CLEAN ENERGY MINI-GRID POLICY DEVELOPMENT GUIDE - Fast tracking rural electrifi cation through accelerated and precise mini-grid policy ...
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Fast tracking rural electrification through accelerated and precise mini-grid policy formulation CLEAN ENERGY MINI-GRID POLICY DEVELOPMENT GUIDE
@ UNIDO 2020. All rights reserved. This document has been produced without formal United Nations editing. The designations employed and the presentation of the material in this document do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the Secretariat of the United Nations Industrial Development Organization ( UNIDO ) concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of frontiers or boundaries, or its economic system or degree of development. Designations such as “developed”, “industrialized” or “developing” are intended for statistical convenience and do not necessarily express a judgement about the stage reached by a particular country or area in the development process. Mention of firm names or commercial products does not constitute an endorsement by UNIDO. Graphic design: Johannes Krenner ( Joker Design )
Fast tracking rural electrification through accelerated and precise mini-grid policy formulation CLEAN ENERGY MINI-GRID POLICY DEVELOPMENT GUIDE
LIST OF ACRONYMS BOOT ��������������������������������������� Build, own, operate, transfer CAPEX ��������������������������������������������������� Capital expenditure CRM ����������������������������� Customer relationship management EPC �������������������������� Engineering-Procurement-Construction ERIL ��������������������������� Électrification rurale d’initiative locale ESCO ���������������������������������������������� Energy service company FDI ������������������������������������������������ Foreign direct investment GDP ������������������������������������������������� Gross domestic product GHG ������������������������������������������������������������ Greenhouse gas GIS �������������������������������������� Geographic Information System GIZ. . . . . . . . . . . German Corporation for International Cooperation IMF ������������������������������������������ International Monetary Fund IT ����������������������������������������������������� Information technology KMM ���������������������������������������������������������� KeyMaker Model MG ������������������������������������������������������������������������ Mini-grid MYTO �������������������������������������������������� Multi-year tariff order O&M ����������������������������������������� Operation and maintenance OPEX ������������������������������������������������ Operating expenditure PAYG �������������������������������������������������������������� Pay-as-you-go PPP ��������������������������������������������� Public-private partnership PV �������������������������������������������������������������������� Photovoltaic REA ������������������������������������������� Rural Electrification Agency REF ���������������������������������������������������������� Rural Energy Fund SDG ������������������������������������ Sustainable Development Goals TOU ������������������������������������������������������������������� Time of use WACC �������������������������������� Weighted average cost of capital 2
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS This policy guide was commissioned by the United Nations Industrial Development Organization ( UNIDO ), in partnership with the Alliance for Rural Electrification ( ARE ); the African Development Bank ( AfDB ) Green Mini- Grid Help Desk; and the Africa Minigrids Developers Association ( AMDA ), under the overall guidance of Rana Ghoneim, UNIDO. The consortium that put this guide together believes it will be an essential tool in the unique and challenging task of bringing an end to energy poverty. This work would not have been possible without the hard work undertaken by the authors, peer reviewers, and other contributors who participated in the development of this publication. For all their efforts, we are extremely grateful. Thank you. The policy guide represents a collaborative effort, made possible by the valuable contributions from experts in their respective fi elds. In this regard, the partners would like to express their gratitude to the professionals that contributed with their expert knowledge, with special thanks to Kolade Esan ( UNIDO ); Jens Jaeger ( ARE ); David Lecoque ( ARE ); Benedikt Lenders ( Engie ); Aaron Leopold ( AMDA ); Deepak Mohapatra ( ARE ); Gabriele Pammesberger ( ARE ); Claudio Pedretti ( ARE ); Quentin Peries-Joly ( Engie ); Rana Singh ( UNIDO ); and Jessica Stephens ( AMDA ). The Clean Energy Mini-Grid Policy Development Guide was authored by an expert team from INENSUS consisting of Nico Peterschmidt, Joanis Holzigel, Jakob Schmidt-Reindahl and Holger Peters, supported by their INENSUS colleagues Sylvain Boursier; Maÿlis Bravard; Andrea Cabanero; Christopher Fuess; Rana Tatiana González Grandon; and Bhoomika Tiwari. The partners are extremely grateful for the hard work and dedication shown by the INENSUS team to produce this policy guide. This publication has also benefited from peer review by an international team from partner institutions, including Thomas Andre ( REN21 ); Harry Andriantavy ( Club-ER ); Albert Boateng ( PFAN ); Nicola Bugatti ( TTA ); Michael Caubet ( EU TAF ); Ad Dankers ( Get.Invest ); Juan Garcia Montes ( Sunkofa ); James Knuckles ( World Bank ); Irene Calve Saborit ( Sunkofa ); Kristina Skierka ( Powerforall ); Ruchi Soni ( SEforAll ); Rebecca Symington ( Energy4Impact ); Pepin Tchouate ( Power Africa ); Antoine Veyre ( Sunkofa ); Steve Wasira ( Virunga Power ); and Ashley Wearne ( Get.Transform ). We would also like to thank our UNIDO colleagues – Emma Sahakian for providing administrative support and Leisa Burrell for supporting the finalization of the publication Lastly, special thanks are due to Julian Rose for his thorough editing of this publication. Authors: 4
