CIO Special - Financial repression: still restraining real rates Policy sustainability and the investment response

Page created by Jim Cunningham
 
CONTINUE READING
CIO Special - Financial repression: still restraining real rates Policy sustainability and the investment response
April 2021

CIO Special

Financial repression:
still restraining real rates
Policy sustainability and the investment response
CIO Special - Financial repression: still restraining real rates Policy sustainability and the investment response
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

Contents
           Authors:
                                   01              Introduction                                                                                                           p.2
      Christian Nolting
   Global Chief Investment

                                   02
            Officer

         Gerit Heinz                               Financial repression: a history                                                                                        p.4
   Global Chief Investment
          Strategist

        Stefan Köhling
     Investment Strategist
            Europe
                                   03              Policy sustainability and risks                                                                                      p.10

      Gabriel Selby, CFA®
     Investment Strategist
           Americas                04              Possible future scenarios                                                                                            p.13

                                   05              What this means for investors                                                                                        p.15

Please use the QR code to access
a selection of other Deutsche
Bank CIO Office reports.

                                   Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                                   risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                           1
CIO Special - Financial repression: still restraining real rates Policy sustainability and the investment response
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

01                             Introduction

      Christian Nolting        GDP growth will return to positive territory in 2021. Reflationary policies in response to the
   Global Chief Investment     devastating economic impact of the coronavirus have already led markets to anticipate some pick
           Officer             up inflation and, in many economies, yields have risen.

                               No-one, however, expects a quick return of interest rates to their levels of a few decades ago.
                               In a historical context interest rates are still at extremely low levels and major central banks
                               have indicated that they will be tolerant with regards to inflation and keep rates low. “Financial
                               repression” – the use of policy to keep real interest rates very low or negative – is here to stay.

                               In some ways, it is surprising that “financial repression” is not more controversial. Low interest
                               rates lower the cost of borrowing but, conversely, may also make it more difficult to reach
                               investment goals. They affect debt levels and asset prices. This is an issue of great importance to
                               all investors.

                               The main reason for general acceptance of “financial repression” is that we have probably just
                               grown too used to it.

                               “Financial repression” long predates the 2020 pandemic: like some other policy issues,
                               coronavirus has simply accelerated an existing underlying trend. It first came to prominence
                               earlier at the start of the global financial crisis (GFC) in 2007-2008, when many central banks
                               deployed financial repression (in the form of lower policy rates and quantitative easing) as an
                               essentially tactical tool to try and kick start economies. Yields on government bonds been falling
                               for a decade or more, when adjusted for inflation, as shown by Figure 1. They have also been
                               falling in nominal terms.

                               Figure 1: 10-year inflation-indexed government bond yield comparison

                               Source: Bloomberg Finance L.P., Deutsche Bank AG. As of April 9, 2021.

                                %
                                2

                                1

                                0

                                -1

                                -2

                                       2010                 2012                   2014                   2016                   2018                   2020

                                     U.S.      Germany

                               But financial repression has even deeper structural roots. It is linked, as we discuss, to longer-term
                               trends in demographics and productivity which will remain relevant, even as the global economy
                               picks up pace in 2021.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                           2
CIO Special - Financial repression: still restraining real rates Policy sustainability and the investment response
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

                               The tendency for government debt levels to rise has been accelerated by the COVID-19 crisis
                               while inflation rates have remained subdued. While the former creates a conflict of interest for
                               central banks, the latter gives leeway to keep interest rates low. Monetary and fiscal policy are
                               more interlinked than in the past, given the huge amounts of government debt now sitting on
                               central bank balance sheets.

                               But is financial repression sustainable, or should we expect some (perhaps involuntary) reversal
                               of policy? One major concern around financial repression is that it could result in high levels of
                               inflation. Such fears have not so far been realised and some central banks would in fact welcome a
                               temporary increase in inflation (with several recently changing their objectives to reflect this). In a
                               historic context, nominal yields as well as inflation rates remain obstinately low.

                               But other issues will arise. While financial repression may help to ensure economic stability in
                               as much as it constrains the cost of government debt servicing, it does not guarantee financial
                               market stability. Low yields may encourage unexperienced investors to take on more risk than
                               suitable or encourage highly leveraged positions. Small market moves may result in higher
                               volatility if leveraged positions need liquidation. This threat of instability is in addition to creeping
                               devaluation of wealth caused by negative real interest rates. We look at how to deal with this.

                                  Financial repression: history and incentives

                                  o Financial repression long predates the 2020 pandemic. The
                                    coronavirus has simply accelerated an underlying trend.

                                  o Central banks are likely to keep real interest rates low, and
                                    financial repression will continue for the foreseeable future.

                                  o But investors should be aware that a policy designed to promote
                                    economic stability will not guarantee financial market stability.

                                                                                    Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are
                                                                                    not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be
                                                                                    at risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the
                                                                                    end of this document. Produced in April 2021.
                                                                                                                                                       3
CIO Special - Financial repression: still restraining real rates Policy sustainability and the investment response
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

02                             Financial repression: a history

                               Financial repression is a policy of keeping interest rates at very low or negative real levels.

                               Historically, this has not been seen as a positive concept: the originators of the phrase (back in
                               the early 1970s) were criticising the use of such a policy as a way of obtaining cheap funding for
                               government debt at the expense of savers.

                               Financial repression, as this implies, is not just due to the coronavirus pandemic. And, while
                               the current market focus may now be on inflation threats and rising yields, financial repression
                               remains in place and will continue to dominate monetary policy for some time to come.

                               In fact, even nominal interest rates have been falling for decades. Risk-free rates (i.e. U.S. T-Bills)
                               fell from more than 10% in 1984 to below 0.1% this year. In some other parts of the world,
                               nominal interest rates on longer-dated government bonds turned negative years ago, reflecting
                               expectations that short-term interest rates would not increase for the foreseeable future.

                               The declining natural rate of interest

                               Various structural forces are pushing down the so-called natural rate of interest (R*) – the rate
                               which brings an economy’s output in line with its potential. This natural rate (sometimes referred
                               to as the neutral rate) is not observable in reality but policy makers around the world estimate its
                               value when they set policy rates – so as to judge whether these rates will stimulate the economy
                               or rein in output to combat inflationary pressures.

                               R* is affected by numerous factors and estimates of it differ from region to region. In the United
                               States, estimates using the Laubach Williams model indicate that R* has fallen to close to zero
                               over the last decade (Figure 2). Equivalent figures for the Eurozone reveal a similar story.

