Nonlinear Pricing and Market Concentration in the U.S. Airline Industry
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Nonlinear Pricing and Market Concentration in the U.S. Airline Industry∗ Manuel A. Hernandez and Steven N. Wiggins† October 10, 2008 PRELIMINARY VERSION Abstract This paper provides new evidence on the impact of market concentration on airlines’ nonlinear pricing strategies. Under a second-degree price discrimination setup, where firms compete via a collection of quality and price pairs, we derive testable implications about the effect of market structure on a firm’s relative price schedule. We then test these predictions using a unique dataset of airline ticket transactions during the fourth quarter of 2004 that allows us to group fares according to certain characteristics and restrictions. We find that market concentration differentially impacts various types of fares. In line with our model predictions, there is a non-negligible decrease in the ratio or quality premium of high- to low-type fares as we move to less competitive mar- kets. The ratio of medium- to low-type fares, however, appears to increase with market concentration. Overall, the observed relative pricing pattern reaffirms the negative cor- relation between market concentration and price dispersion found in previous studies. From a welfare perspective, it is interesting to observe that not all travelers are affected in the same way by a decrease in the level of competition. Business travelers, who purchase high-price tickets, end up paying relatively lower fares in more concentrated markets while leisure travelers pay more. Key Words: Nonlinear Pricing, Price Discrimination, Market Structure, Airline Industry JEL Code: L11, L93 ∗ We thank the valuable comments of Steven Puller, Li Gan, Claudio Piga, Jeff Racine, and participants of the PERC Applied Microeconomics Student Seminar at Texas A&M University. † Department of Economics, Texas A&M University, College Station, TX 77843-4228. Please send any comments to mhg@tamu.edu or swiggins@tamu.edu. 1
1 Introduction It is well established that airlines offer highly dispersed prices. In their seminal paper about price dispersion, Borenstein and Rose (1994) show that the expected absolute difference in prices between two passengers on a route is 36% of the airline’s average price. Moreover, they find that this substantial variation in prices decreases with market concentration. The negative relationship between price dispersion and market concentration has also been con- firmed in other related studies (Borenstein, 1989; Stavins, 2001). The observed dispersion in prices, in turn, may arise both from variation in costs and from discriminatory pricing. In this paper, we focus on nonlinear pricing, a strategy which has been given less attention in the literature probably due to data limitations, and examine the impact of market con- centration on relative prices within a menu of fare options. To the extent that nonlinear prices enable firms to engage into second-degree price discrimination, our ultimate goal is to analyze whether market structure conditions affect a carrier’s price discrimination strategy.1 The airline industry provides an ideal framework to study the effect of market con- centration on second-degree price discrimination for two main reasons. First, airlines price discriminate among their customers by offering a range of fares with different characteristics and restrictions so travelers self-select depending on their individual preferences. On this point, Puller, Sengupta, and Wiggins (2007) find evidence that theories in which ticket char- acteristics segment customers and facilitate price discrimination may play a major role in airline pricing.2 Sengupta and Wiggins (2006) also reveal that ticket characteristics explain much of the variation in fares. Second, the menu of fare types offered by carriers is similar across routes with different levels of competition. While some routes are mainly served by one carrier, other routes are served by several carriers with different market shares. This allows us to compare a standard set of ticket options across different competitive settings. Since the pioneer work of Mussa and Rosen (1978) and Maskin and Riley (1984) on monopolistic nonlinear pricing, there has been a growing theoretical literature extending this analysis to competitive environments.3 These models assume that firms compete via a collection of quality and price pairs so consumers self-select which firm to buy from and 1 In order to conclude that nonlinear prices are discriminatory, we must consider costs. Clerides (2004) argues that despite the controversy on the definition of price discrimination with differentiated products, any price variation that cannot be explained by cost differences is usually regarded as price discrimination. We adopt this reasoning in the present study. 2 An alternative theory argues that airline pricing can also be explained in a context of costly capacity, perishable goods and demand uncertainty. In this setting, airlines may use certain ticket restrictions, such as advance-purchase requirements, to screen consumers and divert demand from peak periods to off-peak periods (Gale and Holmes, 1993; Dana, 1998). 3 For a detailed survey on nonlinear pricing and imperfect competition refer to Stole (2007). 2
which quality-price pair to accept from an offered menu. But, as pointed out by Busse and Rysman (2005), most of these general models do not provide a clear prediction regarding the relationship between nonlinear pricing and market concentration. In this study, we work with a two-type model, as in Villas-Boas and Schmidt-Mohr (1999) and Liu and Serfes (2006), that allows us to derive testable predictions about the impact of market concentration on the relative price schedule. Using a unique dataset of airline ticket transactions that includes detailed information on ticket characteristics and restrictions, we are able to group fares into broad categories according to their cabin and booking class, whether they are refundable or not, and whether they have specific travel and stay restrictions or not. We then select the lowest quality group as our base group and analyze if there are any systematic differences between relative fares across markets with various concentration levels. To the degree that we correctly account for several cost and route-specific differences, we are able to evaluate whether market structure conditions do in fact alter a carrier’s price discrimination strategy. The results obtained indicate that market concentration differentially impacts various types of fares. In line with our model predictions, there is an important decrease in the ratio or quality premium of high- to low-type fares as we move to more concentrated markets. Similar results are obtained under both a two-stage least squares procedure and a partially linear smooth coefficient model. Medium- to low-type fares, however, increase with less competition, although this result is not robust to all model specifications. Overall, the observed relative pricing pattern is consistent with the negative relationship between market concentration and price dispersion found in previous literature. From a welfare perspective, it is interesting to observe that not all travelers are affected in the same way by a decrease in the level of competition. Business travelers, who purchase high-price tickets, end up paying relatively lower fares in less competitive markets while leisure travelers pay more. