Energy Efficiency Obligation Schemes: Policy guidelines
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Energy Efficiency Obligation Schemes: Policy guidelines Deep Dive on Key Policy Mechanism That Can Be Deployed under Article 7 of the Energy Efficiency Directive Prepared jointly by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development and the Energy Community Secretariat February 2019* With the assistance of *This guideline was published in November 2018 and updated in cooperation with the European Commission in February 2019.
CONTENTS Introduction ............................................................................................................................................1 1. History of EEOs ...............................................................................................................................2 2. Status of EEOs in EBRD and Energy Community Contracting Parties ........................................2 3. Key components of EEO schemes ................................................................................................3 3.1. Component 1: Legal and regulatory framework...................................................................4 3.2. Component 2: Scheme administration .................................................................................7 3.3. Component 3: Obligated parties delivery mechanisms / business models.......................9 4. Perspective on EEO scheme roll-out in EBRD and Energy Community region ........................ 13 4.1. Experience to date .............................................................................................................. 13 4.2. Common challenges ........................................................................................................... 14 4.3. Recommendations for getting started ............................................................................... 16 5. EEOs place in the policy measure mix for meeting the national energy savings target provided in EED Article 7.................................................................................................................................... 18 5.1. The contribution of EEO schemes towards the 2020 Article 7 obligation ...................... 18 5.2. The future role of EEO schemes in the Article 7 policy measure mix .............................. 18 5.3. Selecting an effective and coherent policy mix for Article 7 ............................................ 18 Acknowledgements ............................................................................................................................. 20 ANNEX A: Detailed overview of EEO schemes in EBRD COOs / Energy Community Contracting Parties .................................................................................................................................................. 21 ANNEX B: Case study on Ireland’s EEO scheme ............................................................................... 24
Introduction regulatory impact assessment for the Energy Efficiency Obligation (EEO) schemes amended EED1. are a legislative mechanism that places Under Article 7 of the EED, EU countries and requirements on ‘Obligated Parties’ (OPs) to Energy Community Treaty Contracting Parties meet quantitative energy savings targets must achieve and set a cumulative end-use across their customer portfolio. OPs may be energy savings target that has to be achieved retail energy sales companies, energy by 31 December 2020 either through an EEO distributors, transport fuel distributors, scheme, one or more ‘alternative policy and/or transport fuel retailers. Globally, the measures’ of the MS choice, or a amount of finance mobilized for EE measures combination of the EEO scheme and by EEO schemes has grown from alternative policy measures. approximately 5 billion USD to more than 25 billion USD per year between 2005 and 2015 The cumulative end-use energy savings (IEA, 2017). obligation for EU countries is equivalent to new yearly energy savings from 2014-2020 EEOs are market-based instruments that do of 1.5% of a reference quantity, taken as the not prescribe the measures to be deployed – annual energy sales to final customers OPs are given the freedom to choose the averaged over the three-year period 2010- measures and delivery routes that work best 2012 and adjusted for certain allowances. for them within the constraints defined by the The corresponding obligation for Energy scheme administrator. As a result, this Community Contracting Parties is to achieve instrument allows the market as a whole to a cumulative energy savings obligation discover the most cost-effective way to equivalent to new yearly energy savings from achieve energy savings in that particular 2017-2020 of at least 0.7% of the average context. annual energy sales to final customers taken Article 7 of the Energy Efficiency Directive from a reference period of 2013-2015 and 2012/27/EU (the “EED”) plays a central role adjusted for similar allowances. in the package of measures being delivered This requirement has stimulated a number of by the European Union (EU) to achieve a 20% EU Member States to set up EEO schemes improvement in energy efficiency (EE) by and the measure is expected to contribute 2020. The importance of Article 7, which the greatest share of energy savings in requires Member States (MS) to set delivering the 2020 target, and likewise be of quantified energy savings targets for the central importance when looking forward to respective obligation period (2014-2020), 2030. has been further reinforced in the revised EED (Directive (EU) 2018/2002 on energy Given this take-up of new EEO schemes efficiency, "amended EED") which sets a among EU Member States, their potential legislative pathway to 2030 and beyond. The applicability within Energy Community scope of the energy savings obligation has Contracting Parties for meeting their own been a key focus both in negotiations Article 7 targets both to 2020 and beyond to regarding the 2030 headline targets and in 2030 is under serious consideration. the European Commission’s associated Ensuring that any such implementation takes into account the lessons learnt and best 1 cuments/1_en_impact_assessment_part1_v4_0 https://ec.europa.eu/energy/sites/ener/files/do .pdf 1
