Can the Kyoto Protocol promote renewable energy technologies?
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Can the Kyoto Protocol promote renewable energy technologies? Norbert Wohlgemuth University of Klagenfurt, Austria Tel +43 463 2700 4113, Fax +43 463 2700 4191 norbert.wohlgemuth@uni-klu.at.at This paper presents and analyses the capacity of the proposed mechanisms of the Kyoto Protocol to promote investment in renewable energy technologies, whereas the focus is on the Clean Development Mechanism. Analysis of abatement costing studies indicates that the increasing use of renewable energy tends to be a higher cost option compared with other greenhouse gas abatement technologies. This finding, however, does not make renewable energy technologies unattractive for greenhouse gas mitigation as such because, apart from their vast technical potential to reduce greenhouse gas emissions, renewable energy technologies have great capacity to contribute to other aspects of sustainable development. The extent of investment into renewable energy induced by the Kyoto mechanisms will depend on whether the rules and guidelines that are to be developed in the coming years will explicitly support renewables. The Kyoto mechanisms could be instrumental in leading to significant investment into these resources if rules are defined appropriately. 1 The Kyoto Protocol and Renewable Energy The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) has pointed to the large role renewable energy can play in meeting the ultimate goal of virtually replacing fossil fuels, noting that “in the longer term, renewable energy sources could meet a major part of the world’s demand for energy” (IPCC, 1996a). This would be an accelerated decarbonisation of the world’s energy system over the next century — a dramatic reversal of the trend in global emissions during the last decades. The IPCC Second Assessment Report (IPCC, 1996a and b) has concluded that a 60 to 80% reduction in greenhouse gas emissions will ultimately be needed to stabilise atmospheric concentrations of these gases and avert serious climate disruptions.1 The Kyoto Protocol to the Climate Change Convention sets out legally binding emission targets and timetables for developed countries. In order to ease compliance, it allows countries to achieve their 1 Wigley (1999) presents results from the IPCC Third Assessment Report, which has been released in February 2001. The new estimates are now that the global-mean temperature change from 1990 to 2100 ranges between 1.3°C and 4.0°C while the sea-level rise ranges between 17 cm and 99 cm. These latest results indicate a more severe impact of man- made global warming than previously assumed.
emission targets through the “Kyoto Mechanisms”. These mechanisms comprise International Emissions Trading (ET), Joint Implementation (JI), and a Clean Development Mechanism (CDM). The new climate change regime also offers an opportunity for renewable energy technologies (RETs) as they meet the two basic conditions to be eligible for assistance under the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change implementing mechanisms: they contribute to global sustainability through greenhouse gas mitigation; and they conform to national priorities by leading to development of local capacities and infrastructure. Further, with the Kyoto Protocol,2 the Parties to the UNFCCC have moved towards internalising the external costs of the greenhouse gas emissions. While the Kyoto Protocol has not yet proposed any binding emission limitation commitments for developing nations, flexible instruments such as the Clean Development Mechanism and the possibilities of emissions trading are likely to provide economic incentives for significant emissions abatement in developing countries. The altered competitive dynamics should also prove favourable for RETs. The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC, 1992) was adopted to achieve stabilisation of greenhouse gas concentrations in the atmosphere at a level that would prevent dangerous anthropogenic interference with the climate system. The Kyoto Protocol to the UNFCCC (1997) establishes legally binding emission reduction targets for developed countries. They are to be reached in the period between 2008 and 2012, known as the “first commitment period”.3 Agreement on emission reductions was made conditional on the inclusion of additional instruments, commonly referred to as “Kyoto Mechanisms”. They aim at easing the economic burden of emissions reductions by providing the means to achieve targets at lower cost. Overall, the targets adopted at Kyoto commit industrialised nations (Annex B Parties)4 to reduce their emissions of a basket of greenhouse gases, evaluated in CO2 equivalent, by around 5% between 2008 to 2012 as compared to 1990 levels. The Parties have agreed to differentiated individual emissions targets, ranging from an increase of 10% of emissions (Iceland) to the biggest emissions reduction of 2 Depledge (2000) provides an in-depth history of the Kyoto Protocol negotiations, tracing each provision from the original proposals from Parties through to the final authentic language. 