Differential virtue discounting: Public generosity is seen as more selfish than public impartiality
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Differential virtue discounting: Public generosity is seen as more selfish than public impartiality Gordon T. Kraft-Todd*a, Max Kleiman-Weinerb, Liane Younga a Department of Psychology, McGuinn 300, 140 Commonwealth Ave, Boston College, Chestnut Hill, MA 02467 ; b Department of Psychology, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA 02138 *Corresponding author: gordon.kraft-todd@bc.edu Abstract There is a paradox in our desire to be seen as virtuous. If we do not overtly display our virtues, others will not be able to see them; yet, if we do overtly display our virtues, others may think that we do so only for social credit. Here, we investigate how virtue signaling works across two distinct virtues—generosity and impartiality—in eleven online experiments (total N=4,586). We demonstrate the novel phenomenon of differential virtue discounting, revealing that participants perceive actors who demonstrate virtue in public to be less virtuous than actors who demonstrate virtue in private, and, critically, that this effect is greater for generosity than impartiality. Further, we provide evidence for the mechanism underlying these judgments, showing that they are mediated by perceived selfish motivations. We discuss how these findings and our novel terminology can shed light on open questions in the social perception of reputation and motivation. Keywords: virtue signaling, virtue discounting, reputation, generosity, impartiality, virtue
Introduction Virtue signaling—i.e. conspicuous, public displays of admirable moral behavior—has only recently entered the cultural lexicon (Bartholomew, 2015). The term was coined—and is often used—to pejoratively describe a class of behaviors (e.g. "outrage": Crockett, 2017; Spring, Cameron, & Cikara, 2018) enabled by social media where actors invest minimal effort to widely broadcast their support for a cause. Though some defend such behavior by claiming that it can raise awareness of a cause, many remain skeptical because it enables actors to reap reputational rewards without meaningfully contributing to change. Such skeptics engage in what we call virtue discounting, i.e. the devaluing of virtuous behavior to the extent that ulterior, selfish (e.g. reputational) motivations can be inferred for actors’ behavior. The phenomena of virtue signaling and virtue discounting predate social media. Various spiritual and philosophical traditions have debated the merits of public displays of virtue (as discussed in De Freitas, DeScioli, Thomas, & Pinker, 2019). Previous research demonstrating these phenomena generally treat virtue as a single dimension: generosity (e.g. Barclay & Willer, 2007). Yet, in treatments of virtue both ancient (e.g. Aristotle’s virtue ethics) and modern (Graham et al., 2011), virtue is not considered a unitary construct, but a collection of conceptually distinct morally admirable traits. We depart from previous work by asking: are some virtues more subject to skepticism than others? Here, we present the first evidence of differential virtue discounting: different virtues are discounted to a different degree. Specifically, we show that participants engage in greater discounting of generosity than of impartiality. Why do people virtue signal? Individuals demonstrate concern for their reputations, i.e. how they are perceived by others (Emler, 1990). A virtuous reputation, specifically, can grant individuals higher social status (Bai, 2017), which can in turn lead to greater wealth and well- being (Henrich & Gil-White, 2001). We define virtue as a stable trait demonstrating other- regarding preferences through prosocial (i.e. other-benefiting) behavior. There is ample evidence that when individuals’ behavior is observable to others, e.g. done in public, individuals are more likely to behave prosocially (in the lab, e.g. Milinski, Semmann, & Krambeck, 2002; and in the field, e.g. Yoeli, Hoffman, Rand, & Nowak, 2013). People do not merely react to being observed, but also actively engage in managing others’ impressions of them (Jones & Pittman, 1982). It is therefore unsurprising that people attempt to signal their virtue (e.g. Barclay & Willer, 2007; Jordan, Hoffman, Bloom, & Rand, 2016). It is worth noting, however, that most previous demonstrations of virtue signaling have focused on a single virtue—e.g. generosity (Barclay & Willer, 2007), trustworthiness (Jordan et al., 2016), or impartiality (Kleiman-Weiner, Shaw, & Tenenbaum, 2017)—while little research exists comparing virtue signaling across virtues. Why (and how) do observers sometimes discount actors’ virtuous behavior? Given the benefits of a virtuous reputation, people may be motivated to exaggerate or falsely signal their virtue. Our distaste for such behavior may explain our condemnation of moral hypocrites, who espouse moral virtues in public but fail to act on them in private (Jordan, Sommers, Bloom, & Rand, 2017). Virtue discounting relies on the human capacity for theory of mind, i.e. the ability to reason about others’ mental states (Saxe, Carey, & Kanwisher, 2004). Of particular relevance here, this enables us to consider actors’ motivations, which in turn affects our moral judgments (Young, Cushman, Hauser, & Saxe, 2007). When observers infer selfish ulterior motives for prosocial behavior, they perceive actors less favorably (e.g. Newman & Cain, 2014). One cue to such inference is when observers know that actors know that they are being observed: observers
can then infer that actors are motivated by the selfish desire to achieve a good reputation, rather than by their virtue (Barclay & Willer, 2007). Here, we propose to replicate these findings, showing that observers will discount public displays of virtue (H1, see Methods). Expanding on this prior work, we explore perceptions of selfish motivations by decomposing the concept into “negative” self-oriented motivations (e.g. for reputational benefit) and “positive” moral motives (e.g. to signal a desired social norm). We expect these to be negatively correlated (see Methods and Table 3). We further expand on previous research by exploring virtue signaling and virtue discounting across two virtues that have been conceptually distinguished (Shaw, 2013): generosity, which we define as trait willingness to confer benefits to others at cost to oneself; and impartiality which we define as trait desire to treat others equally and without bias. These virtues have also been empirically distinguished (e.g. Shaw, Choshen-Hillel, & Caruso, 2018). As discussed above, there is ample evidence that people signal generosity (Barclay & Willer, 2007), but there is also emerging evidence that people signal impartiality (Kleiman-Weiner et al., 2017), and that this emerges early in development (Shaw & Olson, 2012). We believe that generosity and impartiality might be further distinguished by the extent to which they are discounted. Our tentative directional hypothesis is motivated by the intuition that there might be greater selfish motivations for being perceived as generous compared to impartial. Despite the growing body of work demonstrating the reputational benefits for being seen as impartial (for a review, see Shaw, 2016), there is a large literature demonstrating the reputational benefits for being seen as generous (for a review, see Barclay, 2013). It could be the case that the latter outweigh the former: consider, for example, an observer’s desire to interact with an actor who is seen as an exemplar of each virtue: while the observer