FISCAL CAPACITY IN NEW YORK: THE CITY VERSUS THE REGION
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 3 (September 1998) pp. 531-40 FISCAL CAPACITY IN NEW YORK FISCAL CAPACITY IN NEW YORK: THE CITY VERSUS THE REGION * HOWARD CHERNICK Abstract - This paper addresses the public services, which is comparable in difficulties in developing comparative quality to that of their suburban measures of fiscal capacity for jurisdic- competitors, at a competitive price. A tions with widely varying authority to key element in meeting this competitive levy taxes, with particular reference to test is the fiscal capacity of the city. If a New York City (NYC) and its region. It city’s fiscal capacity is weak or declining compares income and property wealth relative to the region, it will be forced to in the region and computes both make fiscal choices along a politically representative tax system and income- and economically unattractive frontier of with-exporting measures of capacity. In low public services or high tax rates. terms of both income and taxable This paper presents initial estimates of property wealth, NYC’s values per fiscal capacity for the largest city in the household are low relative to the country and its surrounding region region. However, taking account of the within New York State. The research is City’s ability to export taxes to non- part of a larger project on fiscal equity in residents, its fiscal capacity goes from 25 the New York metropolitan area. percent lower than the median jurisdic- tion in the region to approximately 20 The paper has three sections. The first percent higher. discusses briefly the various measures of fiscal capacity, with special attention to the difficulty of applying these measures to the nation’s largest city. The second section applies the fiscal capacity INTRODUCTION measures to New York City (NYC) and a sample of jurisdictions in the New York For central cities to remain competitive metropolitan area. The third section with their surrounding regions, as places provides a brief conclusion. both for residential location and for the production of goods and services, they must be able to provide a bundle of MEASURES OF FISCAL CAPACITY Fiscal capacity can be defined as the * Department of Economics, Hunter College and the Graduate ability of a governmental jurisdiction to Center, City University of New York, New York, NY 10021. translate economic activity within its 531
National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 3 (September 1998) pp. 531-40 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 3 geographic borders into public spend- on firms through gross receipts taxes. ing. The concept is both hypothetical New York City has both a broad-based and comparative, reflecting the differing personal income tax and a separate amounts of revenue jurisdictions could business net income tax, the latter raise, rather than what they actually imposed both on corporate entities and raise. Any definition of fiscal capacity noncorporate firms. Adding an “other” must start with a measure of economic category to represent miscellaneous activity, such as income produced, small taxes, the general expression for income received by residents, or RTS in jurisdiction i is given by property wealth. The ability to transform the economic base into public revenues depends both on the type of taxes that 1 are legally available and on the eco- nomic constraints facing the jurisdiction. RTCi = tPROP BPROP,i + tSALES BSALES,i At the local level, both factors are very + tEARN BEARN,i + tCORP BCORP,i important. Localities are legal creatures + tOTHER BOTHER,i of their states, and taxing authority varies both across and within states. Ceteris paribus, the more restrictive the In equation 1, the subscript PROP refers set of revenue instruments, the lower to the property tax, SALES to general the fiscal capacity. Economic constraints and selective sales taxes, EARN to are measured by the elasticity of the individual income or earnings taxes, and jurisdiction’s tax base and depend on CORP to business income taxes. The the extent of interjurisdictional and weight on each tax base is the average interregional tax competition. If two tax rate on that base. The average may cities have equal economic bases, but be across jurisdictions or it may be one faces more perfect suburban weighted by the jurisdiction’s share of locational substitutes than the other, the total population. The RTS is based then it will also have lower fiscal upon the typical legal authority over tax capacity. Measures of fiscal capacity instruments and the average fiscal should take into account both the behavior of the sample. The drawbacks statutory framework that shapes the of the RTS are well known (Ladd and tax system and the economic base Yinger, 1991). If a particular jurisdiction elasticity. faces a more (or