impact_of_COVID-19_containment_m easures_on_economic_activity. [1] OECD (2020), Tackling coronavirus (COVID 19): Contributing to a global effort, http://www.oecd.org/coronavirus/en/. [2] [1] All population figures are based on country populations for 2019. The sample includes China (about 1.40 billion people) and India (about 1.33 billion people), which helps explain the large number of people covered by the level of containment measures to which these countries correspond. Total population for all OECD and G20 countries is about 4.86 billion.
[2] These countries include India. [3] These countries include India. [4] Former includes India and the latter includes China. Green swans: climate change risks, central banking and financial stability by Luiz Awazu Pereira da Silva, Bank of International Settlements, drafted by Shashwat Koirala, OECD Economics Department The Chief Economist Talks are part of the OECD’s high-level distinguished speaker series in which global economic leaders, top thinkers and decision makers are invited to discuss their perspectives on the world economy with the OECD Chief Economist. The talks aim to foster learning and inspiration and provoke meaningful discussions. Previous speakers have included: Claudio Borio (BIS), Peter Praet (ECB), Maurice Obstfeld (IMF), Penny Goldberg (World Bank), Debora Revoltella (EIB), Hal Varian (Google), Sergei Guriev (EBRD), Stefanie Stantcheva (Harvard), Emmanuel Moulin (Ministry of Economy and Finance, France), Philipp Steinberg (Ministry of Economic Affairs and Energy, Germany), and Jean Pisani-Ferry and George Papakonstantinou (EUI). Participation in these events are by
invitation only and are aimed at OECD staff and the OECD Ambassadors and delegations. They are not open to the press. On April 23, 2020, the OECD hosted Luiz Awazu Pereira da Silva, Deputy General Manager, Bank of International Settlements, to discuss his work on the challenges posed by climate change to financial stability, drawing on his co- authored book, “The green swan: Central banking and financial stability in the age of climate change”. This blog presents key takeaways from his talk. The unprecedented challenge posed by climate change is well documented. The rising concentration of greenhouse gases in the atmosphere has profound environmental impacts (e.g. rising sea levels, extreme temperature events, etc.) that threaten the delicate balance of the planet’s natural systems. The human and societal consequences of the climate emergency are also massive, as environmental damages can exacerbate inequalities, food and water insecurity, and conflicts. Accounting for climate-related risks is, thus, indispensable for building resilient socio-economic-ecological systems. There is an emerging recognition among central banks and financial regulators that climate-related risks are also a source of price and financial instability, and that there is a need to safeguard the financial system against these risks. This is complicated by a paradoxical tension between physical climate risks and transition risks. For example, on one hand, inaction towards the climate crisis means that climate-related accidents become more frequent and severe, threatening socio- economic systems and financial stability (i.e. physical risks). On the other hand, a rapid and aggressive decarbonisation effort can lead to sudden asset repricing (i.e. transition risks). This tension epitomises the fact that
climate-related risks are transmitted through complex and inter-connected channels and have cascade effects. Treating these risks requires a departure from status quo thinking, as outlined by the following four key ideas. First, while similar in some respects to “black swans”– highly unexpected events with severe far-reaching consequences (e.g. 2008 U.S. housing market crash) that can be best explained ex post – climate-related risks are distinct. They are not tail- risk events; scientific evidence suggests that climate-related shocks are virtually certain to occur, though the exact timing of these events is uncertain. Since the climate crisis poses an existential threat to humanity, climate-related risks are also more catastrophic than traditional systemic financial risks. Finally, as alluded to earlier, climate-related risks are much more complex. They are propagated non-linearly with destructive feedback loops and can cascade across sectors, countries and systems (see Figure 1 for a representation of chain reactions stemming from climate-related risks). Taking inspiration from the “black swan” moniker, climate-related events are termed “green swans”.