FOREWORD Mini-grids have been touted by experts as central to regulations needed to radically speed up investment, the rural electrification challenge for many years but deployment and progress on energy access using remain poorly understood by decision-makers. Their mini-grids. energy services are high quality, their technologies are mature, but they are often constructed in remote, This guide builds on the widely utilized Mini-Grid hard to reach areas, and their business models Policy Toolkit, released in 2014. This current guide are quite different to many independent power has been a collaboration between INENSUS, the producers. United Nations Industrial Development Organiza- tion ( U NIDO ), the Alliance for Rural Electrification It is therefore unsurprising that policies and regula- ( ARE ), the Africa Minigrid Developers Association tions currently providing the framework for the mini- ( AMDA ), and the African Development Bank ( AfDB ). grid sector to work within are often not fit for pur- It highlights the challenges that governments and pose. A consequence of this is that while the World policymakers typically face, and presents customized Bank estimates there is a need for over 140,000 approaches by means of decision guides, to facilitate mini-grids in Africa, in 2020 the average regulatory smoother decision-making and to expedite mini-grid approval time across the continent for one mini-grid deployment. is over one year. 1 It also provides a number of templates for contracts This enormous gap between what is needed in terms and agreements, which can be used as references by of delivery and what is currently possible in terms policymakers when seeking to tailor such documents of governance shows the extremely urgent need for for their respective markets. Lastly, the guide pres- new thinking and approaches to policy and regula- ents policymakers with a set of key recommenda- tion across the continent. This is particularly impor- tions on how to approach policies and regulations for tant given that only one decade remains to the 2030 a decentralized infrastructure market such as mini- deadline for achieving the globally agreed Sustain- grids – something that will require important and able Development Goals, around a dozen of which sometimes significant changes to how governments require universal energy access as a prerequisite for approach their energy sectors. their success. We now, however, need you – the reader – to help us To speed up progress on this challenging front, this take this guide to the places it is needed most, the Clean Energy Mini-Grid Policy Development Guide hearts and minds of decision-makers and those who takes a decision-makers perspective on the options, are supporting and working with them. We must take trade-offs and benefits of different approaches a these guides, templates and ideas from paper, and country might take to designing the policies and put them into practice! Signed Tareq Emtairah, Director, UNIDO, Department of Energy David Lecoque, CEO, ARE Daniel Schroth, Advisor to the Vice President and Acting Director for Renewable Energy and Energy Efficiency, AfDB Aaron Leopold, CEO, AMDA 1 AMDA, 2020. Benchmarking Africa’s Minigrids. Africa Minigrid Developers Association ( AMDA ). http://africamda.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/09/AMDA-Benchmarking-2020-.pdf Foreword 5
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Mini-grids have been identified as a critical tool 2. The way in which mini-grids are ultimately towards achieving universal electricity access by deployed, including the degree of private sector governments, donors and private sector actors involvement, depends on decisions taken by alike. To enable the sustainable deployment of government. In order to be sustainable, mini- mini-grids, the public and private sector need to grids require a comprehensive, long-term political cooperate. Policies and regulations which support commitment and a stable, reliable policy framework. the most suitable mini-grid delivery models need The long-term sustainability of mini-grids is in the to be developed to allow the sector to scale. The interests of both the operator and the government ( if Clean Energy Mini-Grid Policy Development Guide, the government is not the operator ). Sustainability developed in partnership by ARE, AMDA, UNIDO, in mini-grids means technically sound and reliable INENSUS and the AfDB Green Mini-Grid Help operation, high-quality customer service and Desk, outlines the various forms and models that financial profitability. public-private cooperation could take and reflects on the outcomes of policy decisions on mini-grid 3. Large government control over mini-grid deployment. deployment, minimum financial subsidies and low end consumer tariffs cannot all be achieved While the guide is not exhaustive, it provides an at the same time. Policy makers need to balance overview of the most important aspects of mini-grid out the level of government control over the mini- policy, with the aim of supporting policy makers to grid deployment with the financial contribution the accelerate mini-grid deployment and to help guide government is willing to provide and the tariff applied national debates and decision making on rural elec- to rural electricity customers. Different delivery trification policies and frameworks. models allow for specific combinations and degrees of achievement of the different objectives. The guide incorporates lessons learnt from existing mini-grid policies and regulations and presents the 4. The development of electricity demand in rural key decisions that need to be taken by policymakers areas is difficult to predict, making it important to in designing the most appropriate mini-grid frame- introduce demand risk mitigation instruments in the work for their country. A decision tree designed for policy framework. Demand growth is influenced by a policymakers outlines which combination of key number of factors beyond the control of the mini-grid decisions leads to which outcome. operator, and may only be accurately predicted after a few years of mini-grid operation. Five critical conclusions may be drawn from the guide: 5. The risk of a sudden end to the project, i.e. the termination risk, ought to be considered by policy 1. Sustainable mini-grid business/delivery models makers and regulators. Termination risk is not only require scale. In order to reach scale, all regulatory related to the regulation of main-grid connection to and administrative processes must be designed to be the mini-grid, but also to concession contracts, lease efficiently applied at large volume. agreements, usage rights agreements, PPP contracts, land right agreements etc. 6
A number of different instruments may be deployed Once a policy framework has been put in place, to support the sustainable roll-out of mini-grids. drastic and rapid changes to the framework must Templates which may be utilized for the practical be avoided. Ultimately, the success of the deployed development of mini-grid policy and regulation are mini-grids will reflect the level of trust between all linked to the guide. stakeholders, including electricity consumers, opera- tors, donors, investors, government, authorities and Among others, the following instruments are featured the general public. Gradual changes must never uni- in detail in the guide: laterally generate disadvantages without compen- • Critical features of tariff tools and tariff sating the respective stakeholder. regulation applicable under the selected subsidy scheme ( or vice versa ) are presented, highlighting When all aspects of a mini-grid framework have been in particular the Cost of Service model. This carefully considered, deployed projects may fulfil a model can be considered a scale that always crucial role in achieving electricity access and fight- needs to be in balance to allow mini-grids to ing energy poverty, also enabling the development of operate sustainably. Government