How businesses are surviving the Covid-19 shock
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
How businesses are surviving the Covid-19 shock By Sebastian Barnes, OECD Economics Department, and Robert Hillman, Neuron Capital. As the economy locked down in March 2020, there were big concerns about how businesses would survive being unable to open normally with retail premises, offices, factories and construction sites closed. There was a fear that these pressures could trigger a “domino effect” that would ripple through the business sector, leading to widespread job losses and bankruptcies. The Corporate Sector Agent-Based (CAB) Model was developed to look at these questions, taking into account the differences across firms in their activities and financial strength, how firms interact with each other through customer-supplier networks, the rule-of-thumb adjustments firms make and the risk of bankruptcy. Agent-based models are simulation models that build up the behaviour of the aggregate economy from the interaction of individual units. This can lead to insights on aggregate and microeconomic behaviour. The CAB takes a data-rich approach to building a model of the United Kingdom business sector based on the Input-Output connections between sectors, firm characteristics from ORBIS data and evidence on network connections between firms. In the real world, many firms are heavily reliant on a small number of suppliers and customers. Matching final demand to the downturn in UK output during the Covid-19, the model sheds light on the mechanisms at work and alternative policy scenarios. In the absence of any policy response, the Covid-19 shock would have led to a large and lasting fall in output: over 15%
of firms would have failed in the first two years, far above the normal rate and similar to during the Global Finanicial Crisis. Almost a quarter of firms in the Accommodation and Food sector would have failed. The reasons for individual firm failure are multi-factored and simple “domino effects” are rare. The UK rapidly mobilised a large-scale firm-level support programmes from spring 2020, including the Coronavirus Job Retention Scheme (CJRS) “furlough” program and a credit guarantee that helped businesses to borrow. The massive policy response has been highly effective in supporting output and avoiding firm failure. The initial fall in output was reduced and the policy support allows activity to recover after two years to close to what it would have been without Covid-19. Figure 1. With massive policy support, the depth and persistence of the Covid-19 loss of output has been reduced Source: Authors’ calculations based on CAB model. The model predicts that the rate of firm failures with this
policy support should be lower than in normal times, as has been observed in the UK bankruptcy statistics to date. As the Table shows, this counterintuitive outcome reflects the fact that policy has protected almost all the previously profitable firms that would have failed as result of the Covid-19 shock, but also allowed more than half of firms that would have failed in normal times to survive. Table 1. Policy supports have protected firms hard hit by Covid-19 and also supported firms that were already vulnerable % share of firms The survival of less productive firms raises the risks in the years ahead of unproductive “zombie firms” weighing on productivity. They may be joined by other firms that were previously successful, but whose business models have been permanently disrupted by Covid-19 and its effects. These firms may be able to survive financially for a long time, but have little prospect of contributing to the growth of the economy. Could policy have been better targeted? An approach, for example, of only helping previously profitable firms or those in severely affected sectors would have led to fewer inherently weak firms surviving, but at the cost of lowering incomes for workers and slowing the recovery. Given the many challenges of targeting, the use of broad supports during the Covid-19 crisis appears justified. Further reading Barnes, S., R. Hillman, R., G. Wharf and D. McDonald et al. (2021). “The impact of Covid-19 on Corporate Fragility in the United Kingdom: Insights from a new calibrated firm-level Corporate Sector Agent-Based (CAB) Model”, OECD Economics
Department Working Papers, No. 1674, Paris, OECD Publishing Demmou, L. et al (2021), “Insolvency and Debt Overhang Following the Covid-19 Outbreak: Assessment of Risks and Policy Response”, I OECD Economics Working Paper, No. 1651, Paris, OECD Publishing Hillman, R., S. Barnes, G. Wharf and D. McDonald et al. (2021). “A new firm-level model of corporate sector interactions and fragility: the Corporate Agent-Based (CAB) Model”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1675, Paris, OECD Publishing. Reconciling housing and the environment: is it possible, and how? By Grace Alexander, Ioannis Tikoudis, Katherine Farrow and Walid Oueslati, OECD Environment Directorate https://www.oecd.org/housing/policy-toolkit/ Ensuring widespread access to affordable housing constitutes a significant policy challenge in many countries. Increasing housing costs in urban areas push many to live in less
accessible locations and to lower their living standards. This can reduce wellbeing, undermine social cohesion and eventually jeopardize political stability. At the same time, another policy challenge, equally urgent and multifaceted, emerges from climate change and environmental degradation in urban areas. The cost that climate change, air pollution and biodiversity loss impose on modern societies is significant: health, food systems and infrastructure are all affected, and the consequences will only grow if these issues are left unaddressed. Are the housing and environmental crises somehow interrelated? Do governments have the relevant tools to pursue affordability and environmental sustainability at the same time? How we build our urban areas affects housing markets and comes with certain environmental costs. The residential sector accounts for a large share of fine particulate matter (Figure 1), an air pollutant associated with severe health impacts, with the sector responsible for 37% of the emissions of fine particulate matter globally. Limits on building height and density, applied widely around the world, reduce housing supply and contribute to observed house price surges. Similar regulations cause cities to spread outwards, causing irreversible changes on the natural areas surrounding cities and generating more greenhouse gas emissions per capita. The phenomenon of rapid suburban expansion, which has come to be known as urban sprawl, possessed tremendous momentum for decades and continues to be a focal issue in urban development today. Sprawled cities imply greater travel distances, make residents more dependent on their cars and tend to increase the cost of providing public transport services (OECD 2018). Figure 1. Housing accounts for a large share of fine particulate matter
Source: Air emission accounts, OECD Environment Database Reconciling housing and the environment, published in the OECD report “Brick by Brick”, provides an anatomy of such practices, and their long run social cost. The chapter explores ways to build our urban areas by balancing housing affordability and environmental quality. It is not only that housing policies affect the environment, the chapter reports, but also that urban environmental policies can have a significant impact on our house values. Reducing pollution and increasing green spaces increase the value of nearby housing stock. Although energy efficiency regulations may increase construction costs, they also add value to homes that are subject to such regulations. Importantly, the value that environmental regulations can add to the existing housing stock should not be confused with the rise in house prices caused by mechanisms causing artificial scarcity, such as regulatory constraints on housing supply. Ultimately, the homes that we live in and the environment around us are crucial to our health and wellbeing. By considering the effect of the residential sector on the environment, and vice versa, the chapter outlines how we may be able to strike a sustainable balance between the two.