less) restrictive legal framework than the average—for The two major approaches to measuring example, is not allowed to use a fiscal capacity are the representative tax particular tax or faces a tight rate or levy system (RTS) and income with export- restriction—its reduced ability to raise ing. Under RTS, fiscal capacity is defined revenue will not be directly reflected in as the weighted sum of the major tax its RTS. The only effect will be small and bases potentially available to the indirect, through its influence on the jurisdictions being compared (Advisory average tax rates used to compute each Commission on Intergovernmental city’s RTS.1 Relations, 1981). At the local level, the major taxes are the real property tax, The RTS measure also fails to capture general and selective retail sales taxes, differences in the competitive fiscal and the earnings or income tax. A small environment or the political economy of number of cities impose separate taxes different jurisdictions. Thus, if the 532
National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 3 (September 1998) pp. 531-40 FISCAL CAPACITY IN NEW YORK average tax rate on any given base were tax instruments, we modify the RTS imposed in a jurisdiction with a lower concept by defining a restricted tax than average rate on that base, the capacity for the subset of taxes that higher rate might induce a greater than are common to all jurisdictions. This average reduction in the value of that approach has the advantage of not base. The RTS will not reflect such a requiring data on tax bases such as constraint. The RTS also ignores business income, which are not available distributional constraints, which may for small jurisdictions. Since the property limit a city’s ability to tax. Cities with tax is the only common tax in our relatively unequal income distributions sample, this measure is simply the must take into account the distribu- average property tax rate in the region tional effects of taxes as well as the multiplied by each jurisdiction’s per revenue productivity of different tax household property tax base. The instruments (Inman, 1989). To summa- measure indicates the amount of rize this critique of the RTS concept, the revenue that NYC could raise if it had a less homogeneous are the jurisdictions tax authority similar to other jurisdic- being compared, either in terms of tax tions in the region. enabling authority or competitive fiscal environment, the less satisfactory is the The income with exporting approach, as RTS as a measure of fiscal capacity. developed by Bradbury, Ladd, and Yinger (Bradbury and Ladd, 1985; Ladd How can one adjust the RTS measure to and Yinger, 1991), is based on the take into account the fiscal capacity of premise that fiscal capacity should those jurisdictions that rely on a broader reflect the amount of revenue that menu of taxes than the typical jurisdic- could be raised if each jurisdiction’s tion? One way to do so is to use residents faced the same tax burden. population-weighted average tax rates. However, resident income is augmented Because larger jurisdictions tend to have by a jurisdiction’s ability to export a more tax instruments available to them, portion of the taxes to nonresidents. using population-weighted averages will Fiscal capacity is defined as tend to give more weight to larger jurisdictions in defining fiscal capacity. If one were to apply this approach to 2 jurisdictions within the New York region, it would undoubtedly raise the mea- FC = K*Y(1 + e) sured tax capacity of the city in relation to its suburbs. However, it would also raise inappropriately the absolute In equation 2, K* is a standardized tax measure of tax capacity for smaller burden, usually defined as the average jurisdictions. From both a political and resident tax burden for all jurisdictions in an economic point of view, it is highly the study. Also, Y is per capita income unlikely that other jurisdictions could and e is the average export ratio. The impose a tax resembling NYC’s corpora- export ratio, defined as exported taxes/ tion income tax. Hence, including such a local taxes, measures the revenue that tax in the tax capacity calculation is not comes from nonresidents per dollar of very meaningful. tax paid by residents. As shown in equation 2, exporting enhances fiscal As a compromise way of dealing with capacity, because it allows a portion of the problem of restrictions on available the cost of public services to be paid by 533