practices and is appropriate to the market in competitive market structures. This was question is therefore of primary concern. particularly true for GB and France where the obligation was placed on unbundled retail As a financial institution, the EBRD is suppliers of electricity and gas – in the case interested in EEOs for the potential to open of GB with unregulated tariffs. new financing pathways for energy efficiency improvement measures. The Energy Further expansion of EEOs within the EU has Community Secretariat (ECS), responsible for been largely driven by the requirement of EED extending the EU internal energy market rules Article 7. Ireland, Austria, Slovenia, Bulgaria, and principles to its Contracting Parties, is Luxemburg, Poland, Greece and Malta have interested in EEOs as a means for countries all responded by setting up their own to achieve Article 7 obligations of the Energy schemes, with the focus on retail entities as Efficiency Directive. Given the common the Obligated Parties. interest in EEO roll-out amongst respective countries, EBRD and ECS have jointly Elsewhere, EEOs have been implemented in developed these Policy Guidelines to support Asia, Australia and South America to bring an countries in their decision-making as to the estimated total of 46 operational schemes by most appropriate policy mix for achieving the 2017 4 . While they vary hugely in terms of required end-use energy savings under scope, focus and design, they all meet the Article 7 of the EED. essential definition of an EEO as a regulatory mechanism that requires Obligated Parties to 1. History of EEOs meet quantitative energy savings targets by EEO schemes began life in the United States delivering or procuring eligible end-use (US) as part of a drive towards Integrated energy savings. The IEA estimates that Resource Planning following the oil crises of together these schemes stimulated around the 1970s, by seeking to consider energy 26 billion USD (21 billion EUR) of additional efficiency as part of a holistic least-cost investment in energy efficiency in 2015 (with approach to energy sector planning 2 . The around 40% of those costs being met directly positive results have seen the popularity of by the Obligated Parties)5. the schemes broaden across the US with the IEA counting 24 operational EEO schemes 2. Status of EEOs in EBRD and now in place3. Energy Community Contracting Parties In the EU, four countries (GB, Denmark, In response to the amount of energy savings France and Italy) followed by implementing required by Article 7, EEO schemes have EEO schemes in the 1990’s and early been adopted, are in the process of being set 2000’s. While the US schemes were up, or are under consideration in several dominated by vertically-integrated markets EBRD Countries of Operation (COOs) or with utility firms enacting measures within Energy Community Contracting Parties. This their own customer base, the EU examples is summarized in Figure 1 below. demonstrated the applicability of EEOs to 2Fawcett T., Rosenow J. and Bertoldi P. (2017), 3 International Energy Agency (2017), Market- The future of energy efficiency obligation Based Instruments for Energy Efficiency: Policy schemes in the EU, European Council for an Design and Choice. Energy Efficiency Economy. 4 ibid 5 ibid 2
Figure 1 – Status of EEOs in EBRD and Energy Community countries. See Annex A for full details. The 2020 deadline is fast approaching and 3. Key components of EEO therefore little time remains to establish new schemes EEO schemes which will make a significant Many EBRD and Energy Community contribution towards the national energy Contracting Parties, despite having the saving targets under Article 7. It is noted as intention to adopt an EEO, are facing a “key policy” beyond 2020, with targets challenges putting in place an effective retained and expected to contribute around scheme. This section summarizes the main half the additional savings targeted by the EU components of an EEO scheme and by 2030. The amended EED extended the international best practice considerations energy savings obligation to achieve new when putting in place an EEO. These include annual energy savings of at least 0.8% (of an adequate legal framework, scheme final energy consumption for all MS, but administration (institutional structures and Cyprus and Malta (0,24%)) during the next capacities, operational methodologies, M&V period 2021-2030 and beyond, coming from systems) and obligated party delivery models new energy efficiency renovations or other (delivery mechanisms, funding / financing measures in end-use sectors (~13% more products, methodologies, organisational ambitious than in the period 2014-2020). strategies, monitoring and verification Member States will likely retain the option of systems). It then highlights key issues / using alternative measures in place of an considerations in the context of EBRD COOs EEO scheme although the scale of savings and Energy Community Contracting Parties required is expected to encourage the further particular circumstances. Annex B provides a roll-out of EEOs across the Union. case study of the Irish EEO scheme which 3
reflects many of the best practice guidelines ministry and the regulator to develop described by the components. associated secondary legislation and put in place the governance structure concerning 3.1. Component 1: Legal and quality control and assurance, scheme regulatory framework processes and enforcement, and co- The obligation itself is typically required to be ordination. This includes empowering the stipulated in effective primary law which also energy regulators to be able to exercise their empowers relevant entities to establish and powers in the area of energy efficiency if exercise the necessary secondary legislation necessary. for implementation. The primary law is usually an energy law, or dedicated EE law. Secondary legislation should then “fall-out” There is substantial variety in the detail of of the obligations stipulated in the primary scheme design stipulated in the primary law legislation and build upon its enabling but in many cases it covers at least a powers. With respect to an EEO scheme, this description of scheme targets, fuel coverage, may be expected to define the operational responsibilities of different agencies and processes of the scheme and relevant empowering the levy of penalties for non- responsible entities as well as describe the compliance of all relevant provisions. content and structure for associated Secondary legislation may then be used to regulations (tertiary legislation), such as describe specific methodologies regarding calculation methodologies, and lead to their the savings target, definition of penalty rates, development. calculation of energy savings attributable to a There exists an extensive body of literature given measure, and monitoring and describing the scope, options, relative verification (M&V) responsibilities. advantages and potential pitfalls of various At what level and to what detail within the design choices in the establishment of an legislative framework the various aspects of EEO scheme. The table below provides a the scheme design are described will in part summary overview. be driven by the norms of the legal systems The business model (see Component 3) is for the country in question. At a minimum directly shaped by the regulatory framework. primary legislation (typically either within the Often, policy makers neglect to take into Energy Law or a dedicated EE Law) will account the limitations on business models empower enforcement and allocate imposed by market maturity (or lack thereof). implementing responsibilities by laying out This can lead to regulatory frameworks that the institutional framework together with the impose overly onerous constraints on roles and responsibilities of each relevant obligated parties, leading to inaction. entity. It will give powers to the relevant Table 1: Summary table of components related to an EEO legal and regulatory framework Component Typical Best-practice considerations (success Country examples responsible factors / potential pitfalls) Defining Line Ministry • Defined in primary legislation Austria (Article 10 of EE Obligated • Ensure OPs are identifiable Law) Parties (consider starting with only Croatia (Article 13 of EE electricity/gas) Law) • Set a minimum threshold for the Greece (Article 9 of EE obligation to apply Law) 4