Further Reading: OECD (2021), Brick by Brick: Building Better Housing Policies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/b453b043-en. OECD (2021), Reconciling Housing and the Environment., Brick by Brick: Building Better Housing Policies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/96aaa66a-en OECD (2018), Rethinking Urban Sprawl: Moving Towards Sustainable Cities, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264189881-en. Fostering a resilient recovery and sustainable growth in Iceland By Hansjörg Blöchliger and Vassiliki Koutsogeorgopoulou, OECD Economics Department Iceland went through a comparatively mild COVID-19 health crisis. Containment measures were less severe than elsewhere, and all domestic restrictions were lifted at the end of June 2021. Yet the economy suffered a lot. Following lockdowns and travel restrictions worldwide, tourism, Iceland’s most important export sector, collapsed with only around a fourth of foreigners arriving in 2020 compared to the previous year. GDP declined by 6.6% in 2020, and unemployment rose to 8%. Even before the pandemic, other sectors had started to draw level with tourism as growth engines. The pharmaceutical industry continues to develop rapidly, and digital services such as data processing and storage benefit from Iceland’s low
energy prices and cool and windy climate. Fisheries are climbing up the value chain with fresh seafood and aquaculture rising fast. Innovative carbon capture technologies help reduce carbon emissions and provide export income. Figure 1. The economy was hard hit as foreign tourism collapsed Note: Passengers who go through security at Keflavík Airport. Source: OECD, National Accounts database; and Statistics Iceland. Macro policy supported households and firms Like overseas, monetary and fiscal policy cushioned the blow for households and firms. In addition, the government plans to increase spending on infrastructure, digital and green transition, and research and development by around 0.5% points of annual GDP over the next few years, to ensure a healthy and sustainable recovery. Yet public debt could continue to rise since Iceland, as a small open economy, is highly vulnerable to external shocks. To maintain fiscal space, the government should start consolidating once the recovery is firmly underway. Although Iceland’s population is young and active, the government should start addressing disability, pension and long-term care spending.
Structural reform could help boost productivity Regulation is restrictive, hampering sound competition. Administrative burdens and an extensive licensing and permit system slow the entry of new and innovative firms. Skills gaps are considerable. To boost productivity and diversify the economy, regulation particularly in the tourism and construction sectors should be eased. The quality of education, from primary to tertiary, should be better aligned with the needs of economy and society. Fostering innovation is crucial for strong economic performance in the digital era Innovation outcomes remain weak in some critical areas, notably ICT. Despite generous R&D tax incentives, many smaller firms have not been inclined to innovate. Icelandic firms should also be encouraged to step up the adoption of digital technologies, which would help the country make the most of innovation niches. Improving framework conditions and easier access to finance for young innovative firms are important. At the same time, the provision of digital skills needs to be strengthened and knowledge exchange enhanced, through closer business-university collaboration on innovation. Making climate action more cost-efficient and inclusive Iceland’s per capita greenhouse gas emissions exceed the OECD average, partly because of emission-intensive aluminium smeltering. The government committed to reduce emissions from their 2005 level by at least 40% by 2030. Iceland’s climate policy should rely on effective carbon pricing, complemented by investment in low-carbon technology and participation in international projects to finance emission reduction in transition and emerging market economies. Revenues from carbon pricing could be redistributed to households and firms. https://www.oecd.org/economy/iceland-economic-snapshot/
Enhancing digital diffusion for higher productivity growth in Spain By Aida Caldera Sánchez, Müge Adalet McGowan and Yosuke Jin Digitalisation is transforming the Spanish economy, changing the way firms operate, with positive implications for productivity. However, these changes are not evenly shared between high and low productivity firms, or small and large firms (Figure 1), which can help explain why aggregate productivity gains from digitalisation have been modest in Spain so far. Hence, Spain still has considerable scope to reap the benefits of the adoption of digital technologies and, perhaps more importantly, their effective use to produce new business models and products, as discussed in the 2021 Economic Survey of Spain (OECD, 2021; Jin, 2021). Figure 1. The adoption of digital technologies varies with firm size Percentage of firms which adopt each technology, 2019
Note: “Small firms” stands for small enterprises with 10-49 employees, while “Large firms” stands for large enterprises with 250 employees and more. Source: OECD, ICT Access and Usage by Businesses (database). The pandemic has shown the benefits of a more digitalised economy (e-commerce, teleworking) and accelerated the pace of digital adoption, with the extent of teleworking and digital sales increasing in Spain during the last year. The Spanish Recovery, Resilience and Transformation Plan allocates 29% of funds to digitalisation, which will help Spain achieve its ambitious objectives laid out in its national digital strategy, “Digital Spain 2025”. In this context of the increasing importance of digitalisation in Spain, the Survey analyses the challenges and opportunities that digitalisation offers through three types of policies. First, good communications infrastructure is a prerequisite to adopt and use digital technologies. This is an area where Spain ranks relatively well in international perspective, with a high share of fibre in total fixed broadband subscriptions and a relatively widespread internet usage. The coverage of fibre networks in rural areas is also well above that in other European countries (46% vs. 21%). Nonetheless, the digital divide between urban and rural areas in Spain remains, even if it has narrowed recently. Barriers to “rights of way” – permission to install necessary equipment – are high in some