3 The Kyoto Protocol comes into effect if it is ratified by at least 55 Parties to the Convention, incorporating Annex B Parties, which accounted for at least 55% of total Annex B CO2 emissions. As of 5 February 2001, 84 Parties had signed and 32 Parties had ratified the Kyoto Protocol. But none of the Annex B Parties had ratified the Protocol. 4 ‘Annex B’ is the group of countries listed under Annex B of the 1997 Kyoto Protocol. Annex B countries have adopted legally binding greenhouse gas emission targets for 2012. ‘Annex I’ refers to the group of countries listed under ‘Annex I’ of the 1992 Climate Convention, and which has adopted the ‘aim of returning [.] to their 1990 levels [.] anthropogenic emissions of carbon dioxide and other greenhouse gases’ (UNFCCC, 1992, 4.2(b)). Both set of countries are almost identical and include most OECD countries, Russia, Ukraine, and the Central and Eastern European countries that are in a process of economic transition from centrally planned economies. Sometimes the terms ‘Annex B’ and ‘Annex I’ are used synonymously. 2
8%, undertaken by 27 Annex B Parties, including the European Union (EU) and its Member States. The emission reduction obligations can be summarised as follows (Weyant and Hill, 1999): • Western European countries accepted an 8 per cent reduction, with the exception of Iceland (+10%) and Norway (+1%). The European Union wants to take advantage of the “bubble” possibility under Article 4, which implies that countries may differentiate their targets (Haites, 2001).5 • Eastern European countries adopted the same obligation as their Western European counterparts, with the exceptions of Croatia (-5%) and Hungary and Poland (-6%). • The Russian Federation and Ukraine were allowed emission stabilisation with respect to 1990 levels, while Latvia, Estonia and Lithuania agreed to 8% reductions. • Japan and Canada agreed to a 6% reduction, and the United States to a 7% reduction. • Australia was allowed to increase emissions by 8%, and New Zealand to emit up to 1990 levels. This is equivalent to stabilisation, as greenhouse gas emissions from Annex B Parties were in 1995 already 5% lower than in 1990. This was caused in large part by the collapse of the centrally-planned economies in the early nineties. Many countries including the United States will have to make serious efforts to meet their own targets if they want to counter economic growth. The level of emissions of Annex B Parties by 2008-2012 will therefore depend on the extent to which Parties achieve their targets through domestic reductions as well as the extent to which the Kyoto Mechanisms are used to obtain credit for reductions abroad. Reducing emissions can be undertaken through various measures, including increasing the efficiency in the provision and end-use of energy, and a switch towards carbon-free (renewable) and less carbon intensive (e.g., natural gas) resources. Often, the cheapest option with significant impact on emissions is fuel switching. The move to gas, however, has, in many cases, already been undertaken through the ongoing liberalisation of electricity markets. New pathways need to be sought. These may include the increased use of renewable energy. However, the Kyoto Protocol provides no specific support for renewable energy, and makes only general references to promoting new and renewable energy. The closest reference to renewable energy is made under Article 2 of the Protocol: 5 Individual Member States commitments in accordance with Article 4 of the Kyoto Protocol are: Belgium -7.5%, Denmark -21%, Germany -21%, Greece +25%, Spain +15%, France 0%, Ireland +13%, Italy -6.5%, Luxembourg -28%, Netherlands -6%, Austria -13%, Portugal +27%, Finland 0%, Sweden +4%, United Kingdom -12.5%. 3
“Each Party included in Annex I … shall: (iv) Research on, and promotion, development and increased use of, new and renewable forms of energy, of carbon dioxide sequestration technologies and of advanced and innovative environmentally sound technologies”. While this is likely to remain rhetoric, Article 6 on JI and Article 12 on a CDM may support renewables in a more concrete way, as investors can earn greenhouse gas emission reduction credits. The new climate change regime may thus offer an opportunity for the development of RETs as they lead to zero greenhouse gas increases, and constitute an ideal tool for sustainable development (Leggett, 1998).6 2 The Kyoto Mechanisms The Kyoto Protocol allows Annex B Parties to implement their commitments by entering into a formal agreement to undertake their obligations jointly (Article 4), to transfer emission reduction units from projects undertaken within Annex B (Article 6), which corresponds to Joint Implementation, or to engage in emissions trading (ET) (Article 17). In addition, a form of Joint Implementation between Annex B and non-Annex B Parties using the CDM was defined in the Protocol (Article 12) through which emission reductions can be earned within a non-Annex B Party and used towards meeting the Annex B Party’s commitments. 