National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 3 (September 1998) pp. 531-40 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 3 nonresidents. However, while exporting Both the exporting concept and the lowers the cost of public services for revenue hill concept are conceptually residents, for nonresidents, it raises the superior to RTS in that they are more cost of doing business in the jurisdic- explicitly related to the economic tion. Nonresidents may respond to this environment faced by any particular higher price by relocating firms, place of jurisdiction. However, implementing employment, or location for shopping. If either of the two concepts requires this relocation occurs, there could be a more information than the RTS. To decline in the jurisdiction’s fiscal base. In determine the revenue maximizing point choosing their tax structures, localities under the revenue hill approach, one must balance these opposing consider- must estimate an econometric relation- ations. The observed value of e for any ship between tax rates and tax bases. particular jurisdiction is assumed to be This estimation requires time-series data the maximum export ratio that the city on tax rates in both the central city and can sustain, implying that localities the various suburban locations, and structure their tax systems so as to raises the issue of correctly identifying maximize tax exporting, subject to the the causal relationship between tax legal restrictions on taxation. rates and tax bases. This is difficult because the tax rate is usually defined A third and less well-known concept of as revenue/base. Therefore, the rate will fiscal capacity is the maximum amount of be negatively correlated with the error revenue a jurisdiction could raise with its term, thus biasing downward the existing tax structure. Inman and others estimated tax rate coefficient. have shown the existence of a revenue hill for Philadelphia and several other To implement the tax exporting concept, large cities (Inman, Craig, and Luce, one starts with an incidence model for 1994). At tax rates close to the summit of the various taxes and assumes that the revenue hill, the value of extra public incidence is uniform across all jurisdic- expenditures financed by a tax increase is tions. For example, Ladd and Yinger more than offset by the decline in the tax assume that capital is perfectly mobile base. If the majority of jurisdictions in the across cities, while labor and land are sample are taxing at rates that are far immobile. As a result, capital is assumed from their maximum taxable revenues, to bear none of the burden of local then the revenue hill concept of fiscal taxes.2 The incidence assumptions capacity should give a larger number produce varying export ratios because of than the other two concepts. differences across cities or metropolitan areas in the residential locations of Our discussion of fiscal capacity has consumers, workers, and landowners, ignored intergovernmental aid. How- the groups who bear the entire burden ever, fiscal capacity from local sources of local taxes. should in principal be augmented by intergovernmental grants. In making The income with exporting approach this adjustment, it is necessary to take has been applied mainly to comparisons account of higher level tax burdens as of central cities and states. However, the well, since a state that has both higher exporting assumptions that are appro- taxes and higher state aid does not priate for most cities and for smaller necessarily increase the fiscal capacity of jurisdictions must be modified to reflect its municipalities. Grants will be in- the special circumstances of NYC. What cluded in future work on this project. stands out in New York are the scope 534
National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 3 (September 1998) pp. 531-40 FISCAL CAPACITY IN NEW YORK and level of its taxes. In 1994, per capita able to shift a portion of taxes forward tax revenues in New York were $2,470 to consumers outside of the region. per capita. This amount was almost two or more times as high as any other city In NYC, a relatively high proportion of except Washington D.C. (U.S. Bureau of output is produced in sectors with the Census, 1994). Though this differ- market power that extends beyond the ence would be reduced if one were to region. New York is a center of national take account of differences in govern- and world finance. The securities mental organization—e.g., Los Angeles industry dominates the national market, has an independent school district, with almost 42 percent of national whereas New York does not—and New output produced in New York.4 About 17 York’s unusually high level of responsi- percent of wages and salaries in NYC bility for welfare programs, taxes per comes from the securities industry, versus capita would still be high in NYC. The only 4 percent of employment. About 38 city has a broad-based personal income percent of revenues from the unincorpo- tax, a local sales tax, a corporation rated business tax and the general income tax, an unincorporated business corporation tax comes from the finance, tax, a commercial rent tax, and a highly insurance, and real estate sector.5 differentiated property tax.3 