Second, a methodological shift in macroeconomic-climate modelling is required to better understand green swan events, and how they emerge, accumulate and cascade. Backward-looking and deterministic approaches (e.g. vector autoregressive models) that extrapolate historical trends do not suffice in capturing the complexity and radical uncertainty of climate- risks. Even current scenario-based forward-looking risks assessment mechanisms are unable to completely incorporate the broad range of chain-reactions associated with climate change. This, in tandem with the fact that these approaches lack granularity and there is uncertainty regarding approaches to climate-change mitigation, means that the current paradigm of models cannot fully elucidate the potential macroeconomic, sectoral and firm-level repercussions of climate change. Thus, an exploration of alternative approaches is needed, such as non-equilibrium models (instead of more sophisticated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models), sensitivity analysis with more complex scenarios, and studies specific to countries, sectors and firms.
Third, given the intrinsic complexity of climate change, international co-ordination and co-operation is vital. While central banks play a critical role in mitigating climate- related risks, they do not possess a silver bullet to do so by themselves. Central banks and financial regulators have a role to play in identifying and managing climate-risks (e.g. integrating risks into prudential regulation), internalising externalities (e.g. incorporating environmental, social and governance considerations into their own portfolios), and enabling structural low-carbon transitions (e.g. reforming the international monetary and financial system). Nevertheless, many tools, such as green fiscal policy and carbon pricing, fall outside their purview, and uncoordinated actions from central banks would be insufficient and could potentially have unintended consequences. A systems-wide green transition necessitates buy-in and action from all stakeholders (i.e. governments, private sector, and civil society), and central banks need to contribute to coordinate on climate change by being more proactive on this front while continuing to fulfil their financial stability mandate. Fourth, it is important to acknowledge that green swans have a tremendous negative redistributive impact, within and between countries. Not only do the physical risks stemming from climate change predominately affect lower-income countries, but also the costs of adaptation to climate-change (e.g. shift away from carbon-intensive industries) are higher for poorer households. This means that addressing climate change requires scaled-up mechanisms for redistribution and a redesign of societal safety nets and efforts to finance the green transition of low-income countries. Otherwise, a society-wide acceptance of actions on climate change will prove elusive. The ecological and environmental stability of the planet is a prerequisite for price and financial stability. So, for
central banks to fulfil their central mandate, they have an important role in contributing to a systems-wide climate- change effort. In a nutshell, this involves identifying and communicating the risks ahead, calling for bold actions from all stakeholders to ensure the resilience of the earth’s socio-ecological systems, and helping manage the risks within the bounds of their mandate. Bibliography Bolton, P., Despres, M., Pereira da Silva, L. A., Samana, F., & Svartzman, R. (2020). The green swan: Central banking and financial stability in the age of climate change. Bank for International Settlements. The COVID-19 crisis creates an opportunity to step up digitalisation among subnational governments By Luiz de Mello, OECD, and Teresa Ter-Minassian, OECD Fiscal Network Recent decades have seen rapid growth of advanced digital technologies, including high-speed computing, big data, artificial intelligence, the internet-of-things and
blockchain. This “digital revolution” creates significant opportunities for all levels of government to improve the delivery of public goods and services, and to raise more and better revenue. This is particularly important in the context of the COVID-19 crisis. Fighting a pandemic while minimising the associated economic costs calls for appropriate digital infrastructure for the design and enforcement of containment measures, as well as to ensure access by the population and enterprises to critical government services. After all, subnational governments (SNGs) account for about 40% of government spending on average in OECD countries; they also play an important role in the delivery of key services that are at the heart of the policy actions being taken to slow the spread of the pandemic, including on health care and social protection. Much of the literature has focused so far on the scope for advanced digitalisation at the central/federal level of government. In a recent OECD paper, de Mello and Ter-Minassian (2020) focus on the opportunities and challenges that digitalisation creates for SNGs. Advanced digital technologies can help improve the quality and efficiency of subnational programmes. Geographic information systems (GIS) are being used to identify potential environmental and health risks, which is important when it comes to controlling the spread of a pandemic and avoiding its recurrence. Of particular interest is the use of sensors, to control road and railway traffic, maintain regional or local infrastructure, and monitor water and sanitation usage, just to cite a few. Digital portals facilitate SNGs’ communication with their populations and the delivery of certain public services, and well-designed information systems can strengthen
all aspects of subnational public financial management, and facilitate subnational transparency and accountability. At the same time, regional and local governments are having to operate digitally in periods of confinement and to broaden the range of services provided on-line to the population, including in some cases in the area of e-health. The case of testing, tracing and tracking through digital devices to contain the spread of COVID-19 is a case in point, where the local governments are in many cases actively involved in these efforts, and privacy/confidentiality concerns are prompting important debates among policymakers. Digitalisation can also help to improve both shared and own subnational revenues. This is particularly important to prepare governments to restore the sustainability of the public finances, once the post-COVID-19 recovery has been firmly established. Especially promising are possibilities to introduce, or strengthen, the enforcement of consumption taxes, regional personal income taxes (PITs), or regional surcharges on national PITs; make more efficient and equitable the administration of local property taxes; and better utilise user fees for local services. Digitalisation, however, also poses significant challenges for SNGs, whose capacities to deal with such challenges vary widely both across and within countries (see Figure). The most important constraint in many SNGs is likely to be the scarcity of requisite skills, not only in government leadership and bureaucracy, but also across the population at large. Lack of skills breeds, in turn, distrust and resistance to digitalisation.
