Patience and "good" institutions: Predicting Real Interest Rates and Institutional Quality?
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Patience and "good" institutions: Predicting Real Interest Rates and Institutional Quality?* Atin Basuchoudhary** Department of Economics and Business Virginia Military Institute Lexington, VA 24450 Phone: 540 464 7450 Email: basuchoudharya@vmi.edu John David Department of Applied Mathematics Virginia Military Institute Lexington, VA 24450 Chap Michie Department of Applied Mathematics Virginia Military Institute Lexington, VA 24450 Abstract: The folk theorem suggests economic institutions that support coordination in markets based in specialization should be quite common as long as people are patient. We test and find supporting evidence for this hypothesis using non-parametric data driven approaches. These approaches suggest that institutions are quantifiably good predictors of real interest rates, even after controlling for the vagaries of monetary policy. This suggests that real interest rates may potentially serve as a proxy for good institutions. *Very rough draft. Please do not quote without permission. **Corresponding author. 1|Page
Introduction. The public choice literature has long acknowledged the tension between predation and beneficial trade in the context of classic coordination games (Mueller, 1989, pp. 9 - 25). This literature looks towards a social contract, the state as it were, that moves individuals from the predatory to the mutually beneficial Pareto improving outcome (Buchanan, 1975). Moreover, this social contract itself is a public good and a matter for public choice. Nevertheless, the public choice literature analyzing the role of the evolution of this social contract has hitherto focused on the size of the community, reliance on formal sanctions, and police enforcement of this social contract (Mueller, 1989). On the other hand, Folk theorems for infinitely repeated games suggest that that all feasible payoffs that payoff dominate the individually rational payoff vector can be supported as payoffs of sub-game perfect equilibria using trigger strategies as long as discount rates are sufficiently close to 1 (Fudenberg & Maskin, 1990). This suggests that cooperation should be quite common as long as people are patient. In other words, the sort of cooperation implied by a social contract that reduces free riding and predation and moves society towards a productive Pareto improving equilibrium is more likely when people are patient, i.e. interest rates are low. In fact, a recent paper (Basuchoudhary & Razzolini, 2013), outlines a formal theory relating the evolution of cooperation and patience. However, it has been hard to find evidence of cooperation among humans when experimental designs simulate institutions by manipulating patience through game termination rules ( (Dal-Bo & Frechette, 2011). Part of this problem may be attributed to faulty experimental design that does not take into account patience endogeneity (Basuchoudhary, et al., 2012; Basuchoudhary, et al., 2010). Of course, evidence for cooperation abounds in the natural world (Nowak & Highfield, 2011). Popular writers ranging from Diamond (2005) to Wright (2001) trace the evolution of cooperation as an institutional matter that follows the arc of history. Greg Clark (2007, p. 167, and 2|Page
2005), points to coordination between technology, institutions, and people as the proximate cause for the end of Malthusian economies. In fact, he notes that interest rates fell quite precipitously in England during this transition from a Malthusian to a modern economy (Table 9, Clark, 2007). The literature in economic growth also suggests that patience is critical for growing economies (Romer, 2001). All of this suggests that the Folk Theorem is indeed at work in generating wealth. Therefore, as a matter of empirical fact, low real interest rates ought to be associated with good institutions. We investigate this link in this paper. Interest rates are a consequence of how people feel about the future and as such arise out of some psychological process that links the availability of money and interactions between people, the institutions that envelop their lives and the evolution of the these very institutions. Then, any attempt to link real interest rates to institutions is fraught with endogeneity problems. Thus, any parametric approach is open to criticism from two fronts. First, there is the risk that a regression based approach misses a variable that explains both institutional evolution and real interest rates. Second, even if good instruments are available to address the first problem, economists tend to use regression based tools to increase in sample fit rather than predictive power. Our non-parametric approach eliminates both problems and can predict real interest rates much better than a simple average. Thus, our approach provides an empirical link between real interest rates and institutions that eliminates many of the theoretical problems that arise from investigating a dataset that may not be distributed in way that adhere to all the assumptions required for a scientifically plausible statistical investigation (Einav & Levin, 2013). Moreover, our ability to use institutional variables to predict real interest rates provides for the first time some real evidence on the role of interest rates as an important factor that links good institutions and the evolution of Pareto improving social contracts. Further, if institutional variables are good predictors of real interest rates then interest rates could potentially serve as a proxy for institutional variables in an observable way. 3|Page