The RTS will underestimate New York’s fiscal capac- Under the income with exporting ity, because the average tax rate is close approach to fiscal capacity, it is also to zero for a number of taxes used only difficult to adjust for significant differ- by New York. For example, in 1994, ences in tax authority. Following Ladd 13.5 percent of NYC tax revenue was and Yinger, define the average export derived from the corporation income ratio for any jurisdiction as tax, versus zero in all other cities except Washington, D.C. 3 The standard incidence and exporting Σ ( REV) e assumptions under the income with n Revj exporting concept will also underesti- e= j j=1 mate NYC’s fiscal capacity. In particular, the assumption that all taxes on capital are shifted backward to labor and land within the region seems inappropriate. where Revj is revenue from tax instru- The traditional analysis of tax exporting ment j, n is the number of separate tax classifies firms according to whether instruments available, REV is total tax they produce for local markets or revenues and ej is the export ratio of national markets (McLure, 1967; instrument j. Under a general or Bradbury and Ladd, 1985). Firms unconstrained measure of income with producing in local markets are assumed exporting, n would include all taxes to be able to raise prices to the extent available to any of the jurisdictions, that there are no untaxed alternatives. while REV would be hypothetical total Thus, property taxes on rental housing revenue that could be raised if the are shifted forward to tenants. Taxes on jurisdiction used all n taxes. Empirically, firms producing for competitive national the problem is that such a hypothetical markets cannot be shifted to consum- revenue concept is by definition never ers, so they are borne by labor and land. observed, so it is difficult to construct an Firms with national market power are empirical correlate. 535
National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 3 (September 1998) pp. 531-40 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 3 If instead of hypothetical revenue one individual income tax. The income uses actual revenue, equation 3 will lead concept is New York adjusted gross to an underestimate of exporting in income, which is reported at the school jurisdictions with broad taxing authority. district level.6 For population, we use the To see this, consider a jurisdiction that number of income tax filing units, which can levy only a property tax, versus a should be a good approximation to the second jurisdiction that gets 75 percent number of families in each jurisdiction. of its tax revenues from the property tax Unfortunately, school districts and and 25 percent from an earnings tax. towns are frequently not coterminous in Suppose that both jurisdictions have an New York State. For towns that contain export ratio for the property tax equal to more than one school district, we 1.0, while the second jurisdiction has a aggregated the income and property tax 0.3 export ratio for its earnings tax. data up to the town level. For school Using actual revenues, e1 equals 1.0, districts that overlapped more than one whereas e2 equals the weighted sum of town, we allocated the school district 0.75.1.0 and 0.25.0.3, or 0.825. It is totals to their respective towns.7 We counterintuitive that the city with restrict our sample to towns and cities broader taxing authority can export a with at least 5,000 filing units. smaller fraction of its tax burden. Table 1 shows income and property To address the problem of outlier values for NYC and the region. As jurisdictions with more taxing authority shown in column (2) of Table 1, despite than the rest of the sample, we first the concentration of high-income compute an intermediate case of tax individuals in some neighborhoods of capacity under income with exporting. Manhattan, the data show that the In this first step, we use only the relative income of persons residing in property tax, which is the only tax NYC is low compared to the region. common to all jurisdictions. To approxi- NYC ranks 33rd out of 38 jurisdictions, mate the exporting ratio for NYC, we with a value equal to only 75 percent of then compute a separate exporting ratio the median for the sample. By contrast, for those taxes that are unique to the the richest jurisdiction in the sample, city, and add this ratio to the property Scarsdale, has a per filing unit income of tax exporting ratio. $192,000, almost five times that of NYC. RESULTS Given the concentration of high-rise We base our analysis on NYC and office buildings in Manhattan, one jurisdictions in the five counties that would expect NYC’s property tax base to make up the Metropolitan Transit be high relative to its resident income. Authority region. The counties are Surprisingly, this is not the case. The real Westchester, Nassau, Suffolk, Rockland, property base is about 3.1 times larger and Putnam. The jurisdictional unit is than resident income in both NYC and cities and towns. Data on market value the median suburban jurisdiction. and property tax revenues are compiled Consequently, NYC’s property tax base by the State Comptroller from surveys is low, equal to only 76 percent of the conducted by the Office of Real Property median, ranking 34th in the region. The Services (New York State Comptroller, fourth and fifth columns of Table 1 1997). Data are from the 1995 fiscal decompose the property tax base into year. 1995 income data come from the its two main components, residential 536