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study to analyze the impact of market concentration on relative fares within a menu of ticket options in the U.S. airline indus- try. Although it is not the main focus of his paper, Borenstein (1989) finds out that increased market concentration appears to raise a carrier’s low-end prices and decrease its high-end prices, but he does not explicitly account for ticket-specific factors such as ticket characteristics (restrictions) and time of purchase. Stavins (2001) uses marginal implicit prices of ticket restrictions as a proxy for price discrimination and concludes that price discrimination decreases with concentration, but she only focuses on two restrictions and on a limited number of routes. The present study is more in line with Busse and Rysman (2005) who examine the relationship between competition and price-size schedules offered for display advertising in Yellow Pages. Contrary to our results, they find out that an additional competitor causes the price of a full page advertisement (high-quality product) 3
to fall proportionally more than that of a quarter of a page (low-quality product). The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The next section provides a brief overview of the existing literature on nonlinear pricing and market structure, and presents a testable model. Section 3 describes the data. The empirical strategy we follow to analyze the effect of market concentration on carriers’ price discrimination strategies is explained in Section 4, together with the estimation results. Section 5 concludes. 2 Theoretical framework There is a growing theoretical literature on nonlinear pricing that builds on the seminal work of Mussa and Rosen (1978) and Maskin and Riley (1984). This literature extends the analysis to settings where several firms compete (Stole, 1995; Villas-Boas and Schmidt- Mohr, 1999; Armstrong and Vickers, 2001; Rochet and Stole, 2002; Johnson and Myatt, 2003; Liu and Serfes, 2006; and Yang and Ye, 2008).4 These models typically consider two dimensions of consumer heterogeneity, one vertical and one horizontal. The vertical dimension captures different marginal valuations of quality while the horizontal dimension captures brand preferences.5 Firms do not observe consumer preferences and compete by offering a menu of quality-price (quantity-price) combinations. Based on their preferences, individuals decide whether to make a purchase and the quality-price pair to buy from one of the firms. These quality-based models of price discrimination rely on self-selection constraints where consumers choose the combination that matches their preferences.6 Most of this literature focuses on the efficiency consequences of competition (Stole, 2007). Specifically, on the quality distortions resulting from the range of product varieties offered under different competitive settings. Similarly, several of these models yield differing predictions regarding the impact of market structure on a firm’s price schedule. Busse and Rysman (2005), for example, point out that in Stole’s (1995) model, competition will have a higher (negative) effect at the bottom of the price schedule since high-valuation consumers are more brand-loyal and the price reductions necessary to attract them are too high. Conversely, in Rochet and Stole’s (2002) model, competition will have a higher (negative) effect at the top of the price schedule since high-valuation consumers can afford more travel costs and are best able to seek out substitutes.7 More recently, Yang and Ye’s (2008) 4 On this matter, Miravete (2007) indicates that models of nonlinear pricing competition are still on their infancy relative to the amount of studies dealing with monopolistic nonlinear pricing. 5 To overcome technical difficulties, most models actually rely on one dimension (vertical or horizontal), perform numerical simulations in case there is not a closed-form solution, or impose further restrictions on preferences to avoid multidimensional settings (Stole, 2007). 6 Firms maximize profits subject to incentive compatibility and participation constraints. 7 Stole (1995) works with a model of horizontal preference uncertainty with a positive correlation between 4
model does not provide a definite prediction about the relationship between competition and prices over the price schedule. They show that competition has a larger (negative) effect on the higher end of the quality range, but at the same time it increases the coverage of individuals with a lower marginal valuation of quality, which in turn end up paying lower prices.8 In this paper, we focus on a discrete model that allows us to explicitly analyze the impact of market concentration on relative prices within a standard menu of fare types. As in Villas-Boas and Schmidt-Mohr (1999) and Liu and Serfes (2006), we work with a two- type model, described below, that yields closed-form solutions and enable us to perform comparative statics analysis, while maintaining the number of product types constant.9 Recall that in the airline industry the variety of fare types offered is similar across markets with different levels of competition. 2.1 A Testable Model10 As in Hotelling’s model, assume that there are two firms located at the end points of a unit-length interval. Firm 1 is located at the left endpoint and Firm 2 is located at the right endpoint. Each firm offers two fares of different quality, a low-quality ticket qL at price pL and a high-quality ticket qH at price pH . We assume that both firms exhibit the same production technology. To produce a unit of quality q a firm incurs in cost cq (c ≥ 0), ± and there are fixed costs of producing good of quality q equal to q 2 2. Consumer preferences, on the other side, differ both in a vertical and a horizontal dimen- sion. In the airline context, the vertical dimension captures different marginal preferences over ticket qualities (restrictions) while the horizontal dimension captures preferences over carriers (or departure times). Firms do not observe these preferences. We assume that there are two consumer types in the vertical dimension. Specifically, there is a fraction λ of individuals with a low marginal preference of quality denoted by θL (hereafter low-type consumers), and a fraction 1 − λ of individuals with a high marginal preference of quality brand preference and marginal valuation for quality, while Rochet and Stole (2002) work with a model of horizontal and vertical preference uncertainty where both dimensions are uncorrelated. 8 Yang and Ye (2008) extend Rochet and Stole’s model by relaxing the assumption of full-market coverage. 9 Villas-Boas and Schmidt-Mohr (1999) analyze the effect of horizontal differentiation (competition), measured through per-unit transportation costs, on loan-granting practices; Liu and Serfes (2006) evaluate the relationship between the degree of competition, measured through distance between firms, and the Gini coefficient in the airline market. 10 The model builds on Liu and Serfes (2006). However, we focus on the impact of horizontal differenti- ation, which measures the degree of competition among firms, on the relative price schedule. Similarly, we make further assumptions that allow us to solve the model as a two-stage non-cooperative game and look for a subgame-perfect equilibrium, as in Piga and Poyago-Theotoky (2005). 5