2.1 Emissions Trading Following Kyoto, many countries focused on ET both because of the extent of emission reductions that may be purchased from other countries and because of the uncertainty surrounding the concrete design of ET (OECD, 1997). Like a carbon tax, ET has been shown to lead to emission reductions where (marginal) costs of abatement are least. ET is thus a suitable mechanism to exploit efficiency gains in terms of cost reduction. However, following Kyoto there has been concern that emission reduction targets had been set too low for these efficiency gains to come about. While most questions surrounding trading remained unresolved even almost three years after Kyoto, it is obvious that the rules governing emissions trading will not be as stringent as for project-based activities (Woerdman, 2000b). In the context of emission trading, negotiators in Kyoto were very concerned about the issue of “hot air”. Hot air is traded when one of the trading parties is subject to too low emission targets. Under 6 “The purpose of the clean development mechanism shall be to assist Parties not included in Annex I in achieving sustainable development and in contributing to the ultimate objective of the Convention, and to assist Parties included in Annex I in achieving compliance with their quantified emission limitation and reduction commitments under Article 3” (UNFCCC, 1997, Article 12, p 13). 4
these circumstances, emission permits may simply be transferred or sold to the account of another country without any further abatement effort. Hot air thus constitutes a costless asset. As a result, the idea that emission trading should take advantage of emission abatement cost differentials does not materialise. Most hot air stems from Eastern Europe, Russia and Ukraine. Projections for 2010 indicate that more than 80% of all allowances on offer, corresponding to about 2% of CO2 emissions in 1990, will come from Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union (Figure 1). The effectiveness of the emission target thus depends on these economies in transition. Rules and regulations of an emissions trading system therefore will need to explicitly address the situation of the economies in transition. Figure 1 Potential Supply of and Demand for “Hot Air” 2 5 0 0 C a n a d a Ja p a n 2 0 0 0 E U 1 5 0 0 Mt CO2 U S A 1 0 0 0 R o m a n ia B u lg a ria 5 0 0 U k ra in e R u s s ia 0 S u p p ly D em and Source: Missfeldt (2000). An element that will determine the evolution of a trading system is the issue of who is eligible to trade. Article 17 limits participation in the trading scheme to those Parties listed under Annex B that have committed themselves to quantifiable emission targets. A priori this implies intergovernmental trading only. Pre-Kyoto, however, experts and Parties discussed the participation of private entities. Tradable 5
permits could then, for example, be made available on spot and futures markets on the international stock exchange (McKibbin et al., 1999). In the political debate two “schools” have formed: representatives of the EU tend to support intergovernmental trading, while representatives of the United States and the “umbrella group”7 favour trading among private entities.8 2.2 Joint Implementation The idea of JI is to reduce emissions through a project in a host country, while a donor country may credit at least part of the emission reductions. The project is economical because the donor country is faced with high marginal emission abatement costs, while the host country exhibits comparatively lower marginal abatement costs. In principle, the economic gains are similar to ET except that under JI, the efforts are typically bound to a specific project. JI has already been subject to a pilot phase under the Climate Convention under the name of Activities Implemented Jointly (AIJ).9 The pilot phase, which does not allow for crediting of emissions, has begun at the First Conference of the Parties in Berlin, 1994. While during the pilot phase, projects were largely sponsored by governments, it is expected that private firms will become increasingly interested in investment since the Kyoto Protocol allows for crediting of emissions reductions. Under the pilot phase mainly small scale renewable and energy efficiency projects were funded, including several solar energy projects.10 JI under the Kyoto Protocol is limited to projects in the developed world. The most likely candidates to host such projects among Annex B Parties are the economies in transition, because they “achieved” large emissions reductions as their centrally planning economies collapsed (Missfeldt and Villavicencio, 2000). Article 6 on JI, as it stands, would cover both emissions reductions and sinks projects including, for example, energy efficient housing projects, the building of renewable, clean coal or nuclear power plants, and forest projects. 7 The “umbrella group” is an informal coalition of countries during the climate negotiations, which in early 2000 consisted of Australia, Canada, Iceland, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, the Russian Federation, Ukraine and the United States. 8 One of the issues in designing an emissions trading framework is how to enforce compliance with the trading rules. If revenues from the sale of quotas exceed the cost of sanctions, countries benefit from non-compliance. Haites and Missfeldt (2001) analyse the economic and environmental performance of different liability proposals for the first commitment period, and find that penalties are sufficient to deter non-compliance if they are high enough and effectively enforced. 9 An overview of Parties’ experience with AIJ can be found in UNFCCC (1999). 10 A list of projects which have been accepted, approved or endorsed by the designated national authorities for AIJ of the Parties concerned can be found at www.unfccc.de/program/aij/aijproj.html. 6