In what follows we try to predict real interest rates using money growth and indices of institutions thought to matter for economic growth. We suggest that if institutional variables can predict real interest rates then institutions generate patience – possibly by reducing uncertainty about the future (cite North). We run a horse race among many prediction techniques and find that ensemble based decision tree analysis provides the most accurate predictions. We then use that technique to find the institutional variables that matter the most for predicting interest rates. Thus, our paper introduces two innovations. First, we find some empirical evidence for the theoretical link between institutions and interest rates. Second, we use atheoretical data mining techniques to investigate whether institutional data can predict real interest rates.1 We describe our data in Section 1. We spend a considerable amount of time describing our scientific methodology in Section 2. Results are described in Section 3. Section 4 concludes. Section 1. Data. We get the data for real interest rates from the World Bank and our institutional variables from the International Country Risk Guide (ICGR).2 Our dataset includes 37 countries(reported in Table 1 in the Appendix) for which we have complete annual data from 1984 to 2007. A set of 22 components, categorized as political, financial, and economic factors proxy institutional health. These components were chosen to give an accurate assessment of the different atmospheres of first and third world nations. Every component within the model is assigned a numeric value, with the lower values indicating high risk and higher values meaning lower risk. This data is then adapted into risk points for all the factors on the basis of a consistent pattern of evaluation. The political risk assessments used in my thesis are produced through subjective analysis 1 We note here that at Susan Athey, a recent winner of the John Bates Clark medal in economics, made an impassioned ple for using data mining techniques to improve the predictive power of economic analysis at a plenary session at the 2013 Southern Economic Association meetings in Tampa, Florida. 2 International Country Risk Guide Methodology 4|Page
of the existing information. ICRG also provides the information and data on which the ratings for the individual risk components are determined, together with its interpretation of that information or data. This allows users of the model to weigh their own interpretation of the information and data against the ICRG staff. Table 1. Variable Descriptions3 Variable Name Description Point Range (Max) Real Interest Rate (RIR) An interest rate that has been adjusted to remove the N/A. The effects of inflation to reflect the real cost of funds to informati the borrower, and the real yield to the lender. The on is real interest rate of an investment is calculated as the provided amount by which the nominal interest rate is higher by World than the inflation rate. Bank. 4 Real Interest Rate = Nominal Interest Rate - Inflation (Expected or Actual) The real interest rate is the growth rate of purchasing power derived from an investment. By adjusting the nominal interest rate to compensate for inflation, you are keeping the purchasing power of a given level of capital constant over time. Government Stability This is an assessment both of the government’s 12 ability to carry out its declared program(s), and its ability to stay in office. The risk rating assigned is the sum of three subcomponents, each with a maximum score of four points and a minimum score of 0 points. A score of 4 points equates to Very Low Risk and a score of 0 points to Very High Risk. The subcomponents (of equal weight) are ● Government Unity ● Legislative Strength ● Popular Support Socioeconomic Conditions This is an assessment of the socioeconomic pressures 12 at work in society that could constrain government 3 Descriptions are from International Country Risk Guide Methodology at http://www.prsgroup.com/ICRG_methodology.aspx 4 http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/FR.INR.RINR 5|Page