denoted by θH (hereafter high-type consumers), where θH > θL .11 Each consumer type is uniformly distributed over the unit-length interval with a unit mass. The exact location of an individual in the horizontal dimension is described by the distance d she has to travel to Firm 1 on the left endpoint. As is standard in this type of models, we assume that trans- portation costs are quadratic in the distance an individual has to travel to her preferred firm, and per-unit costs are equal to t. So, the marginal disutility of consuming a good (or flying in a particular airline or departure time in this case) which is not the consumer’s preferred good is increasing in the differentiation between the two.12 Overall, a consumer is characterized by an ordered pair (θ, d) where her vertical type (θ) and horizontal location (d) are independent. Under scenario 1, a type-(θ, d) consumer who purchases fare (q1 , p1 ) from Firm 1 enjoys utility U (θ, q1 , p1 , d) = v + θq1 − p1 − td2 , where v > 0 is the reservation utility obtained from making a purchase. Conversely, if the same individual purchases fare (q2 , p2 ) from Firm 2, she derives utility U (θ, q2 , p2 , d) = v + θq2 − p2 − t(1 − d)2 .13 We assume that reservation utility v is sufficiently high so that the whole market is covered.14 So, Firm i’s, i = 1, 2, decision problem consists in offering fare menu (qiL , piL ) and (qiH , piH ) that maximizes her profits subject to incentive-compatibility (IC) and participa- tion constraints, given the other firm’s fare menu. Formally, 2 qiL q2 Max πi = λ[(piL − cqiL )diL ] − + (1 − λ)[(piH − cqiH )diH ] − iH (MAX) piL ,piH ,qiL ,qiH 2 2 s.t. θH qiH − piH ≥ θH qiL − piL , (ICH ) θL qiL − piL ≥ θL qiH − piH , (ICL ) qiL , qiH , piL , piH > 0, where diL and diH are demands for Firm i’s low- and high-quality fares, respectively. It can be easily shown that Firm 1’s demand functions are given by, 11 Low-type consumers could be regarded as leisure travelers and high-type consumers as business trav- elers. 12 Alternatively, we could think of transportation costs as being linear. But, given that we normalize the length of the interval to one and that we (later) assume that there is full-market coverage, the model yields similar predictions under both linear and quadratic transportation costs. 13 Note that these utility functions imply that firms are only able to sort consumers with respect to their marginal valuation of quality. Refer to Appendix A for further details about the model. 14 This is equivalent to the full-scale competition case in Villas-Boas and Schmidt-Mohr (1999). 6
t + θL (q1L − q2L ) − (p1L − p2L ) d1L = dL = , (1) 2t t + θH (q1H − q2H ) − (p1H − p2H ) d1H = dH = . (2) 2t The IC constraints imply that truth telling is a dominant strategy for all customers. The participation constraint regarding competition for customers with the other firm is already embedded in the demand functions. The other participation constraint is the usual individual-rationality constraint (IR), which is assumed to be slack for all consumers (θ, d) due to the full-market coverage assumption. If we further assume that the quality of the high-type product is an increasing function of the quality of the low-type product, i.e. qiH = δqiL , i = 1, 2, where δ > 1, we can solve this model as a two-stage non-cooperative game and derive a subgame-perfect symmetric equilibrium where (ICH ) binds and (ICL ) does not.15 In the first stage firms set quality and in the second stage they compete in prices. The details of the derivations are presented in Appendix A. As in Villas-Boas and Schmidt-Mohr (1999) and Yang and Ye (2008), we assume that the degree of horizontal differentiation, captured by transportation cost t, serves as an index for the level of competition among firms. A decrease in t could then be regarded as an increase in the intensity of competition.16 We are interested in the effect of t on the optimal price ratio p∗H /p∗L . We also extend the model in two directions:17 Extension 1 : Each firm offers three product qualities (high, medium, and low) to three different consumer types (high, medium and low marginal valuation of quality), each of them uniformly distributed over the unit-length interval. Per-unit transportation costs remain equal to t. Considering that we later group tickets into several categories, the idea is to observe how the price ratio of different product types will vary with the level of competition. 15 We believe that this further assumption is plausible since first or business class tickets could well be regarded as an upgraded version of economy class tickets. 16 Recall that the horizontal dimension captures in our case preferences over carriers or departure times. A lower t implies that passengers will view alternative carriers (flights) as closer substitutes; in the extreme case of t=0, the horizontal dimension becomes irrelevant and the model will reduce to a perfectly competitive market. Additionally, more competitive markets usually exhibit a higher flight density and competing firms schedule their flights at closer departure times between one another (goods are close substitutes), relative to less competitive markets. In our working sample, the average difference in departure times between flights in monopolistic routes is 96 minutes, 65 minutes in duopoly routes, and 44 minutes in competitive routes. 17 For more details refer to Appendix A. 7
Extension 2 : There are only two product qualities and two consumers types, but we allow for different per-unit transportation costs between individuals, specifically tH > tL .18 We explicitly assume that high-type consumers are less reluctant to switch carriers than low-type consumers or it is more costly for them to move away from their preferred carrier or departure time, similar to Stole (1995). Figure 1 shows the impact of t on the optimal price ratio derived from our base model. As can be seen, there is a negative relationship between market concentration and relative prices or, conversely, there is a positive correlation between market competition and relative fares. Provided that low-quality fares decrease proportionally more than high-quality fares with a lower t, it follows that firms will compete more fiercely for low-type consumers with increased competition.19 Figure 2 presents the effect of t on relative prices when we consider three product qualities and three consumer types. We observe a decrease in both high- and medium- quality fares, relative to low-quality fares, as we decrease the intensity of competition. More