actions that rural industries and new industrial value chains. Suc- lead to an imbalance of the Cost of Service model cessful collaboration between all stakeholders in the will automatically result in a failure of mini-grid sector will result in significant progress and in help- electricity supply, with the regulatory authority ing to achieve energy access milestones. considered as the guardian of the scale. • Appropriate licensing and permitting schemes are discussed, including portfolio licensing and licensing based on system size. The granting of licences and permits is an administrative process that must be carried out quickly to enable You can access the accelerated rural electrification. Therefore, the templates here: documents and tools must be easy to handle for a large number of sites in a short period of time. Digital technologies with automatic data processing are highly recommended. • The diverse set of procurement processes for mini-grids are analysed. Four competitive procedures ( lowest service charge, lowest tariff, lowest weighted average cost of capital ( WACC ) and lowest grant ) and one first-come-first-served procedure ( fixed grant per connection, also known https://greenminigrid.afdb.org/ as RBF or PBG ) are introduced. afdb-mini-grid-training-and-templates Executive Summary 7
FIGURES FIGURE 1. Presentation of the most suitable electrification solution across the rural-urban and low to high agro-industrial divide . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 FIGURE 2. From rural electrification and development targets to policy framework and grant funding scheme. Source: INENSUS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 FIGURE 3. Delivery models in dependency of funding level, tariff level and degree of government control. Source: INENSUS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 FIGURE 4. Tariff methodologies are a regulatory instrument that balances the costs and revenues of mini-grids. Source: INENSUS. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18 FIGURE 5. The main types of government support mechanisms for mini-grid deployment. Source: INENSUS . . . 21 FIGURE 6. Electricity demand development following root function shaped curves. Which trajectory the development takes can only be projected with high certainty after 3 years. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22 FIGURE 7. Demand risk: Break-even of mini-grid projects depends on electricity demand. Demand that is too high or too low endangers the financial sustainability of mini-grids. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 FIGURE 8. Termination risk: If electricity demand develops slower than expected, contracts with fixed end dates or main-grid connection to the mini-grid without compensation may lead to a termination of the mini-grid project before break-even. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 FIGURE 9. Sequence of implementing policies and regulations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25 FIGURE 10. Logic tree depicting the decision-making process leading from the determination of universal electricity access targets to a decision on mini-grid delivery mode . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26 FIGURE 11. Iteration cycle for planning of rural economic inclusion using mini-grids . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27 FIGURE 12. Decision Tree guiding the selection of mini-grid delivery models, taking into consideration structural and contextual features. Tariff levels are based on experience by the authors, and reflect range of values as publicised in SEforALL ( 2020 ) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29 FIGURE 13. Mini-grid policy instruments based on delivery models. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33 TABLES TABLE 1. List of mini-grid regulation and contractual templates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33 TABLE 2. Overview of procurement procedures applicable in various delivery models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34 TABLE 3. Pros and cons of competitive procurement vs. first-come-first-served approaches from a government’s perspective . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36 TABLE 4. Tariff determination applicable in various delivery models. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39 8
CONTENTS List of Acronyms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2 Acknowledgements. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4 Foreword . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 Executive summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 Figures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 1. Introduction to the guide . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 2. Policy development guide for decision-makers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12 2.1 Cross-cutting decisions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 2.1.1 The utility of mini-grids – where and how to deploy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 2.1.2 Delivery models – the degree of private sector involvement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16 2.1.3 Tariff methodologies as a balance between costs and revenues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18 2.1.4 Public funding programmes for the deployment of mini-grids based on private operator models . . . . . . 20 2.1.5 Sustainability of mini-grids – mitigating risk through policy design . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22 2.2 Decision-making process and policy development. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25 2.3 The Decision Tree . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 2.3.1 Decision Tree questions explained . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 2.4 Key takeaways. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30 3. Accelerating electrification through modern mini-grid regulations, procurement and contractual arrangements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 3.1 Procurement, tenders and grant allocation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34 3.1.1 Selecting a procurement procedure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36 3.2 Tariff regulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38 3.2.1 Tariff vs. subsidy setting methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38 3.2.2 Retail tariff structure. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40 3.3 Licensing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42 4. Making a decision on mini-grid delivery models based on a complex holistic assessment . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44 5. Conclusion and Recommendations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46 6. References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 Contents 9