action or fuel social dissatisfaction. The risk rating assigned is the sum of three subcomponents, each with a maximum score of four points and a minimum score of 0 points. A score of 4 points equates to Very Low Risk and a score of 0 points to Very High Risk. The subcomponents (of equal weight) are ● Unemployment ● Consumer Confidence ● Poverty Investment Profile This is an assessment of factors affecting the risk to 12 investment that are not covered by other political, economic and financial risk components. The risk rating assigned is the sum of three subcomponents, each with a maximum score of four points and a minimum score of 0 points. A score of 4 points equates to Very Low Risk and a score of 0 points to Very High Risk. The subcomponents (of equal weight) are ● Contract Viability/Expropriation ● Profits Repatriation ● Payment Delays Internal Conflict This is an assessment of political violence in the 12 country and its actual or potential impact on governance. The highest rating is given to those countries where there is no armed or civil opposition to the government and the government does not indulge in arbitrary violence, direct or indirect, against its own people. The lowest rating is given to a country embroiled in an on-going civil war. The risk rating assigned is the sum of three subcomponents, each with a maximum score of four points and a minimum score of 0 points. A score of 4 points equates to Very Low Risk and a score of 0 points to Very High Risk. The subcomponents are: Civil War/Coup Threat Terrorism/Political Violence Civil Disorder 6|Page
External Conflict The external conflict measure is an assessment both 12 of the risk to the incumbent government from foreign action, ranging from non-violent external pressure (diplomatic pressures, withholding of aid, trade restrictions, territorial disputes, sanctions, etc) to violent external pressure (cross-border conflicts to all-out war). External conflicts can adversely affect foreign business in many ways, ranging from restrictions on operations to trade and investment sanctions, to distortions in the allocation of economic resources, to violent change in the structure of society. The risk rating assigned is the sum of three subcomponents, each with a maximum score of four points and a minimum score of 0 points. A score of 4 points equates to Very Low Risk and a score of 0 points to Very High Risk. The subcomponents are: War Cross-Border Conflict Foreign Pressures Corruption This is an assessment of corruption within the 6 political system. Such corruption is a threat to foreign investment for several reasons: it distorts the economic and financial environment; it reduces the efficiency of government and business by enabling people to assume positions of power through patronage rather than ability; and, last but not least, introduces an inherent instability into the political process. The most common form of corruption met directly by business is financial corruption in the form of demands for special payments and bribes connected with import and export licenses, exchange controls, tax assessments, police protection, or loans. Such corruption can make it difficult to conduct business effectively, and in some cases may force the withdrawal or withholding of an investment. Although our measure takes such corruption into account, it is more concerned with actual or potential corruption in the form of excessive patronage, nepotism, job reservations, 'favor-for-favors', secret party funding, and suspiciously close ties between politics and business. In our view these insidious sorts of corruption are potentially of much greater 7|Page
risk to foreign business in that they can lead to popular discontent, unrealistic and inefficient controls on the state economy, and encourage the development of the black market. The greatest risk in such corruption is that at some time it will become so overweening, or some major scandal will be suddenly revealed, as to provoke a popular backlash, resulting in a fall or overthrow of the government, a major reorganizing or restructuring of the country's political institutions, or, at worst, a breakdown in law and order, rendering the country ungovernable. Military in Politics Higher ratings The military is not elected by anyone. 6 Therefore, its involvement in politics, even at a peripheral level, is a diminution of democratic accountability. However, it also has other significant implications. The military might, for example, become involved in government because of an actual or created internal or external threat. Such a situation would imply the distortion of government policy in order to meet this threat, for example by increasing the defense budget at the expense of other budget allocations. In some countries, the threat of military take-over can force an elected government to change policy or cause its replacement by another government more amenable to the military’s wishes. A military takeover or threat of a takeover may also represent a high risk if it is an indication that the government is unable to function effectively and that the country therefore has an uneasy environment for foreign businesses. A full-scale military regime poses the greatest risk. In the short term a military regime may provide a new stability and thus reduce business risks. However, in the longer term the risk will almost certainly rise, partly because the system of governance will be become corrupt and partly because the continuation of such a government is likely to create an armed opposition. In some cases, military participation in government may be a symptom rather than a cause of underlying difficulties. Overall, lower risk ratings indicate a greater degree of military participation in politics and a higher level of political risk. 8|Page