National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 3 (September 1998) pp. 531-40 FISCAL CAPACITY IN NEW YORK TABLE 1 1995 INCOME AND PROPERTY VALUES IN NYC AND THE REGIONa (PER NEW YORK STATE INCOME TAX FILING UNIT) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Number New York Market Value Market Value Market Value of of Filing Adjusted of Real of Residential Commercial Units Gross Income Propertyb Property Property NYC 2,771,154 $38,901 $122,074 $66,909c $45,407 Median (of 38 jurisdictions) 506,178d 51,904 160,644 114,906 29,556 NYC/median — 0.75 0.76 0.58 1.54 NYC rank — 33rd 34th 37th 8th Highest 8,620 192,053 345,128 319,620 10,893 Source: New York State Comptroller (1997). a Sample includes towns or cities with 5,000 or more filing units in NYC and Westchester, Nassau, Suffolk, Rockland, and Putnam counties. b Excludes tax exempt property. c Calculated adjusting for undervaluation of Class 2 Cooperatives and Condominiums (see endnote 7). d Number of filing units in the rest of the sample. and commercial.8 The importance of only about half of the RTS amount. The Manhattan’s central business district is difference between actual and potential shown in column (5), giving the city a revenues shows the extent to which commercial tax base that is 54 percent NYC has substituted other taxes for the higher than the median (per filing unit). property tax. The substitution reflects However, as shown in column (4), NYC the combination of legal restrictions on has a very low residential base relative property tax assessments in NYC and to the suburbs. This difference is the fact that the city has much broader probably correlated with the difference taxing authority than the suburbs. in average income between NYC and the other jurisdictions. Because the Columns (3) and (4) of Table 2 show residential base is so much greater than fiscal capacity under the income with the commercial base, the disparity in exporting approach. The export ratios residential base dominates the overall used in calculating fiscal capacity, and city-suburban comparison. the rationale for the ratios chosen, are shown in Table 3. Column (3) shows Tax capacity results are shown in Table fiscal capacity with only the property tax 2. The first column shows actual tax assumed to be exported. To calculate the revenues in NYC. Column (2) shows the standardized burden, we allocated the restricted RTS measure, based on the county sales tax total back to individual property tax alone. This measure can be jurisdictions in proportion to the interpreted as the revenue NYC could jurisdiction’s share of county adjusted raise if it had the same rules on taxing gross income.9 Because of its high authority as the suburban jurisdictions. proportion of commercial property, NYC’s Under this measure, NYC’s rank is 34 fiscal capacity increases to $2,684 and its out of 38, reflecting its relatively low rank moves up from 34th to 24th. How- property wealth per filing unit. The ever, it is still below the median for the number in parentheses shows actual region and is only 31 percent of the fiscal property tax revenues in NYC, which are capacity in the richest jurisdiction. 537
National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 3 (September 1998) pp. 531-40 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 3 TABLE 2 1995 FISCAL CAPACITY IN THE NEW YORK REGION USING ALTERNATIVE MEASURES (PER NEW YORK STATE TAX FILING UNIT) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Actual Tax Representative Income Plus Income Plus Revenue from Tax Capacity Exporting Exporting; All Tax Property Tax Onlya Property and Export Ratio Sources (Actual Property Sales Tax for All Major Maximum (1994) Tax Revenue) Onlyb Taxes) Revenuec NYC $6,529d $2,070 $2,684 $3,757e $7,095 (1,074) (e = 0.58) Median (of 38 jurisdictions) 3,183f 2,724 3,132 3,132 not available (2,738) (e = 0.38) NYC/median 2.05 0.76 0.86 1.20 — NYC rank 34th 25th 15th — Highest 7,583 f 5,853 8,786 8,786 not available (5,329) a Calculated as (0.01695)*(property tax base per filing unit). 