                               R* is highly positively correlated to trend GDP growth. Broad shifts in trend growth rates in
                               developed countries over the past few decades may therefore indicate where interest rates are
                               likely to go from here. Many explanations for slower trend growth focus on changing working-age
                               populations, ageing societies and technological progress.

                               Figure 2: The natural rate of interest (R*) and nominal potential GDP growth in the U.S.

                               Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Deutsche Bank AG. As of
                               April 9, 2021.

                               %
                               16                                                                                                                                       7

                               14
                                                                                                                                                                        6

                               12
                                                                                                                                                                        5

                               10
                                                                                                                                                                        4

                                8

                                                                                                                                                                        3
                                6

                                                                                                                                                                        2
                                4

                                                                                                                                                                        1
                                2

                                0                                                                                                                                       0
                                     1961                1971                1981                1991                 2001                2011                2021

                                    Nominal Potential GDP Growth Rate (LHS)                       Natural Rate of Interest (RHS)

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                           4
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

                               The fall in R* has some immediate policy implications: a low R* has meant that central banks have
                               less room to simply cut policy rates as they approach the so-called "lower bound" in many regions.
                               (The worry is that if interest rates fall below this theoretical threshold, investors will prefer to hold
                               physical cash.) Even if we have not yet reached this level in interest rates, central banks have
                               enhanced their policy toolbox. In a low yield environment, they have introduced unconventional
                               measures such as quantitative easing or yield curve control to achieve a greater monetary
                               stimulus effect than with traditional monetary policy instruments. In the p­ast, policy rates stood
                               very much higher and therefore a sufficient monetary impulse could be provided by lowering
                               these rates alone. A return to such a situation looks very unlikely for a long time to come.

                               Central banks use R* in their assessment of the economic situation and then try to adjust the risk
                               free rate (proxied by government bond yields) to set the right impulse dependent on the economic
                               cycle. They can partially influence this risk-free rate implicitly via open market operations (e.g. QE)
                               and explicitly via setting policy rates. R* provides a starting point for such policy calculations.

                               What this shows is that a seemingly abstract discussion of R* is in fact a contributor to the level
                               of yields we see in fixed income securities every day. By intervening in the market (e.g. through
                               bond buying programmes or setting policy rates) security prices are either directly or indirectly
                               mirroring central bank policy. Rising longer-dated government bond yields could for example be a
                               sign of an anticipated rate hike (by markets) in the near future while a drastic fall would imply the
                               opposite.

                               Demographics: the example of Japan

                               Japan is often cited as a real-time example of how long-term shrinkage of the working-age
                               population can translate into a long phase of economic stagnation (which is also closely
                               correlated, as noted above, to lower interest rates). Rising life expectancy and decreasing fertility
                               rates without corresponding compensating migration movements have had a remarkable impact
                               on Japan’s total working-age population (Figure 3). However, Japanese people tend to work even
                               beyond the official retirement age of 65.

                               Figure 3: Working-age population (15-64) indexed so that January 1, 2004 = 100

                               Source: OECD, Deutsche Bank AG. As of April 9, 2021.

                                 120

                                 115

                                 110

                                 105

                                 100

                                  95

                                  90

                                  85

                                        2004         2006          2008         2010          2012          2014          2016          2018          2020          2022

                                       Japan            Germany                 U.S.           Italy

                               Technological progress can only partly compensate for this, particularly if an economy is capital
                               intensive already. The sustained increase in Japan’s median age from 35 in 1985 to over 48 today
                               has therefore pushed down the economy’s growth path. Gross value added for the whole country
                               in general has barely increased while its debt burden relative to GDP has risen significantly.

                               Most of the developed countries in the Eurozone are experiencing similar demographic trends,
                               with the fertility rates of generations born after 1965 significantly lower than the preceding “baby
                               boomers”. Migration may mitigate the effects of an ageing society in Europe, however.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                           5
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

                               Even China – as a consequence of the one-child-policy introduced in 1980 – will face a phase of
                               declining population in the coming decades. One study (by the Institute for Health Metrics and
                               Evaluation, IHME) predicts that the population in China will almost halve from more than 1.4 bn
                               today to 730 million by 2100. (Other studies show a less severe decline.) Since 2016 couples have
                               been permitted to have two children, but with a fertility rate of 1.7 the population is still likely to
                               shrink, as it is the case in many industrialized and emerging countries.

                               Median population ages vary greatly according to United Nations data, with the U.S. (38.3) and
                               China (38.4) slightly above the G20 median of 34.4, but Germany (45.7), Italy (47.3) Japan (48.4)
                               much higher. The latter two also have the highest debt to GDP ratios among developed countries.
                               With fertility rates in long-term decline, global median ages are likely to rise further, and without
                               counter-measures (for example around labour market participation) “Japanification” will spread to
                               other economies. However, trends in working-age populations do vary between countries (Figure
                               3), with the U.S. managing to increase its working-age population (not least due to immigration)
                               while the Eurozone’s has remained static and Japan’s has declined.

                               This will have important implications for policy and thus interest rates. Japanese business cycles
                               have become shorter and relative debt levels have risen further, as policymakers have not been
                               able to achieve either growth or inflation to extract the country from its current predicament. The
                               Japanese economy has also proved more vulnerable to external shocks. However, Japan has also
                               had some idiosyncratic events such as the Kobe earthquake or the Fukushima tsunami with their
                               respective impacts on business cycles. Mounting debt levels may limit the ability to counterbal-
                               ance economic downturns in particular if growth is anaemic for a while due to an ageing society.

                               Ageing populations also have a major impact on savings behaviour and thus interest rates in
                               equilibrium. Ageing populations tend to have higher savings rates during the active working life
                               because they have to save to provide for a longer retirement period than in previous years. There
                               is an argument that increased savings by “baby boomers” in recent decades have increased
                               aggregate savings to an extent that cannot be absorbed by higher investing activity – the so-
                               called “savings glut”. This has pushed down equilibrium rates. A quick end to this imbalance
                               between savings and investment is not expected – although, in the longer run, a growing elderly
                               population could push up spending on goods and (labour-intensive) care services from a shrinking
                               workforce, closing the gap at least partially and possibly finally leading to higher inflation.