Other significant constraints can be posed by inadequate physical infrastructure and financial resources to improve it. Less recognized, but also important, can be legal or regulatory constraints. Tackling cyber security risks, and adequately addressing citizen’s privacy concerns constitute further significant challenges. These challenges in SNG digitalisation highlight the need for a well-structured overall strategy beginning with a stocktaking of the initial state of, and main obstacles to, digitalisation. Within these constraints, SNGs need to define priorities (e.g. which public services should be digitalised first); identify needs for legal and organisational supporting changes; define responsibilities for different tasks; set up realistic timetables for implementation; appropriate the necessary budgetary resources, and procure any needed skills and materials; and closely monitor the implementation of the strategy.
Early involvement of main stakeholders and clear communication to the public at large of expected results, are essential for securing citizens’ support for the digitalisation effort. Moreover, co-operation among and within different levels of government can play a significant role in supporting effective and efficient digitalisation of SNGs. The case for support by national government is made more compelling by the fact that different SNGs are differently equipped to meet the challenges of digitalisation. Smaller and poorer urban, and especially remote, rural communities are more likely to suffer from skill shortages, limited connectivity and scarcity of budgetary resources. Policy innovation is another important area for inter- governmental co-operation in the digital sphere, with considerable potential for SNGs to launch pilot programmes that can be tested and subsequently taken up by other same- level jurisdictions and/or up-scaled to other levels of administration through gradual experimentation. The pandemic is actually triggering a lot of promising innovation by SNGs that can do much to improve their preparedness to deal with future crises. National governments can support subnational digitalisation efforts. This can be achieved in particular through appropriate reforms to intergovernmental fiscal relation systems, including the assignment of own tax bases to SNGs; greater clarity in the assignment of expenditure responsibilities, and the implementation of equalization transfers; by giving adequate weight to regional digital inclusion in public investment choices; by defining appropriate nation-wide standards to facilitate seamless interfaces among the national and subnational digital systems;
and through technical assistance and training of subnational officials. There is also significant scope for horizontal co-operation among SNGs. Peer support can include demonstration effects, technical assistance and joint training of officials, as well as effective interfaces among subnational digital systems in areas of common interest. Dedicated forums for inter-regional and inter-municipal dialogue on digitalisation issues, possibly under the umbrella of broader horizontal co-operation forums, can be instrumental in facilitating both the exchange of experiences and consensus building on common digitalisation issues. The COVID-19 crisis provides an opportunity to step up the digital transformation of SNGs given the need to act steadfastly during the ongoing containment phase but also in preparation for the post-crisis recovery. The lessons that are emerging from the current experience, if put to good use, can do much to make SNGs better equipped to cope with future crises. Reference de Mello, L. and T. Ter-Minassian (2020), “Digitalisation Challenges and Opportunities for Subnational Governments”, OECD Working Papers on Fiscal Federalism, No. 31, OECD, Paris.