Defining the Line Ministry • Targets should be clear and Slovenia/Latvia – build size of the (supporting predictable by OPs target target methodology • Start at realistic level to gain Bulgaria – unpredictable and analysis confidence targets by scheme • Targets should not result in increase Austria – clear administrator in tariffs of >2% check ex-ante in communication on 6) benefits an RIA7 and monitor ex-post • Should be accompanied by clear communication of scheme benefits to consumers Compliance Line Ministry • Must be sufficient to demonstrate GB/France/Ireland – 3 to periods and political commitment 4 year compliance scheme • Longer compliance periods provide periods duration flexibility and clarity • Limited banking/borrowing within compliance periods helps with flexibility Methodology Line Ministry • Proportionate to sales volumes Ireland/Austria – for setting (support from • Consider lifetimes (lifetime targets Cumulative target targets scheme or cumulative annual targets) GB/France – Lifetime administrator) • Accredit all savings from a measure target to OP if contribution is material irrespective of leverage level Cost-recovery Regulator • In liberalised markets should be GB/Ireland/Austria/Slove mechanism treated as cost of doing business nia – cost of doing • Regulated tariffs should explicitly business enable cost recovery (typically as Denmark/Italy/France – opex) regulated tariffs • Start with standard cost-pass New York – PBI through arrangement then consider mechanism performance-based incentive (PBI) Defining Administrator • Allow savings in all major fuel Slovenia – issues in eligible (principles sources counting of solar PV and measures defined by • Only count end-use energy savings eligibility Line Ministry) (careful on RES applications) GB – route for OPs to • Allow a route for OPs to propose new propose measures measures Calculation Administrator • If possible, hold methodologies France/GB – deemed methodologies (with separate from formal legislation to savings lists held technical ease updating process separately support) • Need to consider issues of Poland – concern on materiality, additionality and free additionality riders Ireland – engineering • Deemed savings lists and estimates tools standardised calculation tools for engineering estimates can greatly facilitate ease of implementation by OPs M&V and QA Administrator • M&V procedures should be Ireland/GB – clear M&V (principles established by both the OPs and and QA guidance defined by administrator documentation Line Ministry) • This should be supported by Quality Assurance (QA) requirements for accrediting/certifying firms and 6 Selection of an appropriate entity to act as the scheme administrator is discussed further under Pillar 2 7 Regulatory Impact Assessment 5
materials for eligibility in the scheme. Enforcement Government • Buy-out provisions and/or penalties Ireland/Slovenia/Austria or are necessary for scheme scale-up – moved from voluntary Administrator from voluntary set-ups to formal EEO with buy- • Ensure they are sufficient to out option incentivise OPs to act, proportionate, Bulgaria – example of transparent and predictable insufficient incentive and • Payments should to the extent lack of empowerment possible be retained within the EE GB – penalties remain in sector EE sphere • Clear empowerment of enforcement body and process for collecting penalties Methods for Administrator • OPs should be able to generate Denmark/GB/Ireland – generating and (principles energy savings certificates both by enabling inter-OP trading trading defined by themselves and through contractors France – platform for certificates Line Ministry) (third parties) smaller players • Third parties may also be permitted Italy – use of White to generate certificates although full, Certificates created open trading adds complexity and is complexity and concerns not recommended in initial stages on windfall returns Sub-targets Line Ministry • Ring-fencing a proportion of savings Ireland – ring-fencing for and ring- from residential sector addresses residential and low fencing stronger barriers among these income consumers France – bonus to • Ring-fencing or providing savings from low income preferential credit to low income groups actions can help address regressive GB – sole focus on low nature of EEO scheme income Slovenia – perceives better dealt with by EE Fund Key challenges related to translating legal environments, cost-pass through provisions framework for EEOs in EBRD COOs and must be explicitly enabled in the legal Energy Community Contracting Parties framework. The ‘cost’ to consumers therefore becomes more visible than the benefits Cost-recovery mechanisms have been noted derived from the scheme and thus politically as a particular challenge in the countries difficult. This is particularly the case in many covered by the report. In many markets where EBRD COOs where energy tariffs have EEOs have been rolled-out, the electricity historically received subsidy support, market is liberalized meaning that costs regulated margins are tight and consumers’ incurred are treated as a cost of doing disposable income is comparatively low. But business by the OPs and may be passed on cost-recovery pathways are essential for an to consumers to the extent competitive EEO scheme to be viable. European EEO conditions allow. The cheaper the target is schemes have typically represented up to 2% delivered, the lower the pressure on an OP to of retail tariffs 8 . While this is a small increase costs. In regulated tariff proportion of overall energy costs and is 8 https://ec.europa.eu/energy/sites/ener/files/documents/final_report_on_study_on_costs_and_benefits_ of_eeos_0.pdf 6
vastly outweighed by the estimated benefit, it The responsible body for the administration is important to remember that most supplier and first layer of enforcement of an EEO is costs are pass-through elements (ie typically either a relevant government wholesale energy, network tariffs and taxes). ministry, a semi-independent energy agency The uplift to tariffs therefore represents a or an independent energy regulator. A good much larger percentage of supplier costs and practice approach would be to ensure a profits. To be financially viable to implement degree of separation between the policy will require the affected entities to recover setting and policy implementing bodies with associated costs. either an agency or independent regulator as the key administrative and monitoring body. Another element where issues have been observed in the region is the design of penalty The scheme administrator will be responsible schemes, and giving a clear, legal basis for for ongoing operational tasks to ensure the issuing penalties in case of non-compliance EEO scheme runs effectively and smoothly. that will incentivise OPs to deliver. In newly These will include the vital task of collecting, liberalized / liberalizing electricity markets approving and accrediting claimed savings as with