interesting, the ratio of high to low-quality fares decreases proportionally more than the ratio of medium to low-quality fares with an increase in t. Firms still compete more fiercely for low-type consumers and, to a lower extent, for medium-type individuals.20 Finally, Figure 3 shows how the optimal price schedule will vary with market concentra- tion when high-type individuals are assumed to face a higher per-unit transportation cost than low-type individuals (tH > tL ). In this case, variations in the level of competition are measured through changes in tL and tH . As shown in the figure, there is also a negative relationship between market concentration and relative fares but this inverse relationship is more pronounced with changes in the level of competition for low types, which are also more reluctant to switch firms.21 In sum, under a standard second-degree price discrimination framework we would expect market concentration to have a negative impact on the ratio of high- to low-quality fares, and, to a lower extent, on the ratio of medium- to low-type fares. This seems reasonable 18 As in Liu and Serfes (2006). 19 The fact that absolute fares decrease with a lower t is consistent with the lower market power enjoyed by each firm. The high-quality fare, in turn, must always leave a higher net surplus (information rent) to high-type consumers because they can always buy the low-type product. With increased competition, firms would worry less about providing additional informational rents to high-type consumers because these individuals would enjoy a higher net surplus anyway due to a lower t. 20 It is straightforward to deduce that firms will worry less about high- than medium-type consumers because the former would anyway enjoy higher informational rents with increased competition. 21 Although not reported, absolute fares decrease with either a decrease in tL or tH . This is explained by the incentive compatibility constraints that restrict consumers to select the fare type designed for them. So a decrease in tL , for example, will not only decrease pL , but also pH (in a lower extent), to prevent high-type consumers from buying low-quality fares. 8
in the airline, considering also that low-type individuals are generally less brand-loyal and more price sensitive than high-type travelers. These predictions are also in line with the positive relationship between market competition and price dispersion found in previous empirical studies about airline pricing.22 We now proceed to describe our dataset and empirically examine the relationship be- tween market concentration and relative fares within a standard menu of fare types in the U.S. airline industry. Our goal is to test our model predictions and analyze whether market structure conditions affect a carrier’s pricing discrimination strategy. 3 Data The main data source of this paper is a census of airline tickets purchased between June and December 2004 for travel in the fourth quarter of the same year. The dataset was provided by one major Computer Reservation System (CRS) vendor, and includes tickets purchased directly from airlines, including their websites, and through travel agents and several online travel sites. Overall, the data represents around thirty percent of all domestic ticket transactions in the U.S. in the corresponding quarter. For each ticket sold or itinerary, we have information on the fare paid, origin and destination, segments (or coupons) involved in the itinerary, carrier and flight number, cabin and booking class, and dates of purchase, departure and return. As in Borenstein (1989) and Borenstein and Rose (1994), we define a route as a pair of airports regardless of direction, where one airport is the origin of the itinerary and the other one is the destination. We drop all itineraries other than one-way and roundtrips, and restrict the analysis to direct or nonstop itineraries. We also exclude tickets that in- volve travel with different airlines (e.g. interline tickets). Prices are measured as roundtrip fares, so in the case of one-way tickets the fare is doubled. To avoid holiday peaks, we drop transactions involving travel on Thanksgiving, Christmas and New Year.23 The data includes tickets for flights operated by AirTran, Alaska, American, America West, Conti- 22 It is worth to mention that Borenstein (1985) and Holmes (1989) also uncover the possibility of a positive relationship between price dispersion and competition under a monopolistic competition setup. This will occur in a context where firms primarily sort their customers based on the strength of their brand preferences, so there will be more competition between firms for consumers who are less brand- loyal (probably low-type individuals in our model). Similarly, Gale (1993) developed a simple two-period model of airline price discrimination, where the product is initially homogenous and becomes horizontally differentiated just prior to departure, and finds that price dispersion will also increase with competition. In this case there will be more competition between firms for consumers who are less time-sensitive (probably low-type individuals in our model). 23 We exclude travel on the Wednesday prior to Thanksgiving until the following Sunday. We also exclude all travel beginning on December 22nd through the end of year. 9
nental, Delta, Frontier, Hawaiian, Midwest, Northwest, Spirit, Sun Country, ATA, United, and US Airways.24 Due to confidentiality reasons, the major CRS vendor did not provide information on ticket restrictions. Consequently, the transaction dataset was then merged to historical data from a travel agent’s CRS, containing a large subset of ticket fares, and their restrictions, offered for travel in the last quarter of 2004.25 For each fare listed on this second dataset, we have information on origin and destination, carrier, booking class, departure date from origin, advance purchase requirements, refundability, travel restrictions, and maximum or minimum stay restrictions. The matching procedure followed is fully described in Puller, Sengupta and Wiggins (2007). Basically, an itinerary from the transaction dataset was matched to a posted fare from the travel agent’s dataset based on route, carrier, prices falling within a two percent range of one another, and the itinerary satisfying advance pur- chase requirements, travel and stay restrictions according to the date of purchase, departure and return. In the present study, we restrict the analysis to matched itineraries where we observe at least one thousand observations per route and one hundred observations per route-carrier. This results in 878,169 tickets across 246 routes with different levels of competition. The whole list of routes is reported in Table 1 Since our matched sample represents only 33% of the total transactions observed in the routes analyzed, we proceed to examine if there are any systematic differences in the fare distribution of matched itineraries versus unmatched ones. In Figure 4, we plot kernel density estimates of fares for both groups. Although our matching procedure appears to match a lower rate of tickets within the lower end of