could at most expect fair treatment from an extremely impartial actor, they might expect special treatment from an extremely generous actor. Thus, if an actor is perceived as generous (even if they are not), this might make them more attractive than if they are perceived as impartial. In sum: people stand to benefit from having virtuous reputations, and are therefore motivated to signal (and perhaps exaggerate) their virtue. Because virtue is not monolithic, but is comprised of conceptually distinct virtues, there may be heterogeneity in the benefit of having a reputation for different virtues. Due to the potential for false signaling, observers are likely to be skeptical of virtue signals to the extent that they infer ulterior selfish motivations for actors’ behavior. Finally, the extent that observers discount different virtues may depend on how selfish they think actors’ motivations are for publicly signaling these virtues. General Methods All online experiments were conducted using Qualtrics survey software, a convenience sample of participants were recruited using the crowdsourcing tool Amazon Mechanical Turk (Arechar, Kraft-Todd, & Rand, 2017). Data analysis for all studies was completed using STATA 13, and informed consent was obtained from all participants. We excluded duplicate Amazon worker IDs and IP addresses to prevent analyzing multiple observations per participant. The pre- study procedure was to ask participants to provide their mTurk IDs and transcribe a sentence of difficult-to-read handwritten text (the latter to prevent bot participation and discourage low-effort workers, a commonly used method on this platform; e.g. Kraft-Todd & Rand, 2019). In total, we requested N=4,000 participants (N=100/condition), but because some participants may have
completed the survey but failed to enter their completion code to mTurk (thus allowing others to complete the survey), the final sample was N=4,012 participants (47.0% female, average age=35.8 years) across all nine experiments presented in the primary analyses. Participants completed the study in m=3.8 minutes and were paid $1 for their participation. Experiments 8 and 9 were respectively preregistered at http://aspredicted.org/blind.php?x=zw4ee5 and http://aspredicted.org/blind.php?x=s6v2bx. All data and code are publicly available at: (non- blinded link to be added after review). Though elements of the survey design varied across experiments (see Table 1), all experiments involved hypothetical vignettes in which participants were randomly assigned to one of four between-subjects conditions in a 2 (virtue: generosity vs impartiality) x 2 (observability: public vs private) design (except for Experiments 7 and 8, which included an additional “baseline” observability condition not analyzed here; for an overview of the design of all studies, see Table 1; for complete experimental instructions, see SI Section 7). On the first screen of the experiment, which contained the stimuli, we asked participants to imagine that they know someone whom we briefly described. We provided a name for the friend (henceforth: “the actor”), which varied by condition, and was selected from a list of common female names in the US (because we were not interested in the effect of actor gender on the dependent variables, we used all female names). In all experiments, we provided a dictionary definition of the virtue (which varied by condition) adapted from Merriam-Webster.com (e.g. “Generosity usually means giving an abundance of one's money or time”; “Impartiality usually means treating everyone equally and fairly, without bias”). Table 1. Overview of experiments Sample Data used Analyzed Pre- Experiment Design features size Conditions in analysis variables registered? (all ~100 (all randomized) /condition) no. 1 No example 399 2 behaviors, 398 3 motive stipulated 399 Experiment- Moral goodnes 4 generated behaviors, 397 1 and trait ratings 2 (virtue: impartiality v motive stipulated generosity) Experiment- x 2 (observability: 5 generated behaviors, 400 public v private) motive not stipulated No 6 406 Moral goodnes, trait ratings, 1st-party benefit, 2 (virtue: impartiality v Participant-generated 3rd-party benefit, generosity) 7 beahviors, [motivations:] 612 1,2 x 3 (observability: motive not stipulated reputation, public v private v authentic, baseline) 8 norm-signaling, 599 moral 2 (virtue: impartiality v generosity) Yes 9 402 x 2 (observability: public v private)
Important differences in survey design across experiments were the operationalization of observability (public vs private; see Table 2, Columns 1-2) and the example behaviors for each virtue (see Table 2, Columns 3-4). Regarding the former, in Experiments 1-4, we explicitly stipulated the actors’ motivation for their behavior. We believe this is a stronger manipulation of observability than not doing so because it explains away other motivations that the actor might have had to display this virtue in public vs. in private and does not require participants to infer the actors’ (ambiguous) motivation for themselves. In Experiments 4-9, we provided examples of generous and impartial virtuous behaviors to further clarify the concepts (see Table 2, Columns 3-4). In Experiments 4-6, these examples were experimenter-generated, whereas in Experiments 7-9, these examples were participant-generated (see Supplemental Study 1, SI Section 1) and pre-tested by an independent sample (see Supplemental Study 2, SI Section 2). Table 2. Elements of the stimuli which varied across experiments. Virtue Observability (example behaviors) Experiment Private Public Generosity Impartiality 1 Though she is 2 (none) (none) [generous/impartial] 3 She is especially when she is with [generous/impartial] others, she is - Making sure everyone at a when others are especially social gathering receives the watching her act since [generous/impartial] same amount of food (e.g. when she knows that her when no one is four people share a large pizza 4 reputation for being - Volunteering at a homeless watching since she with eight slices, ensuring [generous/impartial] shelter knows that acting in everyone gets two) will improve. - Donating money to charities this way is consistent - Dividing work evenly among all with her values. like Doctors without Borders participants in a group project (one of their functions is to (i.e. not giving your friend less provide relief to victims of natural work because you like them) disasters) - Making auditions or job Though she is - Donating blood during a blood applications blind (i.e. evaluators [generous/impartial] drive (e.g. to the American Red She is especially can't see applicants' faces) so 5 when she is with Cross) [generous/impartial] that subtle, unconscious biases others, she is even against particular genders or when others are [generous/impartial] ethnicities don't enter into the watching her act. when no one is decision-making process watching. 6 - gave her children equal - bought a friend an expensive 7 She did these things allowances She did these things gift in private; therefore, - conducted a blind audition in public; therefore, - gave a waiter a large tip 8 other people did not - drew names from a hat for a other people knew that - stayed late to help a coworker know that she did project at work she did them. 9 them. Following the stimuli, in all experiments, we presented participants with the two primary dependent measures (in randomized order): moral goodness (“How morally good is [your friend]?” measured with a 100-point unmarked slider scale with anchors at 0 “extremely morally bad”; 50 “neither morally bad nor morally good”; and 100 “extremely morally good”), and trait ratings (“How [generous/impartial] is [your friend]?” measured with a 100-point unmarked slider scale with anchors at 0 “not at all” and 100 “very much”). Secondary dependent measures varied by experiment (see SI Section 7 for more details), and we presented these, as well as the