weaker regulators, as is frequently the well as undertaking/directing related case in the countries under consideration auditing requirements. The administrator will here, this is particularly important as non- have to report at least once a year to the compliance will quickly harm scheme government and publish information on credibility. scheme progress (costs and volumes) and detail any problems encountered. The low institutional capacity also has repercussions for the strength of the M&V One further important task is the regimes established. In each of the countries development and maintenance of non- where an EEO scheme is operational – legislative documentation necessary for Poland, Slovenia and Bulgaria – some scheme operation. This includes process and concern regarding M&V processes has been technical guidance, pro forma templates for cited. Clear guidance on accreditation, evidencing and submitting claims, and requirements and the capacity to undertake maintenance of a centralised database for necessary sampling checks (both by the OPs their processing. The administrator may also and by the administrator) on claimed savings assist OPs by providing supporting tools for are important if confidence is to be gained in calculating energy savings (eg deemed the schemes’ effectiveness. A list of energy lists or spreadsheets for calculating measures with deemed energy saving values scaled savings). can help this process by simplifying the M&V process while retaining transparency. While an extensive array of responsibilities, the resourcing requirements for the above 3.2. Component 2: Scheme tasks should not be overly onerous. Ongoing administration costs for a typical EU country may include one EEO schemes require the development of full-time equivalent technical expert and one administrative capacity in the form of full-time equivalent administrative staff. appropriately skilled staff and supporting Verification would most likely be contracted documentation, and tools to ensure the to an outsourced panel of verifiers (and must processes are in place for effective be done independently of the OP). Additional governance. This will cover accreditation, support, possibly contracted in, will be auditing and scheme monitoring among required for development of the necessary other aspects. regulations and guidance documents as well 7
as setting up of the information and The following table seeks to summarise the communication technology to enable key elements to EEO scheme administration, efficient administration (through web-based best practice considerations in their submissions). There will be ongoing application and useful examples of such maintenance costs for this also. application. Table 2: Summary table of components related to administration of an EEO scheme Component Typical Best practice considerations (success Country example responsible factors / potential pitfalls) Guidance to Administrator • “Plain English” interpretation of Ireland – provision of OPs on legislation to clearly lay out the clear guidance scheme scheme approach and documentation operation responsibilities • Clearly define target setting process, principles of operation, timelines, credit allocation, process for accreditation, penalties and buy-out rules Technical Administrator • Stipulate the certification or UK – provides easily guidance on (technical accreditation standards necessary accessible and clear M&V and QA support may be for suppliers (and how to check for information on expected requirements contracted) these) processes and standards • Lay out the monitoring and verification processes that must be set up and followed by measure category (with derogations) • Reporting requirements to administrator Deemed Administrator • Should cover common, replicable France / Ireland / energy saving (technical large-volume measures Slovenia – provide credits table support may be • Based on proven and deemed energy savings contracted) independently verified energy lists for common saving values measures • Accompanied by technical standards and updated periodically Calculation Administrator • Simple to follow spreadsheets for Ireland – online tools to tools for (technical estimating energy savings support “scaled savings” scaled support may be • Useful for measures such as estimates for common savings contracted) electric motors in industry industrial measures Appropriate IT Administrator • Specification and procurement of Croatia – centralised M&V systems necessary software Platform embedded in • This may be tied to centralised regulations for use on all M&V database for all EE measures NEEAP policy measures Pro forma Administrator • For use by OPs to demonstrate UK – online templates of template proof of involvement necessary documentation Cost reporting Administrator • Monitoring cost impact of the Denmark – cost reporting, scheme as well as impact on benchmarking and competition reviews undertaken • May include a periodic update of annually RIA • Information may lead to revision for next compliance period 8
Trade Administrator / • The administrator should provide Ireland – clear process for facilitation other simple processes for notifying of inter-OP trading any inter-OP trade of certificates Italy / Poland – exchange- • If third-party certificate generation based trading of White is allowed then a trading platform Certificates may be considered Key challenges related to implementing EEO need to be based on robust and scheme administration in EBRD COOs and independently verified analyses which may Energy Community Contracting Parties also be lacking. EEO schemes within the EU, according to 3.3. Component 3: Obligated parties several experts that provided experiences delivery mechanisms / business models from Member States during the course of This covers the Obligated Party strategy for preparation of the guidelines, have frequently EEO implementation. The envelope of options benefited from being run by arms-length for addressing these issues will be led by the agencies (either focused on sustainable legislative framework of the scheme but energy or more general in nature) who are there will typically be a number of eligible able to operate with greater flexibility and approaches and indeed a variety have been independence than a ministry. Such agencies tested in EEO schemes to date. are seen as more responsive to the demands of OPs and can help foster a collaborative EEO schemes often meet resistance from the working arrangement. However, in many OPs during their proposal and set-up stages. EBRD COOs as well as in the Energy Such resistance tends to be driven first and Community, the presence or willingness to foremost by concerns regarding recovery of support establishment of such an agency is costs (and potential to be at a competitive lacking, while support is also lacking to disadvantage9). Other key concerns relate to dedicate the necessary resources within the the lack of experience of OPs in the energy civil service to scheme establishment and efficiency sector (particularly in the Energy operation. This has slowed decision making Community) and the potential to cannibalise and development. their own revenues by lowering demand for energy. The lack of supportive documentation, notably a deemed energy saving list, has also Experience in operating EEO schemes in the proven problematic in some jurisdictions. EU suggests the predominant delivery Reference to such a list provides mechanism has been grant financing. See transparency and simplicity, substantially box 1 for examples below. reducing the administrative burden on OPs. The deemed savings contained in such lists 9 Concern has been voiced in a number of EEO and providing unfair advantages to smaller schemes regarding minimum threshold levels for players, while low thresholds have proven energy sales volumes below which retailers are problematic for very small entities lacking not obligated under the scheme. Relatively high capacity to cope with the administrative burden. levels have been cited as distorting the market 9