the fare distribution, it is clear that we are able to match tickets over a wide range of prices. The resulting dataset allow us to group fares based on certain relevant characteristics and restrictions. Specifically, we group tickets into five broad categories according to their cabin and booking class, refundability, and specific travel and/or stay restrictions. Group F fares include first class tickets. Group 1 fares correspond to refundable business and full coach tickets and Group 2 to refundable coach tickets. Group 3 fares include nonrefundable tickets without any travel or stay restriction, while Group 4 include nonrefundable tickets with travel and/or stay restrictions. Under the plausible assumption that a higher number of restrictions results in a lower ticket quality, Group F is our highest quality group while Group 4 is our lowest quality group. This grouping procedure matches our theoretical 24 With the exception of Southwest, our dataset includes tickets from all of the main carriers operating in the U.S. domestic market during the period of study. We are not able to include Southwest tickets in the analysis since we only have limited data for them. 25 The travel agent’s dataset is incomplete because some of the posted fares in the system are usually deleted after a certain period of time, although not in a systematic way. 10
framework where we assume that carriers offer fares of different quality for consumers to self-select. Our dataset of matched ticket transactions was finally complemented with carrier’s market shares on each route and market structure measures, as well as several controls commonly used in the literature to analyze airline pricing.26 Appendix B provides a full description of all the variables used in the analysis. In the case of market structure variables, we include both a continuous measure, the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index or HHI, and three categorical variables, monopoly, duopoly and competitive, defined according to Borenstein and Rose (1994).27 Other carrier and market controls used include hubs, slot-controlled airports, presence of Southwest and other low cost carriers, distance, total number of flights, per capita income, tourism index and temperature difference. Table 3 presents descriptive statistics of our final dataset. Roundtrip fares range from 62 dollars for a trip Las Vegas (LAS) – Los Angeles (LAX) in American to 4,806 dollars for a trip San Francisco (SFO) – New York-Kennedy (JFK) in United. The average fare paid is 457 dollars or 31.3 cents per mile. As expected, the proportion of tickets sold is negatively correlated with fare quality. The fraction of tickets in Group F through 4 is 5%, 7%, 12%, 28%, and 47%, respectively. Around 61% of the tickets are bought less than two weeks prior to departure, and 25% in the last 3 days. The average flight load factor when a ticket is purchased is 44%. Additionally, more than eight of every ten itineraries involve travel to/from a hub of the operating carrier, three of every four itineraries are a roundtrip travel, and two of every three tickets involve travel during peak times.28 The distribution of tickets by route concentration, reported in Table 4, indicates that 40% of the itineraries in our sample correspond to competitive routes, 48% to duopoly routes, and 12% to monopoly routes. This uneven distribution is mainly explained by the fact that 18% of the routes included in the study are monopoly markets, while duopoly routes represent 48% of the total routes and competitive routes represent the remaining 34%.29 Besides, competitive markets exhibit a higher flight density.30 If we segment the sample by flying distance, we observe a similar distribution of routes (and tickets) by market concentration among most groups. Only in routes involving travel distances between 1,000 26 Table 2 details the sources of information consulted to construct these other variables. 27 We use number of nonstop passengers on a route to calculate carriers’ market shares and market structure measures, instead of number of flights used by Borenstein and Rose (1994). As indicated by Stavins (2001), using either the number of passengers or the number of flights on a route as a basis for market concentration calculations appear to yield similar results. 28 Peak time is defined as Monday through Friday between 7-10am and 3-7pm. 29 In Borenstein and Rose (1994), 12% of the 521 routes analyzed are monopoly markets, 41% are duopoly markets, and 46% are competitive markets. Their period of analysis is the second quarter of 1986. 30 In the markets analyzed, the average number of daily takeoffs in monopoly, duopoly, and competitive routes is 15, 24, and 33, respectively. 11
and 1,499 miles the fraction of monopoly routes (and tickets) is above 18%. On average, we have a reasonable number of tickets per route across markets with different levels of concentration and flying distance. 4 Empirical Estimation Under the theoretical framework described previously, we would expect the ratio of high- to low-quality fares to decrease with market concentration, particularly fares on the higher end of the quality range. To the extent that nonlinear prices enable firms to engage into second- degree price discrimination, our ultimate goal is to examine whether market structure conditions affect a carrier’s price discrimination strategy. This involves isolating the effect of competitive interactions on relative fares from cost and market-specific effects.31 Figure 5 shows a strong correlation between our ticket grouping and fares, as expected. The average fare per mile across tickets in Group F through 4 is 96, 83, 42, 26, and 17 cents, respectively. This positive correlation between quality and price, which is recurrent across itineraries involving different travel distances, perfectly fits in our theoretical setup where we assume that carriers offer different quality-price combinations for consumers to self- select.32 We now proceed to analyze if there are any systematic price differences between these five fare types across markets with various concentration levels. We conveniently select Group 4, the lowest quality group, as our base group so we can examine the impact of market concentration on relative prices on a pairwise basis. A first look at the data indicates that market concentration differentially impacts rel- ative fares within a menu of fare types (see Figure 6). As we move to more concentrated markets, the average fare per mile of Group F or first class tickets decreases relative to Group 4 tickets. In competitive routes, the ratio of Group F to Group 4 fares is close to 5.9 while in monopolistic routes the ratio is less than 4.6. Group 1 relative fares also decrease with market concentration, but to a lower extent. The fare ratio decreases in this case from 4.5 to 3.9. On the contrary, the ratio of Group 2 to Group 4 fares shows a moderate increase as we move to less competitive markets, from 2 in competitive markets to 2.7 in monopoly markets, while Group 3 relative fares do not seem to vary with market structure conditions (the ratio fluctuates around 1.5). More interesting, this relative pricing pattern 31 We do not worry about any cost issues in our model because, as is standard in these type of models, firms are assumed to face a constant marginal cost. As we discuss later, marginal costs in the airline industry are better defined as the sum of a marginal cost of production plus a shadow cost of capacity (Dana, 1998). The latter may vary at the ticket, flight, carrier and market level. 32 Although not reported, this five-type fare structure together with dummy variables for time of purchase and one-way travel and carrier fixed effects, explain on average around 76% of fare variation in each of the routes analyzed. Details are available upon request. 12