Religious Tensions Religious tensions may stem from the domination of 6 society and/or governance by a single religious group that seeks to replace civil law by religious law and to exclude other religions from the political and/or social process; the desire of a single religious group to dominate governance; the suppression of religious freedom; the desire of a religious group to express its own identity, separate from the country as a whole. The risk involved in these situations range from inexperienced people imposing inappropriate policies through civil dissent to civil war. Law and Order Law and Order are assessed separately, with each 6 sub-component comprising zero to three points. The Law sub-component is an assessment of the strength and impartiality of the legal system, while the Order sub-component is an assessment of popular observance of the law. Thus, a country can enjoy a high rating – 3 – in terms of its judicial system, but a low rating – 1 – if it suffers from a very high crime rate of if the law is routinely ignored without effective sanction (for example, widespread illegal strikes). Ethnic Tensions This component is an assessment of the degree of 6 tension within a country attributable to racial, nationality, or language divisions. Lower ratings are given to countries where racial and nationality tensions are high because opposing groups are intolerant and unwilling to compromise. Higher ratings are given to countries where tensions are minimal, even though such differences may still exist. Democratic Accountability This is a measure of how responsive government is 6 to its people, on the basis that the less responsive it is, the more likely it is that the government will fall, peacefully in a democratic society, but possibly violently in a non-democratic one. Bureaucracy Quality The institutional strength and quality of the 4 bureaucracy is another shock absorber that tends to minimize revisions of policy when governments change. Therefore, high points are given to countries where the bureaucracy has the strength and expertise to govern without drastic changes in policy or interruptions in government services. In these low- risk countries, the bureaucracy tends to be somewhat 9|Page
autonomous from political pressure and to have an established mechanism for recruitment and training. Countries that lack the cushioning effect of a strong bureaucracy receive low points because a change in government tends to be traumatic in terms of policy formulation and day-to-day administrative functions. Section 2. Computational Techniques. Data Mining is a large area in science, engineering and mathematics. It is receiving an increasingly large amount of attention in both the technical and general literature, particularly as the amount of available data has rapidly increased. In fact, it was the 2012 topic of Math Awareness Month. While there are many techniques in this field and an abundance of literature on the subject, we will focus on two techniques: artificial neural networks (ANNs) and decision trees (DTs). An ANN is a mathematical model inspired by the way the human brain processes information. It can also be thought of as a generalized nonlinear multivariate regression. See Hand (2001), Alpaydin (2010), Kononenko (2007) and Bishop (2006) for an introduction to neural networks and data mining in general. The fundamental building block of an ANN is the artificial neuron. An artificial neuron is simply a composition of mathematical functions operations. Assuming the input from the previous layer is denoted by a vector, , the artificial neuron outputs, , have the form, ∑ where g is the generally nonlinear transfer function, , are the weights and are the biases. An ANN consists of an interconnected collection of artificial neurons. For example a two layer ANN with linear transfer functions in the second layer would take on the form, 10 | P a g e
∑ (∑ ) where the superscript indicates the layer in which the weight is used and denotes the transfer function for the kth neuron. The data is split into 3 categories when finding the optimal weights for these networks, i.e. training the networks. The training data is the portion of the data in which the optimization algorithm uses to find the weights. The validation data is the portion of the data that is used to determine when to stop training to avoid overfitting. The testing data is the portion of the data that has no effect on training and is used to validate the model. There is a large number of decisions one has to make when using these networks, including the number of layers, number of neurons, how to portion the data into the various classes, optimization routine and types of transfer functions. We experimented with a large number of these options but ultimately settled on using feedforward backpropagation newtworks, with 2 hidden layers, 8 neurons in the first layer and 6 in the second, tan-sigmoid transfer functions in the first two layers and linear in the third, the Levenberg-Marquardt