Two comments need to be made on this approach. Firstly, it may be argued that climate change mitigation should not be undertaken at the expense of worsening other environmental problems. Building a nuclear reactor, for example, results in zero greenhouse gas emissions during plant operation, but entails hazards such as the decommissioning of spent nuclear fuel and waste, the risk of nuclear accidents and potential problems with nuclear proliferation. The Protocol, however, does not address this issue. Secondly, no advice is given as to which technology is to be chosen as long as the emission reductions are additional. Introducing a “clean coal project”, for example, may well lead to “additional” emission reductions, but it may not be the technology that would yield the maximum emission reductions possible in a specific project case. In order to achieve a workable framework for JI, a number of issues will need to be addressed, including baselines, multiplicity of underlying objectives, the issue of hot air and uncertainty (Begg et al., 2001). For example, it will be essential to have a clear and transparent definition of baselines as both the host and donor of a JI project might exaggerate emission reductions by overstating baseline emissions (OECD, 1999; Parkinson et al., 2001). 2.3 Clean Development Mechanism Article 12 of the Protocol describes the CDM, which is essentially JI between developed (Annex B) and developing countries. It could help solve developing countries’ needs for capital to finance technology transfer for and diffusion of sustainable economic development, while also providing a more flexible alternative for developed (Annex B) countries to meet emissions reduction targets (Stewart, 2000; Haites and Aslam, 2000). The difference between the CDM and JI is significant as developing countries are not subject to a (binding) emission ceiling. At its worst, the CDM may therefore lead to increases in absolute emissions as compared with the status quo. Clear guidelines and procedures to assess the greenhouse gas emissions reduction generated from the project have to be developed in order to preclude this possibility. Unlike under Article 6, the project range that is eligible for a CDM activity has not yet been defined. This gives an opportunity to exclude certain types of projects. Other than JI, the CDM requires that projects contribute to “achieving sustainable development” in the developing countries (UNFCCC, 1997, Article 12.2). Thus requirements for project types under the CDM are likely to be more stringent than for JI. As the CDM is based on bilateral project level trading, this instrument also has certain similarities to JI. However, the main difference between JI and CDM is that host countries as developing countries are not committed to fulfil a reduction target under the Protocol. In contrast to JI and ET, the Kyoto Protocol furthermore identifies three institutional aspects to be implemented under the CDM. One 7
such aspect is related to the establishment of operational entities certifying emission reductions resulting from each project. In addition, the CDM is to be supervised by an executive board. Finally, the CDM shall assist in arranging funding of other CDM projects. The assessment of greenhouse gas reductions generated by a project is not easy, and requires that a “baseline” be established against which the emissions reduction may be measured. (OECD, 1999).11 In future negotiations it is also possible to supplement the criteria of “additionality” with criteria of environmentally sound investment. So far no advice is given as to which technology is to be chosen as long as the emission reductions are additional. A project is “additional” if “any such project provides a reduction in emissions by sources, or an enhancement of removals by sinks, that is additional to any that would otherwise occur” (Article 6 of the Kyoto Protocol). Introducing a clean coal project, for example, may well lead to “additional” emission reductions, but it may not be the technology that would yield the maximum emission reductions possible in a specific project case. In addition, there has been concern that projects could be endorsed that – while contributing to greenhouse gas reductions – may entail other environmental problems. Building a nuclear reactor, for example, results in zero greenhouse gas emissions during plant operation, but entails hazards such as the decommissioning of spent nuclear fuel and waste, the risk of nuclear accidents and potential problems with nuclear proliferation. Although the Protocol does not address this issue, at the