regions and municipalities, and should be reduced to lower deployment costs. Second, there are complementary factors that are key to take full advantage of digitalisation. These include organisational capital and managerial skills, R&D and digital skills. There are important gaps in these areas in Spain. For example, business investment in intangible assets and R&D are relatively low. To boost innovation and reap the full benefits of digitalisation, the Survey recommends boosting partnerships between the public and the private sector, for example by enhancing the role of Technology Centres to increase cooperation between research institutes and SMEs, which need to innovate and use digital technologies more. There is also ample room to develop ICT skills, especially for low-educated and older people (Figure 2). Reducing the mismatch between the skills employers need and the qualifications of jobseekers should be a priority. This would help in particular low productivity firms and low-skilled people, making the benefits of digitalisation shared by all. Targeting training to those with lower digital skills and shifting financial incentives for lifelong training at least partially to training programmes chosen by individuals rather than employers would help achieve these outcomes. Figure 2. There is room to develop digital skills Percentage of respondents claiming to have basic digital skills, 2019
Source: Eurostat, Digital skills (database). Finally, policies, which raise competitive pressures and sharpen incentives to better use digital technologies and better access to finance, can also enhance the diffusion of digital technologies. For example, the Survey recommends fostering the implementation of the Markey Unity Law to reduce regulatory differences across regions and facilitate the growth and entry of new firms and this way encourage the adoption of new technologies. It also recommends strengthening targeted support to new and high-potential firms through public guarantee schemes. In addition to these policies, which facilitate the entry and expansion of innovative firms, it is also important to ensure the efficient exit of non-viable firms and restructuring of viable firms in temporary distress. An effective insolvency regime can help reduce the barriers and costs of firm restructuring or exit and facilitates technological experimentation. In this context, promoting out- of-court insolvency proceedings, especially for SMEs, is key. References: Jin, Y. (2021), “Enhancing digital diffusion for higher productivity growth in Spain”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1673, OECD Publishing, Paris. OECD (2021), OECD Economic Surveys: Spain 2021, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/79e92d88-en.
A recipe for lower house prices By Volker Ziemann, OECD Economics Department https://www.oecd.org/housing/policy-toolkit/ Does housing need to become always more and more expensive relative to other services, eating an ever-higher share of income? This situation puts a strain on household finances, making it complicated for people to move close to jobs and often generating macro-economic or financial risks. The economy’s capacity to meet the demand for housing and supply dwellings where they are demanded is crucial to avoid these excessive price and rent increases, contribute to macroeconomic stability and facilitate residential mobility. The OECD has recently launched a report entitled “Brick by Brick: Building Better Housing Policies” to help analysts and policymakers make better housing policies. At its core, one of its chapters focuses on the fundamental drivers of housing supply and demand and the relevance of housing policies to ensure affordable and quality housing for all. The empirical framework underlying the analysis builds on the famous stock-flow model for housing in which i) a positive (negative) shock to housing demand increases (decreases) house
prices, ii) higher (lower) house prices boost (reduce) housing investment, and iii) higher (lower) supply of housing feeds back into house prices and partly offsets the initial demand shock. In this framework, demand and supply elasticities jointly determine how much of a change in demand feeds into prices and how much into construction. Figure 1. Stock-flow model of housing These elasticities depend to a great extent on housing-related policies. Eliminating mortgage interest deduction, for instance, mitigates house prices increases amid demand pressures (lower demand elasticity). A high degree of decentralisation of land-use decisions is generally associated with more restrictive land-use policy settings consistent with the home-voter hypothesis (lower supply elasticity). Strict rental market regulation inhibits new construction by reducing the incentives to invest in
rental housing (lower supply elasticity). These housing-related policies differ considerably across countries. Accordingly, expected benefits from moving towards best policy practices also vary across countries and policy tools. Figure 2 illustrates the expected reductions in house- price to income ratios.[1] Figure 2. Housing affects society and the economy in multiple ways Note: Simulated change between 2020 and 2050 in the number of years over which cumulated average household disposable income equals the average price of a 100m2 dwelling (in years). Source: OECD (2021), Brick by Brick: Building Better Housing Policies, OECD Publishing. Residential construction is simulated to expand by more than 20% in Sweden if rent control becomes as flexible as in New Zealand, increasing the housing stock in 2050 by around 11%, which could reduce house prices in Sweden by around 1.5 years of disposable income for the typical 100m2 dwelling. Sweden, alongside the Netherlands, would also be the largest beneficiary in terms of housing affordability from eliminating mortgage interest deductibility. New Zealand, in turn, could boost affordability the most by streamlining the governance of land-use policies across levels of government.