                               But to boost economic activity, growth in the manufacturing sector is also required. Apart from
                               the labour force, higher investment is one way to encourage higher growth. However, many
                               other trends would support the argument that investment activity will remain rather weak in the
                               future. Decreasing labour force growth also means that lower growth in companies’ capital stock
                               is needed to preserve a given capital-employment ratio. Demographic changes over the last few
                               decades have also happened against a background of gradually declining public investments in
                               many developed economies (at least pre-pandemic) partly because of higher debt burden.

                               Figure 4: Long-term contributors to financial repression

                               Source: Deutsche Bank AG. As of April 9, 2021. R* is the natural rate of interest.

                                                                                   Savings to
                                                                             investments imbalance

                                     Ageing
                                   populations

                                                                                                        Structural trends        Low existing      Further stimulus needs
                                                                                                       reinforce financial      interest rates     unconventional policy
                                                                                                           repression

                                                                                     Low R*

                                                       Lower trend
                                                       GDP growth
                                                                                                                                                         Quantitative
                                                                                                                                                           easing

                                Low productivity                                                                                                         Yield curve
                                    growth                                                                                                               control, etc.

                                                                               Changing economic
                                                                                   structures

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                           6
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

                               Technology and productivity

                               The other main contributor to long term growth apart from labour is technological change
                               (particularly if the labour force working-age population is shrinking as noted above). This is by
                               its nature difficult to measure, but it is possible to identify some general trends. Economic theory
                               defines productivity gains as the growth residual which cannot be explained by labour and capital
                               (so-called total factor productivity).

                               So in that sense, technological progress in general help us increase productivity and hence
                               growth and therefore should be one factor pushing up the neutral interest rate (R*). So why is this
                               not happening?

                               Shifts in the structure of western economies are an important factor behind productivity
                               trends in recent decades. The contribution of the often more innovative and capital-intensive
                               manufacturing sectors to total GDP has been shrinking. Use of capital in the form of technological
                               progress has led to productivity gains be it via hardware (e.g. robotics) or software (e.g.
                               processes). The services sector contribution has risen. While productivity gains via technology are
                               possible (e.g. via software), many traditional services tend to be more labour-intensive and thus
                               productivity gains may be more difficult to achieve.

                               Weaker productivity growth may also be linked to the higher market concentration of companies
                               in some sectors – the emergence of “winner takes it all” firms. Economies of scale from this
                               process may allow for cost savings, but also result in declining competition (as they lead to
                               oligopolistic structures) and rising market entry barriers for new firms, perhaps discouraging
                               innovative approaches.

                               Finally, the low interest rate environment has allowed some non-profitable companies to survive
                               because of very low financing costs. This may have hindered the process of “creative destruction”
                               and thus necessary structural changes in the economy – holding back technological progress.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                           7
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

                               Other factors pushing down interest rates

                               Other possible explanations for the long-term fall in interest rates include a decreasing demand
                               for capital caused by ongoing digitization, e.g. through a shift from investments in capital
                               intensive goods towards more intangible goods (i.e. software). Other commentators – for example
                               the former U.S. Treasury Secretary Larry Summers – have seen the developed economies as
                               being in a “secular stagnation” phase. They point to a decline in investment opportunities caused
                               by slowing population growth and a decrease in the rate of technology progress. This leads as a
                               consequence to a situation with excess supply of savings and lowered aggregate demand.

                               Wealth and income distribution may also have contributed to lower rates. Growing inequality is
                               often associated with a lower average propensity to consume as upper income households tend
                               to save a higher portion of their disposable income, which also contributes to excess savings and
                               by this lowering equilibrium rates.

                               Policy responses

                               In the past, central banks have tried to set the appropriate policy rate by assessing inflationary
                               pressure in conjunction with the natural rate of interest, the economic slack measured by the
                               output gap in an economy and the inflation rate. During normal business cycles, government bond
                               yields fall in the downturn phase, and then rise during the economic recovery phase, anticipating
                               changes in future monetary policy.

                               Figure 5: Central banks' total assets

                               Source: Bloomberg Finance L.P., Deutsche Bank AG. As of April 9, 2021.

                               USD bn
                               8000

                               7000

                               6000

                               5000

                               4000

                               3000

                               2000

                               1000

                                  0
                                        2000       2002        2004         2006        2008        2010        2012        2014        2016        2018        2020

                                  ECB (in EUR)              Fed (in USD)

                               However, the previous correlation between growth rates and interest rates broke down after the
                               start of the global financial crisis (GFC). Government bond yields (taken as proxies for risk-free
                               rates) then fell well below the nominal growth rates of western economies. There were several
                               reasons for this.

                               In the aftermath of the initial phases of the GFC, private actors started to deleverage, keen to
                               reduce the high levels of debt that had contributed to the GFC, but adding further to already
                               extensive economic slack and deflationary pressures. This has helped keep the natural rate of
                               interest low in the last decade. And just as this economic and labour market slack was being taken
                               in, the 2020-2021 coronavirus pandemic then dashed hopes of an imminent return to economic
                               stability.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                           8
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

                               Loose monetary policy, once seen as a temporary measure post-GFC, had become normal before
                               the coronavirus pandemic, despite economic recovery in many parts of the world. Markets and
                               companies quickly got used to the continuous liquidity injections. Low rates have resulted in a
                               classic “liquidity trap” whereby individuals/firms have little incentive to lend money for productive
                               use, preferring instead to keep it as cash balances or invest in financial assets. So while base
                               money (i.e. cash and central bank deposits) has grown, broader measures of money supply which
                               are relevant for the transmission channel from monetary growth to inflation have increased only
                               slowly. The velocity of circulation of money has also decreased. To slightly over-simplify, the new
                               money has been hoarded. Central banks have struggled to normalize their monetary policy in this
                               rather undynamic environment, meaning that interest rates have remained lower for longer than in
                               most other previous business cycles.

                               2021 and probably the following years too will be characterized by continuous loose monetary
                               policy perhaps with further central bank asset purchases (Figure 5) and policy rates at their
                               present or lower levels – a wording the ECB has been using in its policy statements since some
                               time. Implementing lower or negative nominal interest rates may become easier for central banks
                               if central bank digital currencies are introduced. Further information on this can be found in our
                               CIO Special: Central Bank Digital Currencies – Money reinvented.

                                   Low R*: drivers and implications

                                   o Various structural factors are pushing down R*, the natural rate of
                                     interest, which is highly positively correlated to trend GDP growth.

                                   o Demographics, technology and wealth and income distribution are
                                     among factors which may have contributed to a lower R*.