training routine was used and the data was partitioned into training, validation and testing randomly at percents 70%, 15%, and 15% respectively. The Matlab ANN toolbox was used to perform the computations in this work. In general, a decision tree (DT) is a graph which takes options and weighs them by observations to most properly group them. A decision tree groups these final outcomes by classification, where a regression tree groups them by specific numbers. A very simple regression tree would be one to help you decide how much to tip. For example, if your service was very fast (waited less than 15 minutes for your food) and the waiter kept your glass filled (more than 2 refills) you may want to give a good 20 % tip. For example if your service was slow (waited more than 15 11 | P a g e
minutes for your food) and your drink was empty often (less than 2 refills) you may want to give a low 10 % tip. All the possible results for this regression tree can be seen in Figure 1. Figure 1 Figure 1. A simple example of a DTT designed to predict tip amounts at a restaurant. The process used for decision and regression trees consists of using an algorithm that starts the top, analyzes the data, and chooses the best variable on which to split the data. To create the split, regression trees start by analyzing all input data and every possible split it could make. The split is chosen to minimize the MSE of the prediction compared to the training data. This process is repeated for every node until a decision is made. The decision is made when the mean square error (MSE) of the node is less than the MSE for the entire data multiplied by the tolerance on quadratic error per node, where the default tolerance is 10-6 (Matlab 2012). The Matlab statistics toolbox was used for the calculations in this work. In general these models are trained, i.e. the optimal weights are determined or DT structure and assigned value found, by finding the weights or structure that makes the prediction algorithm most closely match the training set. Several measures of can be used including absolute error, squared error and mean square error amongst others. Unlike linear regression where explicit formulas for the weights can be determined, determining the weights or structure for even a mildly complex ANN or DT is often a complicated nonlinear optimization problem. There are a variety of 12 | P a g e
methods to solve this problem, including steepest descent, conjugate gradient, quasi-Newton methods and our choice the Levenberg-Marquardt algorithm, a method designed to utilize the best parts of steepest descent and Newton based methods. A more expansive treatment of nonlinear optimization can be found in Kelley (1999). As the relationship between the statistics and the point differential is potentially highly nonlinear we need a reasonably sized ANN or DT to capture this relationship. However the problem with complex networks is they can tend to overfit, i.e. fit the data they are trained on very well at the expense of having little predictive capability. In addition as the number of weights or size of tree to estimate increases the probability of finding a local minimum greatly increases. In order to overcome these difficulties people often use ensemble methods or a combination of different learning algorithms. A common technique is to train many networks on random portions of the total data set and then evaluate the individual algorithms by their ability to make predictions on data they have never seen before. Using this one can avoid overfitting the training data and having a single network with suboptimal weights. There are a large number of issues related to how to assemble an ensemble of machines such as how many machines to use, whether the individual machines have the same basic architecture, how do you eliminate less predictive machines and how to combine the machine’s prediction once a final committee is chosen. We will not attempt to discuss all these issues here but we will refer the reader to these surveys of methods for combining networks into committees, as well as other related topics in Sharkey (1999) and Moreiraa (2007). Section 3. Results. First, we use ANN’s and DTs to predict real interest rates. We used the following process: 13 | P a g e
Calculate the mean RIR from all training data. Predict this as the RIR for all of our test data. This is the simplest possible technique, in some ways similar to a continuous version of flipping a coin. Linear regression of our 13 ICRG variables in a year to predict the RIR in the same year. An ANN of our 13 ICRG variables in a year to predict the RIR in the same year. A DT of our 13 ICRG variables in a year to predict the RIR in the same year. We report the prediction accuracy of each method relative to a simple mean in this process in Table 1. We then use ensembles of ANN’s and DTs to predict real interest rates using the following process: Ensembles of 30 ANNs or DTs of our 13 ICRG variables in a year to predict the RIR in the same year. Ensembles of 30 ANNs or DTs using ICRG data from the current and previous 2 years and the RIR from the previous 2 years as well. This