These examples illustrate the great potential of housing policy reforms. Many more are discussed in the report. A dedicated Policy Toolkit including an online Dashboard and Country Snapshots allows policymakers to compare their country’s housing outcomes and policies. Finally, a Policy Action Tool helps implement such reforms by anticipating synergies and trade-offs across various outcome dimensions. [1] Measured by the reduction, compared to the baseline of no policy-change, in the number of years over which cumulated average household disposable income equals the average price of a 100m2 dwelling. Monetary policy and housing markets: interactions and side effects By Ernest Gnan, Oesterreichische Nationalbank (OeNB) and the 1 European Money and Finance Forum. https://www.oecd.org/housing/policy-toolkit/ Monetary policy influences housing prices through the level of
interest rates (cost of credit, discount rate, attractiveness vis-à-vis other investments). The housing market affects aggregate demand through construction activity and its influence on consumption (wealth and income effects). Housing booms and busts can threaten financial and macroeconomic stability, and thus ultimately also feed through to consumer price inflation. Central banks can thus not ignore housing market developments. But monetary policy is too crude an instrument to target house prices. A new class of instruments – macroprudential policies – has been created and fills this gap since the Global Financial Crisis. Moreover, housing prices are substantially driven by structural housing policies which affect housing supply and demand. At the same time, including owner-occupied housing in the consumer price basket helps to adequately feed this important part of households’ expenditure into central banks’ reaction functions. While monetary policies worldwide have undoubtedly played a central role in containing the economic fallout from COVID-19, potential side effects, such as shooting up housing prices, and the proportionality of long-lasting unconventional monetary policy measures need to gain increasing attention as economies are bouncing back from the COVID crisis. Why should central banks pay attention to a specific sector such as the housing market? Central banks worldwide are mandated with ensuring price stability, subject to this (or in parallel with, as in the US Fed) also with supporting growth and employment. Their price stability objective is usually coined in terms of consumer price inflation. Monetary policy is a rather “crude” instrument, which affects aggregate demand broadly, and cannot usually be targeted towards developments in specific sectors. So, why should monetary policy care about developments in a specific sector such as the housing market? There are several channels in which housing is relevant for the transmission of monetary policy impulses such as changes
in official interest rates or in bond market yields through QE. First, the level of short-term and long-term interest rates influences mortgage credit rates. So, it makes purchasing a home more (or less) affordable. Thus, demand for housing – and thus employment, aggregate demand and ultimately also consumer price inflation – rises (or falls). Mortgage loans make up 77% of euro area households’ total borrowing (ECB, 2021). The growth of euro area mortgage loans continued its upward trend observed since 2016 to reach around 5% in nominal terms most recently. In 2019, in the EU and euro area gross value added in the construction sector made up 5.4% and 5%, respectively, of GDP, with a wide range of 1.7% to 7.4% across EU countries, though. Construction projects are typically financed to a substantial extent through credit. So, financing costs exert a potentially strong effect on construction activity. Figure 1. Housing makes up a major part of households’ lending and is an important economic sector Positive and negative wealth and income effects from house
price rises Second, the value of an asset is influenced by the net present value of the stream of income from this asset. In the case of housing, this income can either be rental income or the implicit income from using the house (in the case of owner- occupied housing). If the discount rate falls (as implied by lower official interest rates), then the net present value of a home rises. Looser monetary policy thus, ceteris paribus, raises real estate prices. This rise in housing prices can affect household consumption in various ways. First, it can entail that households feel richer and can take out an additional mortgage on their house, to finance other expenditures. In this case, we observe a positive wealth effect. Conversely, rising house prices can also imply that for instance young households need to spend a higher fraction of the disposable income on housing, leaving less for other consumption (see e.g. OECD, 2021). In this case, there would be a negative income effect from rising house prices. Whether the positive or negative wealth and income effects prevail, depends on the fraction of homeowners versus tenants and demographic factors. If, for instance homeowners benefiting from wealth increases have a lower propensity to consume than those just buying a home, the net effect on aggregate consumption will likely be negative. Similarly, rising rents (which are the likely consequence, with some lag and to a certain extent, depending on countries’ institutional and legal frameworks, of higher house prices) will benefit landlords, while tenants will have less of their income left for other consumption. Assuming that renters are wealthier and have a lower propensity to consume than tenants, then a rise in house prices and rents will on aggregate dampen consumption for non-housing goods. A very similar argument applies to households which take out a loan to finance their homes: higher house prices imply the need for a bigger loan, implying lower disposable household income after loan
servicing. Thus, the wealth and income effects from residential price swings also imply substantial redistributive effects across individuals and demographic groups (see e.g. OECD, 2021). Figure 2. Real estate price developments in the euro area Source: ECB (2021). Housing booms and busts threaten financial and macroeconomic stability There is a second reason why central banks carefully look at housing market developments, which has gained prominence in the Global Financial Crisis (GFC): housing market bubbles can trigger and fuel economic booms, which subsequently end up in deep busts. Monetary policy can fuel such housing booms by making credit very cheap, thus encouraging excessive leverage among households. Real estate booms can also, at a more structural level, entail that an excessive fraction of economic activity goes into construction (as was the case in several countries prior to the GFC). Once the housing bubble bursts, a deep financial crisis can be the result, which requires the central bank to take emergency measures to prevent a collapse of the financial system, but also to dampen the resulting recession and the accompanying excessive fall of consumer price inflation, way below the central bank’s target,