fifth Conference of the Parties in Bonn, in November 1999, a number of countries including Austria, Denmark, Germany, Greece, Indonesia, Ireland, Italy, Nauru, Singapore, Sweden and Tuvalu suggested that nuclear projects should not be part of the project-based mechanisms JI and the CDM (CAN, 1999). As of early 2000, however, only the Alliance of Small Island States (AOSIS) has officially submitted the view that nuclear power should be excluded. At the same time, many green non-government organisations such as Friends of the Earth, began supporting the idea of a “positive list” of technologies. Such technologies would not have to prove “additionality”, and could be endorsed as JI or CDM projects on an “ad hoc” basis. It is very likely that such a list would contain RETs. Decisions on modalities for the three mechanisms have not been taken in November 2000 in The Hague at the sixth Conference of the Parties to the Climate Convention but postponed to July 2001. These modalities could contain a framework of rules that will make the mechanisms operational so that countries may start using them ahead of the end of the commitment period in 2012. Key issues 11 A baseline defines a level of emissions against which the actual or estimated emissions of a climate mitigation project is compared. The baseline is the standard from which a measure of valid emission reductions is derived. It must therefore be set at a level that ensures that an emission mitigation activity is additional to that which would have otherwise occurred. 8
that must still be resolved at the resumed talks include a package of financial support and technology transfer to help developing countries contribute to global action on climate change, including measures for adapting to climate change impacts; the establishment of an international emissions trading system and a CDM; the rules for counting emissions reductions from carbon “sinks” such as forests; and a compliance regime (Baumert et al., 2000). 3 The Potential for Renewables In addition to progress at the political level, the flexibility mechanisms’ potential to reduce global greenhouse gas emissions critically also depends on the relative abatement costs in non-Annex B countries.12 ECN (1999) systematically compiled information on abatement costs from 24 non- Annex B country studies (ADB, 1998; UNDP/GEF, 1999), and arrive at an abatement potential of roughly 1.5 Gigatonnes (Gt) of CO2 equivalents, at a price of USD 50/tonne CO2 equivalents or lower.13 Roughly 38% of this potential is found to be achievable at negative or zero incremental costs. The 24 non-Annex B countries for which studies on abatement costs were available comprise a fairly extensive sample: these countries currently account for some two thirds of total greenhouse gas emissions in non-Annex B countries. The studies also indicate that a large fraction of the total identified abatement potential can be realised in a relatively small number of non-Annex B countries. The identified abatement potential for China and India already constitutes nearly 70% of the total identified potential. Figure 2 depicts the projected CO2 abatement costs curve in year 2010 for 24 non- Annex B study countries for options in the range of -50 to +50 USD/tonne CO2 equivalents.14 12 This section covers only abatement costs of CO2 emissions. Tol and Downing (2000) present marginal abatement costs of other greenhouse gases as well. An extensive discussion of the literature on climate change impact estimation and valuation is given in Eyre et al. (1997). 13 Only options in the energy sector have been considered. Greenhouse gas emissions from the energy sector account for more than 70% of the total global greenhouse gas emissions. 14 Out of the total of 247 eligible options included, the costs for 22 options are below -50 1990 US$ and for 15 options the unit costs exceed 50 1990 US$. 9
Figure 2 CO2 Abatement Costs for 24 non-Annex B Countries. Cost curve (all eligible options) 50 40 30 20 (in US dollars 1990 per tonne) Abatement costs 10 0 0,0 0,2 0,4 0,6 0,8 1,0 1,2 1,4 1,6 1,8 -10 -20 -30 -40 -50 Abatement potential (Gigatonnes CO2 equivalent) Source: ECN (1999). The projected potential for all non-Annex B countries at economic costs per tonne of up to 50 USD can be extrapolated to 2.25 Gt of CO2 equivalents. Most of this potential is projected to be achievable at quite low costs. Up to 1.6 Gt per year appears feasible at economic costs of US$ 6/tonne CO2 or lower. The abatement potential in non-Annex B countries is significant when compared with Annex B reduction requirements, and a considerable fraction of this potential can be tapped at low cost. The greenhouse gas abatement cost studies further suggest that approximately 1.7 Gt CO2 equivalents per year would be available during the 2008-2012 budget period, at net incremental costs below 10 1990 US$/tonne CO2. The analysis performed on some 60 AIJ and Global Environment Facility (GEF) projects confirms this conclusion. The different nature of the analysed projects limits the extent to which they can be used to generate representative aggregate cost curves. Nevertheless, an analysis of the net incremental cost curve and the AIJ/GEF contribution cost curve results in the same conclusion that a large number of the projects (up to 99%) has a potential with abatement costs less than 10 US$/tonne CO2 (ECN, 1999). In order to meet the Kyoto targets, Annex B countries must, based on their projected emissions for 2010, reduce their greenhouse gas emissions by some 620 million tons of carbon (MtC). The 10