1. INTRODUCTION TO THE GUIDE The Clean Energy Mini-Grid Policy Development 1. Government control over mini-grid operation and Guide is a tool that helps policymakers to tailor mini- assets. grid policy to country-specific contexts. It guides pol- 2. Required levels of public funding. icymakers through the relevant decision making pro- 3. Resulting electricity retail tariffs. cesses and provides background information where 4. Legal documents and tools to be prepared. required. The guide can be seen as an update to the widely used Mini-Grid Policy Toolkit 2014, incor- While the policy strategy is determined based on a porating lessons learned from developments in the process as described in Chapter 2, Chapter 3 sup- mini-grid sector in the intervening years. Its rationale ports the policymaker in implementing the strategy and messages are widely applicable, but are particu- in the form of tender documentation, tariff setting larly suited to the Sub-Saharan African context. methodology and licensing approaches. Building on this, the chapter discusses the essential features Chapter 2 of this guide introduces a number of key that ensure a balanced policy environment in the decisions that need to be taken by policymakers as mini-grid sector, and provides links for templates for they move towards designing the mini-grid frame- some of the key tools and documents that already work that is most appropriate for their country’s take these essential features into account. context. At the same time, fundamental economic relationships and interdependencies between stake- holders in the mini-grid sector are presented, while the guide also suggests which constellations are feasible and lead to long-term sustainability in mini- grid operation and which do not. From this under- standing, a decision tree for policymakers is derived, showing which combination of key decisions leads to which outcome, with regard to the following: 10
Chapter 4 takes a nuanced look at national planning, The guide shows that sustainable mini-grid business/ with particular emphasis on the debate on national delivery models require scale, i.e. an entity that man- goal setting. This guide uses “delivery models” to ages a large number of mini-grids and an even larger explain the different options of policy strategies. The number of customers. As a result, delivery models term “delivery model” describes the way in which such as the community model, which are unlikely to mini-grids are implemented and operated, by whom be scalable, are not considered in this guide. and with which financing instruments. It should be noted that the delivery models presented in this While this document is not exhaustive, it provides guide are not exhaustive. The same applies to poli- an overview of the most important aspects of mini- cies supporting these business models. grid policy. With this, the partners hope to support national policymakers accelerate mini-grid deploy- ment and to help guide national debates and deci- sion making on rural electrification policies and frameworks. Introduction 11
2. POLICY DEVELOPMENT GUIDE FOR DECISION- MAKERS Mini-grids have become a viable option for providing Governments of countries such as Nigeria, Kenya, reliable and high-quality electricity to rural populations Uganda, Zambia, Sierra Leone and Senegal – among and businesses. In total, 47 million people worldwide others – have recognized mini-grids as a cost-effec- are already connected to 19 000 mini-grids, of which tive and quickly implementable solution for promot- at least 2 577 are operational clean energy mini-grids ing the development and industrialization of rural ( ESMAP, 2019 ). As economies of scale gradually areas, supplying reliable electricity to hospitals, take hold in the mini-grid sector, and the costs of schools, police stations, government offices and reli- photovoltaics and batteries decrease over time, gious institutions, and connecting the surrounding overall system costs are falling. At the same time, households and businesses to decentralized distri- the progressive use of information technology ( IT ) 2, bution systems. together with mobile payment schemes and consumer protection measures, improve the reliability and All the countries outlined above have either carried offtake of power in mini-grids, thereby generating out or are in the process of carrying out a decision- increased revenues. With falling costs and increased making process aimed at developing their unique reliability, mini-grids have become more attractive to mini-grid delivery models and associated policy both the public and private sectors. frameworks, which are tailored to their country-spe- cific conditions. The positive experience of early adopters in countries such as Nigeria 3 has attracted more investors to This chapter aims to provide guidance to interested the sector. This dynamic created a virtuous circle governments on the selection and development of in which mini-grid companies are now ready to appropriate mini-grid delivery models. The assis- expand their operations. This is urgently needed, tance should help the governments to achieve their as a total of 180 000 additional mini-grids need to countries’ respective electrification and development be built to supply electricity to 440 million people goals within the specified time frames on the basis of if the overarching objective of universal access to accelerated rural electrification measures. electricity by 2030 ( ESMAP, 2019 ) is to be achieved. 2 Examples: mobile money integration, remote monitoring and control, customer relationship management systems, digital call centres, Geographic Information Systems ( GIS ), ERP systems, etc. Examples: mobile money integration, remote monitoring and control, custo- mer relationship management systems, digital call centres, Geographic Information Systems ( GIS ), ERP systems, etc. 3 In 2016, Nigeria was among the first countries to pass a specific mini-grid regulation 12
2. 1 | CROSS-CUTTING DECISIONS The following subchapters guide the reader through between stakeholders and business opportunities various fundamental decisions that policymakers that are briefly introduced for each topic on which a may make when developing and implementing mini- policymaker needs to take a decision. grid policy. These decisions are based on mini-grid- specific economic mechanisms, legal dependencies 2. 1. 