potentially even into negative territory. Some economists thus argue that central banks should “lean against the wind” in the face of rising real estate prices. Even if the central bank might not target asset prices, leaning against the wind might be justified since it also helps to cushion excessive swings in consumer price inflation which may be triggered by real estate booms and busts. Others argue that such “preemptive” monetary policy tightening entails high macroeconomic costs in terms of foregone employment and output. Monetary policy is, according to this view, too crude a tool to take real estate prices into account and should exclusively focus on consumer price inflation. Macroprudential policies as a new tool to address housing cycles This is why, notably after the GFC, a consensus has emerged that an additional set of instruments, “macroprudential rules”, should be applied to cool down overheating asset price developments, e.g. by raising loan-to-value ratios or loan service-to-income ratios applied by banks when they grant housing credits (see e.g. ESRB, 2021, ECB, 2021 and OECD, 2021). These new policies have been implemented around the world and experience is accumulating in their application. Note, however, that in practice the stylized notion of two totally separate tools for two clearly distinct economic goals – monetary policy to stabilize consumer price inflation, and macroprudential policies to prevent asset booms and busts – does not fully do justice to a far more complex reality. Including owner-occupied housing in consumer price inflation to better reflect households’ comprehensive cost of living developments in central banks’ reaction functions One way how home prices feed into the central bank’s reaction function is by including the cost of accommodation in the consumer price index. This is already the case for rents. By contrast, at least in most European countries, it is not yet
the case for owner-occupied homes. This implies that the cost of housing for owner-occupiers (including e.g. young families buying a home) is neglected in the measurement of consumer prices and thus in the central bank’s reaction function; it also implies that house price bubbles risk to escape the central bank’s formal reaction function. Including owner- occupied housing is thus useful for improving the metrics used to inform monetary policy. Side effects and proportionality of monetary expansion gain weight as economies bounce back from COVID Another way how asset price developments, including house prices, can enter the central bank’s reaction function is through explicit consideration of side effects and the proportionality of monetary policy measures. Not even the best medicine comes without side effects. To take the current situation of the COVID crisis, clearly central banks had to step in to contain damage to our economies. Central banks are aware of the “side effects” of these policies, such as rising stock prices but also, in many countries, further rising house prices. To contain the latter, e.g. the ECB explicitly excluded mortgage credit from eligibility for meeting banks’ lending benchmarks in order to benefit from preferential interest rates on the ECB’s Targeted Long-Term Refinancing Operations (TLTROs). As mentioned, asset price increases in general, and housing price rises more specifically, may also entail large wealth gains for those already owning these assets, implying large distributive effects. Stronglyexpansionary, unconventional monetary policies over long periods thus ultimately raise the question of proportionality. It is not straightforward how to weigh the benefits against the (potential) costs – there is substantial uncertainty and any decisions ultimately rely on careful judgement. What seems clear, though, is that as the duration of expansionary monetary policy measures extends and as signs of “ exuberance” in asset markets including
residential real estate markets intensify, while the economy seems clearly back on track, the case for taking side effects and proportionality duly into account is becoming more urgent. References ECB (2021). Financial Stability Review, May. ESRB (2021). Lower for longer – macroprudential policy issues arising from the low interest rate environment June 2021. Report by the Joint Task Force of ESRB Advisory Technical Committee (ATC), ESRB Advisory Scientific Committee (ASC), and ESCB Financial Stability Committee (FSC), June. Fell, J., and T. Shakir (2021). May 2021 Financial Stability Review. Presentation at SUERF-Baffi Bocconi Webinar, May 19, 2021. OECD (2021), Brick by Brick: Building Better Housing Policies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/b453b043-en. Housing policy strategies – what is best practice? by Arent Skjæveland, Deputy Director of the Economic Policy Department of Norway’s Ministry of Finance and Chairman of the Working Party No. 1 of the OECD’s Economic Policy Committee.
https://www.oecd.org/housing/policy-toolkit/ The first phase of the horizontal housing project has been completed, resulting in a new OECD Toolkit for housing policy that can guide national reform efforts. The toolkit complements the OECD housing policy strategy. The core importance of the housing market both for welfare and efficiency in our economies makes this toolkit highly relevant and timely. First, debt-driven housing market bubbles are at the root of many financial crises and may imply harsh and very long- lasting downturns. Let me take my own country as an example. The financial crisis in Norway in the late 1800s, the so- called Christiania crash (that was the name of the capital at that time), left deep scars. Not only among ordinary people who saw their fortunes evaporate, but also in the city’s physical landscape. Large parts of today’s city centre in Oslo were built during the housing market frenzy of the 1890s. When the housing market collapsed in 1899, most building activity came to a standstill that lasted for two decades, leaving the architecture of the 1890s as one of the city’s distinctive characteristics. It took 90-years for house prices, in real terms, to recover most of their losses.