contribution of the flexibility mechanisms (in 2010) to this reduction requirement as calculated by Zhang (1999) are presented in Table 1. Depending on the scenario chosen,15 the CDM’s contribution ranges from 131.8 MtC under the “EU ceilings” scenario to 357.5 MtC if Russia and Ukraine are allowed to fully participate in trading. The CDM appears to be the flexible instrument which promises the greatest potential, clearly bigger than trading with economies in transition, including ET and JI.16 Table 1 Allocation of World Wide Greenhouse Gas Reduction Requirements to Flexible Mechanisms, in MtC Scenarios Domestic action Hot air Emissions trading CDM + JI No limits 171.7 105.0 51.8 292.1 50% reduction from 310.3 105.0 36.1 169.2 BAU emissions EU ceilings 387.8 70.2 30.8 131.8 No hot air 203.5 0 59.6 357.5 Source: Zhang (1999). Estimates of the size of the CDM market (in 2010) critically depend on the modelling approach. A literature survey indicates that the CDM potential ranges from 67-723 MtC, resulting in a CDM contribution to the total emission reduction requirements of between 10 and 58% (Zhang, 1999). With respect to the geographical distribution of the CDM flows, China and India are very likely to account for a large majority of the total non-Annex B countries’ exported permits to the Annex B regions (Austin and Faeth, 2000). The abatement cost studies indicate that two types of activities encompass most abatement potential: energy efficiency measures in the power sector and demand side energy efficiency measures (together 66%). The role of renewable energy is limited to 14% of identified abatement measures and the potential for fuel switching is 17% (ECN, 1999). The AIJ/GEF projects indicate that demand side 15 “No limits”: no caps are imposed on the use of all three flexibility mechanisms; “50% reduction from BAU [business as usual] emissions”: the maximum allowed acquisitions from all three flexibility mechanisms are limited to 50% of the difference between projected baseline emissions and the Kyoto targets in 2010; “EU ceilings”: EU proposal for concrete ceilings on the use of all three flexibility mechanisms; “No hot air”: trading in hot air is not allowed. 16 Woerdman (2000a) argues, by providing five reasons, that JI and CDM projects will be more effective, efficient and politically acceptable than an ET system. 11
energy efficiency has received most attention in the GEF/AIJ projects (60%), followed by renewable energy (34%).17 These results may lead to the conclusion that renewable energy may not take a very prominent share as part of JI and CDM. However, several aspects have to be kept in mind. There are clear limitations of analysis: The abatement cost studies are far from comprehensive; different assumptions and approaches across studies make it difficult to reconcile and combine results; the studies do not reveal all information needed to construct cost curves from all available options; estimates of abatement potential and incremental costs are very sensitive to assumptions on the baseline scenarios; definition of costs was not consistent across studies; and CDM transaction costs were often excluded. The cost curve in Figure 2 also does not reveal the distribution of different technologies in the –50 to +50 US$ cost range. Halsnæs (1999) presents energy sector greenhouse gas emission reduction options and their costs. Table 2 shows the number of renewable energy options and the number of total options considered in the Asia Least-cost Greenhouse Gas Abatement Strategy and UNEP studies. As can be seen, only 17% of all options analysed were based on renewable energy, which may also have led to an underestimation of the potential of RETs. Table 2 Renewable Energy Options in Greenhouse Gas Abatement Studies Country Number of renewable energy Total number of options options Thailand 0 13 Vietnam 1 7 Republic of Korea 0 9 Philippines 3 12 Myanmar 2 15 Pakistan 4 21 Peoples Republic of China 4 14 Ecuador 2 11 Botswana 6 18 Zambia 1 9 Estonia 2 8 Hungary 1 12 Total 26 149 Source: Halsnæs (1999). 17 Kamal (1997) also finds that improving energy efficiency is the most cost-effective way for mitigating global warming. 12