North Korea and the coronavirus pandemic by Vincent Koen and Jinwoan Beom, Country Studies Branch, OECD Economics Department The COVID-19 epidemic started in Wuhan, China, but soon spread across borders and became a pandemic on a scale not witnessed since the 1918 flu pandemic. One of the countries most directly exposed to the outbreak was North Korea, whose economy is not as closed as the “Hermit State” moniker might suggest, but highly dependent on China, as documented in the OECD’s first study on North Korea. The North Korean authorities acted swiftly: Air China flights between Beijing and Pyongyang were suspended on 20 January and so were national carrier Air Koryo flights soon thereafter and Chinese tourism more generally – a major forex lifeline. On 21 January, North Korea was reportedly already working with the World Health Organisation to try and prevent the spread of the virus in the country. Quarantine measures followed, including school and university closures. The North Korean economy has been a statistical black hole for decades but is undergoing substantial transformations. Rapid post-war industrialisation had put the country ahead of South Korea by the time Prof Joan Robinson visited in the mid-1960s, prompting her to wax lyrical: “Eleven years ago in Pyongyang there was not one stone standing upon another (…) Now a modern city of a million inhabitants stands on two sides of the wide river (…) A city without slums (…) Even more remarkable are
the neat villages, scattered over the countryside (…) A nation without poverty (…) everyone is adequately provided with food, clothing, shelter, medical care, and educational opportunities” “All the economic miracles of the postwar world are put in the shade by these achievements (…) Every industry and every service is building up capacity so as to be able to rush aid to the South as soon as communications are opened up.” The “miracle” was not sustained, however, and South Korea’s economy far outpaced North Korea’s during the next three decades, during which trend growth declined and turned negative as Soviet support ended and the terms of trade with China became less friendly. Today, GDP in North Korea is reportedly lower than in 1990, notwithstanding a larger population, and gross national income per capita is down to only a tiny fraction of South Korea’s. A large share of the workforce remains in agriculture but domestic food production is insufficient to avoid widespread chronic undernourishment. Infrastructure shortcomings are glaring, not least with respect to electricity supply and transportation.
At the same time, the scale and breadth of market activities has visibly expanded since the turn of the millennium, as part of a transition to a hybrid system mixing State, Party and army control with decentralised initiative, against the backdrop of a military build-up met by tightening international sanctions. The OECD’s new working paper documents a number of the changes that have taken place North of the 38th parallel. It draws on a wide array of published sources, which rest on limited and often indirect hard evidence and numerous bits of more anecdotal evidence. The study describes the evolution of economic planning, currency reform, “yuanisation”, the proliferation of markets, the emergence of a new mercantile class dubbed the “masters of money” (donju), the development of special economic zones and their failure to attract much
foreign investment, the dispatch of North Korean workers abroad and the promotion of tourism as means to secure forex, and how digitalisation is changing lives. It also discusses the impact of the economic sanctions, which can be seen for example when looking at mirror statistics of official crude oil imports. The study lists some of the myriad ways the sanctions are circumvented, including via a bewildering variety of smuggling channels. In many of the aforementioned areas, the country’s very high dependence on China is striking. This has been particularly evident since the outbreak of the COVID-19 pandemic, which cut off some of North Korea’s major sources of supply and the main market for its products – a situation that is hard to sustain for an economy with limited reserves. Indeed, while North Korea closed its border with China in January 2020, some traffic has reportedly resumed, with exemptions provided by the Chinese authorities to North Korean traders in late March and container trucks seen to again cross the Sino-North Korean Friendship Bridge in early April.
Read the full paper: Vincent Koen and Jinwoan Beom, “North Korea: the last transition economy?”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1607, April 2020. Information on COVID-19 in North Korea: https://www.nknews.org/pro/coronavirus-in-north-korea-tracker/ Europe must act now to prepare the aftermath of the pandemic crisis by Laurence Boone, OECD Chief Economist and Alvaro S. Pereira, Director, Economics Department Country Studies Branch, OECD
We are currently facing extraordinary challenges posed by the Covid-19 pandemic, due to which necessary health measures are shutting down part of our economies and precipitating a recession of unprecedented nature and magnitude. In the immediate response to the crisis, governments increased health spending, but also introduced large fiscal support (e.g. short-time working weeks, extended unemployment schemes, tax and social security deferments, new credit lines, among others, see OECD Policy tracker) in an attempt to mitigate the social and economic impact of the pandemic. In addition, in Europe, the ECB launched a large program of asset purchases and a set of other unprecedented measures, and the European Commission temporarily shut down budget rules and exceptionally lifted state aid rules. Still, given the magnitude of the crisis that we are facing, these measures and packages, albeit important and unprecedented, will not be enough for most European countries to address a post-pandemic world where debt levels will be much higher and the job losses tremendous. According to OECD estimates, the widespread shutdowns needed to contain the spread of the coronavirus and save lives will cause an estimated initial direct output decline of around 25% in many economies (Figure 1).This is equivalent to a contraction of about 2 percentage points of annual GDP per month of confinement. Thus, the 2020 output fall will far exceed that of 2009.