A new financial crisis was then approaching. The Norwegian banking crisis in the late 1980s is one of the worst financial crises in advanced economies in modern times according to Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff. Real house prices declined by 40 percent and did not return to pre-crisis levels for more than 12 years. The impact of the crisis was harsh, as the number of unemployed tripled and the three largest banks in the country collapsed. In recent years, house prices have surged once again, fuelled in part by low interest rates at home and abroad. However, we really have a close eye on this. Much is done at the demand side with macroprudential regulations to contribute to more sustainable household debt at the supply side to reduce building cost. Certainly, a lesson both from our crises-experiences and similar crises in other countries is that the housing market is at the core of financial stability and far too important to be left at its own. Not only for financial stability, but also for a range of other aspects of the welfare of the population. To own the house you live in, is of great value to most
people. Owning a house often gives a sense of safety and security. In Norway, 80 percent of households own the house they live in. A high level of home ownership is a typical pattern in most OECD countries, with an OECD average of about 68 percent. Housing is typically the largest asset in household balance sheets, as well as one of the largest spending items in household budgets. Housing market developments are therefore of great influence for the distribution of income and wealth. Housing is a fundamental driver of the accumulation and the distribution of wealth and debt within and across generations. This has a strong link to housing affordability. House prices across the OECD countries have raised to levels that may undermine housing affordability, particularly for low-income households, first-time buyers and in fast-growing urban areas. Access to affordable housing is crucial for achieving a number of key policy objectives, including poverty and homelessness reduction, equality of opportunities and sustainable growth. What policy avenues to follow to achieve housing affordability are challenging. As an example: Tax subsidies to homeownership often favours insiders, as house prices are pushed upwards, making the step into the housing market for first-time buyers even more difficult. Housing is also important for productivity and the growth potential of our economies. A main channel is via the impact on the mobility of workers. The degree of geographical mobility has strong implications for the functioning of the labour market as it affects the job-matching process and use of human resources. This is of crucial importance when labour market developments between regions show an asymmetric development. In this respect, high transaction taxes on houses or difficult access to reasonably priced housing in other regions can trap workers in unemployment or low-productivity jobs, and workers can even end up falling out of the labour market. Such obstacles to worker mobility may have strong
effects on economic efficiency. Another aspect of housing development is how it may affect environmental outcomes, including thorough interactions with urban land-use patterns, residential energy consumption and transport systems. Here there has been a complete change in many countries over the last decades. One might say that car use strongly influenced urban planning in the former millennium. Currently, public transport, less parking, more cycling, less cars in the city centres and better clustering of living areas are more at the forefront. Net zero emissions are the new keywords in urban planning and transport policy. Building land is a scarce resource in urban areas, and it is a strong tendency that big cities experience a stronger house price growth than more rural areas. When working on national house policy strategies, we have to address such differences between pressure areas and areas with less pressure. Taking all this together – a multi-facetted housing policy strategy is needed. Such a strategy has to cut across many policy areas, including financial regulation, taxation, carbon footprint, urban land use regulation, transport policies, local public finance, social housing, welfare support, housing standards, rental regulation and the enforcement of competition in related activities as construction and real estate. To be successful making such national strategies, we need to learn from the each other. What is best practice? The new OECD Toolkit for housing policy and the OECD Housing Policy Strategy give many of the relevant answers. Further insights and policy implications can be found in the new OECD report Brick by Brick: Building Better Housing Policies. The accompanying online toolkit features a Dashboard of indicators covering outcomes and policy settings, Country Snapshots of the housing sector, and a Policy Action Tool that allows policymakers to anticipate synergies and trade-offs across various outcome dimensions
before implementing housing reforms. How will rising shipping cost affect inflation in OECD countries? by Sophie Guilloux-Nefussi and Elena Rusticelli, OECD Economics Department How will rising shipping cost affect inflation in OECD countries? Extraordinary demand and supply factors have pushed up freight prices Shipping cost rates have soared in recent months due to the conjunction of booming demand for consumer durables from Asia and supply-side bottlenecks created by sanitary restrictions in ports and terminals. These have slowed loading and unloading operations and crew changes. Prices of containerised freight started to rise in the second half of 2020 and rose further in the first quarter of 2021, when the average quarterly increase across the main indices of global shipping costs ranged between 30% and 65% (Figure 1). Figure 1: Container shipping prices are on the rise since mid-2020
On the demand side, the pandemic led to a global demand drop at the start of 2020, followed by a quick recovery at the end of the same year. Pent-up demand caused by lockdowns in the first half of 2020, shifts in consumption patterns towards durable goods, and government income support all strengthened demand for goods when transportation services were still limited. On the supply side, multiple factors are compounding shipping delays. Vessels are currently used at almost full capacity and containers remain scarce. Congestion at ports, and lower productivity at terminals and inland depots have also led to bottlenecks. Distancing rules and reinforced hygiene standards have increased intervals between crew shifts. These have prolonged processing times at ports, hampered the return of containers to Asia and generated delays along the entire shipping chain. The March blockage in the Suez Canal also added to shipping disruption and tensions. This atypical situation is expected to persist for a few more months. Port congestion continues to be a big bottleneck in the United States, where all loading/unloading slots for