created the largest inputs to our machine learning techniques for a total of 41 input variables. In order to evaluate these techniques we used 80% of our data to build our models and a final 20% to evaluate their predictive performance. We then looked at the mean absolute error, the median absolute error and correlation between the predicted real IR and the actual real IR. We then repeated this experiment 30 times and averaged each of these measures of predictive ability. Table 1 contains the predictive ability of each technique. Single model techniques, including linear regression, ANNs and DTs performed poorly. In terms of mean and median absolute error, they all performed worse than our simple benchmark prediction technique of predicting the mean IR of the training data set. The ensemble techniques performed a good 14 | P a g e
deal better, lowering all measures of error and increasing the correlation between the model predictions and actual RIR data. The techniques that used ensemble techniques along with the ICRG data and RIR from the past 2 years was the most predictive method, with the ensemble of DTs being more accurate than the ANNs by a substantial amount. 15 | P a g e
Table 2. : Summary of the various measures of predictive accuracy of all machine learning techniques. Mean over Mean Linear ANNs DTs 30 trials (simple Regression predictor) Mean Abs. 6.72 7.42 7.53 7.43 Error Median 3.45 4.75 4.53 3.77 Abs Error Correlation 0 0.29 0.28 0.43 Table 3. Summary of the various measures of predictive accuracy of all machine learning techniques (ensembles). Mean over Ensemble Ensemble Ensemble Ensemble 30 trials of ANNs of ANNs of DTs of DTs (using past 2 (using past 2 years of years of data) data) Mean Abs 5.68 5.43 5.28 4.81 Error Median Abs 3.40 3.13 2.85 2.45 Error Correlation 0.60 0.60 0.62 0.66 The ensemble of DTs, which used both ICRG data and RIR rates from the previous 2 years, was the most predictive model. We therefore attempted to analyze the factors this technique considered most important in making this prediction. As accurate DTs are generally quite large and we are using ensembles of these we will not attempt to show a picture of one of our DTs. Rather we will use a common technique in determining which variables are most important in the prediction of a DT. To analyze the importance of each 16 | P a g e
of our inputs for the DTs we permute the input variable with each other input variable and average the increase in mean square error averaged over all DTs in the ensemble. Thus, if a branch in a decision tree that was originally based on an important predictor is switched with a decision based on an unimportant predictor we would expect the accuracy to decrease and the mean square error to increase (Matlab 2012). 17 | P a g e
'Money Growth-2''' 'Corruption''' 'Government Stability''' 'Corruption-2''' 'Government Stability-2''' 'Religion in Politics''' 'Ethnic Tensions-1''' 'Law and Order-1''' 'Religion in Politics-1''' 'Government Stability-1''' 'Law and Order''' 'Corruption-1''' 'Ethnic Tensions''' 'Religion in Politics-2''' 'Bureaucracy Quality-1''' 'Bureaucracy Quality''' 'Money Growth-1''' 'Law and Order-2''' 'Investment Profile-2''' 'Ethnic Tensions-2''' 'Democratic Accountability-1''' Series1 'Internal Conflict-1''' 'Bureaucracy Quality-2''' 'Military in Politics-1''' 'Internal Conflict-2''' 'Military in Politics-2''' 'Democratic Accountability''' 'Socioeconomic Conditions''' 'External Conflict''' 'Military in Politics''' 'Internal Conflict''' 'Socioeconomic Conditions-2''' 'Socioeconomic Conditions-1''' 'Investment Profile''' 'Investment Profile-1''' 'External Conflict-2''' 'Democratic Accountability-2''' 'Money Growth''' 'External Conflict-1''' 'Real IR -2''' 'Real IR -1''' 0 0.5 1 1.5 Figure 2. Variable importance of all input variables in our ensemble of DTs ranked from least important to most important. 18 | P a g e
We tabulate the relative importance of each variable, with two lags (the numbers in the variable names refer to the lag length) in Figure 2. Notice that last year’s real interest rates are the most important variable for predicting real interest rate. In a statistical sense this suggests a great deal of autocorrelation. Normally this is a weakness of a statistical study and requires correction to get statistically efficient and consistent results. But our atheoretical predictive technique turns this weakness into predictive strength. Having said that, our ability to rank the other, institutional, variables in order of importance as far as drivers of the real interest rate is concerned clearly suggests that variability in institutions can be captured by real interest rates. Thus, while clearly money growth matters for real interest rates, so does democratic accountability (with a two-year lag) and external conflict (with a one year lag). First, of all the “institutional” variables included in our data, external conflict is most important in predicting real interest rates. Conflict has a way of making life uncertain and people impatient. On the other hand, democratic accountability matters as well if at a somewhat slower rate since democratic accountability