primary dependent measures in randomized order. This was true in all experiments except Experiments 2 and 3, where we presented the primary dependent measures in randomized order first, and then we presented the secondary measures in randomized order. All six secondary dependent measures we analyze here appeared in Experiments 6-9, and these measured participants’ perceptions of the actor’s motivation. Two assessed the benefit participants perceived to various parties relative to the actor: 1st-party benefit (“How much do you think Jen will personally benefit from behaving this way?”); and 3rd-pary benefit (“How much do you think another person would benefit from interacting with Jen?”). Four assessed participants’ perceived motivations for the actor’s behaviors (“How much do you think Jen is motivated to act [generously/impartially]…”): reputational (“…because she is trying to make others think she is [generous/impartial]?”); authentic (“…because she wants to be [generous/impartial]?”); norm- signaling (“…because she wants others to be [generous/impartial], and she is trying to lead by example?”); and moral (“…because she thinks it is the right thing to do?”). All six secondary dependent measures were answered on 100-point unmarked slider scales with anchors at 0 “not at all” and 100 “very much.” Following secondary dependent measures, we presented (in randomized order) participants with basic demographic questions (gender, age, race, income, education, and political affiliation; see SI Section 7 for more details). We present two sets of analyses across these experiments in the following sections grouped by the hypotheses they test. In Analysis 1, we test for evidence of: H1 (Virtue discounting hypothesis): Participants will discount ratings of an actor’s virtue when the actor behaves virtuously in public compared to in private. This logic motivates our novel differential discounting hypothesis: H2 (Differential discounting hypothesis): Participants will engage in greater virtue discounting of an actor when their behavior demonstrates generosity compared to impartiality. In Analysis 2, we test for the proposed mechanisms for these effects, respectively, H3 (Multiple mediation hypothesis): Participants’ virtue discounting will be explained by their attributing selfish motivations to actors. H4 (Multiple moderated mediation hypothesis): Participants’ greater virtue discounting of an actor demonstrating behavior that is generous, compared to impartial, will be explained by their attribution of more selfish motivations. For conciseness, in the main text we report effects only for the trait ratings primary dependent measure, though qualitatively similar results are obtained for effects for the moral goodness primary dependent measure (see SI Section 3 for more details). For our preregistered experiments (8 and 9), we conduct posthoc power analyses using G*Power3 software (Faul, Erdfelder, Lang, & Buchner, 2007). First, using only the experiments with the same manipulations (experiments 6 and 7), testing for a 2x2 interaction with an effect size of d=.21 (the interaction effect size we find across these two experiments), and an alpha of .05, results showed that a total sample size of 252 participants with 4 equally sized groups would be powered at .80. Next, using all previous experiments, testing for a 2x2 interaction with an
effect size of d=.31 (the interaction effect size we find across all previous experiments), and an alpha of .05, results showed that a total sample size of 118 participants with 4 equally sized groups would be powered at .80. Thus, the sample size of all experiments (400) provided adequate power to detect our effect of interest. Analysis 1. Generosity and impartiality exhibit differential virtue discounting The purpose of Analysis 1 is to conceptually replicate previous observations of virtue discounting and investigate the novel phenomenon of differential virtue discounting. We conduct a multivariate regression analysis to test the virtue discounting hypothesis (H1): i.e. whether public displays of virtue (collapsed across generosity and impartiality) are perceived as displaying the virtue less than private displays of virtue, as well as the differential discounting hypothesis (H2): i.e. whether the difference between perceptions of public and private displays of virtue is greater for generosity than impartiality. Methods We use data from all 9 online experiments (not including baseline observability conditions; total N=3,597; 46.6% female, average age=35.9 years). We first use a three-way MANOVA to test for an interaction of our experimental manipulations (virtue and observability) and study on our primary dependent measures (moral goodness and trait ratings). We do not observe a significant three-way interaction (Wilks’ lamda=.99, F(16,7112)=1.50, p=.090), so we use the combined data in further analyses and include experiment as a covariate, using contrasts on predicted marginal means to obtain estimates of effect size. We observe that moral goodness and trait ratings are strongly correlated (r=.68, p
generosity are rated as demonstrating the virtue significantly less than public displays of impartiality (Scheffe’s t=-4.44, p
Methods For Analysis 2, we combine all data from experiments in which we administered the complete battery of secondary dependent measures (Experiments 6-9). Analysis 2 therefore included 1,606 participants (47.4% female, average age=35.7 years). We first investigate the pairwise correlations among the secondary dependent measures (see Table 3). We observe that they are moderately correlated (average r=.35, each correlation p
Fig 2. Conceptual diagram of structural equation models used to test the multiple moderated mediation hypothesis (H4). Note that the conceptual diagram of the structural equation model used to test the multiple mediation hypothesis (H3) would look identical but without the “virtue” box and connected arrows (because this analysis is collapsed across virtue). Results The first structural equation model tests the multiple mediation hypothesis (H3): virtue discounting will be explained by perceived selfish motivations (see Figure 3). We first describe correlations in this model, and then we investigate indirect, total, and direct effects in the mediation. Beginning with estimates of model fit, we observe that the model accounts for 57.2% of the variance in trait ratings. Fig 3. Virtue discounting is explained by perceived selfish motivations (with more variance explained by lower perceived moral motivations than higher perceived self-oriented motivations). The first set of arrows left-to-right represents strength of association of each of the six secondary dependent measures with observability, and the second set of arrows left-to-right represents strength of association of trait ratings with each of the six secondary dependent measures. “Self-oriented” motivations are displayed in purple, and “moral” motivations are displayed in orange. Line thickness shows correlation strength among variables in the model collapsed across virtues (see Table 4 for more information). Significant correlations are represented by solid lines, and non-significant correlations are represented by dashed lines. Direction of correlation indicated by “+” for positive and “-” for negative.