cargoes from/to Asia are fully booked throughout the second quarter of 2021. The reopening of European economies is also impacting supply and demand. In this context, industry experts do not foresee any normalisation of prices before the end of 2021. Rising shipping costs could push up inflation temporarily in OECD countries To which extent will the observed rise in global shipping costs impact inflation across OECD countries? The empirical approach to answer this question proceeds in two steps: first, quantifying the pass-through of shipping costs to merchandise import price inflation, and, second, assessing the transmission of import price inflation to consumer price inflation. In the baseline scenario, shipping costs are assumed to rise by 50% in the first quarter of 2021 and to stabilise at the same level for the rest of the year, in line with the recent industry experts’ projections. However, the uncertainty around forthcoming container freight rates remains high and, therefore, two alternative scenarios are considered: one of anticipated normalisation in which shipping costs gradually decline to a price level slightly higher than prior to the pandemic starting from the second half of 2021, and one of delayed normalisation in which the initial rise is followed by a further 10% increase in each of the three remaining quarters of 2021. Figure 2 – Effect of global shipping costs developments on OECD merchandise import prices and consumer prices
In the first quarter, the observed rise in shipping costs is estimated to boost merchandise import price inflation (year- on-year) in OECD countries by 2.5 percentage points on average. After four quarters, depending on the scenario, the impact on merchandise import price inflation could still be between 0.6 to 3.5 percentage points (Figure 2, Panel A). Notwithstanding the swift reaction of import costs, the pass- through to consumer price inflation would be modest. The overall rise in CPI inflation would be by about 0.2 percentage points after four quarters, with no major divergence across the three scenarios (Figure 2, Panel B). Consumer price inflation would start to recede gradually thereafter and settle back over the following 2-year period, reflecting the large inertia in price adjustments of consumption goods. Given the relatively small portion of transport costs normally incorporated in final goods value, this result is not surprising2 and is in line with previous estimates available for the US economy (based on a different methodology).3 Arguably, the rise in ocean shipping costs could compound with other input costs pressures − due to global shortages in specific industries like semiconductors − and rising commodity prices to further push up inflation in the coming months. However, these cost-push pressures are expected to be temporary. Inflation expectations are well anchored and global spare capacity remains sizeable. As a result, a significant and sustained pick-up in underlying inflation is unlikely
beyond a few quarters and monetary authorities should look through these transitory relative price shocks. References: ECB (2021), “What is driving the recent surge in shipping costs?”, Economic Bulletin, Issue 3 / 2021 – Box 1. Guilloux-Nefussi, S. and E. Rusticelli (forthcoming 2021), “Recent developments in input costs on global markets and their consequences on inflation in OECD countries”. Herriford, T., E. Johnson, N. Sly, and A. Lee Smith (2016), “How Does a Rise in International Shipping Costs Affect U.S. Inflation?,” Macro Bulletin, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. OECD (2021), “Rising container shipping costs could push up near-term inflation in OECD countries”, OECD Economic Outlook No 109 (Edition 2021/1), Chapter 1, Box 1.3. The Netherlands: Building a stronger recovery By Daniela Glocker, OECD Economics Department The Netherlands is recovering from its largest economic contraction since the Second World War. Almost overnight, the COVID-19 outbreak restricted people’s daily lives. Work and education shifted to take place from home. Many businesses offering non-essential but close contact jobs could not easily adjust, leading to a reduction in working
hours or number of employed. Travel, social interactions, shopping, cultural and leisure activities were restricted to hold back the spread of the virus. The Dutch government swiftly implemented a comprehensive support package, and extended and adjusted the measures several times in response to prolonged restrictions. These policies reduced uncertainty and protected people, businesses and jobs. In combination with structural and institutional strengths and a high level of digitalisation, the generous fiscal support helped the country to weather the COVID-19 crisis with limited economic damage compared to many OECD countries (Figure 1). Figure 1. The economy contracted less than elsewhere Real GDP, Index Q4 2019=100 Note: The pre-crisis growth path is based on the November 2019 OECD Economic Outlook projection, with linear extrapolation for 2022 based on trend growth in 2021. Source: OECD Economic Outlook 106 and 109 databases. The start of the vaccination campaign earlier this year marked the beginning of the end of the health emergency. As the Dutch roll up their sleeves, restrictions are progressively lifted, business and consumer confidence are improving, and the economy is set to recover gradually. The 2021 Economic Survey of the Netherlands foresees annual growth of 2.7% in 2021 and 3.7% in 2022, with GDP recovering the pre- crisis level at the beginning of 2022. Private
consumption will drive the recovery as households can eat out, shop and enjoy many of the social, cultural and leisure possibilities that have been off-limits during the pandemic. Nevertheless, private consumption will be held back by households facing an increase in pension premiums and rising unemployment as the result of support measures being phased out. Uncertainties still abound. Quicker than expected vaccine roll out can contribute to faster economic growth, especially if returning confidence spurs people to spend some of the savings amassed during the pandemic. On the other hand, potential outbreaks of vaccine-resistant virus strains could postpone the recovery. Well-targeted fiscal support should remain in place in the short term to support the recovery, but the government should also plan forward and carefully weigh permanent spending increases against pressures emerging from population ageing and related health care expenditures. The 2021 Economic Survey of the Netherlands argues that coming out of the pandemic is an opportunity to build back stronger, fairer and greener, by addressing some long-standing structural challenges: In the Netherlands, a high share of workers are on non- standard contracts. This trend has increased over recent years, driven largely by lower labour costs for the self-employed and other non-standard workers than for regular employed. During the crisis, self-employed and other flexible workers on freelance or on-call contracts were more likely to lose their job as the job retention scheme mainly protected workers on permanent contracts. Temporary contracts are also used more frequently in hospitality and service sectors, which were hit hard by the COVID-19 crisis, in lower skilled occupations and among young workers. Although the government provided some income support for the self-employed, the crisis may have exacerbated income