Box 1. Business models for EEOs Directly by the OP who installs the EE measure itself (possibly via a subsidiary unit); Provide to a third party contracted by the OP to install an EE measure; Paid by the OP to a third party in exchange for an energy saving certificate either over-the-counter (OTC) in a bilateral deal or on a platform/exchange. 10
The third party has in some jurisdictions been “MUSH” (municipalities, universities, schools an Energy Services Company (ESCO) who and hospitals) sector. then delivers the energy savings measures using forms of Energy Performance Beyond EEO schemes, the general Contracting (EPC) or loans at concessional experience of energy efficiency loan rates (with the concession being supported programmes is that results are weak by the grant funding of the OP). (particularly those targeting small consumers) unless they are combined with Cost recovery of the grant support usually technical assistance, outreach programmes, takes place in the year of delivery either mechanisms to ease contracting and the through an allowance in regulated tariff aforementioned softening of financial setting or in price-setting by the OPs as part conditions to accelerate uptake. Without of their cost of doing business in a liberalised such efforts, they risk merely repackaging tariff environment. Both approaches reduce activities which would have taken place in the the strain on OP cash flows beyond any initial market anyhow. set-up costs. It is plausible that loan type arrangements While permitted under many EEO schemes, could reduce the costs of an EEO scheme for loans have not formed a significant delivery OPs, softening the impact on tariffs and mechanism. In a number of non-European improving political willingness (a key concern schemes (eg Brazil, some US schemes and among EBRD COOs) to implement. However, South Africa), EEO schemes have been used the lessons learnt from wider EE to provide financial assistance to ESCOs as concessional loan schemes – particularly described above but the OP contribution still those targeting lower cost measures – need takes the form of a grant to the ESCO rather careful consideration and mitigation than a direct financing offer. Activity derived strategies. Also on this matter is the need for from this approach has focused on the capitalisation of the financing entity to manage cash flow in the early years. Table 3: Summary table components related to EEO scheme delivery by OPs Component Typical Best-practice considerations (success Country example responsible factors / potential pitfalls) Engagement OP / • Engagement of OPs through Ireland – Better Energy Administrator previous EE schemes (voluntary Scheme and involvement EEO or other) builds mutual of utilities understanding Greece – early • Early engagement develops EE engagement and competency within OPs collective planning Understanding Administrator • Prior to and in the initial stages, Austria – extensive of the scheme run a series of workshops with OPs workshop programme operation • Back up the guidance document with details for dedicated contact point in administrator • Clear website Developing OP • OPs should have a staffing plan for administrative delivery of obligation capacity • Must have capacity for implementing M&V processes 11
Internal Action OP • This may be a formal element of France – formal Action Plan for scheme (approved by Plans which may be delivery administrator) or an internal approved by document administrator, • Identify business model for streamlining delivery – internal/subsidiary, accreditation contracted, purchased (WC or buy- out), pooled • Scheduling of roll-out Choice of OP • Main options are: grant support, Ireland – explicitly allows delivery soft loans, technical assistance 4 options but mechanism(s) • Cash flow considerations need concentration on grants addressing • Financing support can be channelled through an ESCO Financial Private sector • Financing of OPs is important, as Bulgaria – focus on loans products for / IFIs / utility capital may be already and lack of cost-recovery OPs national stretched mechanisms hindered development • Cost of financing needs to be utility financing banks taken into account when evaluating cost-recovery mechanisms Product Administrator • Deemed savings list profit New South Wales – had innovation retention can result in narrow concerns of narrow focus focus on simple, low cost on low cost measures so measures tweaked rules • Incentives may need consideration Italy – enabled windfall to bring forward more innovative gains on CFLs10 and deep solutions 10 Compact Fluorescent Lamps 12
Key challenges related to EEO scheme Contracting Parties is substantial. Extensive delivery by OPs cost-effective potential is available for energy efficiency within the region. EBRD COOs and In the countries of the region, utilities lack Energy Community Countries which have technical capacity / experience on starting an already attempted to implement EEO EE business line, and often lack upfront schemes have done so with mixed success. capital to undertake measures (which would Therefore, to assist in more consistently then be repaid through tariff cost-recovery). effective roll-out, this report aims to support the region by learning not just from global Successful EEO schemes have been best practice but also from lessons learnt in introduced gradually with rigorous pre- overcoming the particular challenges implementation planning between both the common to the region and in doing so provide administrator and future OPs. Such planning, a useful tool for their future development. as occurred recently in Greece, helps bridge the knowledge and capacity gap that faces The longest running EEO scheme among many potential OPs in the region by helping EBRD COOs is that of Poland which provide a clear picture on how targets may be underwent significant revision in 2016. The achieved in the initial stages of the scheme. original scheme, commenced in 2013, was The pressure to comply in a timely manner perceived to be overly complex, depending with the obligations of the EED should be upon annual tender rounds, categorisation by balanced with the need for such a robust sector, and open trading. The new scheme planning period. design bears closer resemblance to that seen in other newer EU Member State EEOs such If a cost-recovery mechanism through tariffs as Ireland, Austria and Slovenia, albeit with is not possible then this constrains