Investigating associations of the observability manipulation with the secondary dependent measures (see Table 4), we observe that public displays of virtue are significantly associated with all secondary dependent measures (reputational, moral, and authentic motivation, 1st- and 3rd-party benefit), except norm-signaling (see Column 1). Turning to the association of trait ratings with the proposed mediators, we observe that trait ratings are significantly associated with all secondary dependent measures (see Column 2). Consistent with H3, we observe that perceived motivations are affected by public display, and trait ratings are affected by motivations in the hypothesized directions: self-oriented motivations are positively associated with public display (see Rows 1-2, Column 1) and negatively associated with trait ratings (see Rows 1-2, Column 2), while moral motivations are negatively associated with public display (see Rows 3-6, Column 1) and positively associated with trait ratings (see Rows 3-6, Column 2). Indirect effects of public display on trait ratings through each secondary dependent measure (see Column 3) represent the product of the two associations displayed in Columns 1 and 2. Table 4. Shown are correlations (Columns 1 and 2) in structural equation model testing H3 as well as indirect effects (Column 3; significant beta values in bold). “Self-oriented” motivations are displayed in purple, and “moral” motivations are displayed in orange. Observability -> Motivation Motivation -> Trait ratings Indirect effect b =.85 b =-.07 b =-.06 Reputation 95% CI [.76, .93] 95% CI [-.11, -.03] 95% CI [-.13, .02] p
Fig 4. Virtue discounting of both generosity and impartiality is explained by perceived selfish motivations (with more variance explained for each by lower perceived moral motivations than higher perceived self-oriented motivations). Stronger motivational inferences are made for generosity compared to impartiality. For generosity (a) and impartiality (b), the first set of arrows left- to-right represents strength of association of each of the six secondary dependent measures with the interaction of observability and virtue, and the second set of arrows left-to-right represents strength of association of trait ratings with the interaction of virtue and each of the six secondary dependent measures. “Self-oriented” motivations are displayed in purple, and “moral” motivations are displayed in orange. Line thickness shows correlation strength among variables in the model collapsed across virtues (see Table 4 for more information). Significant correlations are represented by solid lines, and non- significant correlations are represented by dashed lines. Direction of correlation indicated by “+” for positive and “-” for negative. First, we detail results explaining trait ratings of generosity (see Figure 5a). Beginning with estimates of model fit, we observe that the model accounts for 61.1% of the variance in trait ratings of generosity. Next, we investigate associations of secondary dependent measures with the observability manipulation (see Table 5): public generosity is significantly associated with all secondary dependent measures (reputational, moral, and authentic motivation, 1st- and 3rd-party benefit), except norm-signaling (see Column 1). We then turn to the association of trait ratings of generosity with the proposed mediators: trait ratings are significantly associated with all secondary dependent measures except 1st-party benefit (see Column 3). Consistent with H3, and replicating the result from the first structural equation model, motivations are affected by public display, and trait ratings are affected by motivations in the hypothesized directions: self-oriented motivations are positively associated with public display (see Rows 1-2, Column 1) and negatively associated with trait ratings (see Rows 1-2, Column 1), while moral motivations are negatively associated with public display (see Rows 3-6, Column 1) and positively associated with trait ratings (see Rows 3-6, Column 1). The total effect of observability on trait ratings of generosity is significant (b=-.74, 95% CI [-.87, -.62], p
Table 5. Correlations in structural equation model testing H4 (significant beta values in bold). Virtue x Observability -> Motivation Virtue x Motivation -> Trait ratings Indirect effect Generosity Impartiality Generosity Impartiality Generosity Impartiality b =1.03 b =.66 b =-.10 b =-.03 b =-.10 b =-.02 Reputation 95% CI [.90, 1.15] 95% CI [.54, .79] 95% CI [-.17, -.04] 95% CI [-.09, .02] 95% CI [-.23, .02] 95% CI [-.10, .06] p
desire for 3rd-party benefit explain virtue discounting for generosity to a greater extent than impartiality (see Table 5, Columns 5-6). Finally, while neither effect was itself significant, we note that participants perceive less motivation for norm-signaling for public compared to private displays of generosity (consistent with other moral motivations), while they perceive greater motivation for norm-signaling when reading about public compared to private displays of impartiality, and these effects are significantly different from each other. Discussion Here we provide evidence for the novel phenomenon of differential virtue discounting: participants devalued the virtue of actors who engaged in public (versus private) acts of generosity to a greater extent than they devalued the virtue of actors who engaged in public (versus private) acts of impartiality. These results build on previous findings that observers discount signals of virtue—in particular, generosity—when observers: 1) know that actors know that they’re being observed (Barclay & Willer, 2007); and 2) infer ulterior, selfish motives for actors’ behavior (e.g. Newman & Cain, 2014). These results also build on previous findings distinguishing the virtues of generosity and impartiality (e.g. Shaw et al., 2018). We provide evidence that discounting both virtues can be explained by observers’ inferring more selfish motivations for actors who engage in public (versus private) acts of virtue. These findings have implications