0.01695 was the average tax rate in the region. b Assumes that only the property tax is exported. Calculated as 0.0437*Y(1 + eprop). The scalar 0.0437 is the average burden on residents of the property tax and the sales tax. eprop is the export ratio for the property tax. c Computed as the sum of estimated summits of NYC’s revenue hills for the personal income, sales, property, and corporation income taxes (Haughwout, 1997). d Calculated by dividing NYC per capita tax revenue of $2,470 by 0.378, the ratio of tax filing units to population. Per capita tax revenue comes from U.S. Census of Governments (1994). e Calculated as 0.0437*Y(1 + eNYC). eNYC is the average exporting ratio for NYC, assumed to equal 1.21. f Calculated as the sum of the local property tax plus the jurisdiction’s share of county sales tax revenues, allocated in proportion to the jurisdiction’s share of county income. TABLE 3 EXPORTING RATIOS Property Taxa NYC Specific Taxes Commercial Industrial property: Residential property: Personal income tax: 0.05b property: 1.5 2.0 0.05 Corporation income tax, unincorporated business tax: 2.0c Sales tax: 0.42d Commercial rent tax: 1.5e a These values are similar to those used by Bradbury and Ladd (1985). b Nonresidents comprise about 12 percent of taxable income and are taxed at a flat rate of 0.45 percent, versus an average rate on residents of 3.5 percent. c Based on the degree of national and international market power of New York firms. d Based on an estimated 30 percent of taxable sales made to nonresidents. e Assumed to be the same as the exporting ratio for the property tax on commercial real estate. Column (4) of Table 2 adds the average mated fiscal capacity now moves up to exporting ratio for NYC’s unique taxes— a rank of 15th, 20 percent above the business and personal income taxes and median. These results are of course the commercial rent tax—to the sensitive to the exact exporting assump- property tax exporting ratio in column tions chosen. However, it is clear that (3). The overall exporting ratio for the greater ability to export taxes raises the city under this approach is 1.21, City’s fiscal capacity substantially relative implying that, for every $1of tax borne to the suburbs. Comparing columns (1) by city residents, an additional $1.21 is and (4), actual tax revenues in NYC are paid by nonresidents. The City’s esti- 37 percent higher than they would be if 538
National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 3 (September 1998) pp. 531-40 FISCAL CAPACITY IN NEW YORK New York imposed the region-wide assumptions in this paper. Given the big average burden on its residents. difference between actual revenues and fiscal capacity so measured, the results For comparative purposes, in column suggest that very high exporting ratios (5), we also show maximum fiscal would be required to close the gap. capacity under the revenue hill ap- Thus, it seems likely that the actual tax proach, estimated at $7,095 per filing burden on NYC residents substantially unit for the four major taxes exceeds the standardized tax burden for (Haughwout, 1997). While one should the region. be skeptical about the exact numbers, the revenue hill approach suggests that, While the tax capacity results are in 1995, New York was close to the suggestive, to assess more fully the fiscal economic limits on its ability to tax. competitiveness of NYC in its region, we must expand the sample to include Conclusions fiscal data for northern New Jersey and Connecticut. We must also take account Despite the concentration of commercial of state and federal aid, variations in activity in Manhattan, as of 1995, NYC expenditure responsibility, and variations had a low level of economic resources— in the cost of providing public services. personal income and property wealth— The next stage of this project is devoted relative to other jurisdictions in the to this task. region. Both its income and its property wealth per filing unit are 25 percent less than the median. While the City’s ENDNOTES relative position has probably improved This paper draws upon work done with the New slightly since 1995, the long process of York City Independent Budget Office. I thank David urban decentralization has left the Belkin, George Sweeting, and Luan Lubuele for largest city in the United States impover- their considerable help with both data and ished relative to the region. concepts, and Ronnie Lowenstein, chief economist for the IBO, for encouraging me to consider the issues. I would also like to thank Andy Reschovsky When we translate economic resources for detailed and insightful comments on an earlier into measures of revenue raising capacity, draft. The views presented are those of the author New York’s relative position improves and should not be attributed to the IBO. 1 somewhat. Taking account of a If each of the n jurisdictions whose fiscal capacity is being compared is weighted equally in computing jurisdiction’s ability to export a portion of the average tax rate to apply