the range the inclusion of open trading. It is noticeable of delivery models significantly. Only in very that the level of savings achieved even under mature markets would it be possible for an the old design had increased substantially by energy supplier to put in place a profitable 2015, indicating that the time required for business line for EE. Under these learning by both OPs and the administrator circumstances, EEOs will be viewed as eating were as important a barrier as the scheme’s into profits, and will meet resistance from complicated design. utilities. Cost-recovery modalities heavily influence business model choice. This finding is supported by the largely successful implementation in Slovenia which Monopoly providers remain in place within a built gradually upon a pre-existing levy placed given fuel source (particularly for electricity) on energy tariffs for funding energy efficiency in many EBRD COOs. This can dilute the activities through the centralised “Eco-Fund”. market benefits to be gained from the By increasing the EEO target in steps and by competitive nature of EEO schemes that arise virtue of the precedent set by the levy, in liberalised environments. Slovenia managed a relatively smooth 4. Perspective on EEO scheme introduction of its EEO. Nevertheless, it remains noticeable that the only year where roll-out in EBRD and Energy the target was not achieved directly by the Community region OPs (as opposed to indirectly using the buy- 4.1. Experience to date out mechanism) was the first year of 2014, As identified in the introduction to this report, despite 2014 having a lower target than the opportunity for EEO schemes within the subsequent years. This reaffirms the EBRD COOs and Energy Community importance of gradually growing the target. 13
Bulgaria originally intended to commence its Challenges in scheme establishment and EEO in 2014. However, delays caused in part legislation by changes in government (an issue also At a high level there is the issue of encountered elsewhere in the region) set international obligations. Targets for most back its formal initiation to 2017. Further EBRD COOs are set, at least in part, by difficulties with a lack of understanding reference to the demands of Article 7 and among OPs regarding responsibilities and Annex V of the EED (as transposed for the opportunities, and the absence of effective Energy Community) which are uniform across enforcement and cost-recovery mechanisms, all EU Member States. have hindered its progress. A number of successful EEOs in the EU have Elsewhere in the region, the other operational been able to build upon either pre-existing EEO schemes in Greece and Latvia have schemes or well-established energy been implemented too recently to draw firm efficiency policy mechanisms, with the conclusions regarding their operation. It is corresponding institutional knowledge, noticeable, however, that both have adopted experience and capacity already established scheme structures broadly similar to that of to support implementation and operation. Slovenia (as well as the successful schemes Such capacity and experience is more run in the Republic of Ireland and Austria). frequently lacking among policy makers, Croatia’s proposed scheme following revision administrators and OPs in the EBRD COOs is similarly aligned to this increasingly and Energy Community CPs, providing a common format within the EU Member States particular challenge for establishing and (eg an obligation placed on retailers, a broad operating a new EEO scheme. With the 2020 base of fuel carriers covered, and a buy-out deadline now fast approaching, policy design option to a centralised National Energy for new EEOs is best advised to turn its Efficiency Fund). attention to the 2030 policy environment, ensuring a long-term perspective is taken on No schemes are as yet operational within the scheme design and development. The Energy Community with only Bosnia and alignment of EEO schemes with Alternative Herzegovina so far indicating a firm Measures, as permitted by the EED, is commitment to establishment, while other discussed further below. Contracting Parties continue to assess their options. Public and consumer cost is another area of clear and repeated concern. Again, while a 4.2. Common challenges common issue internationally, the lower GDP Most challenges to setting up a robust EEO per capita and income levels of the EBRD scheme are common to all jurisdictions and COOs and Energy Community Contracting have been tackled across the world. Parties as compared to other EU Member Extensive literature is available regarding States, lends increased prominence to the options for scheme design and best practice issue. This impacts in a number of ways. implementation. However, there are Firstly, financial capacity may be lacking in commonalities across the EBRD COOs the government and designated regarding the form and relative importance of administrator for dedicating the necessary certain challenges which merit specific human resources to both scheme comment here. establishment and operation, as well as to ensure the required expertise is available for it to be designed and implemented consistent with international best practice. 14
There can also be strong opposition to the Enforcement mechanisms for the payment of notion of cost recovery via energy tariffs. the buy-out price and/or penalties for non- Prices for households and small businesses payment have also been lacking or proven in the region for electricity in particular difficult to establish within the legislative remain low by international standards, are frameworks. Without credible and effective largely regulated, and have a history of enforcement policies, OPs will likely not be subsidisation. This has a double impact by: sufficiently incentivised to act. Slovenia provides a positive example of where clear • reducing the end-user’s savings from enforcement occurs with late payment to the implementing EE measures on energy Eco-Fund of any shortfall subject to interest expenditures (thus increasing the pay- and legally enforceable. Penalties are also back period required); and proportionate to the infringement which has • increasing the uplift to tariffs required as occurred. a percentage of total bills. Challenges in scheme administration Regulated tariffs provide an additional Related to the above challenges is the issue complication due to the inevitable political of selecting an appropriate administrator for nature of agreeing to price rises, which can the scheme. The most common approach result in very tight profit margins for utility among EU countries, which has had a good firms. Combating the cost issue is difficult but level of success, is the use of an arms-length surmountable. The scale of cost-effective energy agency (sometimes dedicated to opportunities for EE activity is vast and by sustainability matters). Agencies generally spreading the obligation across energy have greater flexibility in the hiring of staff, carriers the impact on tariffs can be are partially protected from day-to-day contained, albeit at the cost of greater political pressures, and have proven better administrative complexity. It is important also able to foster a cooperative