for disparate research programs unified by the concept of virtue signaling and suggests fruitful avenues for future research on ultimate mechanisms of reputation as well as the relationship between person perception and moral judgment. First, we introduce precise terminology that may help to conceptually link findings on the general phenomenon of conspicuous, public displays of virtue. Virtue signaling is a term coined recently in the popular press (Bartholomew, 2015); yet, there are few examples of its use in academic literature (e.g. Grubbs, Warmke, Tosi, James, & Campbell, 2019). Virtue signaling encompasses an array of findings, including outrage expressed online (Crockett, 2017; Spring et al., 2018) as well as the application of costly signaling theory to prosocial behavior and cooperation (e.g. Barclay & Willer, 2007; Jordan et al., 2016). We also introduce a new term, virtue discounting, to describe people’s tendency to devalue signals of virtue when actors’ selfish motives can be inferred, uniting previously cited work (e.g. Newman & Cain, 2014) with research on self-signaling: e.g. exploring the phenomena of bragging (Berman, Levine, Barasch, & Small, 2014) and humblebragging (Sezer, Gino, & Norton, 2018). Critically, we also provide evidence for and introduce the novel concept of differential virtue discounting, showing heterogeneity in virtue discounting across two fundamental virtues, pointing to interesting future work on virtue discounting across other conceptually distinct virtues (e.g. loyalty, authority, and purity; Graham et al., 2011). Second, the evidence we provide for differential virtue discounting (H2) provides a clear avenue for future research employing evolutionary theoretical approaches to reputation to illuminate the nature of the selfish benefit observers infer. The predominant account of human reputation is provided by the theory of indirect reciprocity (Nowak & Sigmund, 1998): we gain a good reputation by following social norms and cooperating with others who do the same (Ohtsuki & Iwasa, 2006). If observers infer greater selfish motivations for actors’ behavior when it signals compliance with social norms, then a stronger social norm for being generous versus impartial may account for our results. Alternatively, on the theory of partner choice (Barclay,
2013; Noë & Hammerstein, 1994), individuals compete to display desirable traits so they are chosen as interaction partners for potentially mutually beneficial cooperative interactions. If observers infer greater selfish motivations for actors’ behavior when it signals more attractive traits, then generosity’s being more attractive than impartiality to potential interaction partners may account for our results. It would not be surprising if the strength of social norms and the attractiveness of interaction partner traits were correlated, though there might also be interesting moderators of this association, such as relational obligations (McManus, Kleiman-Weiner, & Young, 2020). There might be interesting cases where These explanations are neither mutually exclusive nor exhaustive, and future work may dissociate their contributions to differential virtue discounting across generosity and impartiality, and other virtues (Graham et al., 2011). Finally, our mediation results have interesting implications for research at the intersection of moral judgment and person perception (e.g. Kim, Park, & Young, 2020; Tamir & Thornton, 2018). We provide evidence for the mechanism of (differential) virtue discounting: observers devalue signals of virtue when they infer actors’ selfish motives. Yet, examining the motivational attributions responsible for this mediation (considering our first model supporting H3, though similar results hold for H4), we note the perhaps surprising result that this effect is explained mostly by a decrease in perceived moral motivations (totaling indirect effects by factor score, 76.8%) rather than an increase in perceived self-oriented motivations (totaling indirect effects by factor score, 18.9%). In other words, virtue discounting is the effect of a perceived lack of relevant moral motivation rather than an abundance of self-orientation, per se. Our selection of items in our motivational scale was not exhaustive (Braver et al., 2014), so future work accommodating other motivational inferences may yield additional insight into the cognitive process underlying (differential) virtue discounting. We all want to be seen as virtuous. The paradox of this desire is that the best way to be seen as virtuous is to be virtuous in public; yet, if we are virtuous in public—as we have shown here—observers may believe our behavior to be selfishly motivated. Or, as Oscar Wilde put it: “The nicest feeling in the world is to do a good deed anonymously—and have somebody find out.”
Author Contributions All authors developed the study concept and contributed to the study design. Data collection and analysis were performed by G. T. Kraft-Todd. G. T. Kraft-Todd performed the interpretation under the supervision of L. Young. G. T. Kraft-Todd drafted the manuscript, and M. Kleiman- Weiner and L. Young provided critical revisions. All authors approved the final version of the manuscript for submission. Acknowledgments This research was made possible by funding by the John Templeton Foundation and The Virtue Project at Boston College. We would like to thank the Morality Lab at Boston College for their feedback. Declaration of Conflicting Interests The authors declare that there were no conflicts of interest with regard to the authorship or the publication of this article. Open Practices Statement All data and analysis code for all experiments have been made publicly available via the Open Science Framework and can be accessed at (non-blinded link to be added after review). All stimuli can be found in SI Section 7. The design and analysis plans for Experiments 8 and 9 were respectively preregistered at http://aspredicted.org/blind.php?x=zw4ee5 and http://aspredicted.org/blind.php?x=s6v2bx (Experiments 1-7 were not preregistered).