generally holds under alternative market structure definitions (see Figure 7).33 The non-negligible decrease in the ratio of high- to low-type fares with market concen- tration, particularly the ratio of Group F to Group 4 fares, matches our model predictions derived in Section II. In our model, as we move to less competitive markets, the lower price ratio results from the fact that low-type fares increase proportionally more than high-type fares. In our data, however, Group F and Group 1 absolute fares actually decrease with market concentration.34 The observed relative pricing pattern is also in line with previous studies that find a negative effect of market concentration on price dispersion (Borenstein, 1989; Borenstein and Rose, 1994; and Stavins, 2001). Provided that these studies do not include first class tickets, it is interesting to still observe a negative correlation between market concentration and price dispersion after allowing for a broader range of ticket qual- ities. A closer look at the data also suggests that market structure conditions affect a carrier’s nonlinear pricing strategy, especially on the higher end of the quality range. Figures 8 and 9 show United Airlines’ (UA) average relative prices, by fare type and day of purchase, for two of her main short-distance and long-distance routes in our sample. Among short- distance routes, Washington-Dulles (IAD) – Boston (BOS) is a competitive market and San Francisco (SFO) – San Diego (SAN) a monopoly market. Among long-distance routes, Los Angeles (LAX) – Philadelphia (PHL) is a competitive route and San Francisco (SFO) – Washington-Dulles (IAD) a monopoly route. With a few exceptions, the ratio of Group F and Group 1 to Group 4 fares is lower in the selected monopoly routes than in the competitive ones, independent of the time of purchase.35 The next step involves examining whether carriers do in fact modify their price discrim- ination strategy when they face less competition. Since we cannot conclude that nonlinear 33 These alternative definitions include the level of HHI and Verlinda’s (2005) market structure categories. In the former case, routes are divided into three groups: HHI less than or equal to 0.5, HHI between 0.5 and 0.8, and HHI greater than 0.8. In the latter case, a route is considered a monopoly if a carrier transports at least 50% of nonstop passengers and the share of the second major carrier is less than one ninth of the share of the first carrier; a route is considered a duopoly if two carriers cumulatively transport at least 50% of nonstop passengers and the share of the third major carrier is less than one ninth of the share of the second carrier; all other routes are considered competitive. 34 As previously mentioned, Borenstein (1989) also finds out that high-end prices decrease in more con- centrated routes while low-end prices increase. His period of analysis is the third quarter of 1987. The relative increase of Group 2 fares with market concentration, which our model fails to predict, together with the relative decrease of high-type fares, suggests that airlines might be following a complementary strategy to induce travelers to purchase tickets of higher quality. We leave this discussion to the end, although it is beyond the scope of the present study. 35 Note that Group F and Group 1 relative fares actually overlap with Group 2 relative fares in the observed monopoly markets, while in the competitive markets they are quite different. 13
prices are discriminatory without considering costs, ideally we would like to compare the price-cost ratio of different ticket qualities under different competitive settings. However, marginal costs are not observed directly. Moreover, marginal costs in the airline industry are better described as the sum of a marginal cost of production, incurred only on the tickets (seats) that are sold, plus a shadow cost of capacity, incurred whether or not the ticket (seat) is sold (Dana, 1998). While the ratio of marginal cost of production across fare types may be neutral to market structure, like the cost of meals and service provided, the expected (and unexpected) shadow cost of capacity ratio may not be neutral.36 Specifically, the shadow cost of capacity will depend on several factors at the ticket, flight, carrier, and route level. Similarly, carriers may face a different relative demand for fare types across markets which, in turn, could affect their price discrimination strategy. In Figures 8 and 9, for example, part of the difference in relative prices across routes may be due to differences in the fraction of business and leisure travelers. Consequently, we cannot assume that the marginal cost ratio and the relative demand for different fare types are invariant to the level of competition, as in Busse and Rysman (2005) in their study on Yellow Pages advertising. The task is then to isolate the impact of competitive interactions on relative fares from other factors that may explain fare variations across markets. We attempt to do so by including in the analysis several controls at the ticket, flight, carrier and market level. The idea is to account for possible differences in (shadow) costs across fares, as well as differences in market characteristics (like population attributes) across routes. 4.1 Model Specification In practice, we estimate two reduced-form models of log airfare on group dummies for fare types, market concentration, carrier’s market share, and a set of controls. Our key variables are the dummy variables for fare groups that measure the quality premium of the different fare types over Group 4 fares, our base group. In the second equation, we interact these group dummies with our market structure measures to examine how these premiums will vary with market concentration. The log-linear fare equations are then given by, 36 For example, assume that there is an excess demand for high-quality tickets from business travelers during peak periods. If, at the same time, competitive routes exhibit a higher flight density during peak periods than monopoly routes, then we would expect the shadow cost of high- to low-quality fares to vary as we move to more competitive markets. The direction of the change is, however, uncertain. As pointed out by Borenstein and Rose (1994), an increase in the number of flights is likely to lower the shadow cost of capacity for flights facing excess demand buy may raise the demand uncertainty for any given flight. 14