environment with that the substantial benefits (both direct and OPs. However, setting up such an agency can indirect) of EEO schemes are as visible to encounter opposition, particularly in the both politicians and the public as the cost. EBRD COOs where cost and lack of political EEO schemes are highly cost-effective in control cause concern. Early planning and aggregate for society but this message is coordination with other areas of energy often lost. legislation as well as the ministry responsible for finance can help overcome this hurdle. In Similarly under regulated tariffs, cost- the absence of such an agency, the energy recovery mechanisms must be implemented market regulator or directly within the with the involvement of the energy regulator. ministry are alternative options for EEO schemes represent a small proportion of administration. overall retail tariffs (typically no more than 2%) but a much larger proportion of utility A common challenge in the region, including profits. Without cost recovery allowances, in Poland, Slovenia and Bulgaria, has been financial distress or non-compliance is establishing robust monitoring and inevitable. Standard regulatory practices verification systems. Administrators have including close oversight, benchmarking, and relied largely upon desk-top document performance-based incentive mechanisms reviews as opposed to physical inspections, can be used to incentivise cost efficiency in leading to concerns regarding the veracity of such circumstances. claims. GIZ, through its Open Regional Fund (ORF) for South-East Europe, assisted in the roll-out of M&V software platforms to the 15
countries of the Western Balkans region. OPs are often concerned about conflicting Croatia integrated the system within its incentives stemming from their position as national legislation and it is planned to be energy sales businesses being obligated to used for the new EEO scheme. However, the reduce energy consumption. Allowing OPs to system is understood to yet to be put into full initiate savings in any end-use fuel type operation in any of the remaining recipient means it is not necessarily the suppliers’ own countries. Appropriate IT systems are an sales which are affected. Furthermore, important cornerstone of managing an delivery of energy services is being effective EEO scheme. increasingly seen by retail firms as a potential growth area for their businesses and Challenges for Obligated Parties therefore the positive potential of EEOs to A lack of understanding of EE potential and contribute towards this shift in focus needs appropriate measures has been a repeated emphasising. For network firms the same concern expressed by potential OPs across a concern will depend on whether tariffs are number of proposed and operational EEOs in formulated on an energy (kWh) basis or a EBRD COOs. Many OPs do not have a history capacity (kW) basis and will anyhow be of involvement in EE programme delivery and partially mitigated in markets where tariffs lack the internal capacity and know-how for are decoupled from throughput volumes (ie seeking and identifying cost-effective using a total revenue rather than a price cap). opportunities. Strong coordination and Similar decoupling mechanisms can help for communication between the administrator retail firms in markets where retail prices and OPs prior to scheme establishment, with remain regulated. information sharing regarding EE potential can help mitigate this challenge. Working Lastly, the market size of EBRD COOs is with industry associations, particularly for the typically smaller than those of EU Member liquid and solid fuel sectors where there is no States with the longest running EEO ongoing relationship with end-users, is schemes. Particularly in markets where a another option which has proven beneficial in monopoly provider’s position is unlikely to be Ireland and Denmark. challenged, a more collaborative and prescriptive approach between government EBRD COOs are also typically at an earlier and OPs in scheme design, planning and stage of energy market liberalisation than the delivery, such as is the case in Malta and wider EU Member States. The presence of Lithuania, could be a workable solution. regulated tariffs and monopoly providers can dilute the benefits to be gained from 4.3. Recommendations for getting competition that an EEO scheme can offer. In started a competitive retail market EEO costs are Based upon the above discussion of common treated as a cost of doing business and there challenges, the following recommendations is a clear incentive for cost efficiency in order are drawn for EBRD COOs to get started with to gain market advantage. This incentive is an EEO scheme: absent under regulated environments. Nevertheless, this issue alone should not be Be realistic on scope and timetable: Policy seen as an insurmountable barrier to makers should take heed of the region’s delivery. Indeed the success of schemes experience by putting in place a realistic placed on network firms, which are inherent timetable for scheme development and monopolies within their region/fuel, attests implementation. Starting with a target at a to the flexibility of EEOs as a policy tool. realistic level before growing over subsequent years is a proven method of 16
improving outcomes, while softer penalty obligations and processes, simplified regimes and/or voluntary arrangements can calculation processes (eg through also be used to smooth the introduction. establishing a list of common measures with Taking time to ensure the legislative deemed energy savings), pro forma framework is well structured, focused on the templates for submitting claims and long-term objectives of the country, and transferring credits between OPs, and comprehensive in scope, will also pay-off in supporting IT systems, are all essential the long-run. ingredients to a well-functioning scheme. Consider related alternatives (perhaps for a Regular reviews are necessary: With the best transitional period): Schemes which co-opt will in the word, all scheme designs will have energy firms for delivery but in a more areas of potential improvement that will only managed manner such as in Flanders, become apparent once in operation. Periodic Lithuania and Malta may lose some of the reviews (around every 3 years) are therefore competitive element but provide a simpler recommended to update processes as administerial arrangement. This can be necessary and update or fine-tune areas attractive for a transition period or in a small which need attention. market where competition is anyhow unlikely to become established. Back-up the obligation with effective, proportionate and dissuasive penalties: Early engagement of the Ministry of Finance Despite the potential of voluntary and energy regulator are essential: EEOs mechanisms for smoothing the introduction have strong net benefits and are a cost- of a new EEO scheme, achievement and effective delivery mechanism of EE compliance at scale is likely to necessitate measures. However, energy bill increases are the introduction of a penalty regime. The always a politically sensitive subject and basic principles of such a regime are that therefore early engagement of entities with incurring a penalty should be more costly for jurisdiction on financing matters is essential the OP than complying with their obligations, in order to ensure they are fully informed as that the size of the penalty is proportionate to to the scheme’s proposed operational the size of the breach, and that funds structure and its expected benefits. recovered through penalties should remain within the energy efficiency sphere. Early engagement of Obligated Parties is also essential: There is a general lack of experience among utility firms in the EBRD COOs in EE matters. Concern over EE potential and how to identify suitable opportunities is a common occurrence. Holding a series of stakeholder workshops to address these concerns, share information, and establish action plans for early stages of scheme roll-out prior to its commencement are recommended mitigation actions. Pay specific attention to M&V and the development of supporting documentation: Good quality guidance documentation regarding scheme operation and M&V 17