References Arechar, A. A., Kraft-Todd, G. T., & Rand, D. G. (2017). Turking overtime: how participant characteristics and behavior vary over time and day on Amazon Mechanical Turk. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1-11. doi:10.1007/s40881-017-0035-0 Bai, F. (2017). Beyond Dominance and Competence: A Moral Virtue Theory of Status Attainment. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 21(3), 203-227. doi:10.1177/1088868316649297 Barclay, P. (2013). Strategies for cooperation in biological markets, especially for humans. Evolution and Human Behavior, 34(3), 164-175. Barclay, P., & Willer, R. (2007). Partner choice creates competitive altruism in humans. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 274(1610), 749-753. doi:10.1098/rspb.2006.0209 Bartholomew, J. (2015, 18 April 2015). The awful rise of 'virtue signalling'. The Spectator. Berman, J. Z., Levine, E. E., Barasch, A., & Small, D. A. (2014). The Braggart's Dilemma: On the Social Rewards and Penalties of Advertising Prosocial Behavior. Journal of International Marketing. Braver, T. S., Krug, M. K., Chiew, K. S., Kool, W., Westbrook, J. A., Clement, N. J., . . . for the, M. g. (2014). Mechanisms of motivation–cognition interaction: challenges and opportunities. Cognitive, Affective, & Behavioral Neuroscience, 14(2), 443-472. doi:10.3758/s13415-014-0300-0 Crockett, M. J. (2017). Moral outrage in the digital age. Nature Human Behaviour, 1(11), 769-771. doi:10.1038/s41562-017-0213-3 De Freitas, J., DeScioli, P., Thomas, K. A., & Pinker, S. (2019). Maimonides’ ladder: States of mutual knowledge and the perception of charitability. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 148(1), 158-173. doi:http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/xge0000507 Emler, N. (1990). A social psychology of reputation. European Review of Social Psychology, 1(1), 171-193. Faul, F., Erdfelder, E., Lang, A.-G., & Buchner, A. (2007). G*Power 3: A flexible statistical power analysis program for the social, behavioral, and biomedical sciences. Behavior Research Methods, 39(2), 175-191. doi:10.3758/BF03193146 Graham, J., Nosek, B. A., Haidt, J., Iyer, R., Koleva, S., & Ditto, P. H. (2011). Mapping the moral domain. Journal of personality and social psychology, 101(2), 366. Grubbs, J. B., Warmke, B., Tosi, J., James, A. S., & Campbell, W. K. (2019). Moral grandstanding in public discourse: Status-seeking motives as a potential explanatory mechanism in predicting conflict. PLOS ONE, 14(10), e0223749. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0223749 Hayes, A. F. (2013). Introduction to mediation, moderation, and conditional process analysis: A regression-based approach.: Guilford Press. Henrich, J., & Gil-White, F. J. (2001). The evolution of prestige: freely conferred deference as a mechanism for enhancing the benefits of cultural transmission. Evolution and Human Behavior, 22(3), 165-196. doi:http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1090-5138(00)00071-4 Jones, E. E., & Pittman, T. S. (1982). Toward a general theory of strategic self-presentation. Psychological perspectives on the self, 1(1), 231-262. Jordan, J. J., Hoffman, M., Bloom, P., & Rand, D. G. (2016). Third-party punishment as a costly signal of trustworthiness. Nature, 530(7591), 473–476. doi:10.1038/nature16981 Jordan, J. J., Sommers, R., Bloom, P., & Rand, D. G. (2017). Why Do We Hate Hypocrites? Evidence for a Theory of False Signaling. Psychological science, 28(3), 356-368. doi:10.1177/0956797616685771 Kim, M., Park, B., & Young, L. (2020). The Psychology of Motivated versus Rational Impression Updating. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 24(2), 101-111. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tics.2019.12.001 Kleiman-Weiner, M., Shaw, A., & Tenenbaum, J. B. (2017). Constructing social preferences from anticipated judgments: When impartial inequity is fair and why? Paper presented at the Proceedings of the 39th annual conference of the Cognitive Science Society. Kraft-Todd, G. T., & Rand, D. G. (2019). Rare and Costly Prosocial Behaviors Are Perceived as Heroic. Frontiers in Psychology, 10(234). doi:10.3389/fpsyg.2019.00234 McManus, R. M., Kleiman-Weiner, M., & Young, L. (2020). What We Owe to Family: The Impact of Special Obligations on Moral Judgment. Psychological science, 0(0), 0956797619900321. doi:10.1177/0956797619900321 Milinski, M., Semmann, D., & Krambeck, H.-J. (2002). Reputation helps solve the ‘tragedy of the commons’. Nature, 415(6870), 424-426. Newman, G. E., & Cain, D. M. (2014). Tainted Altruism: When Doing Some Good Is Evaluated as Worse Than Doing No Good at All. Psychological science, 25(3), 648-655. doi:10.1177/0956797613504785
Noë, R., & Hammerstein, P. (1994). Biological markets: supply and demand determine the effect of partner choice in cooperation, mutualism and mating. Behavioral ecology and sociobiology, 35(1), 1-11. Nowak, M. A., & Sigmund, K. (1998). Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring. Nature, 393(6685), 573- 577. Ohtsuki, H., & Iwasa, Y. (2006). The leading eight: social norms that can maintain cooperation by indirect reciprocity. J Theor Biol, 239(4), 435-444. Saxe, R., Carey, S., & Kanwisher, N. (2004). Understanding other minds: Linking developmental psychology and functional neuroimaging. Annual Review of Psychology, 55, 87-124. doi:10.1146/annurev.psych.55.090902.142044 Sezer, O., Gino, F., & Norton, M. I. (2018). Humblebragging: A distinct—and ineffective—self-presentation strategy. Journal of personality and social psychology, 114(1), 52. Beyond "to Share or Not to Share": The Impartiality Account of Fairness, 5, 22 Cong. Rec. 413-417 (2013). Shaw, A. (2016). Fairness: What it isn’t, what it is, and what it might be for. In D. C. Geary & D. B. Berch (Eds.), Evolutionary Perspectives on Child Development and Education (pp. 193-214): Springer International Publishing. Shaw, A., Choshen-Hillel, S., & Caruso, E. M. (2018). Being biased against friends to appear unbiased. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 78, 104-115. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jesp.2018.05.009 Shaw, A., & Olson, K. R. (2012). Children discard a resource to avoid inequity. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 141(2), 382-395. Sobel, M. E. (1982). Asymptotic Confidence Intervals for Indirect Effects in Structural Equation Models. Sociological Methodology, 13, 290-312. doi:10.2307/270723 Spring, V. L., Cameron, C. D., & Cikara, M. (2018). The Upside of Outrage. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 22(12), 1067-1069. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tics.2018.09.006 Tamir, D. I., & Thornton, M. A. (2018). Modeling the Predictive Social Mind. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 22(3), 201-212. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tics.2017.12.005 Winer, B. J., Brown, D. R., & Michels, K. M. (1991). Statistical Principles in Experimental Design (3 ed.). New York, NY: McGraw–Hill. Yoeli, E., Hoffman, M., Rand, D. G., & Nowak, M. A. (2013). Powering up with indirect reciprocity in a large-scale field experiment. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 110(Supplement 2), 10424-10429. doi:10.1073/pnas.1301210110 Young, L., Cushman, F., Hauser, M., & Saxe, R. (2007). The neural basis of the interaction between theory of mind and moral judgment. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 104(20), 8235-8240. doi:10.1073/pnas.0701408104 Zellner, A. (1962). An Efficient Method of Estimating Seemingly Unrelated Regressions and Tests for Aggregation Bias. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 57(298), 348-368. doi:10.1080/01621459.1962.10480664