3 X ln pijkt = β0 + βf 1 qfi + β2 mktstructurek + β3 mktsharejk (3) f =F +Xijkt λ + α1j + κ1k + εijkt 3 X 3 X ln pijkt = δ0 + δf 1 qfi + δ2 mktstructurek + δf 3 (qfi × mktstructurek ) (4) f =F f =F + δ4 mktsharejk + Xijkt γ + α2j + κ2k + υijkt where pijkt is the price per mile of ticket i charged by carrier j on route k at time t, qfi is a dummy variable for Group f fare, f = F, .., 3, mktstructurek is the route’s market structure (measured through HHI or categorical variables for monopoly and duopoly), mktsharejk is the carrier’s market share on route, and Xijkt is a vector of ticket, flight, carrier and route controls. We specify the error terms to have a carrier effect α1j (α2j ), a route effect κ1k (κ2k ) common to all carriers on a route, and a white noise error εijkt (υijkt ) specific to each observation. The ticket-specific factors include dummy variables for time of purchase (0-3 days, 4-6 days, 7-13 days, and 14-21 days) and one-way tickets. At the flight level, we control for the average load factor at purchase of the itinerary’s flight segments and whether the itinerary involves departure and/or return during peak time. At the carrier level, we control if either endpoint of the route is a primary or secondary hub for the operating carrier. The market- specific factors include a dummy variable to indicate the presence of a slot-controlled airport at either endpoints, categorical variables to indicate if Southwest or other low-cost carriers have more than five percent of the market share on the route, log of distance, log of total number of flights on the route, log of average per capita income at the endpoints, fraction of accommodation to personal income at destination city of itinerary (tourism index), and log of absolute temperature difference between endpoints.37 All of these variables are intended to account for factors, other than market structure, that may explain fare variations across markets, specifically cost and market-specific factors. For example, one-way travel, a higher load factor at purchase or traveling during peak time presumably increases the shadow cost of a ticket. Slot-controlled airports are also supposed to raise the cost of serving a market. Following Borenstein (1989) and Bornstein and Rose (1994), the tourism index is intended to measure the proportion of leisure travelers on each destination city. As 37 Slot-controlled airports include Washington-National (DCA), New York-Kennedy (JFK), and New York-La Guardia (LGA). The five percent threshold to account for the presence of Southwest or other low-cost carriers on a route follows Lee and Luengo-Prado (2005). 15
in Brueckner, Dyer, and Spiller (1992) and Stavins (2001), a larger absolute temperature difference between the origin and destination might also indicate a higher proportion of leisure travelers on the route. It is also widely accepted that the presence of Southwest or other major low-cost carriers induces significant price reductions on the route. Our parameters of interest are βf 1 in equation (3) and, in particular, δf 1 and δf 3 in equation (4). We expect coefficients βf 1 and δf 1 to have a positive effect on prices since they approximate the quality premium of different fare types with respect to our base group (Group 4). The sign of δf 3 indicates how these premiums will vary with market concentration. Naturally, any cost differences across fare types that we are not able to account for may also be embedded in these premiums. To the extent that these differences are basically differences in the marginal cost of production, which are typically neutral to market structure, any variation on the premium across different competitive settings will indicate whether carriers do in fact vary their nonlinear pricing strategy with market concentration. The advantage of working at the ticket level is that we can more accurately account for the shadow cost of fares. 4.2 Estimation Results The estimation results of equation (3), following a two-stage least squares (2SLS) approach, are reported in Table 5.38 We treat carrier effects as fixed and route effects as random, and we address the potential endogeneity of market share and HHI using the instruments proposed by Borenstein (1989) and Borenstein and Rose (1994).39 The carrier’s market share is instrumented using its geometric mean of enplanements at the two endpoint air- ports of the route, divided by the sum of all carriers’ geometric mean of enplanements at the endpoints. The instrument for HHI is the square of the fitted value of market share (obtained from its first-stage regression) plus the rescaled sum of the square of all other carriers’ share. We also instrument log of total number of flights on a route with the log average population at the two endpoints. In Model 1 we measure market concentration using HHI while in Model 2 we use categorical variables for market type (the competitive category is our base group). As expected, the quality premium, over Group 4 tickets, decreases across Groups F through 3. Under Model 1, Group F, 1, 2 and 3 fares are 170%, 108%, 41% and 27% higher than Group 4 fares, other things constant. Under Model 2, these premiums are 170%, 105%, 39%, and 31%, respectively. Similarly, most of the estimated parameters of the control variables result significant and have the expected sign under both models. Tickets 38 For matters of comparison, we also report the ordinary least squares (OLS) results. In both cases, the standard errors are clustered on origin city. 39 We do not use instruments for market type dummies. 16
bought closer to departure time are more expensive than those bought several days ahead. Travelers who purchase 0-6 days in advance end up paying, on average, 15% to 18% more than those who purchase over 21 days in advance. One-way tickets are 14% more expensive than half the price of roundtrip fares. With respect to flight controls, a one standard deviation increase in the load factor at purchase (0.29) is associated with a 4% increase in fares. Tickets that involve travel during peak periods are around 2% more expensive than those during off-peak periods. Similar to Borenstein (1989), airport dominance leads to higher prices. Fares on routes where the operating carrier has a hub at either endpoint are 38-41% higher than fares on routes that do not involve a hub for the carrier. However, route dominance (market share) does not result significant. With respect to route controls, fares are 17-19% higher on itineraries where one of the endpoints is a slot-controlled airport. In routes where low-cost carriers, other than Southwest, collectively have five percent or more of market share, prices are 10-11% lower than in other routes, while in routes where Southwest has five percent or more of market share, prices are 34-35% lower. Besides, the larger the distance traveled the lower the fare per mile paid. A 10% increase in distance decreases the fare per mile by almost 10%. A higher flight frequency also decreases fares while a higher per capita income has the inverse effect. Finally, a one standard deviation increase in the tourism index (0.03), indicating a larger presence of leisure