                                   o A low R* encourages non-conventional monetary policy easing
                                     and markets have become accustomed to liquidity injections: they
                                     are no longer simply a tactical measure.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                           9
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

03                             Policy sustainability and risks

                               Debt growth

                               Fiscal policy has also played an important policy role. Economic restrictions due to COVID-19 led
                               to unprecedented levels of fiscal expenditure. State guarantees, direct money transfers to citizens
                               and furlough schemes have far exceeded in scope the fiscal measures launched in the wake of the
                               global financial crisis (GFC). Extensive governmental support will not end by this year and will go
                               beyond 2021, as shown by the European Recovery Fund and the additional fiscal package under
                               the new Biden administration in the U.S.

                               As a result, debt has increased sharply, to levels which (pre-pandemic) would not have been
                               classified as sustainable under traditional valuation methods (for example, the Maastricht criteria
                               for Eurozone countries subsequently embedded in the stability and growth pact). Elevated
                               spending does not seem likely to be followed by a period of austerity, given the continuing
                               ravages from coronavirus.

                               As a result, the “post-pandemic-age” will be characterized by many countries living with their
                               highest debt levels in post war history. Debt levels in many industrialized countries have already
                               surpassed 100% of GDP.

                               Of course, many economies have temporarily experienced high debt levels before. The question is
                               how sustainable they are, and how they can be reduced.

                               One traditional resolution of the debt problem has been to grow your way out of debt – increasing
                               growth so that the debt/GDP ratio falls. But, as we discuss elsewhere, potential nominal growth
                               for developed economies has been falling for decades, due to demographic and other factors.
                               Attempts to get around this through other ways (e.g. structural reforms) are difficult and take time.
                               Moreover, the extra spending funded by recent debt seems unlikely to give a classical Keynesian
                               uplift: most of it is replacing income rather than creating extra demand. Falls in demand for many
                               services during lockdowns also cannot be made up for by higher post-lockdown supply. Full or
                               partial debt defaults are not an option for countries wanting to preserve easy access to capital
                               markets.

                               The IMF assumes that among the largest western economies, only Germany will succeed in
                               reducing debt significantly. The others (e.g. the U.S., France, Spain or Italy) will continue to have
                               debt levels well above their annual GDP in 2026.

                               Figure 6: Debt to GDP rates and IMF medium-term forecasts

                               Source: IMF, Deutsche Bank AG. As of April 9, 2021.

                                  (%)
                                  300

                                  250

                                  200

                                  150

                                  100

                                   50

                                     0
                                             2001

                                                    2002

                                                           2003

                                                                  2004

                                                                         2005

                                                                                2006

                                                                                       2007

                                                                                              2008

                                                                                                     2009

                                                                                                            2010

                                                                                                                   2011

                                                                                                                          2012

                                                                                                                                 2013

                                                                                                                                        2014

                                                                                                                                               2015

                                                                                                                                                      2016

                                                                                                                                                             2017

                                                                                                                                                                    2018

                                                                                                                                                                           2019

                                                                                                                                                                                  2020

                                                                                                                                                                                         2021

                                                                                                                                                                                                2022

                                                                                                                                                                                                       2023

                                                                                                                                                                                                              2024

                                                                                                                                                                                                                     2025

                                     Italy                  UK                     France                     Japan                      U.S.                  Germany                          Spain

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                         10
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

                               In the past, inflation (as one component of nominal GDP growth) has offered another way of
                               reducing debt. At some point, inflation will pick up, particularly in some sectors (e.g. services)
                               and de-globalisation may play a role in pushing up prices of some goods. Temporary increases
                               in inflation are also possible due to the pro-cyclical nature of some fiscal measures (i.e. boosting
                               spending during an ongoing expansion). But dramatic sustained rises in inflation seem unlikely,
                               given the slack in the labour market, meaning that countries will not find it easy to inflate away
                               debt.

                               This puts the debt management focus firmly on financial repression – holding down interest rates.
                               This can contain debt service (particularly if maturing existing debt can be refinanced at lower
                               interest rates) but will take a long time to reduce debt.

                               Figure 7 shows that, even with growth rates being 3% above interest rates – which would imply
                               quite heavy financial repression – debt levels would fall by less than 30% over a decade.

                               Figure 7: Government debt reduction scenarios (as % of GDP) with balanced budgets

                               Source: Deutsche Bank AG. As of April 9, 2021. Note: The x-axis represents years from when budget is first
                               balanced. In the scenarios, “r-g” is the rate of interest minus the rate of economic growth.

                               % of GDP
                                 110

                                 100

                                  90

                                  80

                                  70

                                  60

                                  50

                                          0          1            2           3            4           5            6            7           8            9          10

                                       r-g=-3            r-g=-2             r-g=-1             r=g

                               Debt and budget deficit sustainability

                               One academic approach (Modern Monetary Theory) argues that debt levels are not a problem
                               and some pragmatic government and central bankers (note former Fed chair and current treasury
                               secretary Janet Yellen recently in the U.S.) have indicated that reducing debt levels is not an
                               immediate priority. Low debt service costs in the current low interest rate environment are one
                               important factor reducing pressure to wind down debt.

                               But there are two reasons why budget deficits are not likely to become eternal.

                               First, interest sensitivity can become extremely high. As noted, low debt service costs are a great
                               help to indebted countries at present. But in the future markets will start to differentiate more
                               between countries – especially in times of crisis. Low policy rates do not by themselves imply
                               low risk premiums. When things worsen, countries could come quickly under pressure. As the
                               Eurozone crisis of 2009-2012 demonstrated, risk premiums can rise very fast when confidence in
                               one country’s credibility is challenged.

                               Secondly, we should not underestimate potential inflationary pressures from higher fiscal
                               spending. Economic slack (from higher unemployment levels, subdued consumer confidence and
                               the output gap) is likely to keep price pressures for the months ahead low. But when inflationary
                               pressures start, they can then grow quickly (e.g. when full employment has been achieved). This
                               is most likely an issue for the long term, not the short term. Inflationary pressures may also unfold
                               when the velocity of circulation of money increases.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                         11
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

                               For now, the situation appears manageable. In fact, as maturing debt is replaced by lower-yielding
                               bonds, debt service costs as a percentage of outstanding debt in general will decrease. For some
                               countries, like Germany, where the majority of bonds outstanding have a negative yield, it could
                               even turn positive over time. So – paradoxically – by issuing debt, the state is actually earning
                               money.