1 | THE UTILITY OF MINI-GRIDS – WHERE AND HOW TO DEPLOY Until the late 2010s, mini-grids were regarded as one Recent approaches have used mini-grids as a stra- of a number of technology options to supply as many tegic tool to establish and actively promote specific rural citizens as possible with electricity at the low- rural industries based on locally available resources, est cost possible under the so-called “least cost elec- in order to significantly advance the development of trification” approach. Mini-grids found their place in a particular community or district 4. Mini-grids are between solar home systems and main grid exten- therefore becoming an integral part of governments’ sion, depending on population density and distance rural industrialization strategies. The approach from the main grid. The preferred operator of mini- underlying this strategy will henceforth be called grids was considered the entity that could best guar- “fourth generation mini-grids” ( see text box ). antee a reliable power supply at the lowest cost, be it the private sector, a government agency or the community itself. Fourth generation mini-grids First generation mini-grids powered by diesel, steam In many cases, mini-grids remain the or hydro were hybridized with renewable energy cheapest and fastest solution for the technologies in the second generation. The third electrification of rural towns and vil- generation introduced information technology to the lages; Further, knowledge of their sector, improving efficiency in tariff collection, remote potential impact on local and national monitoring, customer management and automatic economies has evolved. As a result, operation. The fourth generation uses fully automated pure “least cost electrification” is now complemented by considerations of third generation mini-grids as a tool with which to tap “maximum economic impact”. into or establish new value chains outside of service or product sales to rural customers. The key drivers are Geospatial analysis for integrated those synergies between the business lines that lead rural electrification planning begins to competitive advantages for the operator. Examples by considering the geolocation of ele- of fourth generation mini-grid business models include ments such as agricultural and mineral the multi-utility model, which uses mini-grid staff to resources and the geolocation of criti- also manage government infrastructure, the KeyMaker cal government infrastructure. model, which pre-processes rural goods in mini-grids to establish logistical channels to trade hubs, the agri-hub model, which promotes the latest farming practices, such as drip irrigation in horticulture, and the anchor customer model. 4 This type of approach is currently being developed for roll-out in Ethiopia. Policy develoment 13
Urban area with high population density Grid (Extension) Grid (Extension) Low-Agro-Industrial High-Agro-Industrial Potential 3rd Generation 4th Generation Potential Mini-grids Mini-grids Solar Home Systems Rural area with low population density FIGURE 1. PRESENTATION OF THE MOST SUITABLE ELECTRIFICATION SOLUTION ACROSS THE RURAL- URBAN AND LOW TO HIGH AGRO-INDUSTRIAL DIVIDE In this regard, it is of significant importance to The choice made for each of the least cost electrifi- understand which entity delivers the electricity and cation and rural industrialization planning branches, whether or not the entity is capable of making use as outlined in Figure 2, in turn influences the set of of the opportunities of rural industrialization in the policies and regulations to be put in place. As will best interests of the respective government. A pol- be highlighted in the course of this guide, the mini- icy framework may be based on a variety of delivery grid delivery model also determines the level of tar- models that are chosen with the aim of achieving dif- iffs charged to rural customers, as well as the scope ferent objectives ( e.g. least cost electrification and and type of financial support required for successful rural industrialization ), as shown in the following mini-grid deployment. figure. 14
Rural electrification and rural development targets Least cost Rural Rural electrification industrialization industrialization for sector A for sector B Geographical Geographical and cultural and cultural setting I setting II Preferred Preferred Preferred Preferred mini-grid mini-grid mini-grid mini-grid operator 1 operator 2 operator 3 operator 4 Delivery Delivery Delivery Delivery model 1 model 2 model 3 model 4 Mini-grid policy framework and grant funding scheme FIGURE 2. FROM RURAL ELECTRIFICATION AND DEVELOPMENT TARGETS TO POLICY FRAMEWORK AND GRANT FUNDING SCHEME. Source: INENSUS A mini-grid delivery model is defined as the method • Split asset – The distribution network is financed by which mini-grids are rolled out ( delivered ). It and owned by the government. The private sector answers the following questions: Who delivers and or cooperative operator finances, builds and owns installs the mini-grid? Who pays for the mini-grid the generation assets and operates the entire assets and by what means ( grant vs. private invest- mini-grid. In a slight variant of this model, the ment or a mix of the two )? Who owns the assets and private sector receives a grant to partially finance who is responsible for replacement or extension the generation assets, which will be referred to as investments? Who operates the mini-grids and per- the “hybrid split asset/grant” model. forms customer service? • Private with capital expenditure ( CAPEX ) grant The most popular and most scalable delivery models – The private sector or cooperative mini-grid are considered to be the following: operator finances, installs, owns and operates the mini-grid assets and receives a CAPEX grant from • EPC/utility – A government or national utility the government. contracts a private company to supply and install mini-grids. The national utility subsequently takes In practical implementation, there are different ver- over the operation of the mini-grids. sions of the above-listed delivery models, and com- • ESCO – The government finances and owns the binations often occur. Community-driven models are mini-grid assets, which are installed and/or not mentioned here, as they are not discussed in operated by a private company or cooperative. detail in this guide. For the sake of simplicity, coop- Tariffs charged to electricity customers ( plus eratives, which are managed like private companies, optional government operating expenditure are listed below under the private sector models. ( OPEX ) grants ) cover the private operator’s costs of operation, including profit. Policy develoment 15