to a given base, then the property tax on nonresidential real each jurisdiction’s influence on the average tax rate estate, NYC’s fiscal capacity is 86 percent will be proportional to 1/n. If jurisdictions are of the median. When we allow for the weighted by their relative population in computing average tax rates, then the effect will be City’s additional ability to export a proportional to popi / ∑ pop. portion of taxes on business income, 2 This assumption would seem to be inconsistent estimated tax capacity is 20 percent with the Mieszkowski result that it is the greater than the median. However, actual differential rate of taxation of capital that is borne taxes in NYC were substantially higher by the locality (Mieszkowski, 1972). 3 The NYC ratio of effective property tax rates on than the level implied if NYC imposed a non-residential to residential property is on the standardized burden on its residents. order of four to one, as opposed to a national average differential of 1.15 to one (Chernick and Reschovsky, 1997). The income with exporting measure is 4 The data source is the U.S. Department of Commerce, of course sensitive to the exporting Bureau of Economic Analysis, CA05 Series, Regional assumptions used. We have used middle Economic Information Series Data Base, 1994. 539
National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 3 (September 1998) pp. 531-40 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 3 5 The data source is the Executive Budget of the City Bradbury, Katherine, and Helen Ladd. of New York FY 1999: Message of the Mayor, “Changes in the Revenue-Raising Capacity of pages 57 and 63. U.S. Cities, 1970–82.” New England Economic 6 Because the tax-based income concept excludes Review (March–April, 1985): 20–37. most transfer income, and the proportion of Chernick, Howard, and Andrew Reschovsky. income from transfers is likely to be higher in “Urban Fiscal Problems: Coordinating Actions central cities than in suburban jurisdictions, the among Governments.” In The Urban Crisis: income measure probably undercounts income in Linking Research to Action, edited by Burton A. NYC relative to the other jurisdictions. Weisbrod and James C. Worthy. Evanston: 7 The residential property value data for NYC were Northwestern University Press, 1997. adjusted to reflect the treatment of Class II cooperatives and condominiums under New York’s Haughwout, Andrew. “Taxes in New York property classification law. Under Section 581 of the City: An Examination of the Long Run law, these types of residential property are valued at Implications of Rate Increases for Bases and the same rate as comparable rental units subject to Revenues.” Princeton University. Mimeo, rent regulation. Because rent regulation lowers the preliminary version, 1997. market value of a rental building, the rule makes Inman, Robert. “The Local Decision to Tax: the estimated market value of cooperatives and Evidence from Large U.S. Cities.” Regional condominiums less than their true market value. Science and Urban Economics 19 No. 3 (August, The value of this reduction is substantial, with true 1989): 455–92. market value ranging from 2.5 to 3 times the legal Inman, Robert, Steven Craig, and Thomas “market value” over the local business cycle. While Luce. “The Fiscal Future for American Cities: the state conducts an independent survey of Lessons from Three Cities.” Wharton Real Estate properties to obtain an equalization rate, it uses the Working Paper #189. Philadelphia: The Section 581 values for coops and condos. Coops Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania, and condos comprised 43 percent of Class II 1994. assessed value, and our adjustment increases their estimated market value by a factor of 2.5, from the Ladd, Helen F., and John Yinger. America’s state estimate of $38 billion to $95 billion. Ailing Cities: Fiscal Health and the Design of 8 In the six county New York region, these two types Urban Policy. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins of property comprise about 90 percent of total University Press, 1990. market value. Mieszkowski, Peter. “The Property Tax: An 9 However, because we had no data on nonresident Excise Tax or a Profits Tax?” Journal of Public shopping patterns for the suburban jurisdictions, Economics 1 No. 1 (April, 1972): 73–96. we assume that the tax is not exported. McLure, Charles E., Jr. “Tax Exporting in the United States: Estimates for 1962.” National Tax Journal 20 No. 1 (March, 1967): 49–77. REFERENCES New York State Comptroller. Overlapping Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Real Property Taxes, Tax Levy and Tax Rate Relations. Measuring the Fiscal Capacity and Statistics: New York State Local Governments, Effort of State and Local Areas. Washington, Fiscal Year Ending in 1996. Albany, May, D.C.: ACIR, 1981. 1997. 540
You can also read