                               In the absence of financial stress, even large budget deficits and high debt to GDP ratios can be
                               sustained over a long time period. As long as financial actors believe that outstanding debt will
                               be repaid (and in the absence of other investment with better perceived risk-return profiles) even
                               negative yielding bonds will be bought.

                               However, other factors need to be considered.

                               First, while we do not think that governments will want to risk suppressing the business cycle in its
                               early stages, in the medium term the probability of increased taxes is high – and is already being
                               discussed in many countries. This may in part be driven by legislation: in Germany for example
                               the government is forced by law (the so-called “debt break”) to reduce the additional debt taken
                               2020 and 2021 and to bring it back to levels below 60% to GDP. EU countries with the Euro as
                               their official currency are obliged by EU agreements to have a strategy to reduce their debt to
                               levels seen as sustainable. Higher taxes are a means to increase government revenues and thus
                               ultimately reduce debt and debt payments. Very recently U.S. President Biden has launched an
                               initiative for higher corporate taxes.

                               Second, faith in further liquidity injections could fade. As we had already seen before the
                               coronavirus pandemic, stimulus amounts had been forced to become more generous due to the
                               reduced marginal utility of each unit of stimulus. There is a fear that monetary policy may stop
                               being an effective tool.

                                   Financial repression, fiscal policy and debt

                                   o Fiscal policy has played a major role supporting economies over
                                     the pandemic, resulting in a substantial increase in debt levels.

                                   o "Traditional" options of growing your way out of debt, or relying
                                     on inflation to ease the debt burden, do not look viable this time
                                     around.

                                   o Heavy financial repression is therefore needed to manage the
                                     debt burden – and multiple factors suggest we cannot assume
                                     high fiscal deficits are sustainable for ever.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                         12
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

04                             Possible future scenarios

                               As we touch on above (and explain in detail in our report Peak Debt: Sustainability and investment
                               implications), there are in principle six ways of escaping the debt trap: 1) pro-growth policies (e.g.
                               structural reforms); 2) growth because of productivity gains (not driven by governments);
                               3) expenditure cuts; 4) revenue-boosting measures (e.g. tax hikes); 5) inflation and 6) debt “hair-
                               cuts”/defaults (e.g. a “bail in” of debt holders).

                               Of course, in reality some of these can operate in tandem – for example, a combination of
                               expenditure cuts and tax hikes could be seen as an austerity strategy. However, “hair-cuts” and
                               defaults are worth avoiding as access to capital markets will be negatively affected.

                               With regards to the current financial repression environment, four possible scenarios are worth
                               focusing on – and they are likely to overlap too:

                               Figure 8: Future scenarios

                               Source: Deutsche Bank AG. As of April 9, 2021.

                                           Scenario A                      Scenario B                      Scenario C                       Scenario D
                                       “Policy maintained”             “Structural reforms”                   “Inflation”                   “Stagflation”

                                                                                                             Demand-driven                    Inflation with
                                             No policy shift               Structural reforms
                                                                                                                reforms                        slow growth

                                                                                                          Policymakers manage
                                           Low GDP growth,                Difficult transition to
                                                                                                              growth/rates/                Higher interest rates
                                             low inflation                    higher growth
                                                                                                            inflation balance

                                           Debt levels stable
                                                                          Debt levels reduced                                                  Slow growth
                                              or higher

                                                                                                                                             High debt levels

                               A              Policy maintained; austerity avoided. Without major changes, economic growth may
                                              continue to be low. In an effort to please electorates, governments will avoid austerity
                                              (note the recent discussions on the debt brake in Germany). As a result, government
                                              debt levels will (at best) stay broadly constant; they are more likely to continue to
                                              rise. Central banks will therefore need to maintain a low rates environment (at least
                                              in a historical context). As long as inflation does not kick in, putting central banks in a
                                              difficult situation, investors will be faced with low rates for some time. Such a scenario
                                              can last for a pretty long time, as the example of Japan demonstrates.

                               B              Structural reforms and austerity. Governments introduce structural pro-growth
                                              reforms (e.g. de-regulation, postponement of retirement age) and also pursue fiscal
                                              austerity (public expenditures shrink and/or taxes are raised). This path can be thorny
                                              for politicians as their electorate has to make sacrifices – and there can be a long gap
                                              between the implementation of such policies and their eventual success. But resumed
                                              growth, along with fiscal control, should pull down debt-to-GDP ratios and result in
                                              higher interest rates and the end of financial repression. This scenario is more likely in
                                              regions like the U.S. than in the Eurozone, where different national governments are
                                              embedded in a common monetary framework.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                         13
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

                               C              Inflation. The ultimate goal of low yields imposed by central banks may be to create
                                              inflation. Higher inflation increases nominal GDP while the nominal debt level remains
                                              (ceteris paribus) unaffected. Here financial repression creates a transfer from the
                                              creditor to the debtor in real terms. At present, immediate inflation pressures seem
                                              moderate, given the still low growth environment. However, over the medium term
                                              inflation pressure may pick up when economies reopen, production capacity is fully
                                              utilized and pent-up demand meets limited capacity in the services industry. A loss
                                              of purchasing power is an obvious consequence and financial repression could even
                                              intensify if yields do not follow suit and rise to follow inflation. Central banks should,
                                              however, be willing and able to combat too-high inflation rates by tightening financial
                                              conditions and raising rates. Nevertheless, for a certain period of time (and central
                                              banks have been unwilling to define this time frame) many now appear willing to accept
                                              inflation rates above their previous goals – the Fed, for example, has introduced a long-
                                              term average inflation goal.

                               D              Stagflation. Rising inflation along with rising yields can, however, result in a very
                                              unpleasant combination from both an economic and investor perspective. If rates rise
                                              fast they can dampen economic activity as refinancing becomes more expensive and
                                              investments have to yield higher returns. High inflation rates can also result in higher
                                              wages creating an inflationary spiral ultimately resulting in stagflation: stagnant output
                                              and high inflation. The immediate consequences of rising yields for bond holders are
                                              losses. And still if inflation rates are higher than yields, financial repression continues.
                                              For equity investors a low growth/high yield environment has multiple challenges.

                               Looking across countries, it is possible that we will get a combination of these scenarios – some
                               economies lifting themselves out of their current situation and others getting stuck.