2.1.2 | DELIVERY MODELS – THE DEGREE OF PRIVATE SECTOR INVOLVEMENT mitigating off-taker risk. A lower risk perception leads to lower return expectations and makes The political decision-maker can decide any competition and regulation more effective. either to support a pure least cost See Chapter 2.1.5 for further information on risk electrification approach or to use mini-grids mitigation through policy design. purely as an instrument to achieve rural industrialization goals, or else to promote a The identified mini-grid delivery models can be combination of both approaches. Based on distinguished according to the following: the decision outlined above, the preferred spectrum of mini-grid operators and associ- 1. The degree of government control over key ated business models may be determined. aspects of electricity supply, such as tariff levels vs. quality of service. 2. The operational and capital subsidies required for the successful implementation of these models. 3. The tariff levels to be charged to customers to As outlined in Chapter 2.1.1, all mini-grid delivery make the respective delivery model financially models involve the private sector, whether as a viable. vendor and installer, as a partner in a public-private partnership ( PPP ) or in the fully private sector driven The following figure describes the respective deployment of mini-grids. The involvement of the dependencies between public funding mechanisms private sector in the selected mini-grid delivery for CAPEX and OPEX subsidies and the resulting tariff model can increase the efficiency and quality of levels, based on the degree of government control services and mobilize financial resources for mini- as it would be either presumed or correspondingly grid development. In general, the private sector required. Government contributions to the financing is geared towards financial sustainability and of mini-grids generally decrease as the private sector profitability. In order to attract the private sector to contribution increases. This applies to both CAPEX mini-grids, it is therefore essential firstly to design an and OPEX. Higher CAPEX subsidies allow lower tariffs overall package for risk and return that is attractive to ( see left side of Figure 3 ). Currently, OPEX is typically private companies. In this package, competition and only subsidized in the EPC and ESCO model and only regulation can be used to minimize cost, tariffs and in rare cases in other models. As tariffs increase, the required subsidy. need for OPEX subsidies decreases. ( see right side of Figure 3 ). On the return side, the package may require private investment ( equity and debt ), provide capital grants The total amount of government resources allocated and/or subsidies to finance the capital costs of to the development of mini-grids is also relatively building and operating mini-grids, while ensuring a consistent with the level of control that a government tariff level that is both affordable for end users and would ( wish to ) exert over the operation of the financially viable for mini-grid operators. In order to mini-grid. For delivery models with higher degrees maximize private sector investment and the rate of of government control, the public sector needs to connections operational and investment risks need be prepared to invest more resources in mini-grids, to be mitigated. This includes ensuring the long term including potential cross subsidization of electricity stability of regulation and legislation, minimizing usage of rural customers if a national uniform tariff termination risk and ensuring that subsidies/grants is to be charged. are reflective of the demand profile of consumers, 16
FIGURE 3. DELIVERY MODELS IN DEPENDENCY OF FUNDING LEVEL, TARIFF LEVEL AND DEGREE OF GOVERNMENT CONTROL. Source: INENSUS Funding Level Tariff Level Government Control Tariff level Public OPEX funding level Public CAPEX funding level Degree of government control Hybrid – split Private with EPC / utility ESCO Split asset asset / grant CAPEX grant In the Private Sector with CAPEX Grant model, the In contrast, the “cost-reflective plus” retail tariffs that government will need to subsidize a lower proportion private operators need to charge to enable a busi- of the initial CAPEX than, for instance, in the EPC or ness case are inversely proportional to the level of ESCO model, but the overall level of funding can vary public funding for these projects. These tariffs cover greatly depending on site-specific factors such as the both the operators’ costs and a profit margin. size of the power plant, village layout and density and The selection of delivery models therefore depends the economic status and potential of the community. on the availability of public funding for the roll out It is noteworthy, however, that in any scenario, a of mini-grid projects, the willingness of customers in fully privately-funded mini-grid is difficult, if not rural areas to pay for electricity and the envisaged impossible, to achieve without subsidies due to degree of government control over the operation of the challenges of powering rural communities. mini-grids. These challenges include, among others, challenging logistics to install assets on site as well as maintain remote O&M and comparatively low ability and willingness to pay by consumers. Private developers The political decision-maker can choose can improve the economic viability by implementing one of the delivery models or a combination fourth generation mini-grids, but it remains to be of models, based on the envisaged extent seen whether these will improve project finances of government control, the planned degree sufficiently to enable fully private sector-funded of government funding and the desired mini-grids at scale. levels of retail tariffs. Policy develoment 17
2.1.3 | TARIFF METHODOLOGIES AS A BALANCE BETWEEN COSTS AND REVENUES Retail tariffs in mini-grid projects are determined 2. The allocation of project sites to project developers by the CAPEX and OPEX of a system, the subsidy and operators ( how tendering procedures should level and regulation. As shown above, tariffs can be be designed to allow clustering of sites and reduced with increasing public funding contributions the selection of sites with potential for rural to mini-grid projects ( see Chapter 2.1.2). Larger mini- industrialization ). grids with a high customer density, the existence of anchor customers and interesting productive use and By making targeted use of these instruments, policy- rural industrialization potential are generally able to makers can steer the design of tariffs in the desired sell electricity at lower prices thanks to economies direction. of scale. This effect can also be achieved if mini-grid operators are enabled to operate large mini-grid In contrast, tariff regulation cannot be considered clusters under a single management unit, so that and used as a policy instrument. Rather, the tariffs can be reduced to affordable levels. In addition, tariff calculation methodology applied should be legislative, regulatory and contractual arrangements understood as a scale that balances the costs and have a significant influence on tariffs, and a number revenues in mini-grid power supply. In cost-reflective of targeted measures could contribute to a reduction tariff methodologies, the tariff broadly equals the in tariffs in this context ( refer to Chapter 2.1.5 ). mini-grid’s OPEX plus depreciation and allowable return of the assets minus any applied subsidies From the point of view of policymakers, the following ( see Figure 4: Tariff methodologies are a regulatory aspects are therefore crucial levers for the design of instrument that balances the costs and revenues electricity tariffs in mini-grid projects: of mini-grids. Source: INENSUS ). Once calibrated, the scale should not be changed ( e.g. by lowering 1. The provision of subsidies ( the amount of the tariffs without additional financial support to cover initial CAPEX and, if required, the OPEX of mini-grid the costs ), as this may lead to company losses that operators that is covered by government subsidies ). trigger a reduction in service or the bankruptcy of the companies and then the loss of consumer power. FIGURE 4. TARIFF METHODOLOGIES ARE A REGULATORY INSTRUMENT THAT BALANCES THE COSTS AND REVENUES OF MINI-GRIDS. Source: INENSUS OPEX + depreciation + allowed return Tariff × kWh delivered - subsidies 18