Concerning the relative cost of renewables-based options it appears that they tend to be higher cost options for greenhouse gas mitigation in the energy sector. This finding, however, does not make them an unattractive option for greenhouse gas mitigation as such because, apart from their potential to reduce greenhouse gas emissions, they have great potential to contribute to other aspects of sustainable development, including improved air and water quality, enhanced soil preservation, flood protection, electrification of rural and remote areas and increased employment opportunities; a more diversified resource base, avoided fuel supply and price risks; provision of infrastructure and economic flexibility by modular and small scale technologies; creation of more choice for consumers; contribution to overall system reliability (Austin and Faeth, 2000; Chapman and Ward, 1996). 4 Conclusions Remarkable progress has been made in the commercialisation of renewable energy options. Wind power, for example, is a success story and may soon be the most economic supply alternative. Solar energy is coming of age and unit costs are coming down at an impressive rate. In the long run, renewable energy will be the major contributor to the world’s energy system. The industrialised countries of the North have most of the technologies and the financial resources for utilising RETs, while many developing countries have great potential for renewable resources. Therefore, technology transfer to developing countries is needed, and the Kyoto mechanisms could play an important role. There is concern that RETs might not benefit fully from the Kyoto mechanisms because of their economics and characteristics, including small unit sizes and dispersed application (DeLucia, 1998). On the other hand, these features may not always constitute a hindrance because modular, distributed technologies can have operating and financial attributes, such as modularity and flexibility, very low operating costs and the ability to create new strategic options for the future, which could make them more economically attractive than conventional technologies. While the Kyoto mechanisms may be key in fostering human capacity in the receiver countries, they may not yield the amount of emission reductions required to make them worthwhile if high transaction costs are taken into account. Although there seems to be a large number of low-cost emission reduction projects in developing countries, there may be considerable difficulties in the realisation of these projects within the context of the CDM. In the absence of binding targets in developing countries it will be difficult to determine the net emission reduction effects due to specific CDM projects, since nation-wide indirect and direct effects must be counted. In addition, individual projects that bring about large emissions reductions may prove useful. Alternatively, host countries may want to resort to bundling of small RET projects. With respect to the Kyoto mechanisms, traditional investment criteria for projects to be funded under the mechanisms are not the only criteria: the CDM, for example, is to contribute to sustainability. 13
Therefore, since renewable energy is generally understood as contributing to sustainability, there is a “match” between RETs and the CDM, which could contribute to mutual enhancement. A very favourable outcome for renewables would be if developed countries could seek a relatively large proportion of their emission reductions abroad, combined with strict and relatively exclusive criteria for which technologies are supported under the CDM. If “positive lists” for the CDM are endorsed at the international level, RETs are likely to figure prominently on them. On the other hand, allowing, for example, either forest, nuclear or large hydro project into the CDM would significantly dilute the market for carbon offsets pushing down the value of carbon credits. In turn, this would have a negative impact on the diffusion of RETs in developing countries via the CDM. There are only three climate negotiating sessions left to the important tenth anniversary earth summit, “Rio+10”, to be held in Johannesburg in June 2002. Pressure on OECD governments to show environmental leadership is intensifying. To sum up, the Kyoto Protocol is likely to give a positive push to renewable technologies. The magnitude of the impetus will depend on whether the rules and guidelines that are to be developed in the coming years will explicitly support renewables. In order to achieve this, the renewable industries would be advised to lobby the governments to do so. Bibliography ADB (1998) Asia Least-cost Greenhouse Gas Abatement Strategy (ALGAS) Eleven national reports and a summary report, printed by Asian Development Bank. Austin, D. and P. Faeth (2000) Financing Sustainable Development with the Clean Development Mechanism World Resources Institute, Washington, DC. Baumert, K. A., Kete, N. and C. Figueres (2000) Designing the Clean Development Mechanism to Meet the Needs of a Broad Range of Interests World Resources Institute Climate Note, August, Washington, DC. Begg, K. G., Jackson, T. and S. Parkinson (2001) “Beyond joint implementation – designing flexibility into global climate policy” Energy Policy 29(1), 17-27. CAN (1999) Ministers weigh in ECO – NGO Newsletter October-November ’99, No 3, Climate Action Network. Chapman, C. and S. Ward (1996) “Valuing the flexibility of alternative sources of power generation” Energy Policy 24(2), 129-136. DeLucia, R. J. (1998) “Availability and access of financial support for renewables: issues and an illustrative innovation” Energy Policy 22(2), 131-140. Depledge, J. (2000) Tracing the Origins of the Kyoto Protocol: An Article-by-Article Textual History Technical paper FCCC/TP/2000/2, United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, available at www.unfccc.int/resource/docs/tp/tp0200.pdf ECN (1999) Potential and Cost of Clean Development Mechanism Options in the Energy Sector. Inventory of options in non-Annex I Countries to reduce GHG emissions Netherlands Energy Research Foundation, Petten, The Netherlands. Eyre, N. (1997) “External costs. What do they mean for energy policy?” Energy Policy 25(1), 85-95. 14