                                   Possible future scenarios
                                   In the current financial repression environment, four scenarios (or a
                                   combination of them) look possible:

                                   o Keeping policy broadly “as is”, and hoping that this can keep debt
                                     levels stable.

                                   o Making radical and painful reforms, hoping that eventual stronger
                                     growth will reduce debt.

                                   o Relying on increased inflation to reduce debt levels, which may
                                     require a complex policy balancing act.

                                   o Risking stagflation, where high inflation is unfortunately
                                     accompanied by static or falling output, pushing debt up further.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                         14
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

05                             What this means for investors

                               Asset class trends

                               Financial repression in its current form makes capital preservation (even in nominal terms) even
                               more of a challenge. High grade bonds no longer provide meaningful positive nominal yields (in
                               many cases they are even negative). Despite recent rise in nominal yields in the U.S. real yields
                               continue to be negative. For Europe this is even still the case for large parts of the yield curve.

                               This requires a change in thinking when it comes to asset allocation. Acceptance of risk is a
                               prerequisite for returns, but this implies that investors are able to define their strategic goals and
                               their willingness to accept risks. These parameters can be either temporary or structural in nature.

                               Falling interest rates have particularly supported equities. As can be seen by the high correlation
                               of real yields and valuations (Figure 9), a large part of the increase of the broad S&P 500 in 2020
                               can be explained statistically by higher multiples due to lower real yields.

                               Figure 9: The S&P 500 price/earnings (P/E) ratio and the real U.S. 10-year yield

                               Source: Bloomberg Finance L.P., Deutsche Bank AG. As of April 9, 2021.

                               P/E ratio                                                                                                                                %
                               30                                                                                                                                      -2.0

                                                                                                                                                                       -1.5

                               26

                                                                                                                                                                       -1.0

                               22                                                                                                                                      -0.5

                                                                                                                                                                       0.0

                               18

                                                                                                                                                                       0.5

                               14                                                                                                                                      1.0
                                           2014

                                                            2015

                                                                            2016

                                                                                             2017

                                                                                                              2018

                                                                                                                              2019

                                                                                                                                               2020

                                                                                                                                                                2021

                                    S&P 500 P/E ratio (NTM, LHS)                   10-year U.S. Treasuries real yield (in %, RHS, axis inverted)

                               Low interest rates have particularly helped boost certain types of equities by changing the extent
                               to which we “discount” the future. “Growth” stocks are companies whose earnings are expected
                               to grow strongly in the long term: such growth can be explained not just by structural reasons
                               (e.g. technology trends) but also by accounting. Such companies’ future profits are now less
                               discounted (by lower risk-free interest rates, i.e. highly-rated government bonds) and are therefore
                               more worth from today’s perspective. So financial repression has led to shifts – by sector and by
                               country – with valuations of specific industries growing more than others, and country indices
                               with a higher proportion of such “growth” stocks performing relatively well.

                               For fixed income investors the world looks very different. Earning a return that is higher than
                               inflation is harder than ever, especially for Eurozone investors where, even below investment
                               grade, bonds have very low yields. To enhance the return possibilities bond managers have had to
                               increase their risk profile when it comes to duration, credit and currency risk. This makes returns
                               less predictable and prone to volatility.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                         15
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

                               Real assets, aside from equities, have benefitted from falling yields. The gold price reached new
                               all-time highs in 2020: the fact that gold does not pay any coupon is no longer a disadvantage
                               when overall interest rates are low or negative (Figure 10 shows the link). In relatively illiquid asset
                               classes like real estate or private equity where long-term financing plays an important role, the
                               favourable financing conditions for investors have led to stretched valuations.

                               Figure 10: Gold and real interest rates

                               Source: Bloomberg Finance L.P., Deutsche AG. As of April 9, 2021.

                               2100                                                                                                                                                            -1.5

                               1900                                                                                                                                                            -1.0

                               1700                                                                                                                                                            -0.5

                               1500                                                                                                                                                            0

                               1300                                                                                                                                                            0.5

                               1100                                                                                                                                                            1.0
                                       01/18

                                               03/18

                                                       05/18

                                                               07/18

                                                                       09/18

                                                                               11/18

                                                                                       01/19

                                                                                               03/19

                                                                                                       05/19

                                                                                                               07/19

                                                                                                                       09/19

                                                                                                                               11/19

                                                                                                                                       01/20

                                                                                                                                               03/20

                                                                                                                                                       05/20

                                                                                                                                                               07/20

                                                                                                                                                                       09/20

                                                                                                                                                                               11/20

                                                                                                                                                                                       01/21
                                  Gold (in USD/oz, LHS)                        10-year U.S. treasury real yield (in %, RHS, axis inverted)

                                      Rising real yields: causes and challenges
                                      As an escape route from financial repression, investors may hope for an increase in real
                                      (rather than nominal) yields over the longer term. However, any longer-term increase in
                                      real yields would create challenges as well as opportunities. On the fixed income side, an
                                      increase in real yields could be driven by rising nominal yields (assuming that inflation
                                      does not rise too), and rising nominal yields are associated with a fall in security prices –
                                      implying a rather unsettling path to normalization for an investor concerned about future
                                      income sources. Conversely, if the rise in real yields is due to a fall in inflation (rather than
                                      a rise in nominal yields), then central banks will do “whatever it takes” to combat what they
                                      may well see as dangerously low inflation rates, suppressing interest rates even further to
                                      encourage economic growth and thus (they hope) demand-driven inflation. Hence financial
                                      repression would be likely to continue.

                                      On the equity side the picture would also be complex in a rising real yields environment,
                                      but in rather different ways. Real rates and equity prices are generally positively correlated.
                                      When the former rises, the latter usually does too: from a fundamental perspective, an
                                      increase in real yields can be associated with better GDP growth prospects, which should
                                      in turn be advantageous for equities. Swift moves in real rates, however, can lead to this
                                      correlation between rates and GDP growth turning negative, posing a short-term risk
                                      to equity markets. Negative real yields have resulted, as we can see, in elevated price/
                                      earnings (P/E) ratios. If real yields rise, we should expect a more earnings-driven market,
                                      with P/E multiples likely to decrease. As we discuss above (on page 15) the fall in yields
                                      had also had differing implications for different sectors, in part because it affects how we
                                      discount future earnings. Higher yields therefore could also result in a style rotation from
                                      growth to value stocks, as it would force investors to increasingly discount future earnings,
                                      reducing the relative attractiveness of growth companies.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                         16
CIO Special
Financial repression
            repression:
still restraining real rates

                               Investment responses

                               As we argue above, financial repression is likely to be with us for some years. Investors therefore
                               need to accept it and plan accordingly.