from two years ago is the next best variable for predicting interest rates. An entrenched political leadership who can therefore be fearlessly capricious presumably increases uncertainty and reduces patience; connecting democracy to interest rates. At any rate, the reader will note here that we can establish a hierarchy of institutional variables that help predict real interest rates. This directly fits with the idea that institutions that reduce free riding and predation and move society towards a productive Pareto improving equilibrium are linked with patience. Section 4. Conclusion. There is a significant theoretical literature that suggests that patience can resolve social free rider problems that can lead to the evolution of Pareto improving cooperative equilibria. Another skein of inquiry has looked at the effect of social and political institutions on economic growth. Taken 19 | P a g e
together the two strands of literature suggests that the sorts of institutions that help generate the secular growth trend seen since the industrial revolution and societal patience levels – as expressed in real interest rates – ought to be related. Indeed, we find that indices of institutional quality do seem to predict real interest rates with a level of accuracy greater than a simple average. Of course, a significant amount of the variation in real interest rates remains unexplained by the institutional indices chosen by us in a limited data set of countries. However, we suggest that our study provides a baseline for future work in this area. Adding more data would be extremely useful. Moreover, it would be useful to look at the role of individual institutions in their effect on real interest rates. Last, if institutions are good predictors of real interest rates then we suggest that real interest rates can serve as a proxy for institutions. As a practical matter a business, for example, deciding to invest in a country and trying to figure out the degree of institutional quality might compare the real interest rate there relative to some OECD benchmark to help get some information in a less costly way than that collected by the ICRG. At the same time, we suggest that modern data mining techniques abstract away from many of the endogeneity and data structure problems faced by a purely statistical analysis of the relationship between interest rates and institutions. More generally, our methodological approach might improve the problem of predictability in the social sciences. Works Cited Acemoglu, D. & James, A. R., 2012. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty. 1 ed. New York: Crown Publishing Group. Basuchoudhary, A., Allen, S. & Siemers, T., 2010. Civilization and the evolution of short sighted agents. Virgina Economic Journal, pp. 11-29. Basuchoudhary, A., Mazumder, R. & Simoyan, V., 2012. The Evolution of Cooperation: How Patience Matters. SSRN. Basuchoudhary, A. & Razzolini, L., 2013. The Evolution of Revolution: Is Splintering Inevitable?. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1731654 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1731654. Buchanan, J. M., 1975. The Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and Leviathan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.. 20 | P a g e
Clark, G., 2007. A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economics History of the World (Princeton Economics History of the Western World). Princeton: Princeton University Press. Clark, G., n.d. The Interest Rate in the Very Long Run: Institutions, Preferences and Modern Growth. [Internet] London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.. Dal-Bo, P. & Frechette, G. R., 2011. The Evolution of Cooperation in Infinitely Repeated Games: Experimental Evidence. American Economic Review, Volume 101, pp. 411-429. Diamond, J., 2005. Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Succeed. New York: Viking Press. Einav, L. & Levin, J., 2013. The Data Revolution and Economic Analysis. [Online] Available at: http://www.nber.org/papers/w19035 [Accessed 13 February 2014]. Fudenberg, D. & Maskin, E., 1990. Evolution and Cooperation in Noisy Repeated. American Economic Review, Volume 80, pp. 274-279. Mueller, C. D., 1989. Public Choice II. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.. Mueller, D. C., 1989. Public Choice II. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Nowak, M. & Highfield, R., 2011. SuperCooperators: Altruism, evolution, and why we need each other to succeed. New York: Free Press (A Division of Simon and Schuster).. Romer, D., 2001. Advanced Macroeconomics. 1 ed. New York: McGraw Hill. Wright, R., 2001. Non Zero: The logic of Human Destiny. New York: Vintage Books. 21 | P a g e
Appendix Table 1. List of Countries. Australia Bahamas, The Bangladesh Bolivia Botswana Canada Chile China Costa Rica Gambia, The Guatemala Guyana Honduras Iceland India Israel Italy Japan Kenya Malawi Malta Nigeria Oman Papua New Guinea Philippines Sierra Leone Singapore South Africa South Korea Switzerland Syrian Arab Republic Thailand Trinidad and Tobago United Kingdom United States Uruguay Venezuela, RB 22 | P a g e
You can also read