Supplementary Information for Differential virtue discounting: Public generosity is seen as more selfish than public impartiality Gordon T. Kraft-Todd, Max Kleiman-Weiner, Liane Young Contents 1. Supplemental Study 1: Subject-generated acts of virtue .........................................................................20 2. Supplemental Study 2: Pretesting participant-generated acts of virtue ...................................................23 2.1 Methods ..............................................................................................................................................23 2.2 Results ................................................................................................................................................23 3. Analysis 1 of both primary dependent measures by experiment .............................................................27 3.1 Methods ..............................................................................................................................................27 3.2 Results ................................................................................................................................................27 4. Preregistered analyses only ......................................................................................................................30 4.1 Analysis 1...........................................................................................................................................30 4.1.1 Methods .......................................................................................................................................30 4.1.2 Results .........................................................................................................................................30 4.2 Analysis 2...........................................................................................................................................31 4.2.1 Methods .......................................................................................................................................32 4.2.2 Results .........................................................................................................................................32 5. Complete experimental instructions ........................................................................................................34 6. Unedited participant-generated acts from Supplemental Study 1............................................................49
1. Supplemental Study 1: Subject-generated acts of virtue Our aim in this study was to create a set of participant-generated behaviors that we would pretest (see Supplemental Study 2, SI Section 2) and use as stimuli in Experiments 7-9. Methods Our methods for this study follow the same procedure as that described in the General Methods section. We requested N=100 participants, though because some participants may have completed the survey but failed to enter their completion code to mTurk (thus allowing others to complete the survey), our final sample was N=114 participants (we did not collect demographics for this study). In randomized order, we provided participants with a dictionary definition of each virtue (from Meriam-Webster.com; generosity: “giving or sharing in abundance”; impartiality: “lack of favoritism toward one side or another”), and participants responded to the prompt: “Please name at least 3 and up to 10 real-life acts of [generosity/impartiality]” using free- response text boxes. Results Participants generated on average m=7.48 responses (generosity m=4.18; impartiality m=3.30), indicating that they followed instructions to provide at least 6 total. These were edited for responses which were nonsensical (e.g. “23”; “ruban”), spelling, punctuation, and grammar (see Tables S8 and S9 for complete list of unedited responses). Responses were further edited for simplicity (e.g. generalizing pronouns such as “woman” and “man” to “person”), part of speech (all responses were edited to be in the present participle; i.e. using ending in “-ing”), and semantic commonality (“give a homeless person some food” and “buying a homeless person food”; for complete unedited responses, see SI Section 8). This process yielded a list of 50 unique responses for both generosity (see Table S1) and impartiality (see Table S2). This study therefore provided us with the list of participant-generated generous and impartial act (total k=853).
Table S1. Edited participant-generated acts of generosity (stimuli are highlighted). no. generous acts 1 adopting a child 26 giving a waiter a large tip 2 adopting a pet 27 giving praise 3 babysitting for friend (for free) 28 giving someone a compliment 4 buying a friend an expensive gift 29 giving someone a hand carrying groceries 5 buying a homeless person food 30 giving up your seat on a bus 6 buying a round of drinks 31 helping an elderly person cross the street 7 buying everyone lunch 32 helping out a friend in need 8 buying someone a meal 33 helping someone fix a flat tire 9 buying someone groceries 34 helping someone move 10 buying supplies for an animal shelter 35 holding the door for someone 11 caring for a sick person 36 lending money to a friend letting a friend stay at your house for the 12 cooking for someone 37 night 13 donating a kidney 38 letting someone ahead of you in line 14 donating blood 39 mowing your neighbor's lawn (for free) offering advice to someone who 15 donating clothes to homeless shelter 40 wants/needs it paying for person behind you in line (for 16 donating food to a food pantry 41 example: toll or coffee) 17 donating money at church 42 picking up a hitchhiker 18 donating money to charity 43 picking up trash in a park 19 donating to a toy drive 44 recycling 20 donating to artists or content creators 45 sharing food with friends 21 donating your car to charity 46 staying late to help a coworker 22 giving a gift 47 volunteering at a homeless shelter 23 giving a hug 48 volunteering at an animal shelter 24 giving a ride to someone 49 volunteering to build homes for others 25 giving a scholarship to a student in need 50 walking a neighbor's dog (for free)