Most rural households in previously unserved com- their products on regional or national markets. At munities have a very constrained household income, the same time, customers appreciate the often high which is usually insufficient for covering their basic security of supply and high service quality in mini- electricity demand on a continuous basis. The avail- grids. A tariff reduction, potentially a politically-moti- able budget therefore determines the amount of vated one, should not be enforced at the expense energy consumed by the households, rather than of lower supply security and lower service quality. the reverse. As a result, when tariffs are increased, Doing so could lead to an unsaturated basic demand the revenue of mini-grid operators from this type of and the dissatisfaction not only of low-income cus- domestic electricity consumption remains almost tomers but of all customers within a community, on constant up to a saturation point, while the amount the one hand, and to income losses and thus reduced of electricity consumed changes. Further research 5 profitability of the operators, on the other. is required to determine the satura- tion points of basic electricity demand, which are likely to vary from region to region depending on climate and envi- When planning a large-scale deployment of mini-grids, ronmental conditions ( e.g. demand for political decision-makers ought to decide on the scale of fan or no fan at night, demand for out- this deployment and the location and quality of the sites door safety lights or no lights at night, reserved for it. A larger scale ( a large number of mini- etc. ). grids in large communities ) with high rural industrializa- tion potential leads to lower tariffs at constant subsidy In contrast, for productive and rural levels, thanks to the good economic viability of the busi- industrial users, these budget con- ness models applied. On the other hand, governments straints either do not exist or do so to a run the risk of major political distortions if a large-scale much lesser extent. They generally con- deployment at very prominent locations fails to deliver sume as much electricity as is needed to the desired results. produce their goods or services as long as the electricity provided is cheaper, Political decision-makers are often also opinion leaders more reliable and more convenient than in the tariff debate. Although, from a political point of alternative power sources such as die- view, national uniform tariffs in mini-grids can sometimes sel motors. appear to be the easiest option, as they aim to create supposedly fair conditions for all citizens, very few deliv- Finally, from the perspective of policy- ery models actually meet this requirement. All delivery makers, the above can be summarized models involve high financial obligations on the part as follows: the reduction in domes- of the governments. Indeed, a governmental mini-grid tic retail tariffs primarily increases the deployment approach with tariffs well above the national demand for electricity, which in turn uniform level, that covers the basic electricity demand of requires greater power generation and households based on their available household budgets distribution capacities and, therefore, and, at the same time, rapidly advances rural industrial- higher amounts of CAPEX subsidies. ization, may well be acceptable to rural populations. Experience shows that high electricity Policymakers are advised not to influence the sensitive tariffs lead to dissatisfaction on the cus- structure of a regulatory tariff methodology in such a tomer side, especially when household way that they force lower tariffs on one side of the scale customers are unable to cover their without keeping the balance by compensating for higher basic needs and when rural industrial costs with additional subsidies on the other. customers are unable to compete with 5 Test results supporting this conclusion can be found in Crossboundary, 2019. Policy develoment 19
2.1.4 | PUBLIC FUNDING PROGRAMMES FOR THE DEPLOYMENT OF MINI-GRIDS BASED ON PRIVATE OPERATOR MODELS In most cases, public grants or subsidies are As an alternative to cash subsidies, governments needed to put mini-grid projects on an economically sometimes grant free access to assets, especially sustainable footing. Public assistance may take the to government-owned distribution networks. form of both direct fiscal support measures and This can be done by the government making the complementary indirect incentives. assets available to a private mini-grid operator through free usage rights or a low cost lease. Direct fiscal support to mini-grids can be provided by a combination of the following mechanisms: Governments can provide regular subsidies to the operating costs of a mini-grid if the set 1. Governments can make cash contributions to tariff is too low to generate revenues that cover subsidize some or all of the initial investment. the operator’s costs ( OPEX plus profits ). These The CAPEX grant can take various forms, including measures are usually applied after all options of results-based financing ( RBF ) and performance- CAPEX subsidies have been fully exploited, as based grants ( PBG ). RBF or PBG can be paid out to CAPEX subsidies can usually be disbursed at a mini-grid firms on the basis of verified customer lower transaction cost than OPEX subsidies. To connections. This requires the project developers provide OPEX subsidies, governments need to to pre-finance all of the capital, including the create an independent rural electrification fund grant, which often presents a cash flow challenge that is sustainably financed at minimum for the to smaller mini-grid companies, in particular duration of a mini-grid project cycle ( 20 to 25 domestic ones. With other types of grants, a years ) and has sufficient capacity to perform the certain portion of the cash flow is provided in clearing process. Additionally, a development advance against a bank guarantee and/or upon bank can provide a payment guarantee to gain the achievement of small milestones, which reduces confidence of private investors in the long-term the need for pre-financing, but increases the payment of OPEX subsidies. In African countries, administrative burden and also, potentially, the there is however limited experience with OPEX implementation time. subsidies in the mini-grid sector to date. 2. The amount of grant to be paid can either be a 3. Another way of supporting mini-grids financially percentage of the total eligible costs, which is with a one-off