travelers, results in a 4% decrease in fares. The absolute temperature difference between route endpoints does not result significant. Table 6 presents the estimation results for equation (4), where we allow quality premi- ums to vary with market concentration. Note that the estimated coefficients of the control variables are very similar to those under equation (3). As in our preliminary analysis, there is a non-negligible decrease in the premium of Group F fares, over Group 4 tickets, as we move to highly concentrated markets under both specifications. In the first model, the estimated premium decreases from 176% at the 10th percentile of HHI (0.34) to 159% at the 90th percentile of HHI (0.89). In the second model, this premium decreases from 173% in competitive markets to 129% in monopoly markets. Group 1 premium only shows a significant decrease with market concentration under the second specification, particularly from competitive to duopoly markets (from 119% to 93%). Group 2 premium exhibits, in turn, a moderate increase from competitive to monopoly routes, from 36% to 60%. Group 3 premium does not seem to vary across different competitive settings. All of these results are summarized in Table 7. Overall, after controlling for several costs- and market-specific factors, we still observe differences in relative fares (quality premiums) across routes with different levels of competition, especially on the higher end of the quality range. This suggests that market structure conditions do in fact affect carriers’ price discrimination strategy, at least for some airlines, as we discuss next. 17
We performed separate estimations for each major carrier to examine whether this nonlinear pricing pattern is recurrent across major airlines (refer to Table 7).40 In most cases, we find a significant quality premium of the different fare types over Group 4 tickets. However, the decrease in the premium of Group F and Group 1 fares as we move to less competitive markets is only significant for United and Delta. In the case of the former, Group F and Group 1 premiums decrease from 189% and 172%, respectively, in competitive markets to 127% and 94% in monopoly markets. In the case of the latter, the corresponding premiums decrease from 176% and 158% to 112% and 98%. Group 2 premiums of both airlines show, at the same, a moderate increase with market concentration (from 33% to 77% in United and from 43% to 74% in Delta). American also exhibits a significant decrease in the premium of Group F fares, from 145% to 123%, but Group 1 premium increases from 74% to 141%. Northwest, on the contrary, shows an increase in the premium of all high- quality fares with market concentration, while Continental and US Airways do not seem to vary their premiums with market structure. 4.3 Testing for endogeneity of group dummies In light of our results, we now turn to examine whether the key variables in the analysis, i.e. dummy variables for fare groups, are exogenous, as we have previously assumed. According to the revenue management literature, quantity or inventory control is a natural tactic in the airline industry to maximize the revenue of each flight.41 It may be the case that different ticket types sold at different points in time, partly result from optimal quantity adjustments that we do not account for in our estimations and which also affect prices. If so, dummy variables for fare types would be endogenous and the estimates reported above would be biased. Following Wooldridge (2008), we carried out a regression-based procedure to test the null hypothesis that the set of group dummies is exogenous in equation (3), while allowing another set of explanatory variables to be endogenous. Recall that in our estimations we treat market share, HHI and log of total flights on route as endogenous. The first step involves regressing each dummy variable for fare type on all included and excluded exogenous variables used to estimate equation (3) plus dummy variables for aircraft size. We believe that aircraft size is a valid instrument for group dummies since the possible number of fare types offered by airlines are partly determined by aircraft size, while prices are better determined by seat availability at the time of purchase, i.e. load factor at 40 Main carriers include American (AA), United (UA), Delta (DL), Continental (CO), US Airways (US), and Northwest (NW). 41 For a general discussion on this practice, commonly referred to as yield management in the airline industry, see Talluri and Van Ryzin (2005). 18
purchase. The second step consists in adding the reduced-form residuals of the first step as additional regressors in the log fare per mile equation specified in equation (3). This augmented equation is estimated by 2SLS where we still instrument for market share, HHI, and log of total flights, but group dummies and their reduced-form residuals act as their own instruments. We finally perform a heteroskedastic-robust test to evaluate whether the coefficients of the reduced-form residuals in the augmented equation are statistically different from zero. Although not reported, the reduced-form regressions from the first step confirm that the dummy variables for fare types are partially correlated with aircraft size dummies.42 Table 9 summarizes the test results for the second step. It is easily seen that we cannot reject the null hypothesis that the set of group dummies is exogenous under both specifications of equation (3). 4.4 Alternative Estimation To check the robustness of our results, we also performed a partially linear smooth coefficient regression which allows us to model the quality premiums in equation (3) as a function of HHI. That is, 3 X ln pijkt = g0 (HHIk ) + gf 1 (HHIk )qfi + Xijt φ + αj + κk + νijkt (5) f =F where g0 (·) and gf 1 (·), f = F, .., 3, are unspecified smooth functions of HHI, and Xijt are a subset of controls from equation (3).43 We use least-square cross validation and a second- order Gaussian kernel function to estimate the bandwidth of HHI.44 The advantage of this model is that it does not impose any functional form on the relationship between market concentration and quality premiums. Due to the computational burden of this method, we work with a 1% random sample of the dataset (8,709 observations), maintaining the proportion of tickets by route, carrier and fare type. Figure 10 shows how the quality premiums of the different fare types, over Group 4 fares, vary with less competition. Consistent with our previous results, we observe that Group F premium declines in highly concentrated markets. The premium is around 170% at a HHI 42 Provided that we allow for additional endogenous explanatory variables in our estimations, it is impos- sible to perform a Cragg-Donald weak identification test. These results at least confirm that aircraft size dummies are potential instruments for group dummies. 43 Due to multicollinearity in the estimation process, we only include certain controls at the ticket, flight and carrier level. We treat both carrier and route effects as random. 44 For further details on this estimation method refer to Li and Racine (2007). 19
You can also read