Haites, E. (2001) “’Bubbling’ and the Kyoto mechanisms” Climate Policy 1(1), 109-116. Haites, E. and F. Missefeldt (2001) “Liability rules for international trading of greenhouse gas emissions quota” Climate Policy 1(1), 85-108. Haites, E. and M. A. Aslam (2000) The Kyoto Mechanisms & Global climate change. Coordination Issues and Domestic Policies Prepared for the Pew Center on Global Climate Change, Arlington, VA. Halsnæs, K. (1999) Estimation of the global market potential for the flexibility mechanisms under the Kyoto protocol Risø National Laboratory, Roskilde, Denmark. IPCC (1996a) Climate Change 1995: Impacts, Adaptions, and Mitigation of Climate Change: Scientific-Technical Analyses Contribution of Working Group II to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change edited by Watson, R. T.; Zinyowera, M. C. and R. H. Moss, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. IPCC (1996b) Climate Change 1995: The Science of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group I to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change edited by Houghton, J. T., Meiro Filho, L.G. Callander, B.A., Harris, N., Kattenberg, A. and K. Maskell, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge and New York. Kamal, W. A. (1997) “Improving energy efficiency – the cost-effective way to mitigate global warming” Energy Conversion Management 38(1), 39-59. Leggett, J. (1998) “A guide to the Kyoo protocol: a treaty with potentially vital strategic implications for the renewables industry” Renewble and Sustainable Energy Reviews 2, 345-351. McKibbin, W. J., Shackleton, R. and P. J. Wilcoxen (1999) “What to expect from an international system of tradeable permits for carbon emissions” Resource and Energy Economics 21(3-4), 319-346. Missfeldt, F. (2000) “From Kyoto to Buenos Aires: the new climate regime produces a lot of hot air” European Environment 10, 55-58. Missfeldt, F., and A. Villavicencio (2000) “The economies in transition as part of the climate regime: recent developments” Environment and planning – part b – Planning and Design 27(3), 379- 392. OECD (1997) International Greenhouse Gas Emission Trading Annex I Expert Group on the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change. Working Paper No. 9. Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development, Paris. OECD (1999) Experience with emission baselines under the AIJ pilot phase OECD information paper ENV/EPOC(99)23/FINAL Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development, Paris. Parkinson, S., Begg, K., Bailey, P. and T. Jackson (2001) “Accounting for flexibility against uncertain baselines: lessons from case studies in the eastern European energy sector” Climate Policy 1(1), 55-73. Stewart, R. (2000) The Clean Development Mechanism. Building International Public-Private Partnerships under the Kyoto Protocol. Technical, Financial and Institutional Issues United Nations, UNCTAD/GDS/GFSB/Misc.7, New York and Geneva. Tol, R. and T. E. Downing (2000) The marginal costs of climate changing emissions Institute for Environmental Studies, Vrije Universiteit, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, Document D-00/08. UNDP/GEF (1999) Economics of Greenhouse Gas Limitations. Country Study Series supported by the Global Environment Facility, published by UNEP Collaborating Centre on Energy and Environment, Risø National Laboratory, Denmark. UNFCCC (1992) United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change IUCC/Geneva. UNFCCC (1997) The Kyoto Protocol to the Convention on Climate Change UNEP/IUC/98/2 Bonn. UNFCCC (1999) Activities Implemented Jointly Under The Pilot Phase. Views on the review process of activities implemented jointly under the pilot phase and information on experience gained and lessons learned, including on the uniform reporting format Note by the secretariat FCCC/SB/1999/MISC.I of 23 March. 15
Weyant, J. P. and J. N. Hill (1999) “Introduction and Overview” The Energy Journal Special Issue “The Costs of the Kyoto Protocol: A Multi-Model Evaluation” vii-xliv. Wigley, T. M. (1999) The science of climate change. Global and U.S. Perspectives Prepared for the Pew Center on Global Climate Change, Arlington, VA., available at www.pewclimate.org/- projects/env_science.html. Woerdman, E. (2000a) “Implementing the Kyoto protocol: why JI and CDM show more promise than international emissions trading” Energy Policy 28(1), 28-38. Woerdman, E. (2000b) “Organizing emissions trading: the barrier of domestic permit allocation” Energy Policy 28(9), 613-623. Zhang, Z. X. (1999) Estimating the Size of the Potential Market for the Kyoto Flexibility Mechanisms University of Groningen, Faculty of Law and Faculty of Economics, The Netherlands. 16
You can also read