                               One obvious response might appear to be to allocate a higher portion of your strategic asset
                               allocation to equities. But tail risk events (as we have been brutally reminded by the coronavirus
                               pandemic) demonstrate that diversification remains key to any strategic asset allocation as
                               situations can change unexpectedly and rapidly. For a discussion of diversification within
                               portfolios, please see our report, Diversification: managing eggs and baskets.

                               Overall, the impacts of financial repression for markets is both powerful yet simple. The lack of
                               opportunities for positive real returns on safer assets forces investors further out along on the risk
                               curve. For those asset classes which are favoured, this stretches valuations to new highs, which
                               can be particularly problematic for certain types of investors that would normally want to target
                               lower weights for risky assets or institutions that are bound to a fixed nominal return target.

                               In equities, as noted above, financial repression pushes up valuations in a number of ways.
                               Even stocks of companies with above-average dividend yields or pay-out ratios may experience
                               exaggerated performance, being regarded as bond-proxies by traditional fixed income investors
                               who are forced to accept a lower position in the capital structure pecking order. (The negative
                               is that certain rate-sensitive industries, such as banks, may face profitability pressures from an
                               artificial suppression in yields.)

                               However, the ability of fixed income investors to buy more risky assets may be limited by this or
                               other regulatory hurdles. These restrict certain types of institutional investors (e.g. pension funds)
                               regarding credit quality, meaning that they may not have the flexibility to extend out on the risk
                               curve. Such investors may have to lock in yields at negative real levels and follow a more active
                               approach, depending on additional financial repression in the future to further boost the value of
                               some fixed income investments.

                               As we have discussed above, repression of interest rates eliminates opportunity costs for non-
                               interest bearing assets such as gold or other precious metals. Historically, the move in real
                               yields goes in step with this, with some now thinking (not convincingly in our view) that crypto
                               currencies may play a similar role. Real assets are far from risk-free, however.

                               So, in summary, while financial repression may reduce economic risks, a portfolio response to it
                               may involve increasing risk – achieving reasonable portfolio returns may require increasing equity
                               exposure, or venturing into more risky fixed asset investments, or exploring the world of real
                               assets, or a combination of these approaches. This may make for an uncomfortable ride, even if
                               the current problems with the pandemic are dealt with effectively – as the 2013 taper tantrum
                               demonstrated, the process of even slight policy “normalisation” is inherently risky. Financial
                               repression therefore makes effective risk-management in portfolios even more important.

                                   Portfolio implications

                                   o Low interest rates have helped boost equities and some other real
                                     assets. Certain sorts of equities have particularly benefited from
                                     changes to the extent we “discount” the future.

                                   o For fixed income investors, the world looks very different, but the
                                     ability (and willingness) of such investors to increase risk may be
                                     limited by various factors.

                                   o Financial repression therefore demands a well-considered
                                     portfolio response, or else higher levels of risk may make for an
                                     uncomfortable ride, even if current problems with the pandemic
                                     are dealt with effectively.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                         17
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

Bibliography                   1.    Akcigit, U., & Ates, S. T. (2021). Ten Facts on Declining Business Dynamism and Lessons from
                                     Endogenous Growth Theory. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 13(1), 257-98.

                               2.    Bean, Charles R., et al. Low for long?: Causes and consequences of persistently low interest
                                     rates. ICMB, International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies, 2015.

                               3.    Bernanke, B. S. (2005). The global saving glut and the US current account deficit (No. 77).

                               4.    Brand, C., Bielecki, M., & Penalver, A. (2018). The natural rate of interest: estimates, drivers, and
                                     challenges to monetary policy. ECB Occasional Paper, (217).

                               5.    Demary, M. (2017). The end of low interest rates? (No. 17.2017 a). IW-Kurzbericht.

                               6.    Deutsche Bank Wealth Management (2019). Peak debt – Sustainability and investment
                                     implications. CIO Special.

                               7.    Deutsche Bank Wealth Management (2020). Central bank digital currencies – Money reinvented.
                                     CIO Special.

                               8.    Deutsche Bank Wealth Management (2020). Diversification: managing eggs and baskets. CIO
                                     Special.

                               9.    Deutsche Bank Wealth Management (2021): Yields end deep hibernation. CIO Special.

                               10. Holston, K., Laubach, T., & Williams, J. C. (2017). Measuring the natural rate of interest:
                                   International trends and determinants. Journal of International Economics, 108, S59-S75.

                               11. Lagarde, C. (2020): The monetary policy strategy review: some preliminary considerations,
                                   Speech by the President of the ECB, at the “ECB and Its Watchers XXI” conference.

                               12. Laubach, T., & Williams, J. C. (2016). Measuring the natural rate of interest redux. Business
                                   Economics, 51(2), 57-67.

                               13. Lopez-Salido, D., Sanz-Maldonado, G., Schippits, C., & Wei, M. (2020). Measuring the Natural
                                   Rate of Interest: The Role of Inflation Expectations. FEDS Notes, (2020-06), 19.

                               14. Von Weizsäcker, C. C., & Krämer, H. (2019). Sparen und Investieren im 21. Jahrhundert.

                               15. Wicksell, K. (1898). Geldzins und Güterpreise: eine Studie über die den Tauschwert des Geldes
                                   bestimmenden Ursachen.

                               16. Schmelzing, P. (2020). Bank of England, Staff Working Paper No. 845, Eight centuries of global
                                   real interest rates, R-G, and the ‘suprasecular’ decline, 1311–2018.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                         18
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

Glossary                       Baby boomers are generally defined as those born between 1946 and 1964.

                               The European Central Bank (ECB) is the central bank for the Eurozone.

                               The Federal Reserve (Fed) is the central bank of the United States. Its Federal Open Market
                               Committee (FOMC) meets to determine interest rate policy.

                               Financial repression is a policy of keeping interest rates at very low or negative real levels.

                               The G20 is an international forum of the governments and central-bank governors from 19 individual
                               countries—Argentina, Australia, Brazil, Canada, China, France, Germany, India, Indonesia, Italy,
                               Japan, Mexico, Russia, Saudi Arabia, South Africa, South Korea, Turkey, the United Kingdom and the
                               United States—along with the European Union (EU).

                               The Global Financial Crisis refers to the financial and economic crisis that started in 2007-2008.