commitment are partial risk guar- usually equal to the initial CAPEX plus project antees, under which central banks, for instance, development costs, or a certain amount per provide a first loss coverage guarantee to connection ( as in RBF/PBG programmes, for commercial banks financing mini-grids. This instance ). It can also be subject to a bidding reduces collateral requirements and interest rates. process, as in the minimum subsidy tender ( MST ). Under the latter, the bidder with the 4. Governments can stimulate market development lowest grant requirement for the electrification by helping to increase the demand for electricity of a certain number of customers in a specific by promoting appliances for productive use mini-grid with a specific tariff and certain or facilities needed for rural industrialization technical and service quality requirements processes. Fostering productive use of electricity receives the subsidy and the exclusive right improves economies of scale and thus the to electrify the sites. The MST process could economic viability of mini-grids. Supporting also be structured as a reverse auction. 6 rural industrialization activities in addition to the above-mentioned measures gives the mini-grid 6 For further details on this process, please refer to section 3.1.1. 20
companies access to a second source of revenue tax holidays for profit taxes, etc. For areas in which and can thus increase the profitability of the mini- rural industrialisation is to be encouraged, an grid business. accelerated depreciation of mini-grid assets may be introduced to motivate already profitable domestic 5. For instances in which the developer is struggling players active in the agro-industry to implement to meet a community’s particularly high demand mini-grids and processing infrastructure in the rural for electricity, the government may consider the communities located in their respective supply or distribution of energy-efficient appliances ( e.g. catchment areas. The initial tax burden of these light bulbs ) or other measures promoting energy players would thus be reduced, stimulating rural efficiency, to avoid shortages of electricity supply. industrialization, creating jobs and power supply infrastructure. However, without a strong and In addition to direct financial contributions, there profitable core business of a domestic company, are several indirect ways to provide government accelerated depreciation of mini-grid assets is support to mini-grid projects. likely not to yield any effects, considering that an investment in mini-grid projects as such does not Firstly, funding can be awarded to an entity that usually generate any profits within the first years of provides technical assistance to mini-grid developers. operation. The same applies to tax holidays for mini- Private mini-grid firms report that technical assistance grid profits within the first years of operation. Both provides effective support, especially where it aims instruments can, however, be good incentives to to simplify administrative processes between the promote rural industrialization approaches based on governments and the private sector, rather than in mini-grids, which may deliver early returns. actual site or electricity demand surveys, or similar. Figure 5 illustrates the different types of fiscal Secondly, governments can grant exemptions from support that governments can provide to PPP mini- taxes and duties, including import taxes and duties, grid delivery models. FIGURE 5. THE MAIN TYPES OF GOVERNMENT SUPPORT MECHANISMS FOR MINI-GRID DEPLOYMENT. Source: INENSUS Upfront CAPEX OPEX subsidies Direct fiscal support Partial risk guarantees Subsidies Funding for productive for mini-grids use appliance Technical assistance for permitting procedures Indirect fiscal support Tax exemptions Policy develoment 21
2.1.5 | SUSTAINABILITY OF MINI-GRIDS – MITIGATING RISK THROUGH POLICY DESIGN The returns must outweigh the risks if private cannot be saturated until the developer has invested or public operators are to operate mini-grids in additional generation assets, which reduces sustainably. With regard to the degree of government satisfaction among customers, as well as their influence and the level of risk for mini-grid operators, willingness to pay. In cases where demand is too low, two risks, in particular, stand out, namely demand break-even may never be achieved. Figure 7 depicts risk and termination risk. the areas in which a mini-grid can be profitable. Demands that are beyond these boundaries might Demand risk: Demand for electricity in mini-grids make the mini-grid project financially unviable, typically increases over time due to three factors: possibly leading to a sudden stop in power supply 1 ) new customer connections, usually within the to the rural community with potentially devastating first two years of operation, 2 ) a growing number effects on the local economy. Demand side of appliances and machines per customer up to a management strategies such as load shifting and saturation point, usually within the first three years of valley filling exist, which the developer can exploit to operation and 3 ) improved local economic conditions, a certain degree to address customer demand. 8 resulting in rising income levels and increasing budgets for FIGURE 6: Electricity demand development following root function electricity expenditure. As a result shaped curves. Which trajectory the development takes can only be of these three factors, electricity projected with high certainty after 3 years. demand typically increases in the form of a root function curve 7. ?????? The generation and distribution systems in a mini-grid are optimized to meet a certain estimated electricity demand at Trajectory of curve minimum cost. If the demand development can be Trajectory 1 projected more easily deviates from this estimate, after year 3 either the costs increase or the Trajectory 1 operation becomes technically unfeasible. Until now, no survey methodology has been able to Trajectory 1 project accurately the electricity demand with all its social and socio-economic influencing factors over several years. The 1 2 3 4 5 6 demand risk is the risk that Year after commissioning of mini-grid demand for electricity in a mini- grid does not correspond to the forecast level. Levels of electricity New appliances and machines demand that are both too high and too low can be dangerous for the financial sustainability of a mini- New connections grid. If demand is significantly higher than projected, demand Local economic developmnet > increased income and budget 7 This curve, which takes the form of a root function, contradicts most financial models and policies, which, until a few years ago, errone- ously assumed unlimited exponential growth based on a constant percentage increase in demand. 8 For further reading on demand side management activities, please refer to Green Mini-Grid Help Desk ( 2019 ): Demand Side Management for Mini-Grids. 22
You can also read