5. EEOs place in the policy buy-outs to National Energy Efficiency Funds availed by Obligated Parties in markets where measure mix for meeting the this is an option. The buy-out price is typically national energy savings target based upon the cost to the Fund of provided in EED Article 7 undertaking equivalent energy saving 5.1. The contribution of EEO schemes activities. Hence the low uptake indicates towards the 2020 Article 7 obligation Obligated Parties predominantly find ways to Close to 500 different policy measures were achieve savings at lower costs themselves. notified by EU Member States to the This finding is to be expected given the European Commission for the purposes of structure of EEO schemes is intended to meeting their Article 7 energy savings encourage competition. obligations11. In addition to EEO schemes and Due to their cost-effectiveness, the increase National Energy Efficiency Funds, these in the uptake of EEO schemes among policy measures can be defined using the Member States seen in response to Article 7 (non-exhaustive) list of categories given in obligations for 2020 may be expected to Article 7 Paragraph 9: continue in the period to 2030. • Energy or CO2 taxes Nevertheless, few Member States or • Financing and fiscal schemes Contracting Parties are expected to pursue • Regulations their Article 7 obligations solely via an EEO • Voluntary agreements scheme (only Denmark and Luxemburg aim • Standards and norms to do so for 2020). This leads a policy maker • Energy labelling schemes to consider how to select the most suitable • Training and education programmes mix of Alternative Measures alongside an EEO scheme. Despite this variety in the types of policy measures used by MS to contribute towards 5.3. Selecting an effective and the Article 7 obligations, EEO schemes are coherent policy mix for Article 7 expected to be the category which provides For 2020, the majority of non-EEO measures the largest single contribution in terms of notified by EU Member States had been pre- energy savings12. existing at the time of adopting the EED or are adaptations of existing measures 13 . This 5.2. The future role of EEO schemes in lessens the burden on savings to be borne by the Article 7 policy measure mix a new EEO or other major Alternative The prominent position of EEO schemes in Measure and the associated uncertainty of a the wording of Article 7 has been retained for new scheme. Inevitably, the policy mix the amended EED, extending the obligation chosen by individual Member States or to 2030, as recommended by the Contracting Parties is also influenced not only corresponding impact assessment. This is by the location of the most cost-efficient largely due to their relative cost-effectiveness – a point evidenced by the very low use of 11All such notified savings must comply with the 13 See: requirements of Annex V of the EED http://enspol.eu/sites/default/files/results/D3. 12 1%20Report%20on%20Alternative%20schemes http://www.europarl.europa.eu/RegData/etudes %20to%20Energy%20Efficiency%20Obligations% /STUD/2016/579327/EPRS_STU(2016)57932 20under%20Article%207%20implementation.pdf 7_EN.pdf 18
energy saving potential but also by climatic, efficiency in translating the direct costs political and cultural considerations. involved into energy savings and who is to bear these costs. The ability to select an optimum policy mix • The complementarity or potential overlap from a cost-efficiency perspective can be of the policy option with other policy further hampered by the lack of reliable data options; some measures complement on the costs and benefits of many measures, each other to a greater extent than lack of foresight on unintended others. consequences, and multiple policy • The sensitivity of the option to political objectives. Nevertheless, consideration and cultural acceptance and its stability should be given as to the complementarity of in terms of sustained funding. the policy options selected and whether they • Difficulties in verifying the energy savings are mutually reinforcing, or conversely (a particular difficulty for energy taxes) overlap in application and thus risk delivering and ensuing the eligibility of the option for less than the sum of their individual impact. meeting Article 7 targets. Overlapping policies can result in double • The complexity of the policy option. counting of energy savings (which must be eliminated as required by EED Article 12) and Labelling, information campaigns and potential over-compensation to recipients14. training, as well as minimum performance standards, will continue to provide an Criteria to consider in the selection of an essential role in bringing forward energy appropriate policy mix include: savings via improving the efficiency of • Whether they address the specific markets and addressing the issue of late barriers identified in the market in adoption. However, it is the EEO schemes, question. other financial and fiscal measures (including • Their scalability in delivering energy auctions), energy or CO2 taxes and voluntary savings: i.e. the degree to which the agreements, which will bear the heavy lifting option has been proven, or can of delivering energy savings under Article 7 by reasonably be expected, to deliver a aligning with its core objective of improving significant quantity of energy savings. the rate at which upgrades occur. • The market transformation potential of Careful crafting of these schemes will allow the measure: will it act as a “pull” on the them to work together in concert, delivering rate of market change as an EEO does, or energy savings at sufficient scale to meet does it address late adoption as with targets, across end-use sectors, and with due minimum performance standards? consideration of distributional effects. • Cost-effectiveness: noting the cost of administering the policy option, its 14For a full discussion on the considerations in http://enspol.eu/sites/default/files/results/D5. designing a policy mix for meeting Article 7 1Combining%20of%20Energy%20Efficiency%20 objectives, see the EU-funded ENSPOL project in Obligations%20and%20alternative%20policies.p report D5.1 “Combining of Energy Efficiency df Obligations and alternative policies”, 19
You can also read