                               The International Monetary Fund (IMF) was founded in 1994, includes 189 countries and works to
                               promote international monetary cooperation, exchange rate stability and economic development
                               more broadly.

                               Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) is a heterodox macroeconomic framework that, in some forms, says
                               monetarily sovereign countries like the U.S., UK, Japan and Canada are not operationally constrained
                               by revenues when it comes to federal government spending.
                               Market concentration

                               Quantitative easing (QE) is an unconventional monetary policy tool, in which a central bank conducts
                               a broad-based asset purchases.

                               R* is the natural rate of interest, which (in theory) brings an economy’s output in line with its potential
                               output.

                               Stagflation is a situation where economic growth is slow (or negative) but levels of inflation are high.

                               The yield curve shows the different rates for bonds of differing maturities but the same credit quality.

                               Yield curve control is where a central bank targets part of the yield curve, buying (or selling) these
                               bonds to keep yields (and therefore prices) at what it believes to be appropriate levels.

                               Past performance is not indicative of future returns. Forecasts are not a reliable indicator of future performance. Your capital may be at
                               risk. Readers should refer to disclosures and risk warnings at the end of this document. Produced in April 2021.                         19
CIO Special
Financial repression:
still restraining real rates

Important
                               General
                               This document may not be distributed in Canada or Japan. This document is intended for retail or professional clients only. This

Note
                               document is being circulated in good faith by Deutsche Bank AG, its branches (as permitted in any relevant jurisdiction), affiliated
                               companies and its officers and employees (collectively, “Deutsche Bank”).

                               This material is for your information only and is not intended as an offer, or recommendation or solicitation of an offer to buy or sell
                               any investment, security, financial instrument or other specific product, to conclude a transaction, or to provide any investment
                               service or investment advice, or to provide any research, investment research or investment recommendation, in any jurisdiction.
                               All materials in this communication are meant to be reviewed in their entirety.

                               If a court of competent jurisdiction deems any provision of this disclaimer unenforceable, the remaining provisions will remain in
                               full force and effect. This document has been prepared as a general market commentary without consideration of the investment
                               needs, objectives or financial circumstances of any investor. Investments are subject to generic market risks which derive from the
                               instrument or are specific to the instrument or attached to the particular issuer. Should such risks materialise, investors may incur
                               losses, including (without limitation) a total loss of the invested capital. The value of investments can fall as well as rise and you
                               may not recover the amount originally invested at any point in time. This document does not identify all the risks (direct or indirect)
                               or other considerations which may be material to an investor when making an investment decision.

                               This document and all information included herein are provided “as is”, “as available” and no representation or warranty of any
                               kind, express, implied or statutory, is made by Deutsche Bank regarding any statement or information contained herein or in
                               conjunction with this document. All opinions, market prices, estimates, forward looking statements, hypothetical statements,
                               forecast returns or other opinions leading to financial conclusions contained herein reflect Deutsche Bank’s subjective judgment
                               on the date of this report. Without limitation, Deutsche Bank does not warrant the accuracy, adequacy, completeness, reliability,
                               timeliness or availability of this communication or any information in this document and expressly disclaims liability for errors or
                               omissions herein. Forward looking statements involve significant elements of subjective judgments and analyses and changes
                               thereto and/or consideration of different or additional factors could have a material impact on the results indicated. Therefore,
                               actual results may vary, perhaps materially, from the results contained herein.

                               Deutsche Bank does not assume any obligation to either update the information contained in this document or inform investors
                               about available updated information. The information contained in this document is subject to change without notice and based
                               on a number of assumptions which may not prove valid, and may be different from conclusions expressed by other departments
                               within Deutsche Bank. Although the information contained in this document has been diligently compiled by Deutsche Bank
                               and derived from sources that Deutsche Bank considers trustworthy and reliable, Deutsche Bank does not guarantee or cannot
                               make any guarantee about the completeness, fairness, or accuracy of the information and it should not be relied upon as such.
                               This document may provide, for your convenience, references to websites and other external sources. Deutsche Bank takes no
                               responsibility for their content and their content does not form any part of this document. Accessing such external sources is at
                               your own risk.

                               Before making an investment decision, investors need to consider, with or without the assistance of an investment adviser,
                               whether any investments and strategies described or provided by Deutsche Bank, are appropriate, in light of their particular
                               investment needs, objectives, financial circumstances and instrument specifics. When making an investment decision, potential
                               investors should not rely on this document but only on what is contained in the final offering documents relating to the investment.
                               As a global financial services provider, Deutsche Bank from time to time faces actual and potential conflicts of interest. Deutsche
                               Bank’s policy is to take all appropriate steps to maintain and operate effective organisational and administrative arrangements to
                               identify and manage such conflicts. Senior management within Deutsche Bank are responsible for ensuring that Deutsche Bank’s
                               systems, controls and procedures are adequate to identify and manage conflicts of interest.

                               Deutsche Bank does not give tax or legal advice, including in this document and nothing in this document should be interpreted
                               as Deutsche Bank providing any person with any investment advice. Investors should seek advice from their own tax experts,
                               lawyers and investment advisers in considering investments and strategies described by Deutsche Bank. Unless notified to the
                               contrary in a particular case, investment instruments are not insured by any governmental entity, not subject to deposit protection
                               schemes and not guaranteed, including by Deutsche Bank. This document may not be reproduced or circulated without Deutsche
                               Bank’s express written authorisation. Deutsche Bank expressly prohibits the distribution and transfer of this material to third
                               parties. Deutsche Bank accepts no liability whatsoever arising from the use or distribution of this material or for any action taken
                               or decision made in respect of investments mentioned in this document the investor may have entered into or may enter in future.

                               The manner of circulation and distribution of this document may be restricted by law or regulation in certain countries, including,
                               without limitation, the United States. This document is not directed to, or intended for distribution to or use by, any person
                               or entity who is a citizen or resident of or located in any locality, state, country or other jurisdiction, where such distribution,
                               publication, availability or use would be contrary to law or regulation or which would subject Deutsche Bank to any registration
                               or licensing requirement within such jurisdiction not currently met. Persons into whose possession this document may come are
                               required to inform themselves of, and to observe, such restrictions. Past performance is no guarantee of future results; nothing
                               contained herein shall constitute any representation, warranty or prediction as to future performance. Further information is
                               available upon investor’s request.

                                                                                                                                                                        20
You can also read