Table S2. Edited participant-generated acts of impartiality (stimuli are highlighted). no. impartial acts a boss giving a promotion purely based on donating the same amount to all countries 1 26 merit in need drawing names from a hat for a project at 2 a boss treating all employees the same 27 work a disinterested bystander mediating an giving an award to an equal number of 3 28 argument between two people white and black people a judge giving the same sentence to 4 29 giving children equal allowance people of different races a parent dividing assets equally among giving equal attention to each of your 5 30 their children in their will children a parent giving children equally valuable giving equal attention to each of your 6 31 Christmas gifts friends a parent hearing both sides of her giving equal attention to each of your 7 32 children's dispute without playing favorites parents giving the same level of customer service 8 a police officer giving themselves a ticket 33 to all customers a politician voting for a policy that affects helping to moderate when your friends are 9 34 the poor and the rich equally having a disagreement a restaurant giving tables on a first-come hiring people without regard to whether 10 35 first-serve basis they're your friend or family implementing affirmative action in a hiring 11 a scientist performing an experiment 36 or admissions decision learning to pronounce others' names 12 a teacher calling on all students equally 37 regardless of their country of origin a teacher giving all students the same 13 38 listening to both parties in a conflict equally opportunities to make up work a teacher who disciplines all students the 14 39 making a decision by flipping a coin same planning an event to be accessible to 15 acting as referee in sporting event 40 disabled people 16 adhering to the law every moment 41 providing equal pay for males and females being friendly to people no matter what 17 42 sharing things equally between two people race they are calling the police regardless of who splitting a candy bar evenly between two 18 43 commits the crime kids cheering for both sports teams in a staying neutral when politics are being 19 44 competition discussed 20 choosing a winner's name out of a hat 45 staying out of an argument choosing brands at random when treating people the same regardless of 21 46 shopping their religion treating people the same regardless of 22 conducting a blind audition 47 their sexual orientation 23 conducting a blind study 48 treating siblings equally using a random number generator to make 24 conducting a blind vote 49 a decision dividing food by cutting and letting other voting for a candidate in an election 25 50 person pick which piece they want randomly
2. Supplemental Study 2: Pretesting participant-generated acts of virtue Our aim in this study was to have an independent sample of participants rate our edited list of participant-generated behaviors from Supplemental Study 1 along dimensions of common interest in social psychology (Kraft-Todd & Rand, 2019) in order to create more tightly- controlled stimuli for Experiments 7-9 than the (non-pretested) experimenter-generated stimuli used in Experiments 4-6. 2.1 Methods Our methods for this study follow the same procedure as that described in the General Methods section. We requested N=500 participants from mTurk who did not participate in Supplemental Study 1 for this study, though after screening for repeat IP addresses and mTurk IDs (including only the first entry of either) and filtering participants who accepted the HIT on mTurk but neglected to complete the survey, our final sample was N=460 participants (54.1% female, average age=37.6 years). We randomly assigned participants to one of two between- subjects conditions, in which they were asked to rate either generous or impartial behaviors. We presented participants with a randomly selected subset of 20 behaviors (presented in randomized order) from the 50 generated for the respective virtue in Supplemental Study 1. Thus, each behavior was rated by an average of m=92 participants. Participants rated each behavior on five dimensions (presented in randomized order): moral goodness (“In your opinion, how morally good is it to do this behavior?”); as well as four which replicated the method of previous work (Kraft-Todd & Rand, 2019): descriptive normativity (“In your opinion, how many people in your community do this behavior when they are in the relevant situation?”); injunctive normativity (“In your opinion, how much do people in your community think doing this behavior is what you are supposed to do when you are in the relevant situation?”); benefit to the recipient (“In your opinion, how much benefit (in terms of money, time, effort, etc.) does the recipient of this behavior receive?”); and cost to the actor (“In your opinion, how much cost (in terms of money, time, effort, etc.) does the person who does this behavior incur?”). All ratings were completed using anchored sliding scales ranging from 0 to 100 (see SI Section 7 for more details). 2.2 Results Using the complete pretesting ratings (see Table S3 for complete ratings of all behaviors), we selected six participant-generated acts; three each for generosity and impartiality to be included as stimuli in Experiments 7-9. A number of considerations went into this selection procedure, both semantic (considerations 1-4 below) and numeric (considerations 5-7 below). First, we limited our selection to behaviors that were not role-specific (thus we excluded impartiality behaviors 1-14 which involve specific roles, e.g. “a judge”, “a boss”, etc.). Second, we limited our selection to behaviors that were one-shot interactions, rather than repeated, chronic, or with lasting impacts (and so we excluded behaviors which included e.g. “adopting a child”, “treating people the same regardless of their sexual orientation”, etc.). Third, we sought a diversity of targets of the behaviors (e.g. 10 behaviors across generosity and impartiality mentioned “friend(s)” as the recipient, and we did not want to include more than one “friend” behavior for each virtue). Fourth, we sought a diversity of verbs describing the behaviors (e.g.
generosity behaviors 13-21 use the word “donating”, and we did not want to include more than one “donating” behavior). Fifth, we limited our selection to behaviors that did not have extreme ratings across dimensions; neither high (e.g. generosity: “caring for a sick person”; impartiality: “a parent giving children equally valuable Christmas gifts”) nor low (e.g. generosity: “picking up a hitchhiker”; impartiality: “voting for a candidate in an election randomly”). Sixth, we limited our selection to behaviors that did not have extreme variation in ratings across dimensions (e.g. generosity: “helping an elderly person cross the street”; impartiality: “a parent hearing both sides of her children's dispute without playing favorites”). With these considerations, we selected three behaviors each for generosity (“buying a friend an expensive gift”, “giving a waiter a large tip”, “staying late to help a coworker”) and impartiality (“conducting a blind audition”, “drawing names from a hat for a project at work”, “giving children equal allowance”) as a potential stimulus set for our final, statistical consideration. Finally, we aimed to select a subset of behaviors that would be as similar as possible in each of the dimensions measured—particularly in ratings of moral goodness—so that these dimensions would not bias subsequent results. We therefore use multilevel mixed-effects linear regression to compare each rating as the dependent measure across virtue stimulus set (generosity vs impartiality as a binary predictor), entering act (of which there are 6) as a random factor. First, and, most importantly, our generosity stimulus set was not perceived as more morally good than our impartiality stimulus set (coeff=1.16, z=.16, p=.869; see Figure S1). Further, our generosity stimulus set was not perceived as different from our impartiality stimulus set across other dimensions: descriptive normativity (coeff=-5.77, z=-1.02, p=.310), injunctive normativity (coeff=-3.74, z=-.61, p=.541), and benefit to the recipient (coeff=8.59, z=1.88, p=.060). Our generosity stimulus set, however, was perceived as more costly to the actor than our impartiality stimulus set (coeff=22.22, z=3.52, p
You can also read