When the confinement is gradually withdrawn, European policymakers will have to do more to speed up the recovery and avoid massive unemployment and firm bankruptcies. The challenge will be significant: many euro area countries will have debt ratios above – and sometimes much above – 100% of GDP, and economic fundamentals will have been hurt. History shows that countries that invest in the recovery, rather than tighten too much too fast, not only accelerate the recovery, but are also able to bring debt down faster. Too rapid fiscal tightening in some countries in 2010/2011 weakened the euro area and left it with long-term scars, including an incomplete restructuring of the banking and corporate sectors, higher structural unemployment, low investment and low inflation, and a failure to revive structural reforms agendas. There is an important positive element in the current crisis:
by committing to “do everything necessary within its mandate”, the ECB has responded forcefully and much faster than in the previous crisis, contributing to and buying precious time for policymakers to work out a sustainable response to this symmetric shock. Europe is building up a multi-pronged response to the crisis and the ensuing recovery, but some debate remains regarding the financial instruments that must be used for this purpose. The EIB is proposing substantial support to firms, and the Commission is proposing to support the unemployed, which seems to have met consensus. But the bulk of Europe’s fiscal response to address the “war effort”-like recovery remains largely individual or national. Unlike in the recent financial crisis, this exogenous shock is shared across countries. The debate is made more complex by some perceptions that the uneven situation across countries is due to different levels of responsibility at the national level, especially regarding fiscal policy. It may be fair to say that much of the debt legacy prior to the crisis is indeed individual countries’ responsibility. But this is not the case for the health and economic efforts resulting from the Covid-19 pandemic. Both the widespread pandemic and the close integration of EU countries argue for a financial response that should be large and shared . Such a response should be clearly differentiated from the stock of debt prior to the Covid-19 crisis. It is imperative to bridge the gap between the existing options in the debate for a forceful response. Two options could provide the EU with the necessary fire power to address this crisis: a new financial instrument featuring joint issuance, and the European Stability Mechanism (ESM). We start with the latter.
The ESM was created by euro area members to mobilise funding and provide financial assistance to countries threatened by or experiencing severe financing problems. Its use involves a rigorous analysis of public debt sustainability and strict policy conditionality, because these difficulties were perceived as resulting from past policies having led to poor economic performance. Obviously, these criteria do not apply in the current crisis. In particular, the strong conditionality attached to financial assistance seems totally inadequate when the crisis arises from a pandemic or a natural disaster. Some are suggesting light conditionality. However, this approach may not be acceptable to those countries that believe that strict conditionality is an explicit requirement for accessing its resources. In addition, the 410 billion euros in unused lending capacity (3.4% of 2019 euro area GDP) seems modest when compared to the needs of the euro area as a whole. In addition, the ESM currently relies on short-term credit facilities having an initial maturity of one year, and renewable twice, each time for six months. Therefore, ESM credit lines provide only limited relief against medium-term rollover risks, which makes it more of a bridge facility to overcome temporary fiscal distress pending a medium to long- term solution. For all these reasons, as it currently stands, the ESM is ill suited to provide widespread fiscal support to euro area countries to counteract the economic fallout of the pandemic. If the ESM is to play a significant role in the challenges posed by the current crisis, its firepower will have to be substantially upgraded, the conditionality requirements will have to be significantly watered down and replaced by an allocation usage condition (namely, fund all pandemic-related spending). An alternative is the creation of European financial
You can also read