inequality. Implementing the Commission for the Regulation of Work recommendations is key to reducing labour market duality. More should also be done to reduce the gap in part-time work between women and men. People living in the Netherlands are exposed to the risk of local air pollution and to climate change risks such as floods, as large parts of the country are below sea level. People’s exposure to nitrogen emissions remains among the highest in the EU owing to high population density, high industrial and agricultural production and being home to Europe’s main seaport. A High Court ruling in 2019 stipulated a re- evaluation of permits for a range of nitrogen emitting activities, notably for construction and agriculture projects near natural preservation areas. The available nitrogen space for new developments remains limited, constraining new investment in infrastructure, buildings and agriculture. Greenhouse gas emissions are also high compared to the EU average, and a High Court ruling in 2019 mandated a 25% reduction compared to 1990 levels by the end of 2020. This prompted a reduction in coal power capacity and other measures. The 2020 target was just met, owing in part to the COVID-19 crisis that reduced economic activity and mobility. Long-run prosperity and people’s well-being hinge on the reduction of local air pollution and greenhouse gas emissions, which requires concrete national-level actions, as well as enhanced regional and international cooperation. High debt and a high share of illiquid assets, mainly housing, held by households create macroeconomic and financial vulnerabilities. Household debt is at more than 200% of disposable income, among the highest in the OECD, mainly consisting of mortgages. Limited housing supply and favourable tax treatment for owner-occupied housing have contributed to soaring house prices. As a result, home-owners are not only better off compared to
people not yet owning a house, i.e. often the young and people on non-standard work contracts, due to higher equity, but also compared to investors of other assets. A possible future correction in house prices is a risk to economic growth, as households who suffer large capital losses tend to cut back on consumption in order to continue servicing their debt. A more balanced housing market with affordable prices and a better functioning rental market would not only reduce inequality and macroeconomic risks but also boost growth. A coherent package of reforms is needed, including to the tax treatment of owner-occupied housing, spatial planning and rental regulations. As the Netherlands re-emerges from the shadows of the pandemic, and people and businesses are weaned off emergency support, it is not the time to return to the old ways. It is the time to build a new future. A future that is better. Better Housing For All: How to Square the Circle by Volker Zieman, OECD Economics Department https://www.oecd.org/housing/policy-toolkit/
Housing is one of the most complex policy challenges of our time. There is, of course, the affordability issue and how to cope with the concentration of demand in supply-constrained areas. Yet, the functioning of housing markets also reflects other burning challenges of our lifetimes, including social cohesion, financial resilience, residential and intergenerational mobility or the ecological transition. Against this background, the OECD has launched a Housing Policy Toolkit to help policymakers address these intertwined challenges. The overarching theme is assessing the performance of housing markets across three main policy objectives: social inclusiveness, economic efficiency and environmental sustainability. Figure 1. Housing affects society and the economy in multiple ways Making housing more inclusive Access to affordable housing – a basic human need and central driver of well-being – has become increasingly challenging for many households in OECD countries. Housing-related spending absorbs on average about one-third of household budgets, a
share that has been rising over time. Over the past two decades, prices have risen by 60% more for homes than for goods and services on average across OECD countries. Low interest rates have helped households absorb part, but not all, of these higher prices. Seven of the 23 OECD countries for which the data are available have experienced real house prices in excess of 90%. Moreover, increasingly steep house prices gradients in urban areas make housing close to economic and cultural amenities unaffordable for most families. The resulting spatial segregation by income threatens social cohesion and undermines economic and ecological efficiency. Making housing more efficient The affordability challenge very much reflects the housing sector’s failure to raise supply where demand is strong, particularly in jobs-rich urban areas, which drives up house prices and rents. This is due to geographical constraints but also regulatory restrictions in many cities, including land- use and zoning provisions. In some cases, regulations on tenant-landlord relations, introduced to alleviate the near- term burden of housing costs mainly for incumbent tenants, can discourage the supply of rental dwellings or push up rents, thereby undermining affordability over time. Moreover, housing has often been at the core of financial crises, but there is room for policy, especially prudential regulations, to smooth house price fluctuations and make the economy more resilient to housing shocks. Making housing more sustainable The transition to a carbon-neutral, clean economy poses a formidable challenge for a sector that accounts for 17% of global CO2 emissions and 37% of global fine particulate matter emissions. Progress in this area calls for lowering the carbon footprint of new constructions and improving the energy efficiency of the existing building stock. Almost two-thirds of countries worldwide still lack mandatory building energy
codes. Frontloading efforts is critical as dwellings have a very long lifespan. Besides, energy poverty tends to compound the affordability challenge, as nearly 20% of low-income people in the OECD area experience difficulties heating their homes. Addressing challenges through concerted policy action Some policies can deliver progress across multiple objectives. This is the case, for example, of increasing government investment in social housing, alleviating restrictive regulations on land use and shifting housing taxation towards recurrent levies on immovable property. Other reforms may involve trade-offs, calling for compensatory measures to ensure balanced progress. For instance, more flexible regulations on landlord-tenant relations, including rent control, can encourage housing investment, reduce supply- demand mismatches and lower barriers to residential mobility, but they could also penalise vulnerable incumbent tenants. Similar intertemporal trade-offs apply to relief measures taken during the COVID-19 crisis. Further insights and policy implications can be found in the new OECD report Brick by Brick: Building Better Housing Policies. The accompanying online toolkit features a Dashboard of indicators covering outcomes and policy settings, Country Snapshots of the housing sector, and a Policy Action Tool that allows policymakers to anticipate synergies and trade-offs across various outcome dimensions before implementing housing reforms.
You can also read